LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie...

30
Financial Incentives are Effective - 1 - LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL INCENTIVES ARE MORE EFFECTIVE THAN WE THOUGHT JASON D. SHAW Chair Professor and Co-Director, Centre for Leadership and Innovation The Hong Kong Polytechnic University NINA GUPTA Distinguished Professor and John H. Tyson Chair of Management University of Arkansas To appear in Human Resource Management Journal June 3, 2015

Transcript of LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie...

Page 1: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 1 -

LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN!

FINANCIAL INCENTIVES ARE MORE EFFECTIVE THAN WE THOUGHT

JASON D. SHAW Chair Professor and Co-Director, Centre for Leadership and Innovation

The Hong Kong Polytechnic University

NINA GUPTA Distinguished Professor and John H. Tyson Chair of Management

University of Arkansas To appear in Human Resource Management Journal

June 3, 2015

Page 2: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 2 -

LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN!

FINANCIAL INCENTIVES ARE MORE EFFECTIVE THAN WE THOUGHT

In an editorial nearly two decades ago (Gupta & Shaw, 1998), we outlined the evidence-

based case for the relationship between financial incentives and individual performance.

Drawing on the findings of a meta-analysis of 40 years of financial incentives research (Jenkins,

Mitra, Gupta, & Shaw, 1998), as well as Cameron and Pierce’s (1994) meta-analysis of a broader

array of rewards, we showed that financial incentives were indeed strongly and positively

related to individual performance and further, that incentives appeared to have no negative

bearing on intrinsic motivation, as a number of influential scientists (e.g., Deci & Ryan, 1985;

Pfeffer, 1998) and other writers (e.g., Kohn, 1993) had suggested previously. The research-

based conclusions at that time seemed convincing, if not conclusive.

We hoped that the cumulative evidence would change the tone of the conversation in

the literature and popular press away for the notion that financial incentives are harmful and

toward a comprehensive exploration of the when and why of the effectiveness of financial

incentives. Instead, the contrarian voices appeared to became louder, more varied and,

discouragingly, more popular. A new generation of speakers and authors emerged, covering

much the same ground, but with renewed vigor and technological sophistication. With a

layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point.

His best-selling book (Pink, 2009) and ever-popular internet speeches (nearly 15 million views

at the time of this writing) ignore the accumulated scientific evidence and lambaste pay-for-

performance while purporting to unlock the mystery of human motivation. This is despite the

Page 3: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 3 -

fact that there is much more scientific evidence now, including primary studies, qualitative

reviews (Fang & Gerhart, 2012; Gerhart & Fang, 2014), and meta-analytic summations (Cerasoli,

Nicklin, & Ford, 2014; Garbers & Konradt, 2014). Not surprisingly, the cumulative evidence

shows that financial incentives relate positively to performance, do not reduce intrinsic

motivation, and, in general, are more effective than we previously thought.

In this essay, we rejoin the debate. In the following paragraphs we (1) briefly review the

state of the literature in 1998, (2) highlight new meta-analytic findings and update our

conclusions regarding the financial incentivesperformance relationship, (3) address the myth

that financial incentives erode intrinsic motivation, (4) provide explanations for the presumed

failure of financial incentives, and (5) offer some concluding thoughts and suggestions for

moving forward. In terms of caveats, our review focuses on individual performance outcomes,

primarily performance in workplace settings, although it does include meta-analytic and other

evidence from non-work samples.

We take a broad view of individual performance, but roughly categorize it into quantity

(how much is produced) and quality (how well something is done) dimensions. We also view

individual performance from the organization’s perspective, acknowledging that individuals and

other constituents (labor unions) may differ in their view of the level of individual performance,

but also in terms of the importance of certain performance dimensions (e.g., Guest, 2011;

Thompson, 2011). We focus on the narrow case of incentives and individual performance,

recognizing not only that incentives may not be the best solution in every situation, but also

that factors such as work complexity, coordination requirements, performance measurement

differences, and monitoring systems can affect the decision to use incentives as well as the type

Page 4: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 4 -

of incentive offered (Marsden & Belfield, 2010). In addition, a number of reviews and editorials

have criticized performance-oriented HRM research for a positive normative bent as well as for

ambiguity in the causal sequence between HRM practices and performance (e.g., Kaufman,

2010; Shin & Konrad, in press). These essays are largely irrelevant for our analyses. This review

focuses on individual-level research with stringent designs in which the use of financial

incentives precedes individual performance measurements.

The 1990s – Evidence Shows that “Financial Incentives are Effective”

Prior to the mid-1990s, the organizational literature on the effectiveness of financial

incentives was rather sparse, but was also lacking in systematic summary evaluations. The most

thorough of the summaries came in the form of qualitative reviews such as Jenkins (1986),

Lawler and Jenkins (1992), and Gerhart and Milkovich (1992). Jenkins (1986) compared financial

incentive studies conducted in the laboratory, the field, and in simulations using a qualitative

“voting method.” He concluded that the evidence indicated that financial incentives had

positive effects on performance quantity, and that effect sizes were generally similar across

research designs. The first quantitative summary of the extrinsic reward literature was

conducted by Cameron and Pierce (1994). Their meta-analysis of 96 extrinsic rewards studies

using between-group experimental designs with control groups showed, contrary to assertions

by Deci and Ryan (1985), Lepper, Greene, and Nisbett (1973) and many others, that extrinsic

rewards had no overall negative bearing on intrinsic motivation. The results of this study raised

the ire of proponents of Cognitive Evaluation Theory (CET) in academia (Lepper, Keavney &

Drake, 1996; Ryan & Deci, 1996) and on the speaking-circuit (Kohn, 1996). Cameron and Pierce

(1996) responded by conducting robustness checks of their meta-analytic findings, which

Page 5: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 5 -

yielded similar results (although Kohn’s [1996] suggestion to include a set of poorly-designed,

no-control-group studies was not adopted).

The Cameron and Pierce (1994) study provided the first direct cumulative evidence that

extrinsic rewards were effective and did not diminish intrinsic motivation. The studies were

obtained from the psychology and education literature, however, and did not include

investigations involving actual financial incentives, a legitimate point of criticism. We and others

have highlighted substantive differences between paid work and other situations where

individuals receive extrinsic rewards such as prizes or recognition; these differences could cloud

or change the conclusions drawn from non-monetary incentive studies. Jenkins et al. (1998)

attempted to rectify this situation by collecting and analyzing relevant financial incentives

studies, published over a 40-year period. The inclusion criteria were stringent: eligible studies

had to (a) use non-self-report performance measures, (b) include a control group or a

premeasure of performance, and (c) use actual money as the incentive. Among the curious

details of this meta-analysis was that for all we thought we knew about financial incentives and

performance, the number of studies eligible for inclusion was modest – only 39, or about 1

study per year over four decades. The results were straightforward. Financial incentives showed

a moderately strong positive relationship with individual performance quantity (ρ = .34), a

relationship that was stronger in field settings (ρ = .48) and simulation studies (ρ = .56), than it

was in laboratory studies (ρ = .24). Also of note in the results was that task type did not

moderate the size of the incentivesperformance relationship. An extension of Deci and

Ryan’s (1985) CET perspective is that the effects of incentives should be more negative in

situations where the tasks are intrinsically pleasing. The meta-analysis results showed not only

Page 6: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 6 -

positive relationships across all task types, but that the magnitude of the positive association

was the same in mundane and pleasing task situations.

Only six studies in Jenkins et al.’s (1998) analysis included measures of performance

quality, or how well tasks were accomplished; financial incentives were not significantly related

to performance quality, although the sign was positive (ρ = .08). The accurate, scientific

conclusion from the results was that financial incentives are significantly and positively related

to performance quantity, but not to performance quality. Much was made about this scientific

conclusion; Kohn, for example, interpreted the performance quality findings, as somehow

indicating that financial incentives are significantly and negatively related to intrinsic motivation

(e.g., see Kohn, 1998). Such interpretations simply defy logic. But, the close of the 1990s left us

with additional questions to be answered. The results showed clearly that financial incentives

and performance were positively related, that declines in intrinsic motivation resulting from the

extrinsic incentives were likely mythical, and that there was a dearth of scientific evidence on

the relationship of financial incentives and performance quality.

The New Millennium – Financial Incentives are More Effective than We Thought

Although the meta-analytic evidence of the 1990s revealed a strong pattern of findings

in favor of financial incentives, the paucity of empirical research opened up opportunities for

additional primary research, both primary and summative. It is encouraging that the number of

primary studies has slowly increased, both in the management literature and in other

disciplines including economics, medicine, nursing, and education. Primary studies advance

knowledge, but they also advance confusion, as proponents on both sides of the debate pick

and choose studies which support their views. The need for summative studies has been

Page 7: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 7 -

addressed recently in two new meta-analyses—Garbers and Konradt (2013) focused on the

workplace and included studies involving monetary payments, and Carasoli et al. (2014)

reported a broader meta-analysis of the effects of intrinsic motivation and extrinsic incentives

in the school, work, psychological, and physical domains. These meta-analyses estimated

relationships with incentives across a broader array of performance-related criteria and, in the

latter case, provide strong evidence that extrinsic incentives and intrinsic motivation “are not

necessarily antagonistic and are best considered simultaneously” (p. 980). In short, the

conclusion from research in these intervening years is that financial incentives are more

effective than we previously thought.

Similar to the inclusion criteria in Jenkins et al. (1998), studies in the Garbers and

Konradt (2014) meta-analysis (1) were experimental or quasi-experimental designs with

pretests or control groups, (2) focused on financial incentives (not including other extrinsic

motivators), and (3) included non-self-report performance measures. Their overall meta-

analytic finding (ρ = .32) for individual performance of all types was nearly identical to Jenkins

et al.’s (1998) result, although Garbers and Konradt’s (2014) literature review yielded nearly

four times more studies (k = 116). A primary extension of this new meta-analysis was the ability

to address performance quality in addition to quantity, a key shortcoming in the prior studies.

These authors discovered that the effect size for financial incentives and performance quality

was actually larger (ρ =. 39) than the estimate for performance quantity (ρ = .28). The

association for mixed or undetermined performance outcomes (e.g., ratings of “overall”

performance by supervisors) was also substantial (ρ = .38). Thus, although performance

quantity studies remain the dominant type in the literature, the growing evidence suggests that

Page 8: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 8 -

when carefully-designed financial incentives are used to predict performance quality, the

relationship is just as strong, perhaps stronger, than the relationship with performance quantity.

Cerasoli et al. (2014) took a broader approach, surveying literature in the psychological,

educational, medical, and business areas and focusing on research that specifically

operationalized intrinsic motivation. Like Cameron and Pierce (1994), these authors took a

broad view of extrinsic incentives including financial payments, prizes, and credits. Their

findings were striking. When extrinsic incentives were not offered, the relationship between

intrinsic motivation and performance was positive, modest, and significant (ρ = .27). When

extrinsic incentives were offered, the relationship between intrinsic motivation and

performance was stronger (ρ = .45 when extrinsic incentives were indirectly salient and ρ = .30

when extrinsic incentives were directly salient). The authors drew some interesting conclusions:

“An unexpected main effect for incentivization was observed, such that the predictive validity

of intrinsic motivation did not erode, but in fact increased in the presence of incentives. Thus,

incentivization actually boosted the intrinsic motivation—performance link” (p. 996).

Two new meta-analyses from health-care (Giles, Robalino, McColl, Sniehotta, & Adams,

2014) and psychological (Byron & Khazanchi, 2012) researchers provide strong ancillary

evidence as well. Giles et al.’s (2014) meta-analysis revealed that financial incentives relate to a

number of functional health-related behavior behaviors including smoking cessation (short- and

long-term) and vaccination compliance. In a meta-analysis of 34 experimental and 8 non-

experimental studies, Byron and Khazanchi (2012) found that individuals receiving incentives

contingent on creative performance were indeed more creative.

Page 9: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 9 -

The Myth of Intrinsic Motivation Erosion

The claim that extrinsic rewards erode intrinsic motivation is popular and persistent

among professional speakers (e.g., Kohn, 1993; 1998; Pink, 2009) and academics (e.g., Pfeffer,

1998) and is pervasive across many disciplines including management, accounting, and

education (see Gerhart & Fang, 2014, for a review). As noted above, this claim has been

debunked quantitatively, but there are other qualitative issues as well.

Academically, the claim is rooted in CET (Deci & Ryan, 1985), and largely based on the

findings from “free-time” studies (Gerhart & Fang, 2014), where the behavior of children

playing a game is observed when extrinsic rewards are given and when they are withdrawn.

Compared to control conditions, children in extrinsic rewards conditions tend to play pleasing

games for a shorter period of time following the removal of the incentive. This effect is

interpreted as evidence that the use of extrinsic rewards diminishes the children’s inherent

pleasure in the game.

Several authors have pointed to problems with this interpretation. Gerhart and Fang

(2014) questioned the applicability of “free-time” research to the workplace and to financial

incentives. Bartol and Locke (2000) argued that “what people do during the time they are not

being paid is of no importance” (p. 108). In addition, there is compelling evidence

(acknowledged by CET founders themselves) that adults and children differ in their ability to

separate the “informational and controlling aspects of rewards” (Deci et al., 1999: 656). Indeed,

in workplace settings, evidence suggests that people feel more autonomy when they are paid

for performance (Fang & Gerhart, 2012). These and similar issues led Gagne and Deci (2005) to

acknowledge the inherent risks in using CET principles as a foundation for work motivation.

Page 10: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 10 -

An additional concern not previously identified is that people could have negative

reactions to the withdrawal of extrinsic rewards, not because money erodes intrinsic

motivation, but because of the arbitrary fashion in which the incentive is removed—people do

not like arbitrary and unexplained decisions about their rewards. A recent field experiment

(Bareket-Bojmel, Hochman, & Ariely, in press) speaks to this issue. In a field experiment, the

authors reported a productivity increase of more than 5% when short-term incentives (cash

payments or vouchers) or verbal rewards were offered. But when monetary incentives were

dropped without explanation, productivity declined. The authors explained their findings with

the traditional CET view, under the assumption that workers’ intrinsic motivation was damaged.

This explanation is untenable for several reasons. One, we should keep in mind that

productivity increased when incentives were offered. Two, the bonuses appear to have been

discontinued without explanation. Workers most likely were confused and angered by the

injustice of the decision, particularly since their productivity had increased. The withdrawal of

the incentive could well symbolize a punishment for higher productivity. In other words, the

problem resides in the way the incentives were administered (and arbitrarily deactivated)

rather than in the use of extrinsic incentives per se. A surfeit of studies on pay fairness (Shaw &

Gupta, 2001; Shaw, in press), unexplained variation in pay (Conroy, Gupta, Shaw, & Park, 2014;

Kepes, Delery, & Gupta, 2009; Shaw, Gupta, & Delery, 2002; Shaw, 2014; Trevor, Reilly, &

Gerhart,, 2012), explanations and procedural justice (e.g., Shaw, Wild, & Colquitt, 2003) tell us

clearly that individuals will react negatively – attitudinally and behaviorally – when unfair and

fickle decisions are made about financial incentives and other important workplace issues.

Page 11: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 11 -

In short, the corrosive effects of financial incentives on intrinsic motivation in the

workplace are mythical. The evidence conclusively demonstrates their beneficial effects instead

(Cerasoli et al., 2014). What the CET and Bareket-Bojmel et al. (in press) studies show are the

negative effects of treating people arbitrarily and unjustly, a point long emphasized by justice

and compensation researchers.

But What About the Disconfirming Evidence?

We noted earlier that researchers and professional speakers often pick and choose

among studies to support their particular arguments. The scientific and popular literatures

include examples of the failures of financial incentives—studies showing weak or negative

effects of financial incentives on individual performance and other outcomes. This raises the

question: If financial incentives effective, why do disconfirming studies appear in the literature?

There are at least two responses to this conundrum. For one, scientists understand that the

results of a given study may not be representative of the nature of a relationship in the

population of studies. There are differences across studies in terms of sample characteristics,

sample size, research design, measurement, and, of course, error, which could lead to

somewhat different findings across primary studies. As an example, Park and Shaw’s (2013)

meta-analysis of the relationship between turnover rates and organizational performance

revealed a stable, moderate-in-magnitude, literature-level correlation between these variables.

But, a stem-and-leaf plot of the correlation distribution across studies reveals a number of

studies with near-zero association and a few with positive associations. It would be simple

enough to cherry-pick a set of studies and make a case that organizations should strive to

increase turnover rates in order to improve performance. This would, of course, be misleading,

Page 12: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 12 -

inaccurate, and irresponsible. This is why meta-analytic results are important. They summate

across the peculiarities and idiosyncrasies of individual studies and give us an indication of the

sign and magnitude of the association, in general. In the case of incentives, summative evidence

clearly shows financial incentives relate positively to performance quality and quantity and not

only have no negative bearing on intrinsic motivation, but seem to enhance its potency in

predicting performance.

Two, a closer examination of many of the “failures” reveals design and other problems

which were most likely responsible, as in the case of the Bareket-Bojmel et al. (in press) study

discussed above. Almost forty years ago, Lawler and Rhode (1976) and Kerr (1975) cautioned

against the dysfunctional consequences of control systems and the folly of rewarding A while

hoping for B. Unfortunately, many of these cautions are ignored in the research on financial

incentives. When these issues are accounted for, we find that financial incentives often work

exactly as they are designed, although not always as the designers hoped. The underlying

reasons for the supposed failures can be grouped broadly into three categories – problems with

study design, problems with incentive system design, and problems with incentive system

implementation. It is to these we turn next.

Problems with Study Design. Clear examples of problems with study design appear in

the pay dispersion literature. Pay dispersion—the spread of pay across employees—is, at least

in part, attributable to the use of financial incentives such as merit pay. Pay dispersion is

sometimes reported as having negative effects on employee outcomes (Bloom, 1999; Pfeffer &

Davis-Blake, 1992; Pfeffer & Langton, 1993). But, as Gerhart and Rynes (2003) noted, studies

reporting such negative effects usually control for employee performance. Thus, the observed

Page 13: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 13 -

negative effects of dispersion are attributable to non-performance (and not performance)

factors. In other words, they capture non-financial-incentives-based variance in the spread of

pay. When organizations spread pay based on legitimate performance-related criteria pay

dispersion is positively related to performance (Kepes et al., 2009; Shaw et al., 2002; Trevor et

al., 2012) and organizations are more likely to keep their best performers (Shaw, 2015). For

more detailed reviews of problems in the design of pay dispersion studies, see Conroy et al.

(2014), Gupta et al. (2012), and Shaw (2014).

Another example of problems in study design occurs in the research by Ariely and

colleagues (e.g., Ariely, Gneezy, Lowenstein, & Mazar, 2009). This work is often cited by

professional speakers to support the failure of financial incentives. But as Gupta and Conroy

(2013) indicate, the studies focused on the size of the financial incentive and failed to include a

no-incentive control condition. Although the results can be interpreted as demonstrating the

effects of incentives of different size, they cannot be interpreted as indicating whether or not

the use of financial incentives, in general, is effective.

Other problems in study design can also be identified. We offer these two simply as

illustrative of cautions in extrapolating from the results of previous studies.

Problems with Incentive System Design. Lawler and Rhode (1976) proposed that, for a

control system to be most effective, it must be complete, objective, and influenceable. Even a

cursory glance at the popular reports of ineffective incentive systems demonstrates a clear lack

of attention to these recommendations in incentive system design. Since most research on

financial incentives explicitly or implicitly assumes performance-based incentives (although

Page 14: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 14 -

incentives necessarily needn’t be limited to performance), we focus on performance-related

issues below, and address each of Lawler and Rhode’s recommendations in turn.

That incomplete measures lead to significant problems has been well-documented in

the popular literature. Incomplete measures occur partly because of what Kerr (1975) describes

as a fascination with the objective criterion. For many jobs, objective measures are simply not

available for all critical aspects of the job, and organizations end up focusing on the partial set

for which objective measures are available. Employees then attend only to the measured

aspects, ignoring the remaining significant job duties. For example, in the Atlanta Public School

cheating scandal (2015; Winerip, 2013), the incentive system focused exclusively on

standardized test scores—teachers and administrators in the school district took legitimate and

illegitimate steps to increase standardized test scores. In another example, the Pacific Gas and

Electric Company (PG&E) offered bonuses to supervisors whose crews found fewer leaks and

kept repair costs down (SFGate, 2011). An investigation concluded that bonuses for finding

fewer leaks encouraged crews to ignore safety threats. In 2010, a blast killed eight people and

destroyed 38 homes. Unfortunately, the incentive system worked—the crews found fewer

leaks! Had the performance measurements been more complete and more accurate, the

disaster could have been averted. But our favorite example comes from bus drivers in an Asian

city (Govindarajan & Srinivas, 2013). Drivers were paid bonuses based on whether they reached

their destination on time. One of the authors waited at the bus stop during peak traffic time.

Several buses drove by without stopping, even though there were clearly empty seats. In other

words, the incomplete incentive system encouraged drivers not to pick up passengers during

rush hour, when the most fares (revenue for the organization) would be paid. These are but a

Page 15: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 15 -

few examples of incentive systems working too well, promoting exactly the behaviors that are

rewarded. Again, the problem is in design, not in the use of money.

As noted, Lawler and Rhode (1976) encouraged the use of objective (i.e., not based on

subjective judgments) measures, but objective measures are typically not available for all

aspects of performance, i.e., objective measures tend to be incomplete and suffer from

criterion deficiency. Often, because complete objective measures are difficult to obtain easily,

we settle for proxies that are easily at hand. But careful thought could produce an almost

complete list of objective measures. For example, Arthur and Aiman-Smith (2001) reported that

a joint union-management team developed a customized gainsharing formula (or family of

measures) covering essential aspects of performance. This formula consisted of ten different

dimensions that could be benchmarked historically. The lesson is that objective measures need

not necessarily suffer from criterion deficiency, but that more effort is needed to develop a

network of objective measures that encompass performance fully.

Still, the fact remains that complete objective measures may not always be available. As

an alternative, organizations often use subjective performance appraisals by supervisors. Such

merit systems, based on supervisory performance ratings, are arguably the most common basis

for financial incentives (Heneman & Werner, 2005). But supervisory ratings of performance

suffer from criterion contamination, and represent many other influences beyond employee

performance (Murphy, 2008). Indeed Hoffman, Lance, Bynum, and Gentry (2010) demonstrated

that idiosyncratic rater source effects accounted for 55% of variance in multisource

performance appraisals, whereas performance dimensions accounted for 10% of the variance.

These estimates are consistent with the results obtained by Scullen, Mount, and Goff (2000)

Page 16: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 16 -

and Mount, Judge, Scullen, Systma,and Hezlett (1998). Performance ratings may overcome the

problem of incomplete measures, but they introduce a variety of other problems. Unless the

performance appraisal system is thoroughly examined for validity, tying financial incentives to

them is likely to lead to undesired behaviors such as impression-management and politics.

A good example of the problems inherent in the use of incentive systems with

uninfluenceable measures can be seen in recent scandal involving the Veterans Health

Administration Scandal of 2014 (2015). Rewards in this case were tied to wait times for patient

appointments, but no additional resources were provided to make shortening wait times

feasible. Furthermore, because of the Iraq and Afghanistan wars, the caseload increased

dramatically. Because already overworked workers had no legitimate way to influence the

measure (wait times), they resorted to fudged data. Again, the incentive system worked, but

bad design (uninfluenceable performance outcomes) led to substantial problems.

Beyond these criterion issues, at least two other problems with the design of incentive

systems can be highlighted. One concerns the size of incentives, and the other the

simultaneous use of multiple incentives.

In terms of incentive size, research shows that performance-based pay raises must be

large enough (about 7%) to have meaningful effects (Mitra, Jenkins, and Gupta, 1997, Mitra,

Tenhiӓla, & Shaw, in press). Often, pay raises do not meet this threshold and are thus unlikely

to have the desired effects. At the high end, we need more research on the sensitivity of

performance to financial incentives levels. For many years, we have been proponents of

research designed to understand when the positive performance effects of larger incentives

begin to diminish (e.g., Shaw, 2011). The evidence that does exist, however, is not particularly

Page 17: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 17 -

applicable to real-world incentive contexts. For example, in Ariely and colleagues’ (e.g., Ariely et

al., 2009) research, individuals in a rural village in India were invited to play some games in

return for cash prizes, the largest amounting to half of the typical annual wage in the village. A

second study was conducted among only 24 undergraduate students and also included an

exorbitant reward condition. These authors found that extremely large incentives were

associated with some detrimental outcomes—a finding the authors attributed to choking.

These findings are not surprising; surely, it is possible to induce anxiety, choking, cognitive

inference and the like with such large prizes. What is needed are more reasonably designed

studies that give us some indication of when positive returns to incentives begin to attenuate.

In research terms, more evidence on the non-linearity of performance effects within reasonable

incentive ranges is needed. In practical terms, prudence should be used and care taken in

designing reasonable reward systems.

Sometimes organizations use more than one incentive system, and these incentives

work at cross purposes. Beer and Cannon (2004), for example, reported on the problems

encountered in the implantation of pay-for-performance plans in multiple sites at Hewlett-

Packard in the 1990s. Each site developed its own plan, and their case reports demonstrate

many design problems, but we focus on the use of multiple systems here. At the San Diego site,

the system was designed to have a team pay-for-performance component and an individual

skill-based pay component that encouraged learning new skills. The incentives systems were

dropped after one year in one division, and in the rest thereafter. The training necessitated by

skill-based pay plans implies that, for at least a modicum of time, employees will have sub-par

performance. Implementing a team-performance-based pay plan concurrently militates against

Page 18: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 18 -

employees in training mode. Indeed, many employees were resentful of the need for training,

and ultimately the team pay-for-performance plan overwhelmed the skill-based pay plan. In

other words, the plan failed not due to the use of team incentives (they work, in general; see,

Garbers & Konradt, 2013) or because of the use of skill-based pay plans (they are shown to

work in other settings; see, Shaw, Gupta, Mitra, & Ledford, 2005), but because the two were

used simultaneously, and the two promoted conflicting behaviors.

Problems with Incentive System Implementation. Even when an incentive system is

well-designed, problems can occur in implementation. Two issues are particularly salient in this

regard. We addressed the first issue above—that supervisors and managers take arbitrary,

unjust, and unexplained actions that underlie the negative effects observed in free-time or

post-reward studies. Many years ago, Lawler (1978) noted that the implementation of

innovative financial incentives requires the full commitment of middle as well as top

management. This is in part because no change can be implemented perfectly, and that “kinks”

are likely to develop during implementation. How managers address these “kinks” is vital to the

success or failure of the incentive system. Arbitrary choices inconsistent with the inherent

philosophy of the incentive system are likely to cause problems. Shaw et al. (2005) found, for

example, that employee involvement in the design of the system and supervisor support for the

system were consistent predictors of system success (productivity and workforce flexibility) and

plan survival eight years later.

A related issue that is often observed is that system designers underestimate the power

of the incentive system (perhaps because they listened to Kohn and Pink!). They set low

performance standards that employees meet easily, resulting in higher employee earnings than

Page 19: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 19 -

anticipated. An example of this phenomenon was observed in the Beer and Cannon (2004)

report on Hewlett-Packard. In the first six months, the employees were excited by the team

pay-for-performance plan and outperformed expectations, and the payout was higher than

expected. Instead of building on this success, managers punished employees for their

productivity by adjusting standards. Needless to say, this action triggered significant resistance

among employees, and was partly responsible for the eventual termination of the plan. These

kinds of managerial reactions also explain the development of rate restriction norms in teams

and promotes distrust of management.

Other examples can be observed. But our point is that, quite often, incentives work as

they are designed to do. Standardized test scores were improved, the buses ran on time, there

were fewer leak reports, etc. Individuals performed the behaviors that were rewarded. But

these “successes” are used to demonstrate the failure of incentives. Boxall (2014) considered

contingent compensation or performance-based pay to be “one of the most obviously

dangerous ideas” (p. 587), citing the 2008-2009 global financial crisis as an example of the

pernicious “power of ill-conceived approaches to HRM to do more harm than good” (p. 587).

These statements illustrate vividly the common misattribution—the blame for bad design and

implementation is laid at the door of financial incentives per se. Defective design and

implementation are the true culprits, not the use of money. This is not to say that financial

incentives work in all situations. Rather, this is to say that reflexive laying the blame on financial

incentives precludes a systematic examination of the actual causes of failure. It prevents us

from learning from our mistakes.

Page 20: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 20 -

Concluding Thoughts

As with debates about whether the sun goes around the earth and whether there is

climate change, the scientific evidence has spoken about financial incentives in work settings—

they are effective, they improve performance quantity, they improve performance quality, and

they do not erode, but rather enhance the potency of, intrinsic motivation. It is time to put the

issue of whether they work to rest; it is time attend to issues of how and why they work. It is

time to consider the conditions under which, and the people for whom, they work best. Gupta

and Shaw (2014) highlighted many fruitful areas for compensation research. We urge the

academy of scholars to move away from settled debates toward these promising areas.

Some additional thoughts are in order. First, by arguing that financial incentives are

effective, we are not arguing that only financial incentives are effective or that people are

motivated by money alone. Clearly, we are motivated by challenge, engagement, autonomy,

mastery, and other factors. Instead, we are arguing that, if we accept that financial incentives

work, we can move more easily to questions such as the best combinations of intrinsic and

extrinsic rewards, the best combinations of social and extrinsic rewards, the best combinations

of intrinsic, social, and extrinsic rewards, and so forth. Second, our analysis makes a general

assumption that pay-for-performance is normatively accepted within the context. Much has

been made about whether individuals in different cultural contexts, across different

occupations, and across different levels of the societal strata, are interested in and will be

motivated by the proper use of performance-based pay (Shaw, 2014). For example, we

highlighted poor incentive design as one reason why bus drivers in an Asian city passed up the

opportunity to pick up riders during rush hour. It is possible that other factors were also in play,

Page 21: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 21 -

such as the cultural appropriateness of the system as well as tendencies toward solidarity or

cohesion among workers which may have contributed to these reactions (Marsden & Belfield,

2010). These are important issues to address. We need to make space to begin addressing them.

Kohn is fond of saying things such as “no controlled scientific study has ever found a

long-term enhancement of the quality of work as a result of any reward system” (1998; p. 34;

see also, Kohn, 2009). We agree with him that we need longitudinal studies of incentives. This is

a legitimate issue; such studies are scarce and investigations assessing the immediate and

lasting effects of financial incentives are desirable (feasibility is another matter). One such study

has recently appeared in the literature. Nyberg, Pieper, and Trevor (in press) studied the

relationship between incentives and concurrent and future performance among nearly 12,000

employees over a 5-year period. Not surprisingly, given the meta-analytic evidence outlined

above, they found that “merit and bonus pay, as well as their multiyear trends, as positively

associated with future employee performance” (p. 1). But, we would point out here that

existing theory does not suggest that financial incentives can be used as a behavior

modification or a psychological panacea, inducing permanent changes in employee behaviors

long after the incentives are in effect. Withdrawal of incentives may result in reversion to the

status quo ante, i.e., financial incentives are effective only as long as they are in effect. Many of

the studies highlighted by Kohn (2009) and by others involve assessments of the outcome in

time periods where the incentives are no longer offered. It is not reasonable to expect that

receipt of a financial incentive at one time period should relate to behaviors long in the future

when incentives are no longer offered. Financial incentive decisions (and all other managerial

decisions for that matter) are relevant only within their prescribed time windows. An illustrative

Page 22: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 22 -

example here would be Yahoo CEO Marissa Mayer’s decision to end the long-standing work-

from-home arrangement in the company (MacMillan, 2013). From media reports, we can

reasonably conclude that employees had realized some benefits from flexible working hours in

the past. But, it would be absurd to criticize “flex-time” as being unable to affect “long-term

enhancement of the quality of work” after the program had been eliminated. Going forward

employees’ attitudes and performance would be best predicted by the working arrangements

currently in place.

In conclusion, we encourage more research on critical compensation matters. We also

pointed out many flaws in the design and implementation of incentive systems. Attention to

these and similar issues is likely to result in better-designed incentive systems. Ultimately, we

need to accept that financial incentives are effective, they are more effective than previously

thought, and that therefore it is all the more important that they be used prudently.

Page 23: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 23 -

References

Ariely, D., Gneezy, U., Loewenstein, G., & Nazar, N. (2009). Large stakes and big mistakes.

Review of Economic Studies, 76, 451-469.

Arthur, J., & Aiman-Smith, L. (2001). Gainsharing and organizational learning: An analysis of

employee suggestions. Academy of Management Journal, 44, 737-754.

Atlanta Public School Cheating Scandal. (2015).

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Atlanta_Public_Schools_cheating_scandal.

Bareket-Bojmel, L., Hochman, G., & Ariely, D. (in press). It’s (not) all about the Jacksons: Testing

different types of short-term bonuses in the field. Journal of Management.

Bartol, K.M., & Locke, E.A. (2000). Incentives and motivation. In S.L. Rynes, & B. Gerhart (Eds.),

Compensation in organizations (pp. 104-147). San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

Beer, M., & Cannon, M.D. (2004). Promise and peril in implementing pay-for-performance.

Human Resource Management, 43(1), 3-48.

Bloom, M. (1999). The performance effects of pay dispersion on individuals and organizations.

Academy of Management Journal, 42, 25-40.

Boxall, P. (2014). The future of employment relations from the perspective of human resource

management. Journal of Industrial Relations, 56, 578-593.

Byron, K., & Khazanchi, S. (2012). Rewards and creative performance: A meta-analytic test of

theoretically derived hypotheses. Psychological Bulletin, 138, 809-830.

Cameron, J., & Pierce, W. (1994). Reinforcement, reward, and intrinsic motivation - a

metaanalysis. Review of Educational Research, 64(3), 363-423.

Page 24: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 24 -

Cameron, J., & Pierce, W. (1996). The debate about rewards and intrinsic motivation: Protests

and accusations do not alter the results. Review of Educational Research, 66(1), 39-51.

Cerasoli, C.P., Nicklin, J.M., & Ford, M.T. (2014). Intrinsic motivation and extrinsic incentives

jointly predict performance: A 40-year meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 140, 980-

1008.

Conroy, S., Gupta, N., Shaw, J.D., & Park, T.Y. (2014). A multilevel approach to the effects of pay

variation. Research in Personnel and Human Resource Management, 32, 1-64.

Deci, E.L., & Ryan, R.M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior.

New York: Plenum Press.

Fang, M., & Gerhart, B. (2012). Does pay for performance diminish intrinsic interest?

International Journal of Human Resource Management, 23(6), 1176-1196.

Gagné, M., & Deci, E.L. (2005). Self-determination theory and work motivation. Journal of

Organizational Behavior, 26, 331-262.

Garbers, Y., & Konradt, U. (2014). The effect of financial incentives on performance: A

quantitative review of individual and team-based financial incentives. Journal of

Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 87(1), 102-137.

Gerhart, B., & Fang, M. (2014). Pay for (individual) performance: Issues, claims, evidence and

the role of sorting effects. Human Resource Management Review, 24(1), 41-52.

Gerhart, B., & Milkovich, G. T. (1992). Employee compensation: Research and practice. In M. D.

Dunnette & L. M. Hough (Eds.), Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology,

(Vol. 3, 2nd ed., pp. 481–570). Palo Alto, CA: Consulting Psychologists Press.

Page 25: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 25 -

Gerhart, B., & Rynes, S. (2003). Compensation: Theory, evidence, and strategic implications.

Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

Giles, E. L., Robalino, S., McColl, E., Sniehotta, F. F., & Adams, J. (2014). The effectiveness of

financial incentives for health behaviour change: Systematic review and meta-analysis.

Plos One, 9(3), e90347.

Govindarajan, V., & Srinivas, S. (2013). When your incentive system backfires.

http://blogs.hbr.org/2013/02/when-your-incentive-system-backfires/.

Guest, D.E. (2011). Human resource management and performance: Still searching for some

answers. Human Resource Management Journal, 21, 3-13.

Gupta, N., & Conroy, S. (2013) Evidence-based lessons about financial incentives and pay

variations. WorldatWork Journal, 22(2), 7-16.

Gupta, N., Conroy, S., & Delery, J.E. (2012). The many faces of pay variation. Human Resource

Management Review, 22, 100-115.

Gupta, N., & Shaw, J.D. (1998). Let the evidence speak: Financial incentives are effective!!

Compensation and Benefits Review, 30(2), 26, 28-32.

Gupta, N., & Shaw, J. D. (2014). Employee compensation: The neglected area of HRM research.

Human Resource Management Review, 24(1), 1-4.

Heneman, R.L., & Werner, J.M. (2005). Merit pay: Linking pay to performance in a changing

world (2nd ed.). Greenwich, CT: Information Age Publishing.

Hoffman, B., Lance, C.E., Bynum, B., & Gentry, W.A. (2010). Rater source effects are alive and

well after all. Personnel Psychology, 63, 119-151.

Page 26: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 26 -

Jenkins, G.D., Jr. (1986). Financial incentives. In E.A. Locke (Ed.), Generalizing from laboratory to

field settings (pp. 167-180). Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

Jenkins, G.D., Jr., Mitra, A., Gupta, N., & Shaw, J. (1998). Are financial incentives related to

performance? A meta-analytic review of empirical research. Journal of Applied

Psychology, 83(5), 777-787.

Kaufman, B.E. (2010). SHRM theory in the post-Huselid era: Why it is fundamentally

misspecified. Industrial Relations, 49, 286-313.

Kepes, S., Delery, J.E., & Gupta, N. (2009). Contingencies in the effects of pay range on

organizational effectiveness. Personnel Psychology, 62, 497-531.

Kerr, S. (1975). On the folly of rewarding A, while hoping for B. Academy of Management

Journal, 18, 769-783.

Kohn, A. (1993). Why incentive plans cannot work. Harvard Business Review, 71, 5, 54-63.

Kohn, A. (1996). By all available means: Cameron and Pierce’s defense of extrinsic motivators.

Review of Educational Research, 66, 5-32.

Kohn, A. (1998). Challenging behaviorist dogma: Myths about money and motivation.

Compensation and Benefits Review, 30(2), 27, 33-37.

Kohn, A. (2009, May 21). Cash incentives won’t make us healthier. USA Today.

Lawler, E.E., III. (1978). The new plant revolution. Organizational Dynamics, 6i(3), 2-12.

Lawler, E.E., III, & Jenkins, G.D., Jr. (1992). Strategic rewards systems. In M. D. Dunnette & L. M.

Hough (Eds.), Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology (Vol. 3, 2nd ed., pp.

1009–1055). Palo Alto, CA: Consulting Psychologists Press.

Page 27: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 27 -

Lawler, E.E., III, & Rhode, J.G. (1976). Information and control systems in organizations. Pacific

Palisades, CA: Goodyear.

Lepper, M.R., Greene, D., & Nisbetter, R.E. (1973). Undermining children’s intrinsic interest with

extrinsic rewards: A test of the “overjustification” hypothesis. Journal of Personality and

Social Psychology, 28, 129-137.

Lepper, M.R., Keavney, M., & Drake, M. (1996). Intrinsic motivation and extrinsic rewards: A

commentary on Cameron and Pierce’s meta-analysis. Review of Educational Research,

66, 5-32.

MacMillan, D. (2013, February 26). Yahoo CEO Mayer revives debate over work-from-home

merits. Bloomberg Business (http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-02-

26/yahoo-s-mayer-risks-productivity-with-work-from-home-restriction).

Marsden, D., & Belfield, R. (2010). Institutions and the management of human resources:

Incentive pay systems in France and Great Britain. British Journal of Industrial Relations,

48, 234-283.

Mitra, A., Gupta, N., & Jenkins, G.D., Jr. (1997). A drop in the bucket: When is a pay raise a pay

raise? Journal of Organizational Behavior, 18, 117-137.

Mitra, A., Tenhiälä, A., & Shaw, J.D. (in press). Smallest meaningful pay increases: Field test,

constructive replication, and extension. Human Resource Management.

Mount, M.K., Judge, T.A., Scullen, S.E., Sytsma, M.R., & Hezlett, S.A. (1998). Trait, rater, and

level effects in 360-degree performance ratings. Personnel Psychology, 51, 557-576.

Page 28: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 28 -

Murphy, K.R. (2008). Explaining the weak relationship between job performance and ratings of

job performance. Industrial and Organizational Psychology: Perspectives on Science and

practice, 1, 148-205.

Nyberg, A.J., Pieper, J.R., & Trevor, C.O. (in press). Pay-for-performance effet on future

employee performance: ingrating psychological and economic principles toward a

contingency perspective. Journal of Management.

Park, T.Y., & Shaw, J.D. (2013). Turnover rates and organizational performance: A meta-analysis.

Journal of Applied Psychology, 98, 268-309.

Pfeffer, J. (1998). The human equation: Building profits by putting people first. Boston, MA:

Harvard Business School Press.

Pfeffer, J., & Davis-Blake, A. (1992). Salary dispersion, location in salary distribution and

turnover among college administrators. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 45, 753-

763.

Pfeffer, J., & Langton, N. (1993). The effect of wage dispersion on satisfaction, productivity, and

working collaboratively: Evidence from college and university faculty. Administrative

Science Quarterly, 38, 382-407.

Pink, D. (2009). Drive: The surprising truth about what motivates us. New York: Penguin Group.

Ryan, R.M., & Deci, E.L. (1996). When paradigms clash: Comments on Cameron and Pierce’s

claim that rewards do not undermine intrinsic motivation. Review of Educational

Research, 66, 33-38.

Scullen, S.E., Mount, M.K., & Goff, M. (2000). Understanding the latent structure of job

performance ratings. Journal of Applied Psychology, 85, 956-970.

Page 29: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 29 -

SFGate. (2011). http://www.sfgate.com/news/article/PG-E-incentive-system-blamed-for-leak-

oversights-2424430.php#page-1.

Shaw, J.D. (in press). Pay levels and pay changes:. Forthcoming in N. Anderson, D.S. Ones, H.K.,

Sinangil, & C. Viswesvaran (Eds), Handbook of Industrial, Work, and Organizational

Psychology.

Shaw, J.D. (2011). What’s next in reward management? Changes in practice and challenges for

research from the recent financial crisis. Keynote address at the 3rd Reward

Management Conference, Brussels, Belgium, December, 2011.

Shaw, J.D. (2014). Pay dispersion. Annual Review of Organizational Psychology and

Organizational Behavior, 1, 521-544.

Shaw, J.D. (2015). Pay dispersion, sorting, and organizational performance. Working paper, The

Hong Kong Polytechnic University.

Shaw, J.D., & Gupta, N. (2001). Pay fairness and employee outcomes: Exacerbation and

attenuation effects of financial need. Journal of Occupational and Organizational

Psychology, 74, 299-320.

Shaw, J.D., Gupta, N., & Delery, J.E. (2002). Pay dispersion and work force performance:

Moderating effects of incentives and interdependence. Strategic Management Journal,

23, 491-512.

Shaw, J.C., Wild, E., & Colquitt, J.A. (2003). To justify or excuse? A meta-analytic review of the

effects of explanations. Journal of Applied Psychology, 88, 444-458.

Shin, D., & Konrad, A.M. (in press). Causality between high-performance work systems and

organizational performance. Journal of Management.

Page 30: LET THE EVIDENCE SPEAK AGAIN! FINANCIAL ... and...layperson’s confidence in the tradition of Alfie Kohn (1993, 1998), Dan Pink is a case in point. His best-selling book (Pink, 2009)

Financial Incentives are Effective - 30 -

Thompson, P. (2011). The trouble with HRM. Human Resource Management Journal, 21, 355-

367.

Trevor, C. O., Reilly, G., & Gerhart, B. (2012). Reconsidering pay dispersion’s effect on the

performance of interdependent work: Reconciling sorting and pay inequity. Academy of

Management Journal, 55, 585—610.

Veterans Health Administration Scandal of 2014. (2015).

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Veterans_Health_Administration_scandal_of_2014.

Winerip, M. (March 30, 2013). Indicted in test scandal at Atlanta schools. New York Times, A1.