Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

15
Let's Trade II5 8. Let's Trade In December 2005, at the Second Conference of Chinese and African Entrepreneurs, China's Premier, Wen Jibao, pledged that China's trade with Africa would rise to US$100 billion a year within five years. Forget the capital markets, forget FDI, forget the US$4 0 billion a year aid programme, and forget trade with any other country in the world - this is just trade with Assuming that nothing else changed, that could be US$100 bl1hon in 2010, US$100 billion in 20II, and the year after that, and the year after that, and the year after that. .. By 2015, just five years later, that would be bIlllOn of trade income - 50 per cent of the trillion dollars of aId that has made its way to Africa in the past sixty years. The difference is, of course, one is laced with bromide, the other steroids. . Economic theory tells us that trade contributes to growth m at least two ways: by exactly increasing the amount of actual goods and services that a country sells abroad, and by driving up pro- ductivity of the workforce - our mosquito net maker from Chapter 3, selling 500 nets a week, could perhaps sell I ,000 he able to export some of them abroad. To do so, his productiVIty would have to increase, which is good for growth. The economic benefIts of trade are, for the most part, a generally accepted truth (see Dollar; Sachs and Warner; Edwards). not all countries that have embraced trade have seen a concomItant rise in their growth. Indeed, countries can be classified into three broad categories: winning globalizers, who have increased trade and seen increased growth; non-globalizers, who eschew trade and have, ullSurprisingly, seen little accompanying growth; and, paradoxically, the losing globalizers, who have but seen no associated growth. Tragically, many Afncan countnes fall into this third group. Why? It all comes down to politics. In an uncertain world, Western countries (notably France and the US) are fearful of relying on other nations for their food in the event of a global war. Moreover, elected Western politicians have remained keen to protect their agricultural markets, and win the backing of the powerful farming lobby. The net result is a protective world of trade restrictions and barriers thrown up around the West, to keep African (and other developing regions') produce out. But developed markets are cru- cial, in terms ofboth purchasing power and size, for African trade, which depends on such countries for much of its export revenue. The members of the Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) - a club of rich nations - spend almost US$300 billion on agricultural subsidies (based on 2005 estimates). This is almost three times the total aid from OEeD countries to all developing nations (of course, some aid advocates suggest compensating Africa for this imbalance with more aid). Estimates suggest that Africa loses around US$500 billion each year because of restrictive trade embargoes - largely in the fonn of subsidies by Western governments to Western farmers. In the United States alone, the total annual amount of farm subsidies stands at around US$1 5 billion, and that number is rising. As a share of farmers' income, subsidies rose from around 14 per cent in the middle of the 1990S to around 17 per cent today. The 2002 US Farm Security and Rural Investment Act gave US farmers nearly US$200 billion in subsidies for the subsequent ten years - US$70 billion more than previous programmes, and represented as much as an 80 per cent increase in certain subsidies. The Europeans are just as protective. The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) eats into around half the European Union's budget of €127 billion (direct faml subsidies alone are worth nearly €40 billion), and EU subsidies are approximately 35 percent oHarmers' total income. What this means is that each European Union cow gets US$2.50 a day in subsidies, I more than what a billion people, many of them Africans, each have to live on every day. For the West, it would appear that everything is sacred: steel, cotton, sugar, rice, wheat, corn, soybeans, honey, wool, dairy

Transcript of Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

Page 1: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

Let's Trade II5

8. Let's Trade

In December 2005, at the Second Conference of Chinese andAfrican Entrepreneurs, China's Premier, Wen Jibao, pledged thatChina's trade with Africa would rise to US$100 billion a yearwithin five years. Forget the capital markets, forget FDI, forgetthe US$40 billion a year aid programme, and forget trade withany other country in the world - this is just trade with C~i~a.Assuming that nothing else changed, that could be US$100 bl1honin 2010, US$100 billion in 20II, and the year after that, and the

year after that, and the year after that. . .By 2015, just five years later, that would be US$50~ bIlllOn of

trade income - 50 per cent of the trillion dollars of aId that hasmade its way to Africa in the past sixty years. The difference is, of

course, one is laced with bromide, the other steroids. .Economic theory tells us that trade contributes to growth m at

least two ways: by exactly increasing the amount of actual goodsand services that a country sells abroad, and by driving up pro­ductivity ofthe workforce - our mosquito net maker from Chapter

3, selling 500 nets a week, could perhaps sell I ,000 w.e~e he ableto export some of them abroad. To do so, his productiVIty would

have to increase, which is good for growth.The economic benefIts oftrade are, for the most part, a generally

accepted truth (see Dollar; Sachs and Warner; Edwards). How~ver,not all countries that have embraced trade have seen a concomItantrise in their growth. Indeed, countries can be classified into threebroad categories: winning globalizers, who have increased tradeand seen increased growth; non-globalizers, who eschew tradeand have, ullSurprisingly, seen little accompanying growth; and,paradoxically, the losing globalizers, who have i~creased tra~e butseen no associated growth. Tragically, many Afncan countnes fall

into this third group. Why?

It all comes down to politics. In an uncertain world, Westerncountries (notably France and the US) are fearful of relying onother nations for their food in the event ofa global war. Moreover,elected Western politicians have remained keen to protect theiragricultural markets, and win the backing of the powerful farminglobby. The net result is a protective world of trade restrictions andbarriers thrown up around the West, to keep African (and otherdeveloping regions') produce out. But developed markets are cru­cial, in terms ofboth purchasing power and size, for African trade,which depends on such countries for much of its export revenue.

The members of the Organization of Economic Cooperationand Development (OECD) - a club of rich nations - spend almostUS$300 billion on agricultural subsidies (based on 2005 estimates).This is almost three times the total aid from OEeD countriesto all developing nations (of course, some aid advocates suggestcompensating Africa for this imbalance with more aid). Estimatessuggest that Africa loses around US$500 billion each year becauseof restrictive trade embargoes - largely in the fonn of subsidies byWestern governments to Western farmers.

In the United States alone, the total annual amount of farmsubsidies stands at around US$1 5 billion, and that number is rising.As a share of farmers' income, subsidies rose from around 14 percent in the middle of the 1990S to around 17 per cent today. The2002 US Farm Security and Rural Investment Act gave US farmersnearly US$200 billion in subsidies for the subsequent ten years ­US$70 billion more than previous programmes, and representedas much as an 80 per cent increase in certain subsidies.

The Europeans are just as protective. The Common AgriculturalPolicy (CAP) eats into around half the European Union's budgetof €127 billion (direct faml subsidies alone are worth nearly €40billion), and EU subsidies are approximately 35 percent oHarmers'total income. What this means is that each European Union cowgets US$2.50 a day in subsidies, I more than what a billion people,many of them Africans, each have to live on every day.

For the West, it would appear that everything is sacred: steel,cotton, sugar, rice, wheat, corn, soybeans, honey, wool, dairy

Page 2: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

Let's Trade II7

The US sugar industry receives US$1 3 bl'U' fear ' . IOn 0 support pery ,European Umon producers receive US$2.7 billio d .the tw b n, an In

o years etween 1999 and 2001 the OEeD d '£: supporte Itssugar larmers to the tune ofUS$6 4 b'll'h

. I lOn, an amount .more thant e total value of sugar exports from d 1 . ,eve opmg countrIes and55 p.er cent of the US$1 1.6 billion annual world sugar trade'

LIke cotton suga b'di h' .. ,r su Sl es urt AfrIca. The charity Oxfamestlmat~d the re~ime has deprived Ethiopia, Mozambique andMalaWI ofpotential export earnings ofUS$23 8 '11' .Th

nu IOn SInce 2001e costs of M b' , .

d I.ozam lque s sugar losses equalled one third of its

eve opment aId from th EU d'. e an Its government's spendinon agrIculture and rural development The EU I . gd . a so supports ItS~ro ~cers by blocking the entry of developing-country importsmt~ Its markets with tariffs of more than 300 per cent. Oxfamestl~ated .that. Malawi could have significantly increased exportsto t e .Umon m 20?~ bu~ that market restrictions deprived it of apotentIal US$32 mIllIOn m foreign-exchange earnings, equivalentto around half the country's public-healthcare budget

It' . d .s not Just eveloped countries that are guilty of d' ,trade m k Ch' lstortmg

. adr ets. ma is reported to support its cotton sector by anestimate US$1.5 billion annually. Turkey Brazil Me' Eand India .. . "XICO, gypt

put US$0.6 bIllIOn mto their cotton sectors during 20011

2002.. But p~rhaps the most egregious examples come from Africaltse~f. AfrIcan countries impose an average tariff of 34 per cent onagrIcultural products from other African nations and 21on th 'd ' per cent

elr own pro ucts. As a result, trade between African countriesaccounts for only 10 per cent of their total exports. By contrast40 per cent ofNorth American trade is with other North A ,". merIcan~ou~tnes, and 63 per cent of trade by countries in Western Euro eIS WIth other Western European countries, p

The glaring trade inequity has led to a lot of talk b t d .ro d £l d ' u esplteun alter roun of the World Trade 0 ,. . .U rgamzatlOn negotIatIOns

- ruguay, 1994, Doha 2001 and on-going, et al. - all the chatterhas amounted to little for Africa.

Perhaps the most notable Western a::euorts to level the trade

A World without AidI16

produce, peanuts, chickpeas, lentils and even mohair. These sub­sidies have a dual impact, Western farmers get to sell their produceto a captive consumer at home above world market prices, and theycan also afford to dump their excess production at lower pricesabroad, thus undercutting the struggling African farmer, uponwhose meagre livelihood the export income crucially depends.With the millions of tons ofsubsidized exports flooding the market

so cheaply, African farmers cannot possibly compete.Look at what has happened to two of Africa's chief exports:

cotton and sugar, both of which have to contend with their

Western counterpart producers.In 2003, US cotton subsidies to its farmers were around US$4

billion. Oxfam has observed: 'America's cotton farmers receivemore in subsidies than the entire GDP of Burkina Faso, threetimes more in subsidies than the entire US aid budget for Mrica's

500 million people.'Yet, the livelihoods of at least 10 million people in West and

Central Africa alone depend on revenues from cotton, includingsome 6 million rural households in Nigeria, Benin, Togo, Mali

and Zimbabwe.In May 2003, trade ministers from Benin, Burkina Faso, Chad

and Mali filed an offIcial complaint against the US and the EU forviolating WTO rules on cotton trade, claiming that their countriestogether lost some US$ I billion a year as a result ofcotton subsidies.

In Mali, more than 3 million people - a third of its population_ depend on cotton not just to live but to survive; in Benin andBurkina Faso, cotton forms almost halfof the merchandise exports.Yet thanks to subsidies, Mali loses nearly 2 per cent of GDP and8 per cent of export earnings; Benin loses almost 2 per cent of itsGDP and 9 per cent of export earnings; and Burkina Faso losesI per cent of GDP and 12 per cent of export earnings. Moreover,a 4

0per cent reduction in the world price (that is, equivalent to

the price decline that took place from December 2000 to May2002) could imply a 7 per cent reduction in rural income in atypical cotton-producing country in West Africa like Benin.

The case of sugar is a similarly sour tale.

Page 3: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

playing field have been the US African Growth and OpportunityAct (AGOAy,3 of 2000, and Europe's Everything But Arms(EBA)4 of 2001, neither of which can claim to have made anoverwhelming impact on the state of play. This may, to someextent, explain why Africa's share of global trade remains at around1 per cent (having fallen from a high of 3 per cent sixty years ago),even though Africa is commodity-rich. It seems truly bizarre thatsuch a large continent in population terms is pretty much irrelevant

in trade terms.AGOA opens US markets to a range of African products,

especially textiles, on the basis that freer trade will create jobsand reduce poverty in many sub-Saharan Africa countries. Forexample, the average duty for garment imports into the US standsat 17.5 per cent, but apparel imports from the twenty-five eligibleAfrican countries into the US are duty-free. These imports are,however, capped at a limit of 3 per cent of total US apparel

imports.In 2003, AGOA exports were worth more than US$I4- billion

(£7.4- billion). While the headlines look strong, the devil, again, isin the detail. Only a handful ofAfrican countries have benefited ­and even then, most of them are the oil-rich and larger economies.Nigeria, South Africa, Gabon and Lesotho account for more than90 per cent of AGO A duty-free benefits, and of the total US$I4­billion export value, petroleum products accounted for 80 percent with textiles and clothes accounting for US$ 1.2 billion.

The picture is not much rosier with the EBA. The EBA isdesigned to give duty- and quota-free access for the forty-eightcountries (thirty-three African nations) described by the UnitedNations as 'least-developed'. But in 2001, trade in goods givenpreference for the first time under its auspices amounted to just0.02 per cent of exports by least-developed countries to the Euro­pean Union. The narrow range of goods eligible, coupled withthe amounts, dramatically minimize these schemes' effectiveness.The process can be arbitrary and absurd. For instance, whereasT -shirts produced in war-torn Somalia are welcomed under theEBA, shirts made in the equally deserving Kenya are excluded.

s

As things stand in 2008, the European Union is still Africa'slargest trading partner (26 per cent), followed by the United States(18 per cent), and then China at 1I per cent (Asia excluding Chinais 1] per cent as well). It is clear that however good their handmay seem, when trading with the West the cards are stacked againstAfrica, and will always be. Western political imperatives againstfreer trade continue to reign, and efforts to depose the currentregime are proving futile. If the West wants to be moralistic aboutMrica's lack of development, trade is the issue it ought to address,not aid. Of course, such are the West's demands that even if all itstrade barriers were lifted, Africa no longer has the technologicalequipment and know-how to compete on many products whereit once had a comparative advantage. Together with environmentaland labour issues, these are now serious barriers to trade.

Although Europe remains Africa's main trading partner, its shareofthe region's foreign trade has dropped to 26 per cent from 4-0 percent in the ten years from 1996. It's time that Africa faced up tothis fact and moved on; time that Africa sat down at another table,with another set ofplayers - ones who deal a fairer deck. For now,China again is just one such player.

China is motoring. It's getting richer and hungrier. Since 1998China has accounted for nearly the entire increase in global con­sumption of major commodities such as copper, tin and alu­minium. But China also needs to feed itself, clothe itself and, asdiscussed, fuel itsel£ All this requires vast amounts of grain, beef,cotton and oil, the very things Africa is poised to provide. WhatChina so desperately needs, Africa has: tea in Kenya, coffee inUganda, beefin Botswana, cashews in Mozambique, cotton in Mali,oil in Gabon - the list goes on and on and on. And, in addition,Africa also accounts for nearly half of the world's production ofbauxite, chrome and diamonds, for more than halfofits cocoa andplatinum, and nearly three quarters of its cobalt.

Over recent decades, China has registered unprecedented ratesofeconomic growth - to the point that, today, China is the world'sthird-largest economy. It has achieved the seemingly impossible ­moving vast numbers of its people from the depths of poverty,

lIS A World without Aid Let's Trade 119

Page 4: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

120A World without Aid Let's Trade 121

decidedly into the ranks of the middle class. Yet the 300 millionin China's rising middle class are just a fraction of its 1.2 billionpopulation. As China's middle class continues to grow, so too will

its appetite.For Africa, this is a golden opportunity.But, in 2008, Sino-African trade was a paltry 2 per cent of

China's total; fortunately these numbers are growing. Between1990 and 2000, trade between China and Africa grew by 450 percent. From 2002 to 2003, it rose over 50 per cent to almost US$I 2

billion and then nearly quadrupled by 2007, jumping to US$45billion. China is now the continent's third most important trading

partner, behind the US and France, and ahead of the UK..As with FD I, the impressive rise in trade between Chma and

Africa has primarily been driven by China's voracious appetite forraw materials, and most notably oil. But, although oil and mininghave dominated trade between the two continents, there are nowwelcome signs ofdiversification, such as agricultural commodities.Burkina Faso sends a third of its exports, almost all of which arecotton, to China, compared with virtually nothing in the mid- I990s.

The trade figures sound fantastic - doubling, tripling and even

quadrupling; on paper it looks like a bonanza. But t~e reali~ isquite different. There are still too many African countnes stan~lllgby the sidelines, unable or unwilling to capitalize .on the 0~VI0USopportunity staring them in the face. A mere five 011- and mm~r~­exporting countries account for almost 90 per cent of Afnca sexports to China (in order of importance, Angola, Sudan, Equa­torial Guinea, Gabon and Mauritania); this at a time when China'sdemand for grain, meat (China's meat consumption has doubledinjust three years) and other foodstuffs is rising at an unprecedentedrate. With only 7 per cent of the world's arable land, and abillion-plus people to feed, China will have to shop everywhere.And it is doing everything it can in Africa to make up the numbers_ offering duty-free treatment to some goods (increasing thenumber of tariff-free imports to over 400, from 190), establishingtrade and economic cooperation zones, and going so far as to setup a China-Africa Joint Chamber of Commerce and Industry.

For some reason, many African countries seem to be reluctantto embrace this eager suitor. There are fears that an African fixationon trade with China, and catering to China's all-pervasive needs,will solidify the continent's status as only a commodity exporter,and history has shown that no country has become rich by relyingon its agricultural exports alone (save, perhaps, New Zealand). Butthis is not about perfection; it's about survival- and survival today.

The theory would go that the trajectory of economic devel­opment starts with agricultural production (African states domi­nate this lowest rung of the economic ladder, mirrored by theirlowest per capita incomes), moves up the curve to manufacturing(currently dominated by Asia), then services, ending up with high­value-added research and development (the latter two stages popu­lated with the world's most economically rich and industrializedcountries - the US, Singapore, Germany, etc.). And, obviously, itshould be every country's dream to attain the highest incomelevels. But many of the most successful Asian countries have madethe transition from commodity exporter to manufacturing power­house. The question is, what has happened to Africa?

While Asian economies were scaling the manufacturing ladder,African nations have (all but a few) been relegated to agriculturalproducers (but even so are sometimes unable to feed themselves).African labour is not more expensive than Asian labour - theconverse is, in fact, true. On pure wages alone, Mrica shoulddominate the world's manufacturing slot (manufacturing does tendto employ lowly skilled workers, so Africa's poor education show­ing ought not to hamper its prospects ofbecoming a manufacturingengine). But once the infrastructure costs are factored in, Africa isa let-down in spades.

Although Africa is the centre ofthe universe on the area-accuratePeters Projection Map (occupying a much-coveted proximity tothe industrialized hubs of Europe and America), it takes way toolong to transport goods on its unnavigable rivers, impassable bridgesand pot-holed roads. Besides, to state the obvious, no profit­seeking company can afford to bet on Africa's unreliable powerand erratic telecommunications as the source of its manufactured

Page 5: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

122A World without Aid

Let's Trade 123

inputs. Of course, were Africa's dire infrastructure predicamentremedied, its chance for higher-value trade (thereby distancingitself from the tag of commodity exporter) could dramaticallyimprove. Thankfully, as discussed in Chapter 7, the recent forayinto Africa by China and others means there is some hope that theinfrastructure will be there for Africa to move up the development

curve.There are also concerns - given that trade works both ways -

that Africa is susceptible to China flooding the markets with cheapmanufactured goods. There is clearly the risk that cheaper Chinesegoods can undercut African manufacturers, putting our mosquitonet producer back out of business. He is definitely out of businessin the aid scenario, and could be out of business in the Chinesetrade scenario, but the important point here is much more nuanced.Crucially, under the aid regime there is nothing else for him to do_ he lives in a sterile landscape, opportunities are scarce, and

corruption is rife. In the trade scenario, even with a modicum ofcorruption, opportunities abound - there is a thriving economy;people are buying and selling. Our mosquito net producer, who'sforced to stop making mosquito nets, might start making hair netsfor a burgeoning middle class; or may in another way need toretool. The point is, as hardhearted as it sounds, it is better to faceeconomic hardship in a thriving economy with prospects than tobe confronted by it in an aid-dependent economy, where there

are none. Mosquito man lives.

Dongo can benfjit from trade

Dongo can clearly benefit from more trade - trade creates employ­ment, improves trade balances, lowers the price of consumer goodsthrough greater imports and generates income for the country'sexporters, but, perhaps most importantly, trade produces incomethat accrues to governments through tariffs and income taxes.

However, common sense should tell Dongo that it would befoolhardy to hitch itself to China alone. Certainly Africa makes up

only 2. per cent of China's trade, so obviously there is scope forexpa~slOn.But, equally, there is a lot ofscope for Africa's trade part­ner~hl~s to de~elop elsewhere, and although China has emerged asAfnca s preemment partner, it is by no means the only one.

India, too, is anxious to trade with Africa. Although the IndianJunior Commerce Minister, Jairam Ramesh, remarked that 'thereis no rac~ between us, the Chinese have left us far, far behind',Indo-African trade has risen from US$1 billion in 1991 to US$30billion in 200712008.6

At the first India-Africa Forum, attended by eight African headsofstate, calling for a 'new architecture' in the Indo-African partner­ship, India's Prime Minister, Manmohan Singh, announced duty­free ac~ess to Indian ~arkets for the world's fIfty least-developedcountnes (LDC), thIrty-four of which are Mrican. India haspledged preferential market access on 92.5 per cent of all LDCexports, including diamonds, cotton, cocoa, aluminium ore andcopper ore.

In just five years (since 2003), African trade to Asia has grownby almost 30 per cent a year.

According to the World Bank economist Harry G. Broadman:skyrocketing' Afro-Asian trade represents the beginningofachang~m trade patterns. Although most trade is still between Mrica and

Eur.ope, J~pan or .North America, Broadman notes: 'what's goingon m Chma, IndIa, and Africa is part of the broader trend in theworld of rapidly growing South-South investment and trade ­trade among developing countries'.

But, like charity, trade begins at home. Africa need not look sofar away: it can look to itself Although since the 1970S therehas been a proliferation of economic and trade agreements - thePreferential Trade Agreement, Common Market for Eastern andSouthe~ Africa, Southern Africa Development Community,EconomIC Community of West African States, East African Com­munity and, recently, New Partnership for Africa's Development-. most of these agreements have had a lot of bark but very littlebIte. No doubt political intransigence and myopia have once againprevailed.

Page 6: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

124 A World without Aid Let's Trade 125There are numerous policies the African leadership should seri­

ously embrace to boost trade and increase regional cohesivenessand integration. A simple decree to remove inter-country tradebarriers, which average more than 30 per cent, would be a goodstart. It is bizarre that shipping a car from Japan to Abidjan, inIvory Coast, costs US$I,500, whereas moving it from Abidjan toAddis Ababa, in Ethiopia, coses US$S,000.7

African leaders must also take a broader view on what a tradingmarket means. There are 10 million people in Zambia, but ISO

million in the Southern African region alone. Similarly, Kenya hasalmost 40 million people, but with Uganda and Tanzania the EastAfrican market is about LOO million. How much more economic­ally (and politically) powerful these regions would be if leaderslearnt to think big. One day soon, hopefully, Dongo could becomepart of a free-trade, single-currency, vibrant economic zone ­think America, think European Union. But also think East AsianMiracle, where regional integration such as the Association ofSoutheast Asian Nations played a vital role .,in ensuring the region'sstartling success.,

Trade is not the panacea ofAfrica's woes - but with the prospectofUS$IOo billion in trade income each year from China alone, itis bound to put a dent in them.

Trade need not just be international. Take a country like Paki­stan, for example, With little trade to show (Pakistan's trade shareof GDP in 2006 was only 37 per cent - less than half the low­income group mean trade openness ratio), it has registered solidgrowth rates - in 2006, Pakistan's GDP growth was around 7 percent. How has it done this? The simple answer is, by generatingdomestic demand for goods and services locally produced (that is,its non-tradeable sector).

African countries must also focus on their non-tradeable sectorby encouraging their entrepreneurs (of course, FDI can boostthe non-tradeable sector also). The entrepreneurs (their small andmedium-sized enterprises) are the life-blood of any economy, andthe crucial emerging private sector in poor countries is the enginefor private-sector-Ied growth. Yet, although small and medium

enterprises (SMEs) are a significant part of the total employmentin the most developed and rapidly developing countries, their shareacross African economies (rather disturbingly given the abundanceof labour) lags behind. Whereas SMEs (defined as formal-sectorenterprises with up to 250 employees) account for as much as60 per cent across countries like Japan, Denmark and Ireland (andmore than 80 per cem in Italy and Greece), Zambia's share ofSMEs is 40 per cent, and Cameroon's just 20 per cent. If thesetwo Mrican Countries are anything to go by there is clearly muchscope for improvement across the board.

Entrepreneurs need a receptive and user-friendly environmentwithin which to thrive, but they also need money. Entrepreneurialfirms are more likely to spring up in countries where there is betteraccess to finance (as well as business environments where it's easierto do business). Fortunately, there are other non-aid ways tofinance themselves and contribute to their countries' development.

Page 7: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

But if trader A does not repay, the group is extended no further

loans.Although, technically speaking, there is no group joint liability

(the group as a whole is not responsible for the loan when onemember defaults), the group is implicitly liable in the sense thatthe behaviour of each individual member affects the group as awhole. 50 very often when difficulties in repayment do arise, thegroup members contribute the defaulted amount (with an inten­tion of collecting the money from the defaulted member at a latertime), thus keeping the loan-cycle turning. In this sense micro­finance in poor countries works much like credit cards in richcountries - borrowers repay their loans because they know that ifthey don't pay the loans they have today, their lender will blacklistthem, and they won't be able to borrow more tomorrow. Thebonds of trust extend not only between the members ofthe group,but also between the group and the bank - there is no legalinstrument between Grameen Bank and its borrowers.

The Grameen model has met with resounding success. At leastforty-three countries around the world have adopted some versionof it. Grameen Bank initially offered micro-finance to 36,000members with a portfolio of US$3. I million when it became abank in 1983. By 1997, it had 2.3 million members and a portfolioof U5$230 million. Perhaps most impressively, its default rates areat less than 2 per cent and, with its success, the bank now providesa host ofother financial services (beyond also insurance and pensionschemes) to the poor - micro-enterprise, scholarships and housing

programmes.According to Grameen Bank estimates from March 2008, over

1.3 million members took micro-enterprise loans (mainly forpower-tillers, irrigation pumps, motor vehicles, and river craft fortransportation and fishing), for a total of over U5$450 million. Onthe education side, scholarships amounting to U5$950,000 havebeen awarded to over 50,000 children, and by March 2008 nearly23,000 students received higher-education loans, many for medi­cine, engineering and professional certificates. Finally, in thetwelve months to February 2008, Grameen housing loans alone

9. Banking on the Unbankable

In December 2006, Muhammad Yunus, a Bangladeshi national,was awarded the Nobel Peace Prize. 1 His work on structuringfinancing in Bangladesh revolutionized the thinking on how tolend to the poorest, and most rural, segments of countries; that is,the communities in which the majority of poor people areemployed in the agricultural sector, often buffeted by unpredictableevents, and live in villages which lack physical infrastructure (roadsor power supplies), making the costs of establishing a fomlal bank­ing network prohibitive.

Professor Yunus's innovation was to find a way to lend to thepoorest of the poor who have no collateral - no house, no car, notangible asset against which to borrow. People whose only nominalpersonal wealth would probably be in the form ofland, where thecollateral is undocumented and legally unenforceable.

Looking across Bangladesh, Yunus realized that although manyvillages had no obvious visible asset, they all shared one thing - acommunity of interdependence and trust. The genius behindYunus's Grameen Bank (literally translated from Bengali as 'Bankof the Village') was in converting that trust into collateral.Z

The mechanics of Grameen Bank's solidarity lending are prettystraightforward. Take a small village with five traders for a basicillustration. Through its micro-lending programme, the GrameenBank lends the group U5$roo. Within the group the U5$roo ispassed on to trader A for a pre-specified period (a loan periodcurrently runs for about one year). At the end of this time, she(97 per cent of Grameen's loans are made to women) has to payback to Grameen Bank the loan amount plus interest (which canbe between 8 and 12 per cent). Trader A is solely responsible forrepaying her loan. When the loan is repaid, the next U5$rooloan is made to the group, which is then passed on to trader B.

Banking on the Unbankable 127

Page 8: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

128 A World without AidBanking on the Unbankable

have reached US$l.I9 million with some 8,300 houses havingbeen built. Since the housing programme's inception in 1984, over

650,000 houses have been constructed.The most truly extraordinary aspect of this extraordinary tale is

their 'No Donor Money, No Loans' policy. In 1995, GrameenBank decided not to receive any more donor funds, and todayfunds itself 100 per cent through its deposits. Although recognizedas the grandfather of micro-credit and micro-lending, GrameenBank has spawned numerous variations all over the world, alltargeting the segment of the population that has fallen through thehigh-street banking cracks. The BKI in Indonesia, Acci6n in LatinAmerica, BRAC in Bangladesh and K-REP in Kenya are just a

sample of the growing and expansive list.In Africa, Zambia offers an interesting case study of how micro­

finance has developed. Traditionally, conservative banking insti­tutions have generally targeted large and established companies (forexample, those in the mining sector) and shown little appetite forsmall businesses and individuals (save a few high-income salariedearners). In a population of around 10 million people, where onlyabout 500,000 are formally employed, some 9·5 million (althoughthis includes children) remained ignored by the banking sector.Enter micro-finance. The many thousands of would-be Zambianentrepreneurs finally had a way to secure capital to fund their

businesses.In practice, like many other poor countries, the Zambian micro-

finance market can be split into three tiers. The first two targetsalaried workers, who pay different rates of interest depending ontheir employer. In the first tier are civil servants (doctors, teachersand military personnel), who by virtue of working for the govern­ment are charged relatively low interest rates. Second come salariedprofessionals, not employed by government (lawyers and bankers)and who, because they work in the private sector and do not havethe security of the government behind them, are charged a higherrate of interest. In each of these two cases, the micro-loan lenderuses the salary as collateral- using the individuals' wage to directly

secure the loan.

The third category, which encompasses the vast majority ofZambia's poor, and for which the Grameen Bank structure wasoriginally intended, are the unsalaried, often rural poor, with vari­able incomes, and generally no access to loan capital- think of awoman selling tomatoes on a side street. Yet this group - the realentrepreneurs, the backbone of Zambia's economic future - needcapital just as much as the mining company to see their businessesestablished and grow.

In Zambia, as in other African countries where micro-financehas started to blossom, the risk oflending to the most risky is oftenreduced through joint liability - the notion that members of agroup ofborrowers are all liable for any loans that a micro-financelender makes to them.

Consider again a group of borrowers in a small rural village,where the lender has virtually no information on the individual~orrowers. Joint liability gets around this infonnation asymmetryIII a number ofways. When forming their groups, borrowers havean incentive at the onset to match themselves with other goodborrowers, and exclude those known to be high-risk. Naturally,this self-selection mechanism helps the lender screen the borrowersand reduce the risk ofdefault. Joint liability also addresses the moralhazard lenders typically face - that is, the risk that once a loan ismade, once the borrower has secured the cash, she defaults. Underjoint liability, other members of the group have a vested interestto ensure their partners do not cheat, to see the loan repaid, so thatthey too can access funds.

Having seen the explosion and success in micro-finance (micro­finance default rates in Zambia are less than 5 per cent), traditionalbanks have w9ken up to the opportunity that hitherto they haveleft untapped. Since 2000, there has been a rapid growth in inter­national investment in micro-lending by various agencies and fundsthat tend to be more commercially oriented. By mid-2004, thisgroup had invested a total of nearly US$23 billion in about 450micro-finance institutions.

B~t micro-finance is not without its naysayers. This type oflendlllg to the poor is criticized as loan-sharking (charging punitive

Page 9: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

13° A World without Aid Banking on the Unbankable 131

and exorbitant rates), as fuelling Ponzi schemes (borrowing fromone lender to payoff another) and as simply supporting recklessconsumption. However, with ever-increasing numbers ofmicro­lenders, and growing participation in this type of lending, theinterest rates charged inevitably become lower and, in this sense,more competitive. As to the Ponzi scheme criticism, the objectionmerely points to the need for more information concerning bor­rowers - who's good and who's bad (which, by the way, is exactlythe information asymmetry that the Grameen model mitigates).And on the issue of consumption versus investment, this appliesto any loan, any time, anywhere.

The important point, not to be overlooked, is that the previouslyunbankable and excluded poor are now part of a functioningfinancial dynamic. With this comes a culture of borrowing andrepayment crucial for financial. development in a well-oiled suc­cessful economy. Small-scale banking to poor people has thecapacity to create enterprise and growth in developing countries.

Lending to the poor is also no longer constrained by nationalboundaries, or by financial institutions. With the advent of Kiva,a California-based interface, pretty much anyone sitting anywherewith a keyboard can lend money to anyone across the planet.3 Thisis how it works: a woman in Cameroon goes on line seeking aUS$200 loan towards her tailoring business. She makes her case,as best she can, and a man in Des Moines, Iowa, lends her US$25of it, someone in Sweden lends another US$25, and the balanceis covered by someone in Japan. The loan is made for a set period,for a pre-agreed interest rate, and she regularly updates her lenderson her progress. In the week - just one week - leading into19 April 2008, over US$625,oOO was lent by almost 3,000 newlenders.

Like the Grameen model (and unlike aid) the default rates havebeen minimal. Thus far, since Kiva's inception in 2005, someUS$30 million has been lent, 45,000 loans made to people inforty-two countries. A wonderful innovation - get involved.

Remember the mosquito net manufacturer who, thanks to aid,is now out ofbusiness? And remember the 176 people (one owner,

ten workers and their 165 dependants) now with no stable income,

dependent on handouts?How much better would it have been ifjust half of the million­

dollar donation had been invested as micro-lending in the countryinstead? Within five years, our mosquito net manufacturer couldhave expanded production to meet growing demand, doubled hisworkforce (and by default provided support for another 150 oftheir dependants), and his product would be there to replace the

nets as they fell into disrepair.Of course, other entrepreneurs, seeing how his business has

flourished and recognizing the ever-present demand for mosquitonets, would venture into the market, thereby lowering the cost of

the nets over time, and of course improving quality.

What should Dongo do?The extension of financial services to people who otherwise

have no access to banks dates as far back as when municipalsavings banks began in Europe in the eighteenth century, andwhen German groups based on the self-help principle and calledsavings and credit cooperatives were first organized by HermanSchulze-Delitzsch and Friedrich Raiffeisen in the middle of the

nineteenth century._In more recent times, micro-credit( o}anizations were

developed in the 1960s to serve Africa and Asia's needs for agricul­tural support, yet most Africans today still have very limited accessto fmancial markets. In Ghana and Tanzania, for example, onlyabout 5-6 per cent of the population has access to the bankingsector, although some 80 per cent ofhouseholds in Tanzania wouldbe prepared to save if they had access to appropriate products and

saving mechanisms.The oldest private, worldwide, fully commercial micro-finance

investment fund is the Dexia Micro-Credit Fund. It is managedby Blue Orchard Finance, a micro-finance investment consultancy,and finances some fifty micro-fmance institutions in twenty-fourcountries. It has investments ofUS$77 million. However, it wasreally not until Grameen Bank's success that micro-finance really

took off.

Page 10: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

132 A World without Aid Banking on the Unbankable r33

Today, micro-finance brings groups ofpeople into the economyfor the first time, by offering the poor a range of saving tools.Beyond the direct capital injection it puts into a borrower'spockets, it can also be a powerful development tool. Even smallloans can boost business productivity gains and contribute to jobcreation and raise family living standards (better nutrition, better

health and housing, more education).By some estimates some ro,ooo organizations (from non-

governmental organizations to registered banks) today offer overUS$1 billion worth of micro-finance loans annually to many mil­lions of customers around the world; projections are that thisamount will have to grow twenty-fold (to US$20 billion) over thenext five years to meet projected demand. But in more extreme

forecasts, some predict even more exponential growth. VijayMahajan, a micro-finance practitioner, puts potential annualmicro-credit demand in India alon~ at U5$30 billion, 10 per centof the estimated global US$300 billion.4 According to an April2006 survey by McKinsey Consulting, India has the potential to

become a US$500 billion market by the year 2020,Growth in most emerging-market regions has been meteoric:

For example, the Bangladeshi organization BRAC signed up 5,000customers in Afghanistan, just six months after setting up there;two Cambodian organizations (Acleda and EMT) each have over80,000 customers; Banco do Nordeste in Brazil has become thesecond-largest micro-fmance operation in Latin America, with1 ro,ooo clients in just a few years; and Compartamos, in Mexico,has nearly doubled the number of its clients in the past year tobecome the largest Latin American programme, with over 150,000

clients.Despite all this expansion, the industry has yet to reach 5 per

cent of the customers among the world poor. Even according tothe Grameen Foundation USA's more optimistic estimates that10 per cent of a potential US$300 billion micro-finance markethas been penetrated, there is plenty of scope for developmentfinancing through micro-lending. It's about time Dongo, and the

rest of Mrica, got involved,

Remittances

The UN estimates that there are around 33 million Africans livin'd h' gOUtSI e t elf country of origin. Nigerians and Ghanaians princi-

pally move to the United States, Malians and Senegalese settle inFrance, and the majority of Congolese make their home in theNetherlands. Some 30 per cent of Mali's population lives else­where. In total, emigrants represent almost 5 per cent of Africa'stotal population, and they are yet another source of money to helpfuel Africa's development.

Remittances - the money Africans abroad sent home totheir families - totalled around US$20 billion in 2006 (remittanceswere US$68 billion and US$1 I 3 billion in Latin America andAsia, respectively). According to a United Nations report entitledResource Flows to Africa: An Update on Statistical Trends, between2000 and 2003 Africans sent home about US$r7 billion each

yea~, a fi~ure t~at even tops FDI, which averaged U5$15 billion,dunng thIS penod. What is more, according to the World Bankthe figures on Africa's remittances are most likely grossly under~valued, as a lot of money makes its way to the continent through

unrecorded channels (Freund and Spatafora estimate informalremittances ~re 35-75 per cent of the official flows); so muchso that remIttances may possibly be the largest source of ex­tem~ funding in many poor countries. At US$5 billion, NigeriareceIves the greatest amount of remittances in Africa, followedby South Africa (U5$1.5 billion) and Angola (US$1 billion).They accounted for roughly 40 per cent of Somalia's 2006 GDPthe same year that six out of fifty-three countries received remit~tance~ in e~cess of US$1 billion. Quite clearly remittances are(and Increasmgly should be) a significant piece of many Mricancountries' financing puzzle.

In July ~006, the UK's Department of IntematlOnal Develop­ment publIshed a report, The Black and Minority Ethnic RemittanceSurvey., which revealed that within black communities 34 per centof Afncans send money home to relatives. Perhaps more startling

Page 11: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

134 A World without Aid Banking on the Unbankable 135

was the fact that of the almost ro,ooo minority households inter­viewed across the UK, Black Africans were found to remit money(an average of around £910 annually, or almost US$I,800; theglobal average per capita is around US$200 per month) more

frequently than any other group.Like the other forms of private capital flows already discussed,

the benefits of remittances are far-reaching.Although the actual remittance sums taken individually are rela­

tively small, taken collectively the remittance amounts flowinginto African nations' coffers (banks, building societies, etc.) areenormous. The US$S6S million that flowed into Mozambique andthe US$642 million that went to Uganda in 2006 most certainly

contributed to bolstering their economies.Remittances can play an important part in financing a country's

external balances, by helping to pay for imports and repay externaldebt. As remittances tend to be more stable than other capitalflows, in some countries banks have used them to securitize loansfrom the international capital markets - that is, to raise overseasfinancing using future remittances as collateral, thereby loweringborrowing costs. Banco do Brasil raised US$250 million in 2002by using future dollar- or yen-denominated worker remittances as

collateral.An April 2008 World Bank publication entitled 'Beyond Aid:

New Sources and Innovative Mechanisms for Financing Develop­ment in Sub-Saharan Africa', estimated that sub-Saharan Africancountries can potentially raise as much as US$I-3 billion by reduc­ing the cost of international migrant remittances, US$5- IO billionby issuing diaspora bonds (a bond issued by a country (or even aprivate company) to raise financing from its overseas diaspora) , andUS$I7 billion by securitizing future remittances - not small·change. Incidentally, India and Israel have raised as much as US$I Ibillion and US$2S billion, respectively, from their diaspora abroad,showing that these schemes can work, and work very well if

executed efficiently.sOn a household level, remittances are used to finance basic

consumption needs: housing, children's education, healthcare, and

even capital for small businesses and entrepreneurial activities - theheart ofan economy. More fundamentally, more remittances meanmore money deposited in the bank, which means more cash thatthe banks have to lend. In Latin America, deposits-to-GDP ratios(a key indicator of a country's financial development) markedlyimproved as a result of high remittances. Naturally, the most directchannel through which remittances have an impact on GDP is byincreased spending by the recipient households.

Remittances make an important and growing contribution torelieving poverty. According to a paper by World Bank econom­ists, evidence shows that a 10 per cent increase in per capitaremittances leads to a 3.5 per cent decline in the proportion ofpoor people. Household surveys in the Philippines indicate that a10 per cent increase in remittances reduced the poverty rate by2.8 per cent by increasing the income level of the receiving familybut also via spillovers to the overall economy. Moreover, this10 per cent increase led to a I.7 per cent increase in schoolattendance, a 0.3 S-hour decline in child labour per household perweek, and a 2 per cent increase in new entrepreneurial activities. 6

All of this is good news, but there is a price to be paid - andone that potentially constrains the growth of remittances to thecontinent. For every US$100 sent to Africa, only US$80 gets there- the middleman takes the rest - while from the US to MexicoUS$85 gets home (that is, a 15 per cent charge), and from the UKto India as much as US$96 Uust a 4 per cent tax) reaches itsdestination.

This form of higher 'taxation' on monies sent to Africa throwsup a double-whammy: it encourages those abroad to send moneysecretly and can ultimately discourage them from sending anymoney at all. In a survey, remitters said that they would send 10 percent more money if costs were 50 per cent cheaper.

The bulk of the transfer cost for remitting money from thesender abroad to the recipient at home is determined in the privatemarkets. Therefore, the high remittance costs can really only bereduced by increasing access to banking and strengthening compe­tition in the remittance industry.

Page 12: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

A World without AidBarlking on the Unbankable 137

However, there is scope for African governments to encourage

greater remittance flows by offering cheaper ways for mon~y tobe sent home. In Latin America, for example, the InternatlOnalRemittance Network facilitates remittance flows from the UnitedStates to Latin America. Similar initiatives in Africa would un­doubtedly do the same. It is encouraging to note that innovativemobile phone technology is making it both cheaper and quickerfor people to send and receive money. In April 2007, a moneytransfer system called M-Pesa was launched in Kenya enablingsubscribers to send large sums of money in an instant transaction.

Within just two weeks of the launch over 10,000 account holderswere registered and more than US$100,000 had been transferred.At the moment the M-Pesa programme only facilitates money

transfers within the country's borders, usually from richer urbandwellers to their poorer rural relations. However, there are plansunderway to roll the scheme out on an international basis, notonly tapping the billions ofinternational remittances Kenyans regu­larly send home, but doing it in the most competitive way - that

is, getting more cash into the recipient'S pocket. .Remittances are, of course, in some sense a form of aId (the

recipient is essentially getting something for nothing). And likeother forms of aid, there is the inherent risk that remittancesencourage reckless consumption and laziness. In 2006, Jamaica'sfinance minister, Dr Omar Davies, expressed concern that themultimillion-dollar flows of remittances to Jamaicans were instil-

ling a culture of dependency over achievement. .Perhaps this is true, but at least some part of the money IS

reaching the indigent and making its way to productive uses. Andunlike aid it does not increase corruption. Indeed, Giuliano andRuiz-Arranz, and Toxopeus and Lensink, conclude that remit-

tances do have a positive impact on growth.

Savings

In April 2005, two young boys stumbled upon US$6,000 whileplaying football in Maiduguri, in north-east Nigeria. Maiduguri isnot Nigeria's bustling capital city ofAbuja or its largest commercialcity of Lagos; nor, for that matter, is it Nigeria's third, fourth orfifth business hubs (those honours go to Port Harcourt, Kano andIbadan). Yet it was here, in Maiduguri, that the US$6,000 wasfound. 7

This money hadn't been lost. As it turns out, in the absence ofa credible, formalized banking system the owner of the cash hadopted to neatly wrap his savings in a black plastic bag and hide hisstash near a rubbish dump.

This incident raises a fundamental question: does Africa lackcapital~ Or might it be that there is a lot of cash in these poorcountrIes - unseen, dormant cash, which simply needs to bewoken? Could it actually be that the countless development agentsand agencies and innumerable man-hours deployed to send cashto Africa have been for naught - attempting to address a problemthat simply does not exist? That, in fact, the core problem withAfrica is not an absence of cash, but rather that its financial marketsare acutely inefficient - borrowers cannot borrow, and lenders donot lend, despite the billions washing about.

In The Mystery if Capital, the Peruvian economist Hernando deSoto suggests that the value of savings among the poor ofAsia, theMiddle East and Africa is as much as forty times all the foreign aidreceived throughout the world since 1945. He argues that werethe United States to hike its foreign-aid allocations to the 0.7 percent of national income (as prescribed by the United Nations atMonterrey), it would take the richest country more than 150 yearsto transfer to the world's poor resources equal to those that theyalready have.

Evidence from India would seem to add weight to this theory.~y some estimates, as much as US$200 billion worth of untappedmvestment potential is privately held in gold in India.s In 2005,

Page 13: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

139Banking on the Unbankable

in Grameen for US$2; localized financial development at its best.What Africa desperately needs is more innovation in the finan­

cial sector. We can put a man on the moon, so we can mostcertainly crack Africa's financing puzzle, jump-start economicgrowth and drastically reduce poverty. But herein lies the key ­innovation. Innovation means breaking out of the mould, andfinding more-applicable ways for Africa to finance its development.There is a history of financial innovation to draw from: the SoftBanks of America's Wild West and the Scottish Banks of theeighteenth century. Both catered to the unsecured and traditionallyunbankable.

At the time of the gold rush in 1800s California, for example,one would have expected the well-established East Coast Americanbanks to have simply migrated westwards, opening branches andsetting up their lending shops on the West Coast to cater to thedemand from those in search of yellow (and black) gold. Instead,what happened was that there emerged hybrid banking structures- a combination of venture capital, where the lenders would lendmoney with the prospect of a portion of the spoils when theborrower struck gold, and standar'd lending practices, where theborrower would have to pay back the principal plus some interest(in this case the lender got no share in the project). To illustrate,under a venture capital (VC) arrangement, the lender would givethe collateral-less gold-seeker US$I,OOO to invest in explorationand hiring all the staff he needed, and in return the lender wouldget 20 per cent of the gold project or all future profits emanatingfrom the project. Naturally, this structure was very different to thestandard banking practices which would have lent out theUS$I,OOO with an interest rate attached. But, of course, understandard banking practices most ofthe borrowers without collateralwould have been excluded. In essence, as is the case in many placesin Mrica today, the gold-rushers of America's Wild West had agood idea, but no collateral which standard bankers would feelhappy to lend against.

The financing revolution of eighteenth-century Scotland wasnot much different in its innovative thinking. By essentially

A World without Aid13 8

India introduced a policy which allowed Indians to excha~get~eirphysical gold holdings (often held in jewellery a~d coms) mto'paper' gold in denominations as low as U S$2: ~stlmates suggest

that this policy unlocked as much as US$200 bl~h?~ ~orth of ~n­tapped investment potential privately held. The mltlatlVe promIsedto bring the poorest 700 million villagers, who purchas~about twothirds of India's gold, into the more formalized bankmg system.Moreover, this gold policy injected more money into the econ~mythan the total FD I India received in 2004 - in that year Indians

poured about twice as much money in.to ~old (aroun~ US$l~billion) as the country received from foreIgn mvestors. W 1th m~rthan half ofIndia' s savings tied up in physical assets, such.strategl~scan bring millions of poor into the banking system, offermg credIt

access to many Indians, and inject capital into the economy.The Indian experience is an example of how a government has

successfully unlocked latent resources. Africa should tak~ note andlook for ways to bring the hidden money into the fmanClal stream.Of course Africans might not hoard gold to the same extent asIndians, b~t many of them do have access to (and no~inal owner­ship of) the land they till. And this is de SolO'S mam argument,that the inability of people across the developing world t.o secu~etheir property rights is what prevents them from unlockmg theuvast capital. What is needed is a functioning and tra~sparent legalframework so that Africans can convert that land lUto collateral

against which they can borrow and invest.It is not the case that African countries do not have legal frame-

works (many inherited from their colonial past); it. is, however,the case that in environments of ralnpant corruptIon the legal

systems are often impotent. ,Savings are a hugely important part of a count~ s g.rowth, and

a country's fmaneial development. Domestic savmg IS the m.ostimportant source of flnancing investment and thus boostmggrowth. Looking back at the Grameen Bank. model, it too i~c1udesa component to encourage saving amongst Its borrowers - m fact,they are required to save and invest. Customers must save US$0.02per week, and new members are required to buy a share of stock

Page 14: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

A World without Aid14°

. I rket (provid-, L. 11 fl dged all-service £InanCla superrna .

becommg a iU y e, 'I d d mmerclal, 11 1 ts of banking - venture capIta, stan ar co ,mg a e emen k' ) ScottIshbanking, investment banking, mercha~t ~a~ m~'e~:c~f a whole

ks could customize the cash and hqUldity n ,~: e of businesses and individual entreprene~r~. ~ankm~ ~~~fi

g are about risk - risk assessment, risk mItigatIOn an 'fmance . h d fi d 't out Even 1

estimation, Scottish fm~ncial engmeersb a k'sl~:~da~d, p~escribedotential borrower dId not meet a an ,

a p , h d no collateral no guarantees, no obvIousrisk profIle (that IS, a h' the bank would tailor

) th than turn t em awayability to repay ,ra er h' k oflIe of the borrower.a lending instrument to meet tens pr . t get the

. ' . h have meant infmite permutatIOns 0Certamly, It mIg t doubt that a fmancingright structure, but there was never any

structure could be found. f h twO independent farmThere is a story, for example, 0 o~ . thel'r individual

, d £i fi ing to mvest m

~a;;:~~~:c~n:~I~:uldo:O;~::~ow to lend to ~ac~ far~~~:~~~:~11 but somehow ifthe two farms were merge ,t elr ns k

a y, t could be struc 'and therefore mitigate,d, a loa~ arrange~:: micro-loans as well

It is this type of mnovatIOn, proVl g . ' cia d(' dditIon to stan r

ffi' hybrid venture capital structures m ao en,ng h Africa should look to replicate in ord~r tobankmg fare), t at t has economIcallybring its masses into the global fold. N°ficounlrythe risk capital to

. fi d' a way to unnesucceed~d ~lthllountd :e:~m-sizedenterprises. For Africa, this isfmance Its sma aan imperative that must be heeded,

Dongo Revisited

After sixty years of dead aid, Dongo is regressing. Its finances standas follows: roughly 75 per cent of the money coming into theeconomy is from foreign aid (essentially, all of which accrues tothe government), capital markets 3 per cent, trade 5 per cent,foreign direct investment (including micro-finance) 5 per cent,and the rest from remittances and savings. This financing portfoliohas been costly, and Dongo is going nowhere fast.

If Dongo is to survive, development finance demands a newway of thinking. It needs to abandon the obsession with aid anddraw on proven financial solutions. Dongo should aim for just5 per cent of its total development financing to come from aid,30 per cent from trade (with China as the lead partner), 30 percent from FDI, 10 per cent from the capital markets, and the25 per cent that is left should emanate from remittances and har­nessed domestic savings. The key is to wean countries off aid byputting them on a tight schedule instead of continuing to givethem open-ended commitments.

Clearly, however, not all African countries are equal, and whatmight be right for Dongo may not be suitable for land-lockedZambia, Zimbabwe and Chad, versus oil-rich Sudan, Nigeria andAngola. But the point is that, in order to succeed and escape themire of poverty and despair, they need a mix of each of thesesolutions and an end to aid-dependency,

It has been shown, from case to case and example to example,that this can be done. In fact, in many African countries some ofthis is already being done, but on nowhere near the scale that isneeded. Implementation (as we shall see) will be challenging, butnot impossible.

The transition from today's low equilibrium to tomorrow'seconomic promise requires proper and active management, as

Page 15: Let's Trade II5 It countries (notably France and the US ...

A World without Aid

challenges will inevitably arise. As described earlier, large capitalinflows, whatever the source, can introduce the risk of Dutchdisease (although Rajan and Subramanian have found no evidencethat remittances hurt export competitiveness). But where privatecapital trumps aid every time is on the question of governance.You can steal aid every day of the week, whereas with privatecapital you only get one shot. If you steal the cash proceeds of aninternational bond issue, you most certainly will not be able to getmore cash this way. The capital markets may be forgiving, but notso forgiving as to be fooled by the same culprit twice. And withoutcash to assuage the restlessness of an army, no despot can stand.

Besides, whereas earnings from trade filter through to manythousands of exporters and remittances accrue to innumerablehouseholds, foreign aid almost exclusively lands up in the hands ofa 'lucky' few. Quite simply, investment money is not as easy tosteal.

Africa's time is now. In the past £lve years there has been goodeconomic and political news from the continent. Helped, in part,by soaring commodity prices, African countries are posting solidgrowth numbers, and, although nascent, positive political changeshave swept across the continent. But these will count for little ifthe proposals set out here, essential for Mrica's growth trajectory,are not implemented. Opportunities abound; investment prospectslie all around, in every sector - agriculture, telecommunications,power, infrastructure, banking and £lnance, retail, property. Howcan they not? With roughly a billion people Africa is a big conti­nent. This continent needs everything: roads, hospitals, schools,airports, food, houses, cars, trains, aeroplanes. There is inordinatedemand, and supply is not coping.

In the near term, external forces like the Chinese can and shouldplaya key role in jump-starring Africa's renaissance. But Mricancountries would be wise to prepare for the eventuality that Chinacould pack up and leave - Africa may not always be the belleof the ball. Countries must after all face up to the reality thatcircumstances change - their resource endowments are not in£lnite,and commodity prices could tumble from the highs of today; but

Uongo KevlSlted14-3

the good news is that some countries a I .this possibility by saving their commodi~:::~~~edgingagainst

The Dead Aid strateoi 'f b .I o~es, 1 em raced wholeheartedly '11

on y turn the economic tide in the short ter ' WI ~otlonger-term growth And h . ill, but also promIsea count's t . as t e gr~wth pIe expands, so too does

firy ax base - another relIable source of clevel

Inance. opment

Good governance trumps aU. In a world f b df d . 0 a governance th

cost 0 omg business is much h' h eeven wh . Ig er, on every level. This is true

. en mvestments are securitized (that is backed b 'fiasset) smce th .k' ,ya speCl ICbeha~iour of ae;I~ premlUm associated with the unpredictable. a government always looms large As 1Issues of bad Ii . ong as

. governance nger overhead (guaranteed to be thcase In a world ofaid-de end) . ew'Il 1 b . P ency , the cost of Investing in Africa

I a ways e exorbItant! h' h(such as skill transfer dY I~ even :vhen the social benefitsinto . 'V" e ucation and Infrastructure) are taken

account. .l et 1ll a w ld f dor 0 goo governance whl'ch 'Unaturally e 'h ' WI

. m~rge In t e absence of the glut of aid the '~fdomg bUSIness in Mrica will be lower (wheth 'th . cost (fIsk)IS securitized or not). er e Investment

The absolute imperative to make Afri' , .to . k . , ca s pOSlt1ve growth trajec-

ry stIC IS to nd the continent of aid-de d .hindered good governance for so long. pen ency, whIch has