KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably...

35
KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Purdue University West Lafayette, Indiana On The Efficiency Of Nominal GDP Targeting In A Large Open Economy By Matthew Hoelle M. Udara Peiris Paper No. 1273 Date: February, 2013 Institute for Research in the Behavioral, Economic, and Management Sciences

Transcript of KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably...

Page 1: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Purdue University West Lafayette, Indiana

On The Efficiency Of Nominal GDP Targeting In A

Large Open Economy

By

Matthew Hoelle M. Udara Peiris

Paper No. 1273 Date: February, 2013

Institute for Research in the Behavioral, Economic, and Management Sciences

Page 2: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

On the Efficiency of Nominal GDP Targeting

in a Large Open Economy1

Matthew Hoelle2 M. Udara Peiris 3

February 16, 2013

Purdue and HSE working Paper, 4

1We have had very helpful conversations with Pablo Beker, Herakles Polemarchakis and Dimitrios

Tsomocos, which have greatly improved the paper. We would also like to thank Oliver Bush, Martin

Jensen, Nikolas Kokonas, Ken Okamura, Roberto Pancrazi, Thijs van Rens, Alexandros Vardoulakis

and participants at seminars in Oxford and Warwick for providing comments and feedback. First

version November 2012.2Department of Economics, Purdue University; [email protected], NRU Higher School of Economics, Moscow; [email protected] latest version of this paper and an extended working paper is available on the authors’

websites: http://www.matthew-hoelle.com/ and http://www.udarapeiris.org/

Page 3: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Abstract

Since 2007 there have been increasing calls to abandon a regime of Stabilizing Inflation (SI)

in favor of Nominal GDP (NGDP) targeting. One argument in favor of NGDP targeting

is that it allows inflation to redistribute resources among bond holders efficiently. Here we

examine this claim in a large open monetary economy and show that, in contrast to SI,

NGDP targeting is in fact (Pareto) efficient in a world with stochastic real uncertainty, and

in the absence of complete insurance markets (only nominally risk free bonds are available).

However this result is ultimately fragile and breaks down once we attempt to deviate from

the simplistic setting necessary for the result to hold

Key words: monetary policy; open economy; uncertainty; incomplete markets; Pareto

efficiency.

JEL classification numbers: D50; E31; E40; E50; F41.

Page 4: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

1 Introduction

The abrupt end of the Great Moderation in 2007 has raised calls to abandon a regime of

Stabilizing Inflation (SI) and the Taylor Rule1 in favor of a regime of nominal GDP (NGDP)

targeting whereby nominal income, rather than nominal prices, follows a stationary path2.

We examine the claim that the path of inflation consistent with a NGDP target policy

provides additional risk-sharing opportunities to households. We study the role that inflation

plays in allocating resources between bondholders across countries in a world with incomplete

financial markets and the implications for the optimal conduct of monetary policy and show

that, even if agents are unable to insure against risk via existing asset markets (a complete

set of asset markets, in an Arrow-Debreu sense, is unavailable) it is true that, under specific

conditions, a global policy of NGDP targeting provides natural risk sharing opportunities to

households to the extent that they can completely hedge risk (achieving the Pareto optimal

allocation). However we find this result is ultimately fragile and breaks down once we

attempt to deviate from the simplistic world necessary for the result to hold.

The most common arguments in favor of the NGDP target are that it (i) stabilizes

employment as wage bills depends more on nominal income (than on the rate of inflation),

(ii) limits asset market instability as asset bubbles tend to form when NGDP growth is

higher than average, and (iii) stabilizes demand more effectively as an adverse supply shock is

automatically divided between inflation and real GDP, in contrast to the excessive tightening

in response to adverse supply shocks by stabilizing inflation.3

1SI, while optimal in economies with pricing frictions in the goods market, may be suboptimal in

economies with financial frictions such as credit constraints or the possibility of default, since these fric-

tions are persistent and propagate across markets. An example of recent work on monetary models with

credit frictions includes Christiano et al. (2010). To fully analyze the welfare implications of SI, information

and credit frictions should also be formally modeled. See Faia and Monacelli (2007), Carlstrom et al. (2010)

and Fiore and Tristani (2012).2 Notable recent proponents include Crook (2011), Krugman (2011), Romer (2011),Frankel (2012), Sum-

ner (2012) and Woodford (2012). See Hall and Mankiw (1994) for an excellent overview of the historical

debate on nominal income targeting.3As Koenig (2012a) argues:

Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

The main difference between the two policy approaches is that nominal-GDP targeting takes

a longer-term view of inflation than does the Taylor rule when pointing to a loose or tight

policy setting. Consequently, nominal-GDP targeting is less forgiving of near-term expected

deviations of inflation from long-run target inflation than is the Taylor rule: It requires that

any near-term expected inflation shortfall be offset by expected forward inflation overages so

that expected average inflation over the medium term holds steady. This unwillingness to let

bygones be bygones can be an advantage if the zero bound limits current policy stimulus. Under

nominal-GDP targeting, the monetary authority promises future accommodation to offset the

current tighter-than-desired policy stance.

1

Page 5: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

The other claim in favour of NGDP targeting stems from the Fisher debt-deflation story,

whereby inflation redistributes resources among bond holders. The argument, briefly, is

that there exists an optimal stochastic rate of inflation, consistent with that obtained under

NGDP targeting, that supports an efficient allocation of resources (i.e. optimal risk sharing)

in the absence of complete asset markets. To our knowledge, examinations of this claim have

required the endowments of households to be perfectly correlated and have focused entirely

on closed economies. As a result, they have ignored the role of the current account in

distributing resources across countries exposed to idiosyncratic fluctuations in real income.

Our purpose is to disentangle the effects of inflation in redisributing resources, from the

specific endowment structure necessary to obtain effiiciency. An open economy provides a

natural setting to do this.

We study the role that inflation plays in redistributing income across international bond

holders who are subject to idiosyncratic and possibly also aggregate risk and show that

even in the absence of any insurance markets (only nominal risk-free bonds are available),

NGDP targeting by all countries in a large open economy can support the Pareto optimal

allocation. In an economy with the same (real) fundamentals, switching to an SI regime by

at least one country destroys these risk-sharing opportunities. This is because in a large

open economy, optimal policy that would support the Pareto optimal allocation under SI

requires a combination of active monetary (interest rate) policy and exchange rate policy

which would violate the implicit debt constraint of the infinite horizon model. Our results

are similar in spirit to Koenig (2012b) and Sheedy (2012) though we consider a large open

economy, with an explicitly modeled monetary structure, and our results do not depend

on the transfer of resources between creditors and debtors. Rather, our results describe

how inflation affects the efficiency of the transfers of resources between bond holders across

countries; the distinction between debtors and creditors is inconsequential in our analysis.

We consider a monetary economy of large open economies inhabited by homogeneous

households. Money has value via a cash-in-advance constraint. The only assets are nom-

inally risk-free bonds denominated in each currency. Monetary policy and exchange rate

intervention affect either (i) the money supplies to change the price level and/or (ii) interest

rates to affect the real value of domestic output. Under a global policy of nominal GDP

targeting, the nominal value of endowments remains constant across states of uncertainty.

This implies that the endowments are inversely related to the nominal price level. This

setting naturally achieves the desired change in the real value of the nominal assets, as the

real payouts span both the individual and the aggregate endowments. There is no role for

active exchange rate policy and monetary policy is completely characterized by the mone-

tary growth rate. On the other hand, if inflation is to be stabilized, monetary policy must

be contingent on the idiosyncratic endowment realizations. This affects both the real value

of the bond payoffs and the real value of endowments via the inflation tax on money bal-

2

Page 6: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

ances. Pareto efficiency requires an additional degree of (policy) freedom which is obtained

through exchange rate intervention. However such policy violates the debt constraint and

hence Pareto efficiency cannot be an equilibrium outcome by stabilizing inflation (over a

generic subset of endowments).4

This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents a stylized economy that captures the

essence of the risk sharing argument under different monetary policies. We then present a

formal model with an explicit monetary structure in Section 3 and the efficiency of monetary

policies in Section 4. Finally in Section 5 we give some concluding remarks about the robust-

ness of the arguments in favour of NGDP targeting and how extensions and generalization

to the model affect the results.

2 Motivating Example

The debt-deflation story of Irving Fisher requires, in a rational expectations world, the in-

ability to fully insure for inflation to have real effects. Incompleteness of asset markets is

a realistic description of the functioning of modern asset markets, and avoids the extreme

assumption of the standard Arrow-Debreu model that all agents meet at one moment in time

and trade assets that allow for every conceivable contingency in the infinitely long future.

The absence of complete contingent markets may arise for several reasons.5 First, asymmet-

ric information may imply that certain events are unobservable to all market participants.

Second, households may not have access to all asset markets, possibly for reasons of moral

hazard. Third, transactions costs may prohibit the opening of additional markets.

When there are missing asset or insurance markets (incomplete markets), competitive

allocations are generically inefficient6 and one may envisage a role for active monetary

policy and exchange rate management that would otherwise be unnecessary under complete

markets. Our purpose in such a setting is to characterize policy that supports the (Pareto)

efficient allocation of resources in a large open economy. Such policy deviates from (current)

monetary orthodoxy7, but is consistent with the arguments in the theory of incomplete

markets that proceeded the seminal works of Arrow and Debreu.

In the open economy context we consider here, the incompleteness of markets may arise

quite naturally. We can rationalize the domestic representative agent as the outcome of

4In an extended working paper we show that an optimal combination of monetary and exchange rate

policy supports the Pareto optimal allocation under SI in a 2-period model. An optimal policy exists because

the terminal period provides an additional degree of freedom for central banks.5See Geanakoplos (1990) for an excellent overview of the general equilibrium literature on incomplete

markets.6See Stiglitz (1982) and Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis (1986).7Nominal income targeting has been formally discussed since the late 1970’s in monetary economics.

Early contributions to the contemporary literature on nominal income targeting include Meade (1978), von

Weizsacker (1978), Tobin (1980) and Bean (1983).

3

Page 7: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

domestic markets being complete, whereas if there are limited risk sharing opportunities

internationally, then global markets would be incomplete. Under the appropriate conditions,

complete markets is observationally equivalent to a representative agent. In this sense, our

global market incompleteness captures the inability of households to fully hedge foreign

income risk. Though not formally modeled here, reasons that households may be unable to

fully hedge foreign risk are incomplete information about foreign markets or even regulations

that prohibit foreign capital flows into certain domestic markets.

Efficiency under incomplete markets requires (following Geanakoplos and Shubik (1990)

and LeRoy and Werner (2001)) that the real payouts of the available nominal assets span

both the individual and the aggregate endowment. This span condition can be achieved in

one of two ways: (i) change the nominal payouts themselves or (ii) change the real value

by changing the price level. Any economy with nominal contracts is characterized by its

degrees of indeterminacy, nominal and possibly real.8 This indeterminacy can be removed

by formally modeling money and, more precisely, the actions of a central bank. If the

underlying indeterminacy is real, as in the incomplete markets economy we consider, then

these actions determine the equilibrium allocation.9 In this motivating example we present

only the efficiency of prices in equilibrium. In contrast, the formal model that follows in

Section 3 will be determinate and will allow us to explicitly characterize the efficiency of

monetary policy.

The proceeding analysis shows that when markets are incomplete, optimal monetary

policy in a large open economy must take the form of nominal income targets globally. That

is the price level should vary inversely with future output to allow inflation to redistribute

resources among bond holders. We illustrate our argument with a stylized 2-period economy

which captures the essence of the argument concisely. Importantly, the analysis of this 2-

period economy dictates that our results are not specific to the particular monetary structure

that we later impose.

2.1 Stylized Large Open Nominal Economy

Consider a 2-period large open economy with two countries, incomplete markets, and nom-

inal assets with S states of uncertainty in the final period. In the initial period, households

trade assets, but do not consume nor receive endowments. In the final period, one of S

possible states occurs. In each state, one physical commodity is traded. There exist 2

countries: home (h) and foreign (f). Each country is populated by homogeneous house-

holds of equal measure, with real GDP (endowment) vectors given by yh = (yh(1), ..., yh(S))

8There is an extensive literature on indeterminacy of monetary equilibria. An important example is

Geanakoplos and Mas-Colell (1989).9See Bloise and Polemarchakis (2006) for an overview on formally modeling money in a general equilibrium

setting.

4

Page 8: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

and yf = (yf (1), ..., yf (S)) . Total world output is denoted Y = (Y (1), ..., Y (S)) where

Y = yh + yf . As the goods are identical, the law-of-one-price prevails and the real exchange

rate is trivially one. The assets available to the households are nominal bonds, one bond

issued by each country, with risk-free nominal payouts in the issuing country’s currency.

Denote the equilibrium commodity price for the home country as p = (p(1), ..., p(S))

and that for the foreign country as p∗ = (p∗(1), ..., p∗(S)) . When solving the households’

problem, we typically express the budget constraints in terms of real payouts, so the real

asset payouts of the two assets (the home bond and the foreign bond) in each of the S states

of uncertainty in the final period are expressed by the following payout matrix:

R =

1p(1)

1p∗(1)

: :1

p(S)1

p∗(S)

.Define the span of the payout matrix as 〈R〉 .Mathematically, the span is the 2−dimensional

linear subspace of the S−dimensional Euclidean space that can be achieved through a vector

of bond holdings (home and foreign): 〈R〉 ={x ∈ RS : x = Rθ for some θ ∈ R2

}.

Definition. Span Condition

The endowment vectors (yh, yf ) both lie in the span of the payout matrix R : yh ∈ 〈R〉 and

yf ∈ 〈R〉 .

If this span condition is met, the household in the home country can use the home bond to

hedge against domestic output risk and the foreign bond to hedge against aggregate output

risk. The span condition implies that the total endowment Y will also lie in the span,

Y ∈ 〈R〉 . Provided that the preferences of the representative agents in each country are

identical and homothetic, the Pareto optimal allocation is such that all households consume

a constant fraction of the total world output in all states: θh for home households and θf

for foreign households with θh + θf = 1.

At the optimal allocation, the excess demand for the home households is θhY −yh ∈ 〈R〉 ,which belongs to the span since both domestic output yh and aggregate endowment Y do.

Thus, this excess demand can be supported by an appropriate vector of bond holdings. The

same conclusion is reached for the foreign households. Market clearing for the bonds holds

trivially.

2.2 Policies and the Span Condition

We now turn to what equilibrium prices and monetary policies must prevail to ensure Pareto

efficiency. Provided that velocity is state-independent (though not necessarily identical

across countries), the quantity theory of money states that the money supply in each country

5

Page 9: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

is linearly related to both the commodity price and domestic output. Assuming this relation

holds, the span condition holds for any economy if and only if the money supplies are stable,

i.e., the money supplies are state-independent. This invariance is how we define nominal

GDP targeting. Formally, the real asset payoff matrix is equivalent to:

R̂ =

yh(1) yf (1)

: :

yh(S) yf (S)

.With constant domestic and foreign money supplies, the matrix R̂ is a linear transforma-

tion of the matrix R, meaning that the spans are identical:⟨R̂⟩

= 〈R〉 . And since yh ∈⟨R̂⟩

and yf ∈⟨R̂⟩

by definition, the span condition is satisfied.

Notice that the result permits both aggregate risk (Y (s) can vary across states) and

idiosyncratic risk (yh and yf are not perfectly correlated).

With an arbitrary number of states of uncertainty (consider S > 2), the span 〈R〉 is a

measure zero subset of the S−dimensional Euclidean space. Thus, if policies result in a span⟨R̂⟩6= 〈R〉 , then the Pareto optimal allocation is typically unable to be supported as an

equilibrium allocation. For any policies other than global nominal GDP targeting, R̂ is not a

linear transformation of R, meaning⟨R̂⟩6= 〈R〉 . Thus, a policy of stabilizing inflation by at

least one country suffices to destroy the risk-sharing opportunities of the financial structure.

Consider the consequences if the domestic households are not homogeneous, but hetero-

geneous with endowments that are not perfectly correlated. For this economy, all house-

hold endowments (both the heterogeneous domestic households and the homogeneous for-

eign households) must lie in the span, but the set of household endowments is at least

a 3−dimensional subspace,10 while the span remains at most a 2−dimensional subspace.

Thus, the appropriate span condition for within-country heterogeneity cannot be satisfied.

In conclusion, prices that are consistent with both the quantity theory of money and

Pareto optimality exist if and only if (i) global policies of nominal GDP targeting are adopted

and (ii) domestic financial markets are complete.

The risk-sharing implications of this motivating example are the central message from

Koenig (2012b) and Sheedy (2012). In fact, the Koenig (2012b) result is a special case of the

above result for a closed economy with aggregate risk only (the individual household risk is

perfectly correlated in Koenig (2012b)). However, in a monetary economy, the role of policy

and its effect on the determinacy of prices in sustaining Pareto optimality is nontrivial and

an issue to which we soon turn.11

10The subspace will be equal to, in general, the number of households in the world economy whose

endowments are not perfectly correlated.11Determinacy is an important result in our chosen monetary structure. In a closed economy with an

OLG monetary structure, Sheedy (2012) also verifies the efficiency of nominal GDP targeting, but not the

determinacy of such a policy (see Kehoe and Levine (1990) and Feng (2012) for the difficulties of obtaining

6

Page 10: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

2.3 Supporting the Pareto Efficient Equilibria

Knowing now that prices exist that support the Pareto efficient allocation, what can be

said about the implementability of these prices and which ones are supported by monetary

policy (i.e. the determinacy of the equilibrium)? In general, the equilibrium above displays

both nominal and real indeterminacy: setting either money supplies or interest rates is not

enough to determine a locally unique optimal policy.12 These questions cannot be answered

from the above analysis, which only explores the risk-sharing implications of a nominal

economy. To answer these questions, we must formally model a monetary structure. Such

analysis provides not only an incentive for households to hold money, but also makes prices

determinate and a function of central bank policy. Thus, the task for the remainder of

the paper is to introduce a proper monetary structure and investigate if the risk-sharing

implications of this example continue to hold in a determinate monetary economy where

central bank policy has real effects.13

3 The Model

Consider an economy with an infinite time horizon. In each discrete period t ≥ 0, one of S

possible shocks s ∈ S is realized. Denote the shock occurring in period t as st. We represent

the resolution of uncertainty by an event tree Σ, with a given date-event σ ∈ Σ. Each date-

event σ is characterized by the history of shocks up to and including the current period

st = (s0, ..., st) .14 The root of Σ is the date-event σ0 with realization s0, where s0 ∈ S is a

fixed state of the economy. Each σ ∈ Σ has S immediate successors that are randomly drawn

from S according to a Markov process with transition matrix Π. Each σ ∈ Σ has a unique

predecessor, where the unique predecessor of the date-event st is st−1. Finally, for a variable

x(st) at date-event st, the variables in the set of successor date-events are (x(st, s))s∈S .

3.1 Households

There are two countries: home (h) and foreign (f).15 In each country there is a continuum of

homogeneous households of measure 1. At each date-event, households are endowed with an

determinacy in an OLG framework).12There is a long standing literature in the general equilibrium with incomplete markets literature on the

indeterminacy of equilibria with financial contracts. For an important example in the context of an open

economy see Polemarchakis (1988).13The conditions for determinacy of monetary equilibria with nominal assets and incomplete markets in

a closed setting are provided by Dubey and Geanakoplos (2006), while the conditions for a deterministic

setting of an open economy are provided by Tsomocos (2008).14The vector st is equivalently interpreted as an ordered set, so that s ∈ st refers to a particular shock in

the history of shocks up to period t.15We have adopted the notational conventions of Svensson (1985).

7

Page 11: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

amount of the single, homogeneous good, which is identical in both countries. In date-event

st, the endowment of the home household is yh (st) > 0 and the endowment of the foreign

household is yf (st) > 0; that is, endowments only depend on the current realization st.

The economy does not contain any aggregate risk, meaning that yh (st) + yf (st) = Y for

any shock st ∈ S. This assumption is made for expositional convenience, meaning that our

results remain valid without it.

The home households in date-event st choose the consumption vector (ch(st), cf (st)) ,

where ch(st) ≥ 0 is the consumption of the home commodity and cf (st) ≥ 0 is the con-

sumption of the foreign commodity. The goods are identical across countries, so the home

household preferences are only defined over the sum c(st) = ch(st) + cf (st). Similarly, the

foreign household consumption vector in date-event st is defined by(c∗h(st), c∗f (st)

)with

c∗(st) = c∗h(st) + c∗f (st).

The probability that the date-event characterized by st is realized is defined recursively

as

π(st) = π(st−1) · π (st|st−1) ,

where the initial probabilities π(s0) are parameters of the model and π (st|st−1) are elements

of the Markov transition matrix Π.

The household preferences are identical and characterized by the utility function

∑t,st

βtπ(st)u(c(st)

), (1)

where β ∈ (0, 1) is the discount factor. The utility function, u(c), satisfies standard condi-

tions:

Assumption 1. The utility function, u : R++ → R, is C1, differentiably strictly increasing,

and strictly concave. The Inada condition holds:

limc→0

u1 (c) =∞.

3.2 Monetary Structure

We follow the monetary cash-in-advance structure of Nakajima and Polemarchakis (2005)

and Peiris and Polemarchakis (2012).16 Our timing convention is such that transactions

occur after uncertainty is realized so that there is only a transactions demand for money.

We assume a unitary velocity of money.

Consider the initial date-event s0. The home household and the foreign household begin

this date-event with nominal assets w (s0) and w∗ (s0) , respectively, where each is valued in

terms of the local currency.

16These models are closely related to the open economy models of Lucas (1982) and Geanakoplos and

Tsomocos (2002) and the open economy model with incomplete markets of Peiris and Tsomocos (2012).

8

Page 12: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

The timing proceeds as follows. First, the asset market opens, in which cash and the

bonds, one from each country, are traded. Additionally, the currency market opens, in which

cash denominated in one currency is traded for cash denominated in another currency. Let

e∗(s0) be the nominal exchange rate for the foreign country (number of units of home

currency for each unit of foreign currency) and e(s0) is the exchange rate for the home

country, where e (s0) = 1e∗(s0)

. Let r (s0) and r∗ (s0) denote the nominal interest rates for

the home and foreign country, respectively, implying that 11+r(s0)

is the price of the nominal

bond in the home currency and 11+r∗(s0)

is the price of the nominal bond in the foreign

currency. Accounting for the foreign exchange markets, the budget constraint for the home

household in terms of the home currency (and similarly for the foreign household) is given

by:

m̂h(s0) + e∗(s0)m̂f (s0) +bh(s0)

1 + r(s0)+ e∗(s0)

bf (s0)

1 + r∗ (s0)≤ w(s0). (2)

The variables m̂h(s0) and m̂f (s0) are the amounts of the home and foreign currency held,

while bh(s0) and bf (s0) are the home and foreign bond positions (net savings). Cash amounts

are nonnegative variables, while the bond holdings can take any values.

The market for goods opens next. Denote p(s0) and p∗(s0) as the commodity prices in

the home and foreign country, respectively. The purchase of consumption goods is subject

to the cash-in-advance constraints:

p(s0)ch(s0) ≤ m̂h(s0), (3)

p∗(s0)cf (s0) ≤ m̂f (s0).

The home household also receives cash by selling its endowment, yh(s0). Hence, the amount

of cash that it carries over to the next period is

mh(s0) = p(s0)yh(s0) + m̂h(s0)− p(s0)ch(s0). (4)

mf (s0) = m̂f (s0)− p∗(s0)cf (s0).

Given (4), the cash-in-advance constraints (3) are equivalent to

mh(s0) ≥ p(s0)yh(s0), (5)

mf (s0) ≥ 0.

In equilibrium, the Law of One Price must hold, meaning that p(s0) = e∗(s0)p∗(s0). Us-

ing this fact and substituting for mh(s0) and mf (s0) from (4) into (2) yields the budget

constraint in date-event s0 :

p(s0)c(s0) +bh(s0)

1 + r(s0)+ e∗(s0)

bf (s0)

1 + r∗ (s0)≤ w(s0). (6)

The transactions of the home household in all date-events st for t > 0 are similar.

Maintain the notational convention with nominal exchange rates as e(st) and e∗(st) for home

9

Page 13: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

and foreign respectively, nominal interest rates as r (st) and r∗ (st) for home and foreign

respectively, and commodity prices p(st) and p∗(st) for home and foreign respectively. The

budget constraint that the home household faces in date-event st is given by

p(st)c(st) +bh(st)

1 + r(st)+ e∗(st)

bf (st)

1 + r∗ (st)(7)

≤ p(st−1)yh(st−1) + bh(st−1) + e∗(st)bf (st−1).

Similar to (5), the cash-in-advance constraints are given by:

mh(st) ≥ p(st)yh(st), (8)

mf (st) ≥ 0.

The debt constraint requires that the real value of the portfolios are uniformly bounded:

inft,st

[bh(st)

(1 + r(st)) p(st)+

bf (st)

(1 + r∗ (st)) p∗(st)

]> −∞. (9)

These debt constraints suffice to rule out Ponzi schemes and guaranteee an optimal solution

to the household problem.17 We consider the real values of the portfolios as we allow for

inflation in the economy resulting from the selected monetary policy.

Define the choice vectors as c,mh,mf ∈ `∞+ and bh, bf ∈ `∞ for the home household

(and c∗,m∗h,m∗f ∈ `∞+ and b∗h, b

∗f ∈ `∞ for the foreign household), where c = (c (st))t≥0,st is

the infinite sequence of consumption choices for all date-events, with similar definitions for

all other choice vectors. Define the home equilibrium price vectors as e, r, p ∈ `∞+ and the

foreign equilibrium price vectors as e∗, r∗, p∗ ∈ `∞+ , where r = (r (st))t≥0,st is the infinite

sequence of nominal interest rates.18

The problem for the home household is given as follows (and symmetrically for the foreign

household):

maxc,mh,mf ,bh,bf

∑t,st β

tπ(st)u (c(st))

subj. to budget and CIA constraints (6) and (5) in s0,

budget and CIA constraints (7) and (8) in st,

debt constraint (9).

(10)

3.2.1 The Monetary-fiscal Authority

Each country contains a monetary-fiscal authority whose responsibilities include monetary

(interest rate) policy and exchange rate policy.

17See Hernandez and Santos (1996) and Beker and Chattopadhyay (2010) for the sufficiency of such a

condition.18`∞ is the set of bounded infinite sequences, with respect to the sup norm. It is a metric space and

more specifically a Banach space (one can apply the contraction mapping theorem to verify that the value

function is well-defined and the Bellman equation is valid). `∞+ is the set of nonnegative bounded infinite

sequences. Further details on this can be found in Bertsekas (1976).

10

Page 14: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

The parameters W (s0) and W ∗ (s0) are the nominal payments owed to the household in

the home and foreign country, respectively, where the debt is owed by the monetary-fiscal

authority in each country. In the initial date-event s0, the monetary-fiscal authority in the

home country chooses the domestic money supply M (s0) , the domestic debt obligations

Bh (s0) , and the foreign debt obligations Bf (s0) . The money supplies are nonnegative,

while the debt obligations can be either positive (net borrow) or negative (net save). The

similar choices for the monetary-fiscal authority in the foreign country are M∗ (s0) , B∗h (s0) ,

and B∗f (s0) . The constraint in s0 for the monetary-fiscal authority in the home country (and

similarly for the foreign country) is given by:

M(s0) +Bh (s0)

1 + r(s0)+ e∗ (s0)

Bf (s0)

1 + r∗(s0)= W (s0). (11)

Similarly, the constraint in date-event st for any t > 0 is given by:

M(st) +Bh (st)

1 + r(st)+ e∗

(st) Bf (st)

1 + r∗(st)= M(st−1) +Bh(st−1) + e∗

(st)Bf (st−1). (12)

Define the choice vectors as M ∈ `∞+ and Bh, Bf ∈ `∞ for the home household (and M∗ ∈ `∞+and B∗h, B

∗f ∈ `∞ for the foreign household), where M = (M (st))t≥0,st is the infinite

sequence of money supplies for all date-events, with similar definitions for all other choice

vectors.

3.3 Sequential Competitive Equilibria

The market clearing conditions are such that w(s0) = W (s0) and w∗(s0) = W ∗(s0) hold in

the initial date-event and for all date-events st :

ch(st) + c∗h(st) = yh(st),

cf (st) + c∗f (st) = yf (st),

mh(st) +m∗h(st) = M(st),

mf (st) +m∗f (st) = M∗(st)

bh(st) + b∗h(st) = Bh(st)

+B∗h(st),

bf (st) + b∗f (st) = Bf(st)

+B∗f (st).

A sequential competitive equilibrium is defined as follows.

Definition. Given initial nominal obligations W (s0) and W ∗(s0), a sequential competitive

equilibrium consists of an allocation (c, c∗) , household money holdings(mh,mf ,m

∗h,m

∗f

),

household portfolios(bh, bf , b

∗h, b∗f

), money supplies (M,M∗) , monetary-fiscal authority

debt positions(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

), interest rates (r, r∗) , commodity prices (p, p∗) , and ex-

change rates (e, e∗) such that:

11

Page 15: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

1. the monetary-fiscal authorities satisfy their constraints (11) and (12);

2. given interest rates (r, r∗) , commodity prices (p, p∗) , and exchange rates (e, e∗) , house-

holds solve the problem (10);

3. all markets clear.

3.4 Exchange Rate Policy

We define moneary-fiscal policy without and with foreign exchange intervention. The two

policies differ in that foreign exchange intervention permits monetary-fiscal authorities to

hold debt obligations in the foreign bond.

Definition. Monetary-fiscal policy without foreign exchange intervention

Zero international debt positions, Bf (st) = B∗h (st) = 0 for all date-events st.

Definition. Monetary-fiscal policy with foreign exchange intervention

Non-zero international debt positions, Bf (st) ∈ R and B∗h (st) ∈ R for some date-events

st.

We now consider the existence and determinacy of our equilibria.

3.5 Existence

This paper focuses attention on two policies of monetary-fiscal authorities: nominal GDP

targeting (NGDP) and stabilizing inflation (SI), though the results can equivalently be stated

in terms of global NGDP and the complementary set of all other policy combinations. The

policy of NGDP does not require foreign exchange intervention, while the policy of SI does.

Thus, rather than specify existence and determinacy results in terms of the target values for

the money supplies (for NGDP) and the target values for the interest rates (for SI, since the

rate of inflation is directly related to the interest rate via the Fisher equation), the specified

policies of the monetary-fiscal authorities will be the debt positions(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

).

An appropriately chosen vector of debt positions(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)can support NGDP

and SI under the constraints (11) and (12). Thus, the global policy choice is characterized

by the vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

), which can be viewed as parameters to the households in

the economy.

The existence of a sequential competitive equilibrium follows standard arguments. The

existence of a truncated equilibrium is known from Theorem 3 of Bai and Schwarz (2006)

for the case of initial fiscal transfers W (s0) and W ∗(s0) and zero fiscal transfers in all future

period t > 0. The existence of the infinite-horizon analogue of the aforementioned truncated

12

Page 16: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

equilibrium follows the standard approach of Levine and Zame (1996) or Magill and Quinzii

(1994), as the debt constraints (9) suffice to obtain the necessary uniform bounds.

The existence claim is stated as follows, where the proof follows standard arguments

with the key steps discussed above.

Claim 1. For any given policy vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

), there exists a sequential competitive

equilibrium.

3.6 Determinacy and Monetary Policy

As we are concerned not only about the efficiency of different monetary policies, but also

the implementability of these policies, it is important that we verify that the model allows

the policy vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)to select a determinate allocation. It is no use to claim

that efficiency arises under a particular policy vector if such a policy is also consistent with

other equilibria that are inefficient.

The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level (see, e.g., Woodford (1994)) argues that the speci-

fication of fiscal transfers suffices to pin down the initial price level and the vector of state

prices, provided that the fiscal transfers are fixed. Fixed fiscal transfers imply in a 2-period

model that the terminal constraints are not satisfied for off-equilibrium vectors of money sup-

plies, interest rates, and monetary-fiscal authority debt positions. This is the exact setting

of our infinite horizon model, as our model only contains strictly positive nominal transfers

in the initial period, W (s0) and W ∗(s0), and zero fiscal transfers in all other date-events.

Further, the infinite horizon analogue of the terminal constraint is the debt constraint, which

need only be satisfied in equilibrium and not for all possible off-equilibrium vectors.

Theorems 3 and 4 from Bai and Schwarz (2006) verify the determinacy of cash-in-advance

equilibria in a closed 2-period economy. Their model notably limits monetary-fiscal author-

ities to only holding riskless domestic debt positions. Thus, our determinacy result, for the

infinite horizon model with the possibility for foreign exchange intervention, subsumes Bai

and Schwarz (2006) as special cases. We first describe the special cases and then provide

intuition for our determinacy result.

Consider the policy vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)that is consistent with nominal GDP target-

ing for both countries. As previously discussed, the monetary-fiscal authorities can support

both the nominal GDP targets and the optimal allocation by only holding domestic debt

positions (no foreign exchange intervention). This is the setting of Bai and Schwarz (2006).

Thus, Theorem 4 of Bai and Schwarz (2006) is directly applicable and for every policy vec-

tor(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)consistent with a global policy of nominal GDP targeting, the set of

sequential competitive equilibria is determinate.

Consider the policy vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)that is consistent with stabilizing inflation

for both countries. It would be straightforward for the monetary-fiscal authorities to support

13

Page 17: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

the inflation targets using only domestic debt positions, but as previously mentioned, we

provide them with additional policy tools to improve risk-sharing. Specifically, monetary-

fiscal authorities can inject or withdraw money from their respective domestic economies in a

state-contingent manner by holding foreign debt positions. This additional policy tool allows

the monetary-fiscal authorities to target the nominal exchange rate to support a stationary

path of inflation. As previously discussed, this additional policy can achieve the Pareto

efficient allocation in a 2-period model in which the terminal condition must bind for all

monetary-fiscal authority choice vectors. Thus, the results of Bai and Schwarz (2006) are not

applicable, but the monetary-fiscal authorities have an additional policy tool (international

debt positions) and an additional target (nominal exchange rate).

Extending Bai and Schwarz (2006) to an open economy, we argue that for any com-

bination of policies for the two monetary-fiscal authorities,(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

), the set of

sequential competitive equilibria is determinate. This encompasses a global policy of nomi-

nal GDP targeting, a global policy of stabilizing inflation, and all other policy combinations,

including asymmetric ones.

Claim 2. For any given policy vector(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

), the set of sequential competitive

equilibria is determinate.

3.7 Stationary Markov Equilibria

In addition to the set of sequential competitive equilibria, we are also interested in the set

of stationary Markov equilibria, a subset of the former set.19 If one exists, a stationary

Markov equilibrium can be numerically approximated using standard computational meth-

ods. Additionally, such an equilibrium allows the monetary-fiscal authority policy to depend

on the smallest subset of observations, avoiding any (unmodeled) problems of incomplete

information.

Definition. A stationary Markov equilibrium is a sequential competitive equilibrium in

which functions Fb, Fb∗ , FB , FB∗ , Fr, and Fr∗ exist such that for any date-event st and all

conditional realizations in the following period (st, s)s∈S :(bh(st+1

), bf(st+1

))= Fb

(bh(st), bf(st), st+1

),(

b∗h(st+1

), b∗f(st+1

))= Fb∗

(b∗h(st), b∗f(st), st+1

),(

Bh(st+1

), Bf

(st+1

))= FB

(Bh(st), Bf

(st), st+1

),(

B∗h(st+1

), B∗f

(st+1

))= FB∗

(B∗h(st), B∗f

(st), st+1

),

r(st+1

)= Fr (st+1) ,

r∗(st+1

)= Fr∗ (st+1) .

19Stationary Markov equilibria are also referred to as recursive equilibria by Ljungqvist and Sargent (2012).

14

Page 18: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Given the above financial variables specified by stationary transition functions, the re-

maining variables can also be defined by stationary transition functions using the bud-

get constraints (7), the monetary-fiscal authority constraints (12), and the price equations

M(st+1

)= p

(st+1

)yh (st+1) and e∗

(st+1

)=

p(st+1)p∗(st+1) .

4 Efficiency of Policies

This section considers the normative effects of the following policies under incomplete mar-

kets: Theorem 1 considers nominal GDP targeting by both countries; Theorem 2 considers

stabilizing inflation by both countries; and Theorem 3 considers all global policies in between

those just mentioned.

4.1 Nominal GDP Targeting

Definition. Nominal GDP Targeting

If the monetary policy of the home country satisfies p(st+1

)yh (st+1) = p (st, s) yh (s) =

p (st, 1) yh (1) for all possible realizations s ∈ S, then the home country is implementing

nominal GDP targeting.

Define the nominal GDP target growth rates as µ and µ∗ for the home and foreign

country, respectively20. Define the largest expected endowment growth in the home country

(similarly for the foreign country) as:

G = maxs∈S

∑s′∈S π (s′|s) yh (s′)

yh(s).

To ensure nonnegative interest rates and a consistent equilibrium definition, we impose the

following bounds on the growth rates.

Assumption 2. The nominal GDP target growth rates (µ, µ∗) are such that βG ≤ 1 + µ

and βG∗ ≤ 1 + µ∗.

Policies of nominal GDP targeting do not require either monetary-fiscal authority to

engage in foreign exchange intervention. This implies that Bf (st) = B∗h (st) = 0 for all

date-events st.

Under nominal GDP targeting, the monetary-fiscal authority in the home country chooses

a monetary policy consisting only of the initial money supply M(s0) and the monetary

growth rate µ. Given these choices, the infinite sequence of money supplies is trivially de-

termined. Further, the infinite sequence of debt positions Bh is determined to satisfy the

monetary-fiscal authority constraints (12). Thus, the entire policy is automatic given M(s0)

and µ (and similarly for the monetary-fiscal authority in the foreign country).

20See proof of Theorem 1 for a precise definition of this.

15

Page 19: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Theorem 1. If both countries adopt nominal GDP targeting, then the stationary Markov

equilibrium allocations are Pareto efficient.

The recursive structure suffices to guarantee the existence of a stationary Markov equi-

librium, since Theorem 1 ensures that the welfare theorems are applicable. The proof of

Theorem 1 is a constructive argument and ultimately verifies two things: (i) that the Pareto

optimal allocation can be supported in the sequential equilibrium budget constraints and

(ii) that the transition functions implied from the budget constraints are stationary for all

price variables, household choice variables, and monetary-fiscal authority choice variables.

Standard arguments from dynamic programming (see Bertsekas (1976)) guarantee that the

constructed equilibrium with Pareto optimal allocation is a stationary Markov equilibrium.

Remark

There is a long standing view that the main cost of inflation lies in the distortion it

induces in households’ intertemporal savings decisions. The meaningful deviation of our

approach from others in the literature is that we do not consider costs of inflation such as

inefficient long-term planning (Clarida et al. (1999)) that arises from unanticipated inflation.

In our framework inflation is perfectly anticipated, in a rational expectations sense, but

the incompleteness of markets means that agents cannot insure against this risk. More

importantly, under a global policy of NGDP targeting, the fluctuations of inflation are not

random but rather correspond exactly to fluctuations in domestic GDP and so inflation

does not necessarily inhibit the ability to make long term planning decisions.21 In the open

economy context we consider, the fluctuations in inflation provide a natural hedge against

fluctuations in the current account which would occur for reasons outside of the remit of

domestic monetary-fiscal authorities. In contrast, the next section shows that policies which

attempt to stabilize fluctuations in the current account by targeting the nominal exchange

rate are not sustainable in the long run.

4.2 Stabilizing Inflation

We next address the implications of policies of stabilizing inflation by both countries.

Definition. Stabilizing Inflation

If the monetary policy of the home country satisfies p(st+1

)= p (st, s) = p (st, 1) for all

possible realizations s ∈ S, then the home country is implementing stabilizing inflation.

Define the expected inflation rates for both the home and foreign country, respectively,

as a Markov process that only depends on the current period realization s ∈ S : {τ (s)}s∈Sand {τ∗ (s)}s∈S .

21See Sheedy (2012) for an extended discussion on this point.

16

Page 20: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Assumption 3. The inflation rates {τ (s)}s∈S and {τ∗ (s)}s∈S are such that β ≤ 1 + τ (s)

and β ≤ 1 + τ∗ (s) for all shocks s ∈ S.

Unlike with nominal GDP targeting, we permit the monetary-fiscal authorities to engage

in foreign exchange intervention. Formally, this implies Bf (st) ∈ R and B∗h (st) ∈ R for all

date-events st. In a purely nominal economy, such as the one presented in the motivating

example, we showed that only a global policy of nominal GDP targeting could support the

Pareto efficient allocation. However, the cash-in-advance technology we consider provides

an additional mechanism through which stabilitizing inflation may possibly do the same.

The cash-in-advance constraint effectively taxes nominal money balances at the rate of

inflation and, in equilibrium, effectively causes agents to defer their nominal incomes by

a period. In a present value sense, this is equivalent to discounting future income by the

nominal interest rate. If real income is subject to stochastic shocks, then nominal interest

rates could potentially be chosen in such a way so as to offset the real shock, leaving the

present discounted value of current period nominal income state-independent or stationary.

In order to support both the Pareto efficient allocation and a stationary path of prices,

the central bank needs an additional mechanism to adjust the nominal money supply. This

can be done in two ways. The most obvious is for the monetary-fiscal authority to provide

nominal lump sum transfers to agents. Such transfers would, however, be given only to

domestic households, which would create wealth effects that offset the stationarity of income

obtained through having a policy of state contingent nominal interest rates.

The second option for policy makers, and the policy we consider, is that the monetary-

fiscal authority intervenes in the currency markets by purchasing and selling foreign bonds,

thereby effectively injecting or withdrawing money from the economy. From the law of one

price, this would imply that to maintain stable prices, the exchange rates would be constant

over time. That is, the policy we consider is one where the monetary-fiscal authority uses

nominal interest rates to affect domestic aggregate demand and targets a fixed exchange

rate to support a stationary path of inflation.

Our result shows that under stabilizing inflation, not only is monetary policy insufficient

to obtain a Pareto efficient allocation, but so is monetary policy combined with foreign

exchange intervention. The equilibrium household bond holdings that are required to sup-

port the Pareto efficient allocation violate the debt constraint under a policy of stabilizing

inflation.

Under a policy of stabilizing inflation, the monetary-fiscal authority in the home country

chooses a monetary policy consisting only of the initial price level p(s0) and the Markov

process for inflation rates {τ (s)}s∈S . The implementation of the sequence of money supplies

and debt positions is automatic given that the constraints (12) must be satisfied for all date-

events st.

Theorem 2. If both countries stabilize inflation, there do not exist policies that result in

17

Page 21: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

a Pareto efficient sequential competitive equilibrium allocation.

From the statement of the theorem, notice that we do not restrict ourselves to only

stationary Markov equilibria. The inefficiency result holds more generally.

The argument nowhere requires the variables to be specified in a stationary Markov

manner. The stationary structure is imposed from the Markov endowment process and the

Markov process of stabilizing inflation. The remaining variables of interest are the bond

holdings of households and we do not impose any restrictions on the transition functions

for these variables. Thus, inefficiency occurs under stabilizing inflation for all sequential

competitive equilibria.

The proof proceeds by verifying that the Pareto efficient allocation cannot be supported

as an optimal solution to the households’ problem (10). The monetary-fiscal authority

policy vectors(Bh, Bf , B

∗h, B

∗f

)can take any values such that the inflation targets are met,

markets clear, and the constraints (11) and (12) are met. This obviously subsumes the case

of foreign exchange intervention.

4.3 Mixed Global Policies

This section generalizes the result in Theorem 2 to show that for any global policies other

than nominal GDP targeting by both countries, Pareto efficiency is not supportable under

the stationary Markov equilibrium concept. Obviously, both countries stabilize inflation as

in Theorem 2 is a special case of global policies other than nominal GDP targeting by both

countries. While we only show that the Pareto inefficiency holds for the more restrictive def-

inition of equilibrium (stationary Markov), it is this stationary Markov equilibrium concept

that is typically considered in the theory and practice of monetary policy.

The definition of a stationary Markov equilibrium does impose minimal structure on the

monetary policies that can be implemented. Namely, the definition requires that∑s∈S π(s|st)

M(st)M(st,s)

only depends on the current shock st. As special cases are (i) nominal GDP targeting in which∑s∈S π(s|st)

M(st)M(st,s) = 1

1+µ and (ii) stabilizing inflation in which∑s∈S π(s|st)

M(st)M(st,s) =

yh(st)1+τ(st)

∑s∈S

π(s|st)yh(s)

.

From the Fisher equation, the interest rates are in fact stationary functions and defined

for the home country (and similarly for the foreign country) as:

r(st)

= Fr (st) =yh (st)

β∑s∈S π(s|st)yh(s) M(st)

M(st,s)

− 1.

The function Fr (st) is stationary iff∑s∈S π(s|st)

M(st)M(st,s) only depends on the current shock

st.

This implies that the growth rates for any stationary monetary policy must be of the

form:

M(st, s

)= (1 + µ (st, s))M

(st)

18

Page 22: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

for all date-events st, where the growth rate µ (st, s) only depends on the two most recent

shock realizations.

We must impose assumptions to guarantee that the interests rates are nonnegative.

Assumption 4. The growth rates {µ (st, s)}st,s∈S and {µ∗ (st, s)}st,s∈S are such that

β∑s∈S π(s|st)yh(s)

M(st)M(st,s) ≤ yh (st) and β

∑s∈S π(s|st)yf (s)

M∗(st)M∗(st,s) ≤ yf (st)

for all shocks st ∈ S.

The state-contingent definition of nominal GDP targeting for the home country specifies

that µ (st, s) = µ (st, 1) ∀s ∈ S. We allow for this general definition in the following result,

rather than the original definition (state-independent) in which µ (st, s) = µ ∀st, s ∈ S.

Theorem 3. If one of the countries adopts a policy other than nominal GDP targeting,

there do not exist policies that result in a Pareto efficient stationary Markov equilibrium

allocation.

As previously discussed, this result nests Theorem 2 when we agree to only focus on the

policy-relevant equilibrium concept of a stationary Markov equilibrium.

5 Concluding Remarks

This paper analyzed the conditions under which a global policy of NGDP targeting permits

optimal risk-sharing by households. The key points in this analysis are twofold: (i) while

the risk-sharing implications hold for any nominal economy (recall the motivating example),

the formal modeling of an appropriate monetary structure is crucial and (ii) the efficiency

of NGDP targeting is fragile and not robust to simple extensions and generalizations.

Regarding the delicate nature of the efficiency result under NGDP targeting, we offer

our thoughts for each of the following extensions. Each result is either derived from the

classical literature in general equilibrium, or is formally proven by the authors and available

upon request.

1. If multiple commodities are traded and consumed in each date-event, the assumption

that preferences are identical and homothetic suffices to guarantee that a global policy

of NGDP targeting remains efficient. In contrast, if preferences are no longer identical,

then the presence of multiple commodities suffices to destroy the efficiency properties.

2. If domestic households are heterogeneous with endowment vectors that are not per-

fectly correlated with the domestic or aggregate output,22 then in order for a global

policy of NGDP targeting to remain efficient, domestic households must be able to

completely share risk domestically through either an equity market or a complete set

22This lies in contrast to Koenig (2012b) and Sheedy (2012).

19

Page 23: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

of assets in zero domestic net supply. Without these complete within-country insur-

ance opportunities, a model containing within-country heterogeneity (i.e. individual

real incomes are not perfectly correlated) is unable to support an efficient allocation.

3. Velocity must be state-independent for a global policy of NGDP targeting to remain

efficient. If velocity depends on domestic real output, for example, then this condition

is violated. However, NGDP targeting is efficient if velocity is modeled along the lines

of Cagan (1956) in which velocity depends on the future path of money supplies, which

is stationary under NGDP.

4. Our results are robust to a model with any finite number of countries. Provided that

all countries adopt nominal GDP targeting, then efficiency is achieved. However, if

just one country deviates, then efficiency is broken as the shocks to the current account

can no longer be hedged.

5. We have not Pareto ranked different equilibria corresponding to different combinations

of monetary policy, but we can provide some initial insights on how to study these

issues. Using the simple parametric specifications in Neumeyer (1998), in particular

mean-variance preferences, the distance between the complete markets allocation and

the marketed subspace (the asset span) is a well-defined welfare measure. This distance

is smaller when one country adopts NGDP targeting compared to when neither country

adopts NGDP targeting. This implies that the equilibrium allocation under the former

Pareto dominates the equilibrium allocation under the latter (see Proposition A1 of

Neumeyer (1998) for the formal treatment of Pareto dominance).

While there is merit to the argument that NGDP targeting allows inflation to redis-

tribute resources efficiently among bond holders, the extent to which these arguments carry

weight in practice remains unclear. It remains to be shown, through characterizing equilibria

under different policy choices and Pareto ranking their respective allocations, whether or

not NGDP targeting can allocate resources more efficiently than other monetary policies.

References

Bai, Jinhui H. and Ingolf Schwarz (2006), ‘Monetary equilibria in a cash-in-advance economy

with incomplete financial markets’, Journal of Mathematical Economics 42(4-5), 422–451.

Bean, Charles R. (1983), ‘Targeting nominal income: An appraisal’, The Economic Journal

93(372), 806–819.

Beker, Pablo and Subir Chattopadhyay (2010), ‘Consumption dynamics in general equi-

librium: A characterisation when markets are incomplete’, Journal of Economic Theory

20

Page 24: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

145(6), 2133–2185.

URL: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0022053110000578

Bertsekas, D. (1976), Dynamic Programming and Stochastic Control, Academic Press.

Bloise, G. and H. Polemarchakis (2006), ‘Theory and practice of monetary policy’, Economic

Theory 27, 1–23.

Cagan, P. (1956), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, chapter The Monetary Dynamics

of Hyperinflation, pp. 25–117.

Carlstrom, C.T., T. S. Fuerst and M. Paustian (2010), ‘Optimal monetary policy in a model

with agency costs’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42, 37–70.

Christiano, Lawrence, Cosmin L. Ilut, Roberto Motto and Massimo Rostagno (2010), Mone-

tary policy and stock market booms, Working Paper 16402, National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gal and Mark Gertler (1999), ‘The science of monetary policy: A

new keynesian perspective’, Journal of Economic Literature 37(4), 1661–1707.

Crook, C. (2011), ‘The fed must fix on a fresh target’, Financial Times .

Dubey, Pradeep and John Geanakoplos (2006), ‘Determinacy with nominal assets and out-

side money’, Economic Theory 27(1), 79–106.

Faia, Ester and Tommaso Monacelli (2007), ‘Optimal interest rate rules, asset prices, and

credit frictions’, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31(10), 3228–3254.

Feng, Zhigang (2012), ‘Tackling indeterminacy in overlapping generations models’, pp. 1–

13–.

Fiore, Fiorella De and Oreste Tristani (2012), ‘Optimal monetary policy in a model of the

credit channel*’, The Economic Journal pp. no–no.

Frankel, J. (2012), ‘Inflation targeting is dead. long live nominal gdp targeting’, Voxeu .

Geanakoplos, J. D. and D. P. Tsomocos (2002), ‘International finance in general equilibrium’,

Research in Economics 56(1), 85–142.

Geanakoplos, J. and H. M. Polemarchakis (1986), Essays in Honour of K. J. Arrow, Vol. 3,

Cambridge, chapter Existence, Regularity and Constrained Sub-optimality of Competitive

Allocations when the Asset Market is Incomplete.

Geanakoplos, J. and M. Shubik (1990), ‘The capital asset pricing model as a general equi-

librium with incomplete asset markets’, Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory

56(1), 85–142.

21

Page 25: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Geanakoplos, John (1990), ‘An introduction to general equilibrium with incomplete asset

markets’, Journal of Mathematical Economics 19(1-2), 1 – 38.

Geanakoplos, John and Andreu Mas-Colell (1989), ‘Real indeterminacy with financial as-

sets’, Journal of Economic Theory 47(1), 22–38.

Hall, R.E. and N. G. Mankiw (1994), Monetary Policy, University of Chicago Press, chapter

Nominal Income Targeting, pp. 71–93.

Hernandez, Alejandro and Manuel S. Santos (1996), ‘Competitive equilibria for infinite-

horizon economies with incomplete markets’, Journal of Economic Theory 71(1), 102–130.

Kehoe, Timothy J. and David K. Levine (1990), ‘The economics of indeterminacy in over-

lapping generations models’, Journal of Public Economics 42(2), 219–243.

Koenig, E.F. (2012a), ‘All in the family: The close connection between nominal-gdp target-

ing and the taylor rule’, Federeal Reserve Bank of Dallas Working Paper .

Koenig, E.F. (2012b), ‘Like a good neighbor: Monetary policy, financial stability, and the

distribution of risk’, Federeal Reserve Bank of Dallas Working Paper .

Krugman, P.R. (2011), ‘Getting nominal, the conscience of a liberal (blog)’, New York Times

October 19.

LeRoy, S.F. and J. Werner (2001), Principles of Financial Economics, 3rd edn, Cambridge

University Press.

Levine, David K. and William R. Zame (1996), ‘Debt constraints and equilibrium in in-

finite horizon economies with incomplete markets’, Journal of Mathematical Economics

26(1), 103–131.

Ljungqvist, L. and T. Sargent (2012), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, 3rd edn, MIT Press.

Lucas, Robert Jr. (1982), ‘Interest rates and currency prices in a two-country world’, Journal

of Monetary Economics 10(3), 335–359.

Magill, Michael and Martine Quinzii (1994), ‘Infinite horizon incomplete markets’, Econo-

metrica 62(4), 853–880.

Meade, James (1978), ‘The meaning of ”internal balance”’, The Economic Journal

88(351), 423–435.

Nakajima, Tomoyuki and Herakles Polemarchakis (2005), ‘Money and prices under uncer-

tainty’, Review of Economic Studies 72(1), 223–246.

22

Page 26: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Neumeyer, Pablo Andrs (1998), ‘Currencies and the allocation of risk: The welfare effects

of a monetary union’, The American Economic Review 88(1), 246–259.

Peiris, M.U. and D.P. Tsomocos (2012), ‘International monetary equilibrium with default’,

working paper OFRC.

Peiris, M.U. and H. Polemarchakis (2012), ‘Monetary policy and quantitative easing in an

open economy: Prices, exchange rates and risk premia’, University of Warwick working

paper .

Polemarchakis, H. M (1988), ‘Portfolio choice, exchange rates, and indeterminacy’, Journal

of Economic Theory 46(2), 414 – 421.

Romer, C. (2011), ‘Dear ben: It’s time for your volcker moment’, The New York Times 29

October.

Sheedy, K.D. (2012), ‘Debt and incomplete financial markets: A case for nominal gdp tar-

geting’, London School of Economics working paper .

Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1982), ‘The inefficiency of the stock market equilibrium’, The Review of

Economic Studies 49(2), 241–261.

Sumner, S. (2012), ‘The case for nominal gdp targeting’, Mercatus Center, George Mason

University, working paper.

Svensson, Lars E. O. (1985), ‘Money and asset prices in a cash-in-advance economy’, Journal

of Political Economy 93(5), 919–944.

Tobin, James (1980), ‘Stabilization policy ten years after’, Brookings Papers on Economic

Activity 1980(1), 19–89.

Tsomocos, Dimitrios P. (2008), ‘Generic determinacy and money non-neutrality of inter-

national monetary equilibria’, Journal of Mathematical Economics 44(7-8), 866 – 887.

Special Issue in Economic Theory in honor of Charalambos D. Aliprantis.

von Weizsacker, C. C. (1978), ‘Das problem der vollbeschaftigung heute’, Zeitschriji fur

Wirstschajis und Sozialwissenshaften 98, 33–51.

Woodford, M. (2012), ‘Methods of policy accommodation at the interest-rate lower bound’,

2012 FRB Kansas City Economic Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY. .

Woodford, Michael (1994), ‘Monetary policy and price level determinacy in a cash-in-

advance economy’, Economic Theory 4(3), 345–380.

23

Page 27: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

6 Appendix

Proof of Theorem 1

Proof. The money supply M (st) for the date-event st only depends upon the period t :

M(st)

= (1 + µ)tM (s0) ,

where M (s0) is the initial money supply. For simplicity, we define the scaled money supplies

as

M̂(st)

=M (st)

(1 + µ)t = M (s0) .

Prices are given by

p(st)

=M (st)

yh (st),

where the scaled prices are Markov processes that only depend on the current realization

st :

p̂(st)

=p (st)

(1 + µ)t =

M (s0)

yh (st).

The same definitions hold for the foreign country.

At a Pareto optimal equilibrium allocation, the Fisher equation under the nominal GDP

target is given by:

M (st)

M (st−1)= β

(1 + r(st−1)

) ∑s∈S π(s|st−1)yh (s)

yh (st−1).

Thus, the interest rates that satisfy the Fisher equations are a Markov process that only

depends on the current realization st ∈ S :

r(st)

= Fr (st) =(1 + µ) yh (st)

β∑s∈S π(s|st)yh (s)

− 1. (13)

Using (13), r (st) ≥ 0 provided that the expected endowment growth never exceeds the

discounted monetary growth:

1 + µ

β≥∑s∈S π(s|st)yh (s)

yh (st)

The inequality holds given Assumption 2. The same properties hold for the foreign country.

The exchange rates are also a Markov process if we assume that the nominal GDP growth

rates are equal across countries. Without such an assumption, the exchange rates can drift

over time:

e(st)

=(1 + µ)

t

(1 + µ∗)t

M (s0)

M∗ (s0)

yf (st)

yh (st).

The only remaining variables that must be shown to be stationary are the bond holdings

of households and debt positions of monetary-fiscal authorities.

24

Page 28: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

Specify the following growth rates for household bonds: γh (st) , γf (st) , γ∗h (st) , and

γ∗f (st) . Specify the following growth rates for the monetary-fiscal authority debt obligations:

Γh (st) and Γ∗f (st) . The growth rate definitions are such that

bh(st)

=(1 + γh

(st))bh(st−1

), (14)

and similarly for each of the 5 other variables. Define the scaled financial variables as

b̂h(st)

=bh (st)

(1 + µ)t , (15)

and similarly for each of the other 5 variables. The exposition is simplified by expressing all

budget constraints and debt constraints in terms of these scaled variables. Consequently,

the transition equations for the scaled variables are given by

b̂h(st)

=1 + γh (st)

1 + µb̂h(st−1

), (16)

and similarly for each of the other 5 variables.

Part (i): Market clearing

Observe that for any date-event st, market clearing in scaled variables, b̂h (st)+ b̂∗h (st) =

B̂h (st) , is satisfied iff market clearing in the original variables, bh (st) + b∗h (st) = Bh (st) ,

is satisfied.

To support a Pareto efficient equilibrium allocation, the budget constraint for the home

household in date-event st (and similarly for the foreign household) is:

θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) +bh(st)

1 + r(st)

yh (st)

M(st)+

bf (st)

1 + r∗(st)

yf (st)

M∗(st)

=bh(st−1) +M(st−1)

M(st)yh (st) +

bf (st−1)

M∗(st)yf (st)

for some θ ∈ (0, 1) , where θ is the Pareto weight for the home household. Given (16), the

budget constraint can be re-written in terms of scaled variables:

θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) =1

1 + µ

(1 +

b̂h(st−1

)M (s0)

r(st)− γh (st)

1 + r(st)

)yh (st) (17)

+1

1 + µ∗

(b̂f(st−1

)M∗ (s0)

r∗(st)− γf (st)

1 + r∗(st)

)yf (st) .

Sufficient conditions are:

θ = 11+µ

(1 +

b̂h(st−1)M(s0)

r(st)−γh(st)1+r(st)

)and

θ = 11+µ∗

(b̂f(st−1)M∗(s0)

r∗(st)−γf(st)1+r∗(st)

) . (18)

25

Page 29: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

In exactly the same manner, we obtain the sufficient conditions for the foreign household:

1− θ = 11+µ

(b̂∗h(st−1)M(s0)

r(st)−γ∗h(st)1+r(st)

)and

1− θ = 11+µ∗

(1 +

b̂∗f(st−1)

M∗(s0)

r∗(st)−γ∗f (st)

1+r∗(st)

) . (19)

The sufficient conditions (18) and (19) are satisfied provided that for all date-events st,

there exists constant variables(χh, χf , χ

∗h, χ∗f

)∈ R4 such that

χh = b̂h(st−1

) r(st)− γh (st)

1 + r(st), (20)

and similarly for the remaining three variables.

For any initial period transfers w(s0) and w∗ (s0) , there exists a range of Pareto weights

θ such that the corresponding Pareto optimal allocation can be supported in a stationary

Markov equilibrium. For any growth rates µ and µ∗, initial money supplies M(s0) and

M∗(s0), and any θ in the range discussed above, the constant values(χh, χf , χ

∗h, χ∗f

)∈ R4

are defined as

χh = θM(s0) (1 + µ)−M(s0) and

χf = θM∗(s0) (1 + µ∗) ,(21)

and similarly for the foreign household.

The realization st determines the nominal interest rate r(st) = F (st) , so we simply write

the interest rate as r(st). From (16), (20), and (21), the transition functions for the bond

holdings are stationary:

b̂h(st)

=1 + r(st)

1 + µ

(b̂h(st−1

)− θM(s0) (1 + µ) +M(s0)

), (22)

b̂f(st)

=1 + r∗(st)

1 + µ∗

(b̂f(st−1

)− θM∗(s0) (1 + µ∗)

),

and similarly for the foreign household. The transition function is of the form required for

a stationary Markov equilibrium:(b̂h(st), b̂f(st))

= Fb

(b̂h(st−1

), b̂f(st−1

), st

).

Given (16), the monetary-fiscal authority constraint in the home country for any history

st can be written in terms of scaled variables:

µM(s0) = B̂h(st−1

) r(st)− Γh (st)

1 + r(st)(23)

and similarly for the foreign country. Exactly as above for household bond holdings, the

transition function is

B̂h(st)

=1 + r(st)

1 + µ

(B̂h(st−1

)− µM(s0)

)(24)

26

Page 30: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

for the home country with stationary transition function defined as B̂h (st) = FB

(B̂h(st−1

), st

)(and similarly for the foreign country).

Market clearing is verified using an inductive argument. The market clearing conditions

are w (s0) = W (s0) and w∗ (s0) = W ∗ (s0) and in the date-event s0, the scaled bond holdings

are identical to the unscaled holdings. The bond holdings{b̂h(s0), b̂f (s0), b̂∗h(s0), b̂∗f (s0)

}are

set such that the following excess demand condition is satisfied:

yh (s0)− c (s0) =b̂f (s0)

p∗(s0) (1 + r∗(s0))− b̂∗h (s0)

p(s0) (1 + r(s0)).

As a result, the debt positions B̂h (s0) and B̂∗f (s0) then trivially satisfy the market clearing

conditions b̂h (s0) + b̂∗h (s0) = B̂h(s0) and b̂f (s0) + b̂∗f (s0) = B̂∗f (s0) as

B̂h (s0)

p(s0) (1 + r(s0))=W (s0)

p(s0)− yh (s0)

from the monetary-fiscal authority constraint of the home country (11) and

b̂h (s0)

p(s0) (1 + r(s0))+

b̂f (s0)

p∗(s0) (1 + r∗(s0))=w (s0)

p(s0)− c (s0)

from the budget constraint for the home household (and similarly for the foreign household).

Thus the initialization step of the argument is confirmed: b̂h (s0) + b̂∗h (s0) = B̂h(s0) and

b̂f (s0) + b̂∗f (s0) = B̂∗f (s0).

Given these date-event s0 variables and the monetary growth rates µ and µ∗, we show

that appropriate paths for the bond holdings and debt positions can be specified to support

the Pareto optimal allocation while satisfying market clearing.

For the induction step, fix the date-event st−1and assume that b̂h(st−1

)+ b̂∗h

(st−1

)=

B̂h(st−1) and b̂f(st−1

)+ b̂∗f

(st−1

)= B̂∗f (st−1). For the home country in any date-event st,

(22) implies

b̂h(st)

+ b̂∗h(st)

=1 + r(st)

1 + µ

(b̂h(st−1

)+ b̂∗h

(st−1

)− µM(s0)

)for any st =

(st−1, s

)s∈S . Using the assumption b̂h

(st−1

)+ b̂∗h

(st−1

)= B̂h(st−1) :

b̂h(st)

+ b̂∗h(st)

=1 + r(st)

1 + µ

(B̂h(st−1)− µM(s0)

).

Given (24), markets clear in all date-events st =(st−1, s

)s∈S :

b̂h(st)

+ b̂∗h(st)

= B̂h(st).

Part (ii): Debt constraint

The scaled bond holdings{b̂h(st), b̂f (st), b̂∗h(st), b̂∗f (st)

}are uniformly bounded random

variables. Suppose otherwise, that is, limt→∞

supst

∣∣∣b̂h(st)∣∣∣ = ∞. From the sufficient condition

27

Page 31: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

(20), it must be that

limt→∞

infst

∣∣∣∣∣r(st+1)− γh(st+1

)1 + r(st+1)

∣∣∣∣∣ = 0. (25)

With r(st+1) ≥ 0 and only dependent on the period t+1 realization st+1, the limit condition

(25) is only satisfied if limt→∞

infst

[γh(st+1

)− r(st+1)

]= 0. This requires that γh

(st+1

)only

depends on the period t + 1 realization st+1 : γh(st+1

)= γh (st+1) . If γh (st+1) is inde-

pendent of the shock st+1, then (20) cannot be satisfied as r(st+1) varies with the current

endowment yh (st+1) according to the Fisher equation (13). If γh (st+1) varies with the shock

st+1, then b̂h(st+1

)= 1+γh(st+1)

1+µ b̂h (st) varies across the realization st+1. Taken together,

b̂h(st+1

)varies with st+1, while

r(st+2)−γh(st+2)1+r(st+2)

varies (only) with st+2. Thus, (20) cannot

be satisfied for all possible histories st+2. This shows that b̂h(st) is uniformly bounded. The

same argument holds for the other 3 financial variables.

In terms of the scaled bond holdings, the debt constraint for the home household is

written as:

inft,st

[b̂h(st)

(1 + r(st)) p(s0)+

b̂f (st)

(1 + r∗ (st)) p∗(s0)

]> −∞.

Since{b̂h(st), b̂f (st), b̂∗h(st), b̂∗f (st)

}are uniformly bounded random variables, then the debt

constraints for both households are satisfied.

The nominal GDP targets impose the Markov structure on equilibrium prices as discussed

leading up to the statement of the theorem. Given that a Pareto efficient allocation can

be supported as a stationary Markov equilibrium, then any stationary Markov equilibrium

allocation must be Pareto efficient (or else households would not be optimizing). Existence

is trivial since a stationary Pareto efficient allocation exists for the specified endowments

and preferences of the economy.

Proof of Theorem 2

Proof. The price p (st) for any date-event st is independent of the period t realization st :

p(st−1, s

)= (1 + τ (st−1)) p

(st−1

)∀s ∈ S. (26)

For simplicity, we define the scaled money supplies as:

M̂(st)

=M (st)∏

s′∈st−1 (1 + τ (s′)).23 (27)

By definition,

p (s0) =p (st)∏

s′∈st−1 (1 + τ (s′))and

M(st)

= p(st)yh (st) ,

23For example, M̂(s2

)= M̂ (s0, s1, s2) =

M(s2)(1+τ(s0))(1+τ(s1))

.

28

Page 32: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

meaning that the scaled money supplies M̂ (st) are Markov processes that depend only upon

the current realization st :

M̂(st)

= FM (st) = p (s0) yh (st) . (28)

The same properties hold for the foreign country.

At a Pareto efficient equilibrium allocation, the Fisher equation for the home country

under the inflation rate target is given by:

1 + τ (st−1) = β(1 + r(st−1)

). (29)

Thus, the interest rate that satisfies the Fisher equation in any date-event st is a Markov

process that only depends on the current realization

r(st)

= Fr (st) =1 + τ (st)

β− 1. (30)

The interest rates are nonnegative provided that:

1 + τ (st) ≥ β

for all shocks st ∈ S. The inequality holds given Assumption 3. The same properties hold

for the foreign country.

The exchange rates are also Markov processes if we assume that the contingent inflation

rates are identical for both countries. At the optimal allocation, the uncovered interest rate

parity condition is derived from the Fisher equation (29):

e∗(st)

=(1 + τ (st−1))

(1 + τ∗ (st−1))e∗(st−1

). (31)

Define the scaled financial variables as

b̂h(st)

=bh (st)∏

s′∈st−1 (1 + τ (s′)), (32)

and similarly for each of the 7 other variables.

Part (i): Market clearing

With a Pareto efficient equilibrium allocation, the budget constraint for the home house-

hold in date-event st (and similarly for the foreign household) is given by:

θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) +bh(st)

p(st) (1 + r (st))+

bf (st)

p∗(st) (1 + r∗ (st))(33)

=bh(st−1)

p(st)+bf (st−1)

p∗(st)+

yh (st−1)

1 + τ (st−1).

The real bond payouts are collinear. With dependent assets, a continuum of possible optimal

household bond holdings exists, meaning that it is innocuous to assume bf (st) = bf (st−1) = 0

29

Page 33: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

and b∗h(st) = b∗h(st−1) = 0. In words, households are indifferent and only trade domestic

bonds. Given (32),

bh(st−1)

p(st)=

b̂h(st−1

)p(s0) (1 + τ (st−1))

. (34)

From the Fisher equation (29):

bh(st)

(1 + r (st)) p(st)=

βb̂h (st)

p(s0) (1 + τ (st)). (35)

Consequently, the budget constraints can be updated from (33):

θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) =yh (st−1)

1 + τ (st−1)+

1

p(s0)

(b̂h(st−1

)1 + τ (st−1)

− βb̂h (st)

1 + τ (st)

). (36)

The transition function for the home household is then an implicit function of the equation:

p(s0)

(θ (yh (st) + yf (st))−

yh (st−1)

1 + τ (st−1)

)=

b̂h(st−1

)1 + τ (st−1)

− βb̂h (st)

1 + τ (st). (37)

Mathematically, the difference between the transition function under stabilizing inflation

and under nominal GDP targeting is that the transition function under stabilizing inflation

must account for the endowment variation yh (st−1) . Not only will this prevent a stationary

transition function from being defined, but more importantly will lead to a sequence of

scaled bond holdings that violate the debt constraint (9).

An implicit transition function for the monetary-fiscal authorities can be similarly spec-

ified.

Part (ii): Debt constraint

Consider any fixed time period τ > 0. It cannot be that both

θ (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))− yh (sτ )

1 + τ (sτ )= 0

(1− θ) (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))− yf (sτ )

1 + τ∗ (sτ )= 0

for all sτ ∈ S. If so, then 1 + τ (s) ≥ 1 ∀s ∈ S iff mins∈S

yh (s) ≥ θ (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ )) (and sim-

ilarly, 1 + τ∗ (s) ≥ 1 ∀s ∈ S iff mins∈S

yf (s) ≥ (1− θ) (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))). Taken together, this

implies that yh (s) = θ (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ )) ∀s ∈ S (and yf (s) = (1− θ) (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))

∀s ∈ S) meaning that the endowments are perfectly correlated and equal to the Pareto op-

timal allocation. Such an economy is ruled out by our assumption that endowments are not

perfectly correlated. We then specify, without loss of generality, that(θ (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))− yh(sτ )

1+τ(sτ )

)can be either positive or negative.

Let the realization sτ be such that sτ+k = sτ for k ∈ N and

θ (yh (sτ ) + yf (sτ ))− yh (sτ )

1 + τ (sτ )> 0 (38)

30

Page 34: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

and let the history of shocks sτ be such that b̂h (sτ ) < 0.

Transition function (37) then implies

b̂h (sτ )

1 + τ (sτ )−βk b̂h

(sτ+k

)1 + τ (sτ+k)

> 0 (39)

for k ∈ N. Given that sτ+k = sτ ∀k ∈ N :

βk b̂h(sτ+k

)< b̂h (sτ ) < 0 (40)

for k ∈ N.The debt constraint (9) for the lone independent asset in the portfolio and specified in

terms of the scaled variable is given by:

infk,sτ+k

[b̂h(sτ+k)

(1 + r(sτ+k)) p(s0)

]> −∞. (41)

The interest rate 1+r(sτ+k) is only a function of the current realization sτ+k and is uniformly

bounded. From the strict inequality (40), for any k ∈ N :

βτ+k+1b̂h(sτ+k+1) < βτ+k b̂h(sτ+k

)< 0. (42)

Given that β < 1, then the debt constraint (41) is violated for the home household. If, on

the other hand, b̂h (sτ ) > 0, the realizations sτ+k = sτ ∀k ∈ N are chosen such that the

inequality in (38) is reversed and we obtain a similar expression as (42):

βτ+k+1b̂h(sτ+k+1) > βτ+k b̂h(sτ+k

)> 0. (43)

In this second case, market clearing dictates that the debt constraint (41) is violated for the

foreign household.

This contradiction completes the argument.

Proof of Theorem 3

Proof. Suppose, without loss of generality, that the home country adopts a policy other

than nominal GDP targeting. Suppose, in order to obtain a contradiction, that the station-

ary Markov equilibrium allocation is Pareto efficient. The budget constraint for the home

household in any given date-event st is:

θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) + 1p(st)

(−p(st−1

)yh (st−1) + bh(s

t)1+r(st)

− bh(st−1))

+ 1p∗(st)

(bf (s

t)1+r∗(st)

− bf (st−1))

= 0.

As the home country monetary policy is something other than nominal GDP targeting, then

M(st−2, s

)6= M

(st−2, σ

)for some s, σ ∈ S, implying that p

(st−2, s

)yh (s) 6= p

(st−2, σ

)yh (σ)

for the different shocks st−1 = s and st−1 = σ.

31

Page 35: KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENTdebate on nominal income targeting. 3AsKoenig(2012a) argues: Suitably implemented, nominal-GDP targeting is the more-familiar Taylor rule’s close cousin.

By the definition of a stationary Markov equilibrium, the bond positions are only func-

tions of three variables:(bh(st), bf (st)

)= Fb

(bh(st−1), bf (st−1), st

).

Without aggregate risk, θ (yh (st) + yf (st)) is constant. This implies that the net portfolio

gain1

p (st)

(bh(st)

1 + r (st)− bh(st−1)

)+

1

p∗ (st)

(bf (st)

1 + r∗ (st)− bf (st−1)

)must be a function of the shock st−1 and must vary 1 : 1 with the variation in

(p(st−2, s

)yh (s)

)s∈S .

Household optimization implies that the net portfolio gain defined above is a nonincreas-

ing function of the portfolio bh(st−1)

p(st) +bf (s

t−1)p∗(st) . Given this fact and the definition of the

stationary transition function(bh(st), bf (st)

)= Fb

(bh(st−1), bf (st−1), st

),

the requisite variation in the net portfolio gain is possible iff bh(st−1)

p(st) +bf (s

t−1)p∗(st) are functions

only of the shock st−1, and independent of the previous period portfolio(bh(st−2), bf (st−2)

).

Now apply the same analysis to the budget constraint in the date-event st−1. If the

portfolio gain in st−1,

1

p (st−1)

(bh(st−1)

1 + r (st−1)− bh(st−2)

)+

1

p∗ (st−1)

(bf (st−1)

1 + r∗ (st−1)− bf (st−2)

),

is a constant function of bh(st−2)

p(st−1) +bf (s

t−2)p∗(st−1) , then it is unable to match the variation in(

p(st−3, s

)yh (s)

)s∈S . The only remaining option is that the portfolio gain in st−1 is a

strictly decreasing function of bh(st−2)

p(st−1) +bf (s

t−2)p∗(st−1) . Thus, matching the variation in

(p(st−3, s

)yh (s)

)s∈S

in the st−1 budget constraint results in a contradiction of the conclusion that bh(st−1)

p(st) +

bf (st−1)

p∗(st) are functions only of the shock st−1, and independent of the previous period port-

folio(bh(st−2), bf (st−2)

)(which is required to match the variation in

(p(st−2, s

)yh (s)

)s∈S

in the st budget constraint). This contradiction finishes the argument.

32