KN_spring2012_RD5

download KN_spring2012_RD5

of 27

Transcript of KN_spring2012_RD5

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    1/27

    THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY KOGOD SCHOOL OF BUSINESS | SPRING 2012

    BONDS OF PARTNERSHIP

    Do We Prepare Partners

    Adequately For Challenges?

    CRASH LANDING

    Congress Attempts to

    Deate Golden Parachutes

    WOMENS WORTH

    Why a Token Female Board

    Member Cannot Add Value

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    2/27

    FROMTHE DEAN

    LETTER BY

    MICHAEL J. GINZBERG

    DEAN, KOGOD SCHOOL

    OF BUSINESS

    Nowhere is this more true than in the case o

    amily frms. By exploring this nuance, Proessor

    Ronald Anderson zeroes in on the unique orces

    at play in amily frms that impact corporate gover-

    nance decisions. His groundbreaking research has

    opened up entirely new avenues o thought on what

    amily ties do to, and or, businesses. His collabora-

    tions with Associate Proessors Parthiban David and

    Augustine Duru have revealed that the closely held

    frms with the most market value are also the mosttransparent; he has also uncovered that G reat-Aunt

    Tilly just might be trading a little too early on that

    undisclosed quarterly earnings report.

    Barry Dewberr y, MS 82, provides a captivating

    frst-person perspective on the tough choices amily

    members who double as managers must make when

    planning or the uture o the frm.

    CEO compensation decisions create an intriguing

    quandary or the boards o amily and publicly held

    frms alike. Assistant Proessor Yijiang Zhao joins

    his colleagues David and Duru to consider why a

    handsomely rewarded chie executive, hired to steer

    a company into new seas o opportunity, may be

    taking major risks that yield little return.

    Ready to raid the external audit team or fnan-

    cially savvy leadership? Take heed, warns As sistant

    Proessor Yinqi Zhang: negative investor percep-

    tion, along with regulationincluding the Sarbanes-

    Oxley Actencourages greater distance between

    ormer auditors, auditing frms extraneous business

    services, and their clients.

    Across the board, our aculty are pushing past

    the accepted thinking in fnance, accounting, taxa-

    tion, management, and more. Through their collabo-

    rations with private- and public-sector businesses,

    government agencies, and a bevy o nonproft orga-

    nizations, new knowledge is being created to shape

    the markets o today and tomorrow.

    Creating sustainable value or shareholders, now

    and in the uture, is a complicated endeavor and a

    key concern o Kogod School o Business aculty.The carnage wrought by short-term thinking peppers

    daily headlines and flls congressional committee

    dockets. Market perceptions ormed around green-

    ing core business unctions, like supply chain

    management, are being reconsidered by Proessor

    Bruce Hartman and Assistant Proessor Ayman

    Omar. And DuPonts chie sustainability ofcer,

    Linda Fisher, weighs in on how the global science

    giant helps its clients consider sustainability as a

    business priority.

    Viliying corporations, and their leaders who

    make too much and think too little, has become

    a national pastimeone that will certainly remain

    an undercurrent in the unolding presidential race.

    Yet the long-term value that business gener-

    ates cannot be distilled into a single number. For

    our part, well keep digging deeper into the multi-

    aceted concept o value creation, and examine

    how a little perspective may help bridge the seem-

    ingly insurmountable divide between K Street and

    Main Street.

    Few would argue that good corporate governance is not important to the long-term success o businesses and our entire fnancial system. There is, however,much less agreement on exactly what constitutes good governance.

    IN THIS ISSUE

    1 FROM THE DEAN

    2 THE RISK-RETURN PARADOX

    4 O PARTNER, WHERE ART THOU?

    COVER STORY

    8 Blood in Business13 Relative Leaders

    KOGOD TAX CENTER

    18 Golden Parachutes Get a Lit From Congress

    22 RUSSIAS CORRUPT FREE MARKET

    24 DUX FEMINA FACTIWomen and Board Leadership

    32 KOGOD STANDOUT Adventures in Silicon Valley

    34 THE FRAGILE NATURE OF SUPPLY CHAINS

    39 SUSTAINABILITYS SPLINTER EFFECTS

    40 FINDING FEDERAL SAVINGS IN THE STRATOSPHERE

    PRACTITIONER PERSPECTIVE42 When Succession Planning Goes Beyond the Family

    Barry Dewberry, Chairman, Dewberry, Inc.

    44 The Business Case or SustainabilityLinda Fisher, Chie Sustainability Ofcer, DuPont

    47 REGULATING INDEPENDENCE

    48 WEB EXCLUSIVES Beyond the Page

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    1

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    3/27

    market discipline. In almost every case, the market

    measures tempered the paradox.

    In the presence o weak market mechanisms,

    the risk-return relationship was negative, as the

    paradox predicts. However, as the market mecha-

    nisms gained inuence, the relationship between

    risk and return became less negative. This relation-ship even became positive as the market mecha-

    nisms, such as monitoring by dedicated institutional

    owners, grew stronger.

    The returns to risk taking are increasingly

    positive as the frm aces stronger market orces,

    Zhao said.

    This was what they had hoped. And in the

    context o manager incentives, its clear what led

    to these results.

    A vigilant board o directors, or example, oers

    a powerul deense against brash business plans.

    Board members hold many trump cards; they sign

    o on executives compensation plans, and they also

    approveor disapproveproposals. The presence

    o more outsiders on a board, requent board meet-

    ings, and the separation o duties on the board have

    all proved to take the edge o excessive risk taking.

    IT STOPS AT THE TOP

    There was one notable exception to the markets

    inuence, in the realm o CEO compensation.

    As a corporate governance measure, compensa-

    tion should help to ensure that managers take risks

    only when they are sure to be ollowed by a return.

    When motivated correctly, executives should swingor the ences with shareholders returns in mind,

    rather than their own payos. But the researchers

    point out that this does not hold true when the

    compensation structure isnt working.

    Certainly, CEO compensation has been heavily

    scrutinized and hotly debated. But the risk-return

    paradox has never beore been considered in terms

    o the inuence o market mechanisms, compensa-

    tion being one.

    CEOs are compensated in a myriad o ways,

    but oten the majority percentage o their salary is

    dependent on perormance. A typical compensation

    package includes a mix o total cash compensation

    (salary, bonuses), long-term incentives (restricted

    stock, stock options), benefts, and perks.

    Two compensation methods that the proessors

    ocused on were CEO ownership and stock options.

    They ound that these two components behaved

    quite dierently when analyzed.

    Fundamentally, an owner ship stake exposes

    CEOs to both the upside and downside o a risk.

    Their regression showed that CEO ownership, like

    the other market mechanisms they studied, helped

    alleviate the risk-return paradox.

    Not so with CEO stock options. Thats not too

    surprising; i stock options are never exercised, the

    CEO is not any worse or the wear (even though the

    shareholders suer).Lets say that CEO Barney Johnson is given the

    rights to buy 10,000 shares o Cheap N Quick

    Restaurant Chain or $100 a share in January

    2013. I the companys stock is trading at $120 a

    share at that point in time, Barneys made a cool

    $200,000without investing a personal cent. And

    i the companys stock is only trading at $75 a

    share at the time, well, he simply wont exercise

    his options. At that point the options are called

    out o the money.

    The stock options shield the manager rom the

    downside, so there is a tendency to take excessive

    risks; that is what we are seeing, Duru said. All

    were trying to point out is that stock options could

    lead to distorted incentives.

    NO MAGIC SOLUTION

    The proessors research clearly indicates that

    strong market mechanisms provide some relie or

    the risk-return relationship. But the larger ques-

    tion remains to be answered: Can the market truly

    mitigate managers actions as they seek to climb

    mythical beanstalks? Without the ability to isolate

    the markets individual inuences, the remedy to

    the problem could remain as elusive as Jack himsel.David, Duru, and Zhao expect to submit their

    paper to journals this year.

    THE RISK-RETURN PARADOX

    Ever since young Jack traded his cow or some magic beans, society has boughtinto the concept that greater risk promises greater reward. The relationship istaken or granted as act; empirically, researchers have shown it is fction.

    There is a negative relationship: frms that take

    bigger risks get lower returns. This ies in the ace

    o what we would expect to fnd, said Associate

    Proessor Parthiban David, who holds the Collins

    Chair in Strategic Management. His expertise is in

    corporate governance.

    The risk-return contradiction, known as

    Bowmans paradox, has beuddled management

    scholars or years. Its unavoidable that frms must

    undertake riskeach time they enter a new market,

    launch a new product, or look or creative ways to

    cut costs. But they should do so only when rational

    decision making is at work.

    Heres the conict: managers, not shareholders,

    are the ones making the decisions. And their biases

    and behaviors can cause excessive risk taking in

    two common ways, agree like-minded researchers.

    In Framing, managers categorize perormance

    as either a gain or a loss. When they see a clear

    point or the Win column, risk taking seems like

    a threat. But when a project is seen as a loss,

    then risks are suddenly viewed in a new light: as

    potential salvation. Simply classiying a project as

    a loss prompts the manager to take an excessive

    risk to get it back on track.

    Overconfdence is easier to relate to. By overes-

    timating their own competence or the frms uture

    prospects (or by underestimating their competition),

    prideul managers are led astray. They buoy their

    own belie in the likelihood o a positive return.

    Aligning risk and return is a riddle worth

    solving, because there are deep consequences

    or the company when a risk doesnt pay o.

    Beyond the direct fnancial hit to the frm, risks

    can lead a frm to grow its personnel or reallocate

    its resources gratuitously. They can also negatively

    aect consumers confdence in the frms products.

    No one is arguing that risks should never be

    taken. On the contrary, managers must be induced

    to take risks, the authors write, but only those

    that are likely to produce gains.

    CHECKS AND BALANCES

    For the frst time, the Kogod proessors looked at the

    perplexing risk-return relationship in the context o

    market mechanisms. They wanted to unearth whether

    the markets role could help explain the paradox.

    Is the market, let to its own devices, capable o

    correcting managers mistakes? Market mechanisms

    might be the reason that the risk-return relationship is

    not working well, said Associate Proessor Augustine

    Duru, who had previously studied CEO compensation

    in the context o accounting.

    In theory, these mechanisms should constrain

    the managers rom taking excessive risks. For

    example, the labor market could act as a constraint

    to an overzealous CEO; i he takes unwise risks and

    is fred, he may not be able to fnd another job.

    David, Duru, and their colleague, Assistant

    Proessor Yijiang Zhao, undertook the project.

    Zhaos research background in corporate gover-

    nance (in particular, takeover markets) and fnancial

    reporting primed him or the eort.

    The researchers studied how two broad types

    o mechanismscorporate governance measures

    and product market competitionwould aect

    the risk-return relationship. With a sample o more

    than 2,100 frms rom the S&P 1500, the authors

    studied perormance over a 12-year period and

    tested the interaction between the relationship and

    each o these market mechanisms:

    Institutional ownership

    Blockholder ownership (concentrated owners)

    External corporate governance (measured

    through frms antitakeover provisions)

    Board o directors monitoring

    CEO ownership

    CEO stock options

    Product market competition

    Using regression analysis, the proessors simu-

    lated the eect o each mechanism on the risk-

    return relationship. They controlled or other actors

    that might aect perormance, such as frm size,

    leverage, and diversifcation, as well as the possi-

    bility that risk taking can arise rom withinsay,

    in frms operating in high-perormance industries

    (like the high-tech sector).

    They ound that Bowmans paradox is direr

    or companies that are not subject to efcient

    ARTICLE BY

    JACKIE SAUTER

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    3

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    2

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    4/27

    O PARTNER,WHERE ART THOU?

    Contrary to the romantic notion o a passionate dreamer going it alone, moststart-ups are ounded by partners, not solo entrepreneurs. Think o some othe high-tech companies that have risen to ame and stunning capitalization inalmost no time: Google, Facebook, LivingSocial. All started by partners.

    DAVID GAGE, PHD,

    IS A CLINICAL

    PSYCHOLOGIST AND

    MEDIATOR, CO-

    FOUNDER OF BMC

    ASSOCIATES, AND

    ADJUNCT PROFESSOR

    AT THE KOGOD SCHOOL

    OF BUSINESS. HIS

    BOOK ON EFFECTIVE

    PARTNERSHIPS,

    THE PARTNERSHIP

    CHARTER: HOW TO

    START OUT RIGHT WITH

    YOUR NEW BUSINESS

    PARTNERSHIP (OR FIX

    THE ONE YOURE IN),

    WAS PUBLISHED

    IN 2004.

    The trend isnt limited to cutting-edge tech frms.

    Partners also ounded some o the best-known

    companies o the 20th century: Black & Decker,

    Warner Bros., Hewlett-Packard. And then there are

    3M, Costco, Microsot, Intel, and Apple. Partners,

    too, ounded them.

    PARTNER ADVANTAGES

    Partnerswhether they are amily members or

    notare extremely important because their pres-

    ence boosts the chance o success. It seems

    like common sense; ater all, there is strength in

    numbers. Generally speaking, partners mean greater

    resources: more skills, energy, capital, psychological

    support, networking capabilities.

    Need urther proo? A study published last year

    by the National Bureau o Economic Research tried

    to determine whether having partners is really an

    advantageous strategy or entrepreneurs trying tocommercialize inventions. The results were impres-

    sive. Projects run by partners were fve times more

    likely to reach commercialization, and their average

    revenues were approximately 10 times greater than

    projects run by solo entrepreneurs.

    Research rom Marquette University backs that

    up. The researchers investigated a sample o nearly

    2,000 companies, categorizing the top perormers

    as hypergrowth companies. Solo entrepreneurs

    ounded only 6 percent o the hypergrowth compa-

    nies. Partners ounded an amazing 94 percent.

    One or all and all or one! Even Alexandre

    Dumas knew there needed to be three Muske-

    teersnot one.

    UNDENIABLE RISKS

    So why wouldnt all start-ups begin with co-owners

    at the helm? Because there is also a dark side to

    the partner story.

    There are no hard numbers that spell out how

    many companies die premature deaths as a result

    o partner difculties. Private companies are not

    obliged to undergo a postmortem, but estimates

    oten run to more than 50 percent ailure within

    a ew years.

    We know that many business advisers regu-

    larly warn entrepreneurs not to start businesses

    with partners, oering horror stories rom past

    clients. There are too many risks involved, and

    its extremely difcult to extract yoursel rom par t-

    ners, they warn.

    The risks arenumerous. Many would-be business

    owners are under the dangerous misconception that

    completing certain legal documents ully prepares

    them or partnership. I anything, these legalities

    give partners a alse sense o security that they

    have done all they need to do to protect themselves.

    I we accept that partner problems are a leading

    cause o start-up ailure, we have to ask: Why arent

    we doing more to educate and train entrepreneursto maximize the benefts and minimize the risks o

    co-ownership? Why arent organizations that und

    entrepreneurial research helping start-ups prepare

    better or the challenges o having partners? Why

    arent VCs asking start-ups to do more to ensure

    their survival?

    As advisers to entrepreneurs and business

    students, we are not guiding them out o harms way.

    We are not teaching them sufciently about either

    the risks o having partnerstur battles, person-

    ality clashes, values conicts, money disputes,

    distrustor how to minimize them.

    The box ofce hit The Social Network helped

    bring this issue to light in 2010, when moviegoers

    turned out en masse to watch the story o Mark

    Zuckerberg and his ill-ated Facebook co-ounder

    Eduardo Saverin unold on the big screen. A high-

    profle multimillion-dollar lawsuit between the two

    was eventually settled out o court.

    And Saverin wasnt the only one to haul the

    Facebook co-ounder to court. How do we prepare

    entrepreneurs or the Winklevoss twins o the

    worldthose who publicly allege they hold partner

    status, even though they may not?But helping uture Mark Zuckerbergs mitigate their

    risks is not sufcient either. We need to also teach

    them how to proactively create healthy partnerships.

    PREPARATION FOR SUCCESS

    Reviewing the curricula o our peer business schools

    reveals that very ew oer courses or entrepre-

    neurs who want to learn how to set up healthy

    business-partner relationships. Courses on lead-

    ership, managing teams, choosing among legal

    entities, and identiying unding are valuable to

    entrepreneurs, but miss the mark when it comes

    to having partners.

    Developing and maintaining good relationships

    with partners is not the same as leading an execu-

    tive team or managing a company o a thousand

    employees. The intimate dynamics among part-

    ners are quite dierent rom the dynamics o any

    employer-employee relationship.

    True co-owners tie their utures and ortunes

    together in a unique way. Partners have a fduciary

    duty, and a loyalty, to one another that employers do

    not have to their employees, even i they give them

    honorifc partner or associate titles.

    Business schools arent the only ones behindthe partner curve. Incubation labs, economic devel-

    opment centers, the Small Business Association,

    venture unds, and even other private organizations

    ocused on helping entrepreneurs seem to miss the

    importanceand the challengeso having partners.

    To address some o these defciencies, I devel-

    oped and have taught a graduate course at Kogod

    or the past 10 years on managing private and

    amily businesses. It covers the range o partner

    issues described above, delves into the value o

    co-ownership, and gives students concrete strate-

    gies to minimize the risks. In my view, more schools

    need to experiment with courses to help students

    understand partnerships.

    ABSENCE OF ATTENTION

    I we are going to improve our perormance in

    teaching about partnership, it will be important

    to create a sound base o research or the lessons

    we convey. To date, there is very little scholarship

    available on this subject.

    One reason or this is the complexity o the feld.

    How many times have you heard the amous line, Its

    not personal, its just business rom The Goda-

    ther? For partners, amily business owners, and even

    mafosi, it couldnt be urther rom the truth. Almost

    everything that occurs among partners in closely held

    companies is both personal andbusiness. Co-owners

    constantly describe their partner relationship as a

    marriage, but hasten to add, Except I spend more

    time with my business partner!

    Recognizing the duality is advantageous.

    Researchers need to develop a realistic conceptu-

    alization o the challenges that partners ace, one

    that ully appreciates the interpersonal-business

    pairing o partnerships.

    Anything less will be too simplistic to be helpul.

    The ocus has to be on the individuals who do busi-

    ness together, not on the business itsel.

    Unortunately, researchers who want to study

    partners oten eel slightly out o their element. Theyare typically experts in one disciplinepsychology

    or businessbut not both. Researchers rom

    dierent disciplines may need to collaborateas

    partners!to study this topic eectively.

    Another hurdle is the act that closely held

    businesses are truly closely held. They are private,

    which is an advantage or co-owners but a barrier

    or researchers. Researchers will need to provide

    partners with an incentive to share private inor-

    mation. Without a reason to open up, partners will

    likely remain something o a mystery.

    MEDIATION AS AN ACADEMIC RESOURCE

    As the ounder o a irm that specializes in

    preventing and resolving co-owner disputes, I have

    learned that mediation is not only a process that

    partners usually agree on when they have serious

    dierences. It is also a process that opens the door

    to the private, inner workings o partners.

    I discovered that the confdentiality o media-

    tion helps partners open up and discuss things

    THE INTIMATE DYNAMICS

    AMONG PARTNERS AREQUITE DIFFERENT FROM THEDYNAMICS OF ANY EMPLOYER-EMPLOYEE RELATIONSHIP.

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    5

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    4

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    5/27

    they would otherwise never reveal to a stranger,

    rom plans to sell the company to creative and

    sometimes ill-conceived methods or taking moneyrom the business.

    Behind this shield o confdentiality, partners in

    mediation quickly realize that they only hurt them-

    selves i they play their cards too close to the chest.

    Mediators, like mysel, strive to convince the parties

    that to be eective, we must know everything that

    has transpired. We need to understand how their

    partnership works.

    Part o the conict resolution process involves

    separate, individual caucus sessions in which

    each partner has a chance to lay his or her story

    completely on the table. They are oten quick to

    seize this opportunity, because they believe that

    i they dont disclose something, another partner

    almost certainly willand no one wants to be seen

    as withholding key inormation, or appear to have

    something to hide. Partner mediations have thus

    been ertile ground or learning about what makes

    partners tickand stop ticking.

    CASE IN POINT

    Heres one example, rom more than two decades

    o mediating business partnerships, that illustrates

    one o the common challenges partners ace and

    or which they are ill prepared: determining owner-

    ship percentages.

    These partners, who ran a company in an

    emerging medical device industry, were not

    neophytes by any stretch o the imagination.

    Numbering fve in total, they included a successul

    CEO rom a regional consulting frm, an attorney,

    a seasoned marketer, a physician-investor, and an

    established medical researcher.

    As all partners must do, they had to determine

    their respective percentages o ownership. From

    the starting gate, each began jockeying or as large

    an interest as possible. Like orty-niners staking

    their gold rush claims, each o the fve ought or

    his share o equity. Eventually they ollowed the

    conventional advice o their advisers and flled in

    the blanks o an operating agreement. The stormappeared to pass.

    Exactly one year later, the consulting irm

    CEO (now the CEO o the new company) and the

    researcher claimed that they had all agreed to review

    everyones perormance ater a years operation,

    and then adjust their percentages accordingly.

    The lawyer and the marketing director disagreed

    vehemently, claiming that the idea o revising the

    percentages had been raised but then dismissed.

    The physician-investor, a riend o both the

    marketing director and the CEO, demurred, saying

    he was unable to remember the decision.

    The resulting deadlock took a toll on their rela-

    tionships, their motivation, and their productivity.

    Worse, their employees were becoming aware o

    the disagreement. With threats o lawsuits hanging

    in the air, the partners agreed to try mediation.

    The convoluted dynamics among the partners

    quickly became apparent in individual discussions

    with mediators. The mediation was an in-depth

    study o the complexity o determining ownership

    percentages, and it revealed how tightly the part-

    ners egos were wrapped around these percentages.

    Since they were united around the goal o growing

    and selling the company in a ew years, they wereacutely aware o the value o every percentage point.

    With the help o the mediators, the owners even-

    tually resolved the equity battle. In brie, some o

    the partners agreed to reduce their percentages to

    ree up equity or certain key employees, and they

    shited certain management responsibilities to resolve

    underperormance issues. The details can be ound in

    my book on having partners, The Partnership Charter:

    How to Start Out Right With Your New Business

    Partnership (or Fix the One Youre In).

    Four things are important about this case study.

    First, mediation provided an opening to better

    understand how partners operate. Second, the

    plot line is very common: some variation o this

    true story occurs in most partnerships.

    Third, despite it being a common problem,

    there is almost nothing written to help entrepre-

    neurs with a more rational process or determining

    equity percentages. And fnally, this story describes

    but one o the many challenges partners may ace.

    THE BOOKAND BEYOND

    The lessons I learned rom scores o mediation

    clients became the blueprint or The PartnershipCharter. The book talks on the interpersonal side

    about personalities, values, expectations, and air-

    ness. On the business side are roles and responsi-

    bilities, decision making, governance, money, and

    ownership. Partners also have to decide how they

    will handle dierences.

    A scenario-planning process orces partners to

    prepare or the uncharted waters that lie in ront o

    them. Some o the what-is they need to prepare

    or are unique to having partners:

    What happens i a partner hires a key

    employee whom the other partner(s)

    dislike(s)?

    How will you decide how to respond to an

    unsolicited buyout oer rom a competitor?

    What i the partners decide to close the busi-

    ness and the company has nothing but debt?

    Though mediation has taught us a great deal,

    we need to investigate the inner world o partners

    with more typical research paradigms and tech-

    niques. The research topics are many, but could

    include the importance o fnancial transparency,

    whether establishing a governing board mitigates

    conict, and whether a partnership with a best

    riend improves, or lessens, the chance o success.

    Despite the gap in partnership know-how, we

    have learned a signiicant amount about what

    causes partners to all out with one another.

    While there are numerous topics partners must

    address, the most important step they can take is

    to engage in a comprehensive planning process.

    To get the ball rolling, my business partner

    and I have also set up a website or The Busi-

    ness Partner Institute, an organization that can

    help people to share research ideas and explore

    interdisciplinary collaboration.

    By joining eortsas partners doI have no

    doubt that we can dramatically improve the short-

    and long-term success rate o start-ups.

    PARTNER MEDIATIONS HAVEBEEN FERTILE GROUND FORLEARNING ABOUT WHAT

    MAKES PARTNERS TICK ANDSTOP TICKING.

    WHAT IF?

    WHAT IF THE PARTNERSDECIDE TO CLOSE THEBUSINESS AND THECOMPANY HAS NOTHINGBUT DEBT?

    HOW WILL YOU DECIDEHOW TO RESPONDTO AN UNSOLICITEDBUYOUT OFFER FROMA COMPETITOR?

    WHAT HAPPENS IF APARTNER HIRES A KEYEMPLOYEE WHOM THEOTHER PARTNER(S)DISLIKE(S)?

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    7

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    6

    Sorry!WE ARE

    CLOSED

    $

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    6/27

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    9

    ARTICLE BY JACKIE SAUTER

    I "The Godather" truly provided the answer to any business question, there wouldbe a lot less angst about how to motivate employees. Its not a stretch to contend

    that business was simpler under the Mobs thumb. Processes and procedureswere understood: amily came frst. The appearance o propriety was

    paramount. No Sicilian could reuse a request on his daughterswedding day. And i gambling debts arent paying the bills,

    its time to diversiy the business. Why not tryan emerging market?

    JOHNDOE

    JR.

    JOHNDOEIII

    RACHELROEJACOBDO

    ESR.

    RICHARD

    ROESR.

    JOHNDOEIV

    REGINAROEJACOB DOEJR.

    JACKIEDOE

    RICHARDROEJR.

    JANEDOE

    JOHNDOESR.

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    7/27

    But imagine how turbulent the markets would be i

    a violation o respect resulted in literal bloodshed.

    It would make 2008 look like a banner year.

    The key was that in the gangster-ridden world o

    Old New York, everyone in the organization had

    aligned goals: preserve pride, proft, and a pulse.

    The same cant be said or modern-day frms.

    This indisputable act has given rise to the feld o

    corporate governance, which endeavors to mitigate the

    myriad conicts between managers and shareholders.

    It all boils down to a matter o diverging interests.

    Shareholders frst priority is to maximize their

    own wealth: stock prices should go up, dividends

    should be paid.

    Shareholders are oten thousands o miles

    away; they generally dont want to know about

    the day-to-day operationsthere is a separa-

    tion between management and ownership, said

    Proessor Ronald Anderson, who has spent the last

    decade researching corporate governance, particu-

    larly in amily frms. Anderson holds the Gary D.

    Cohn Proessorship in Finance.

    On the other hand, no one is entirely sure whatcompany managers hold sacred. They should be

    ocused on maximizing shareholder wealth, but they

    have a natural tendency to protect themselves and

    maximize their own utility, Anderson said, citing

    examples like the implosion o Enron and scandal

    at Tyco. Its a problem that has reared its head a

    lot over the last 10 to 12 years.

    ITS NOT PERSONAL

    A companys ownership structure should be a super-

    uous ingredient in its success, but Anderson and

    his colleagues have proved that amily owners are o

    a unique avor. Firms with controlling amily owners

    (those who wield sufcient power to enorce deci-

    sions) are singularly motivated. Though the amily

    members may not be as hands-on as Vito Corleone,

    their frms make distinctive investment choices, and

    ourishor ounderin certain circumstances.

    Spurred by the lack o research on amily frms,

    Anderson and colleague David M. Reeb, now at the

    National University o Singapore, began in the late

    1990s to evaluate amily ownership and its connec-

    tion to frm perormance. Their fndings changed the

    way academics and practitioners view this previously

    underrated demographic.

    Further research at Kogod has investigated

    amily frms transparency, proclivity or insider

    trading, investment choices, and the impact o

    amily-style debt. The surprising fndings serve

    as indicators o how this inimitable slice o the

    business world stands apart.

    FAMILY FIRSTIn hindsight, amilies should have gotten acclaim

    beyond the box ofce or their business skills. Ater

    all, amily owners are highly incentivized to pay

    attention: on average, amily owners have held their

    shares or more than 78 years, and have 69 percent

    o their personal wealth invested in the frm. They

    have a vested interest in ensuring that the managers

    running their companies are protecting their assets.

    Anderson and Reeb proved that despite their

    bumbling portrayal in the media (see: the Bluths o

    HBOs Arrested Development), amily frms are more

    valuable than diusely owned frms, which are held

    by a large number o shareholders and investors.

    Family businesses are also highly prevalent.

    Thirty-fve percent o Fortune 500 companies and

    60 percent o publicly held companies in the US

    are amily-controlled, according to the advocacy

    group Family Enterprise USA.

    It turns out amily presence cannot be ignored.

    Just as overbearing amilies tend to weigh in on deci-

    sions or our own good, frms with actively engaged

    amily owners generally outperormed frms without

    an active amily member. Decades ater public frms

    initial oerings, many amily members continue to

    hold hands-on positions in day-to-day operations.

    The fndings ignited a urry o attention rom

    academic and mainstream media, including aBusinessweekcover story. For Anderson, the next

    questions quickly took shape: Why are these frms

    more valuableand under what circumstances?

    NOW YOU SEE ME

    In their recent article in the Journal o Financial

    Economics, the pair invited Associate Proessor

    Augustine Duru to study the eects o corporate

    transparency on amily frms. Thanks to his prior

    research on the use o accounting inormation in

    CEO compensation, Duru had expertise in measuring

    transparency through an accounting lens.

    Like many others, Duru had initially assumed

    that amily irms would be less valuable than

    diusely owned frms. But my colleagues empirical

    work showed that, certainly, amily frms were more

    valuable. It seemed counterintuitive, Duru said.Past research has demonstrated that corporate

    transparency is crucial in order to protect share-

    holders and mitigate conict between large and

    small investors. But no one had studied transpar-

    ency specifcally within the context o amily frms .

    When they decided to bring in the accounting

    perspective, Duru noted, the question became: I

    we believe that accounting inormation is important

    to frm perormance, what would happen i there

    was a lack o inormation?

    While all publicly traded frms must comply

    with mandatory accounting disclosures, the authors

    acknowledge that there is still substantial variation

    in what frms choose to revealas well as in the

    amount o outside scrutiny they receive. Firms can

    also elect to engage in voluntary disclosures.

    Transparency is clearly a choice; there are

    public companies that are not as transparent as

    they could be, Anderson said. But some o it

    is market-driven, and some o it is shareholder-

    driven as well.

    To test their theories, the researchers built an

    index that ranked the opacity o the largest 2,000

    US frms. Family involvement was defned as frms

    in which the ounders or heirs maintain inuence,

    usually through an equity stake. About 22 percent

    o the frms in the sample were ounder-controlled,

    and another 25 percent heir-controlled.

    Opacity was categorized using our actors

    that indicated the levels o both internal and

    external opacity:

    Trading volume and bid-ask spread,

    which lend insight into the amount o

    inormation uncertainty

    Analyst ollowing and analyst orecast

    errors, which help explain the availability

    o frms inormation

    The researchers determined that both types o

    amily frms are signifcantly more opaque (by about

    fve percent) than diuse shareholder frms. Their

    shares trade less than those in diuse shareholder

    frms and exhibit signifcantly less analyst ollowing,

    they wrote.

    Analysts are important because they play a

    monitoring role. Large, publicly traded multina-

    tional frms are subjected to scrutiny; multiple

    monitoring keeps controlling amilies on their best

    behavior, just as the looming threat o the Five

    Families did in the Godathers world.

    How does opacity impact other shareholders

    wealth, beyond the amily? Since amily frms are

    more valuableand tend to be more opaquethen

    was opacity more valuable?

    The opposite was true.

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    11

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    10

    THERE APPEARS TO BE A LOT MOREINFORMED TRADING GOING ON INFAMILY FIRMS; GIVEN THE MAGNITUDEOF IT, SOME OF IT IS LIKELY ILLEGAL.

    RONALD ANDERSON, PROFESSOR

    JUST AS OVERBEARINGFAMILIES TEND TO WEIGH INON DECISIONS FOR OUR OWNGOOD, FIRMS WITH ACTIVELYENGAGED FAMILY OWNERSGENERALLY OUTPERFORMEDFIRMS WITHOUT AN ACTIVEFAMILY MEMBER.

    WMT1.95M@62

    .11

    [email protected] [email protected] 0.16...CPB455

    [email protected] [email protected] 0.04

    COVER STORY BLOOD IN BUSINESS

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    8/27

    Where a positive relationship existed between

    amily ownership and perormance, it was limited

    to frms with a high level o corporate transparency.

    When the corporate inormation environment was

    opaque, however, amily frms ceased to be as valu-

    able as frms without amily owners.

    When its harder to see whats going on inside

    the company, it is much harder or the market to

    monitor the amily, and as a consequence maybe

    the amily can misbehave, Anderson said. Opacity

    reduces the ability o outsiders to police opportunism

    by amily frms. Simply put, the top-perorming amily

    frms are also the most transparent.

    Think Walmart. The Walton amilys massive

    multinational is currently ollowed by 36 analysts,

    all o whom are listed on the Walmart website, along

    with extensive stock inormation, historical pricing,

    and governance documents. The worlds largest

    retailer is also covered widely in the news media.

    For Walmart, there is no escape rom scrutiny.

    The researchers also looked at CEO types in

    these transparent top perormers. In their sample

    the original ounders held the top spot

    37.7 percent o the time;

    outsiders, like Campbell Soup Co.s

    Denise Morrison, 34.2 percent; and

    heirs, such as Nordstrom Inc.s

    Blake Nordstrom, 28.1 percent.

    Transparent amily frms led by an outsider

    perormed best, ollowed by those led by ounders

    and then heirs. Yet all three types o these trans-

    parent amily frms still outperormed transparent,

    diusely owned frms.

    In the absence o a highly transparent environ-

    ment, there was no evidence o a beneft attributableto amily ownership. In act, in more opaque amily

    frms, there was a negative relationship: as opacity

    increased, perormance ell. Opaque amily frms

    perormed worse than any other type o frm. In those

    muddy waters, amilies can exploit control to extract

    private benefts at the expense o smaller investors.

    Its clear that shareholdersand thus the

    S&Pvalue ounder or heir involvement only when

    those amily values include fnancial transparency.

    TAKE THE CANNOLI

    As it turns out, inormed trading may also be a

    amily aair. And when there are short sales, theres

    gonna be trouble.

    Andersons latest project, with coauthors Reeb

    and Wanli Zhao o Worcester Polytechnic Institute,

    fnds that amily frms boast substantially higher

    volume o abnormal short sales, where traders bet

    on a companys poor perormance.

    There appears to be a lot more inormed

    trading going on in amily frms; given the magnitude

    o it, some o it is likely illegal, Anderson explained.

    Prior studies have ound that amily owners are

    among the best inormed o shareholders. Anderson

    postulates that this is attributable to a ew actors.

    For instance, they are likely to know about skeletons

    in the amily closet. Also, amily members who do

    not serve in senior management at the frm can y

    under regulators radar more easily, and potentially

    avoid detection.

    O course, outside investors could play a role

    in these antics by gleaning inormation rom a

    amily member and using it or personal beneft.

    Or perhaps the short sales are a product o disgrun-

    tled employees who perceive amily domination as

    hurting the frm.

    Take the case o Robert Chestman, a stock-

    broker convicted on insider trading charges ollowing

    the 1986 takeover o Waldbaum Inc., a New York-

    based grocery chain now owned by the Great

    Atlantic and Pacifc Tea Company. The Securities

    and Exchange Commission (SEC) asserted that Mr.

    Chestman had received nonpublic inormation rom

    a member o the Waldbaum amily, which he used

    to trade 11,000 shares o company stock.

    But Chestman was by no means the only one

    selling. In the days beore the companys announce-

    ment, the trading volume in Waldbaum stock skyrock-

    eted. In two days, trading climbed rom 2,300 shares

    to more than 77,000 shares traded daily, according

    to The New York Timesand the SEC.

    Insider trading hardly capped in the 1980s.

    In 2005, ormer senator Bill Frist, heir to the or-

    proft hospital chain HCA, raised the SECs ire. The

    commission conducted an 18-month investigation

    into Frists sale o his blind trust o HCA shares,

    but ultimately did not press charges. Frist ordered

    the sale during a peak in the stocks trading; weeks

    later, a less than stellar earnings report drove the

    share price down by nine percent, according to

    USA Today.

    THE VALUE OF DISCRETION

    Inormation leakage was at the center o Andersons

    study. At the root o short sales is the spread o

    nonpublic inormation. By identiying and homing

    in on the times when short sales preceded negative

    earnings surprises, the researchers made the issue

    empirical. The question: Does amily presence aid

    or impede inormed trading?

    They analyzed short sales that occurred prior

    to earnings surprises, merging the SECs short-

    sales database with their own inormation on amily

    ownership in the largest US frms. The resulting

    sample was 1,571 strong, with amily frms making

    up more than one-third o the sample.

    Rather than ocusing on the motivation o the

    sellers, the researchers simply sought to uncover

    whether insider trading was more prevalent in

    amily frms.

    It was. Family frms experienced almost 17

    times more abnormal short s elling preceding nega-

    COVER STORY BLOOD IN BUSINESS

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    12

    Compiled by Nicole Federica and Jackie Sauter

    Founder CEO

    Michael Dell, Dell Inc.

    NASDAQ: DELL

    Mark Zuckerberg wasnt the frst

    tech entrepreneur to start a

    billion-dollar enterprise rom a dorm

    room. Dell began his computer

    business at the University o Texas in

    1984. By 1992, the then-27-year-old had become the youngest CEO

    o a Fortune 500 company.

    Dell has since racked up accolades,

    written a book on his success, and

    served on the US Presidents

    Council o Advisors on Science and

    Technology. Though he stepped

    down as CEO in 2004, he returned

    to the position in 2007 at the

    request o the board o directors.

    The Texan has our teenage

    children; perhaps a successor is in

    their midst? In the meantime, Dell

    Inc. announced plans to launch its

    frst consumer tablet late this year.

    Proessional Manager CEO

    Denise Morrison,

    Campbell Soup Company

    NYSE: CPB

    Denise Morrison, president and CEO o

    Campbell Soup Company, hails rom a

    amily o successul businesswomen.

    Perhaps, then, its appropriate that

    she took over leadership o the

    amily-rooted company in August2011. Morrison is only the 12th CEO

    in Campbells 140-year history, and its

    frst emale leader; she joined the

    company in 2003.

    With 35 years experience in the

    packaged goods industry, Morrison

    started in the sales department o

    Procter & Gamble, and previously

    served at Pepsi-Cola, Nestl USA,

    Nabisco Inc., and Krat Foods.

    Campbells has projected net sales

    growth between 0 and 2 percent

    in 2012.

    Heir CEO

    Micky Arison, Carnival Cruises

    NYSE: CCL

    Micky Arison is the CEO o Carnival

    Cruises CCL, the cruise operator

    that owns brands such as AIDA,

    Seabourn, Carnival, Ibero, and a

    series o others. His ather, Ted,

    ounded the business in 1972.Micky joined in 1974 and worked

    his way up to the chairman role in

    1990; he became known or

    acquisitions, including the purchase

    o Holland America Line in 1989

    and P&O Princess Cruises in 2002.

    The Israeli American also owns the

    NBAs Miami Heat.

    Hes no stranger to controversy;

    early this year, the partial sinking o

    cruise ship Costa Concordiain Italy

    claimed at least 17 lives, with many

    more injured or missing. The

    company said it expected a $175

    million hit against net income in

    fscal 2012 as a result o the

    disaster, according to Reuters.

    ESTABLIS

    HED1984

    INHERITE

    D1990

    HIRED20

    03

    RELATIVE LEADERS

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    9/27

    tive earnings shocks than nonamily frms, the

    authors wrote. These frms also had marginally ewer

    abnormal short sales beore positive surprises

    indicating that more sellers were hanging on to their

    stock in anticipation o good news.

    This was no coincidence. The presence o amily

    members as managers or board members increased

    the likelihood o short sales. The researchers

    contrasted amily ownership with that o hedge

    unds, private equity unds, and other large-block

    shareholders, but did not fnd the same results.

    There are regulatory implications. Despite

    the researchers fndings, the SECs enorcement

    actions o late have ocused on hedge unds, with

    22 enorcements between 2006 and 2008 against

    the unds, and zero fled against amily owners.

    Further investigation reveals zero enorcements fled

    against amily owners through early 2012.

    Certainly, the SEC takes abuse o short sales

    seriously. The commission has held numerous

    public hearings, enacted new rules on naked

    short sales, and required more transparency about

    the short-selling process. The ocus on short sales is

    warranted: the SEC says that short selling comprised

    almost hal o US equities volume, based on data

    provided by exchanges or June 2010.

    Our analysis suggests that regulations to reduce

    inormed trading, while potentially limiting such

    activity in nonamily frms, appear substantially

    less eective in amily frms, Anderson concluded.

    DO ME THIS FAVOR

    O course, in order or earnings surprises to occur,

    frms have to play a role in the action. That could

    mean an acquisition or investing in a new business

    venture. And the latter oten requires frms, and

    their managers, to borrow money.

    Debt can be a tricky business, and all debt is

    not equalnow that debt is no longer traded inMafa-style personal avors, that is.

    No one knows this better than Associate Proessor

    Parthiban David, whose expertise ocuses on the

    impact o corporate governance on frm perormance.

    David holds the Collins Chair in Strategic Management.

    David, along with coauthor Jonathan OBrien

    o Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, examined how

    the type o frm debt is related to growth. The pair

    chose Japanese frms to make up the sample, due

    to their predilection or growth.

    On its ace, growth is a noble goalbut

    there can be too much o a good thing. Excessive

    growth can harm profts i managers dont share

    the resulting wealth with investors, and instead

    unnel it back into the frm.

    Debt helps to keep managers in check: they

    have to make interest payments, repay the balance

    at the end o a contract, and ace the threat o

    deault. Just as amily-owned frms are inherently

    anchored in relationships, orms o debt can also

    have a relational quality. And debt plays an impor-

    tant, pseudo-parental role in corporate governance.

    Exhibit A: Bank loans are built on relationships.

    Business owners have a rapport with the bankers

    who invest in the growth o their businesses. Loans

    are not merely dollars and cents to the bank (or so

    they would have us believe); rather, banks assess

    the complete picture o the borrower and company.

    They also consider the possibility o ancillary

    business relationships that might orm down the

    line; loans could be a oot in the door to a more

    robust, potentially lucrative relationship. Oten

    bank representatives will hold seats on the frms

    board o directors, provide other business services

    beyond lending, and have relationships with the

    frms customers and suppliers.

    Bank loans are long term, David said,

    explaining that both sides build trust and may act

    as partners. Banks have business relationships;

    growth is important to them, because more growth

    means more business.

    In contrast, bonds are transactional, impersonal

    orms o debt. Bonds allow lenders to keep their

    borrowers at arms length. These securities are

    diusely held, and lenders are ocused solely on

    the returns they earn.

    Consider the case o Columbia Sportswear Co.,

    a amily-owned business that began selling hats

    in 1938.

    Ater the 1970 death o the amily patriarch,

    the near-insolvent company struggled to stay aoat;

    it had already taken a $150,000 loan rom the

    Small Business Administration. Within two years

    the company racked up a negative net worth o

    $300,000, according to Funding Universe.

    Yet the Boyle amily was able to draw more

    credit rom its bank; bank ofcers even suggested

    the amily consult an adviser, which was the frst

    step on a path toward stability and then growth,

    the owners told Family Businessmagazine. Theinusion o credit happened to pay o; Columbia

    has come a long way since then, projecting revenues

    o $1.7 billion in 2011.

    SO WHATS THE RUB?

    There is no question that relational debts are benef-

    cial to frms that invest substantially in R&D. The

    long-term relationship between lender and borrower

    allows continuity o investment; the bank can step

    in more easily i the frm were to deault.

    Transactional debt was more eective in

    preventing overinvestment in irm growth than

    relational debt. While relational debt may lead to

    more growth, the growth may hurt profts, David

    and OBrien concluded.

    This may be best understood with an example

    one thats all too amiliar.

    In 1980s Japan, stock and real estate markets

    peaked, and real estate was all the rage. Many frms

    that previously had never invested in real estate

    were tempted to get in on the action.

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    15

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    14

    COVER STORY BLOOD IN BUSINESS

    ON ITS FACE, GROWTHIS A NOBLE GOALBUT THERE CAN BETOO MUCH OF A GOODTHING. EXCESSIVEGROWTH CAN HARMPROFITS IF MANAGERSDONT SHARE THERESULTING WEALTHWITH INVESTORS...DEBT HELPS TO KEEPMANAGERS IN CHECK.

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    10/27

    COVER STORY BLOOD IN BUSINESS

    As Northwesterns I. Serdar Dinc discovered,

    frms that had relational debt were more likely than

    those with transactional debt to make real estate

    investments. When the bubble burst less than 10

    years later, they were hurt badly. Parthiban Davids

    work implies that the leniency o those relational

    lenders led to that overinvestment, which ultimately

    weakened the frms.

    I debt is to be used eectively or corporate

    governance, then managersand shareholders,

    amily or otherwiseneed to understand the vast

    dierences provided by these two diverging orms

    o debt.

    GO TO THE MATTRESSES

    Debt was something that J. Willard Marriott

    detested. When the ounder o Marriott Interna-

    tional wanted to ocus on growing Hot Shoppes, the

    amilys modest restaurant chain, his heir saw the

    promise o hotels. Getting into bed with the hospi-

    tality industry meant going into debt, something

    the elder Marriott avoided at all costs.

    Debt was something that [my ather] didnt

    understand, and he hated ithe didnt want

    anything to do with it, Bill Marriott once told The

    Washington Post. Luckily or travelers, J. Willards

    son went to the mattresses or the company, now

    valued at around $10 billion.

    In the frst six years ater Bill took over the presi-dency, the company quadrupled in size, surpassing

    Howard Johnson and Hilton Hotels in both revenue

    and profts. The younger Marriott acquired Big

    Boy and Roy Rogers restaurant chains, and made

    the company international with an acquisition in

    Venezuela. He also invested heavily in research,

    which inormed the decision in 1983 to target the

    mid-priced hotel market with Courtyard by Marriott.

    Still, J. Willards conservative business strategies

    are consistent with Anderson, Duru, and Reebs

    fndings rom a recent study o the ties that bind

    amily ownership and investment decisions.

    The authors examined dueling potential motiva-

    tions behind investment decisions: an aversion to

    risk was one possibility, or an extended invest-

    ment horizon. With Durus help, the team ocused

    on accounting disclosures required by regulators,

    including R&D and capital expenditures.

    What was the amilys biggest inuence?

    The researchers discovered that amily frms

    preerred to construct their uture in physical assets,

    like new restaurants, as opposed to riskier ventures

    such as expanding into a new industry segment.

    We ound that amily irms invested less

    in R&D; they are more risk averse, Duru said,

    explaining that amily frms devote less capital to

    long-term investments than do diusely owned

    frms. Compared to their peers, amily frms also

    receive ewer patents per dollar o R&D investment.

    Rather, they seem to preer doubling down on

    reinorcements that strengthen their core business.

    Take Carnival Corporation, which has 101 ships

    among its brands and 10 new ships on order, ocusing

    on expansion into Europe, Australia, and Asia. The

    Arison amily retains 35 percent o company stock

    in the worlds largest cruise ship operator.

    The reluctance to pony up or long-term invest-

    ments may be counterintuitive. Tales o amily

    business owners oten hinge on the notion o their

    ar-reaching view o the uture and their fnancial

    sacrifces, made to prop up the business. It is

    possible that there is less spending on R&D in

    amily frms simply because amily oversight makes

    frms more efcient.

    TIMES HAVE CHANGED

    Efciency is something that Richard Lenny, the

    frst outsider to serve as CEO o Hershey Foods

    Company, understood. Lenny increased company

    profts by closing six underperorming plants in the

    US and Canada in 2007, cutting 3,000 workers,

    and outsourcing the production o cocoa.

    It was a ar cry rom the utopian community

    that Milton Hershey envisioned or his employees

    and their amilies. When the Great Depression hit

    and sales plummeted 50 percent, Hershey did not

    lay o a single worker, but instead used employees

    to pursue growth opportunities. His ideals were

    as popular as his companys sweets; more than

    a century later, the towns identity is still tightlywrapped in silver oil with a tidy bow.

    Milton Hersheys ocus on protecting employees

    was not the norm or corporate America, but it is

    representative o many Japanese frms, which oten

    increase their investments in growth when demand

    or their products alls.

    Given a choice between cutting dividends or

    workers, CEOs there generally say their employees

    and suppliers are the most important stakeholders,

    David said. Its almost a amily situation.

    The reason behind frms diversifcationand

    whether the motivation diered by the identity o

    its ownerswas the ocus o Davids recent study.

    In the same way that types o debt can be consid-

    ered either relational or transactional, domestic and

    oreign owners also display these characteristics.

    Prior research on corporate diversifcation and

    its implications or frm perormance had treated

    all owners as i they had the same end goal: proft.

    Not so, David and his colleagues ound, in a

    paper published by the Academy o Management

    in 2010. Diversifcation is also a means to other

    ends, such as career advancement opportunities

    or employees, higher compensation, and lower

    employment risk.

    Using data rom our sources, and excluding

    small frms and those in highly regulated sectors,

    their sample resulted in 1,180 unique frms.

    It turns out that relational owners emphasize

    growth, while transactional owners emphasize proft

    or shareholders. The dierences are considerable:

    on a share-per-share basis, transactional owners

    are over three times more eective than relational

    owners in pressuring managers to improve proft.

    What we ound is that when there is more rela-

    tional ownership, the frms are less likely to cut their

    wages or lay o people, even when perormance

    goes down, David said. But with transactional

    ownership, they are more likely to do so.

    For domestic owners, he believes, it all comes

    down to stakeholder relationships. Firm growth

    means new business, which keeps frm employees

    and their suppliers working. But frms with oreign

    ownership are more likely to diversiy the business

    in order to collect more profts.

    David was quick to point out that domestic

    owners are not blindly making poor business deci-

    sions. There is a sel-interest here also, he said.

    It is not irrational altruism. There is an economic

    incentive or domestic owners to support growth;

    once again, more growth means more business.

    The project helped to rerame a central question

    about frm perormance, which previously had been

    viewed only through the proft lens.

    Like his colleagues work, the fndings rom

    Davids team had signifcant implications or gover-

    nance literature.

    Taken together, the emphasis that Kogods

    aculty have placed on researching the value o

    amily frms has highlighted the frms critical valueto the US economy.

    Beyond their proftability, amily businesses

    also employ 63 percent o the US workorce. As

    regulators look ahead to a November election in

    which the key issue is jobs, they should pay a visit

    to these frms or counsel on how policy will impact

    expansion and job creation, said Ann Kinkade, CEO

    o Family Enterprise USA, in Forbes.

    Questions remain. Will the SEC step up its

    ocus on short-sale trading in these valuable frms?

    Can larger frms in the US gain access to relational

    unding to uel frm growth, traditionally a more

    popular investment choice or small businesses? How

    can amily businesses be encouraged to add jobs?

    As Clemenza argued to Michael Corleone, At

    least give me the chance to recruit some new men.

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    16

    KOGODNOWFALL2011

    |kogodnow.com

    17

    CREATINGTHE COVERSTORY

    Academic papers that gave rise to the cover story

    Ronald C. Anderson, Augustine Duru, and David M.

    Reeb, Investment Policy in Family Controlled Firms,Journal o Banking and Finance(orthcoming).

    Ronald C. Anderson, Augustine Duru, and David M.

    Reeb, Founders, Heirs, and Corporate Opacity in theUS, Journal o Financial Economics(2009).

    Ronald C. Anderson and David M. Reeb, Founding-

    Family Ownership and Firm Perormance: Evidence

    From the S&P 500, The Journal o Finance(2003).

    Ronald C. Anderson, David M. Reeb, and Wanli Zhao,

    Family Controlled Firms and Inormed Trading:

    Evidence From Short Sales, The Journal o Finance

    (orthcoming).

    Parthiban David, Andrew Delios, Jonathan Paul

    OBrien, and Toru Yoshikawa, Do Shareholders or

    Stakeholders Appropriate the Rents From Corporate

    Diversifcation? The Inuence o Ownership

    Structure, Academy o Management(2010).

    Parthiban David and Jonathan Paul OBrien, Firm

    Growth and Type o Debt: The Paradox o Discretion,

    Industrial and Corporate Change(2010).

    WHAT WE FOUND IS THAT WHENTHERE IS MORE RELATIONAL OWNER-SHIP, THE FIRMS WERE LESS LIKELYTO CUT THEIR WAGES OR LAY OFFPEOPLE, EVEN WHEN PERFORMANCEGOES DOWN.

    PARTHIBAN DAVID, ASSOCIATE PROFESSOR

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    11/27

    In two very visible situations, Congress used the

    Internal Revenue Code to deal with this growing

    concern. Both times, these provisions were contro-

    versial; ater all, executive compensation has typi-

    cally been considered a matter to be resolved by

    corporate boards and executives.

    As the debate over tax reorm rages on, it is

    imperative to consider the eectiveness o this

    approach. The question is, has using the ederal

    tax law to deal with corporate governance issues

    solved the problem Congress was trying to remedy?

    We think not.

    A BALLOONING PROBLEM

    In the late 1970s, high-profle executive sever ance

    packages, known as golden parachutes, began to

    unold. The so-called parachutes triggered substan-

    tial payments in the event o a corporate acquisition.

    One o the frst corporations to adopt a para-

    chute-type arrangement was Hammermill Paper.

    According to a study on the origins o golden para-

    chutes by Peer Fiss, Mark Kennedy, and Gerald

    Davis, the provisions stated that, upon a change

    o control, the executives employment by thecompany shall continue or at least three years,

    at an annual rate o compensation equal to his total

    compensation or 12 months preceding the change.

    In other words, Hammermills senior executives were

    guaranteed three ull years o salary in the event

    o a company acquisition.

    By the early 1980s, high ination rates and a

    depressed stock market led to a wave o corporate

    acquisitions. Economic conditions simply made it

    more attractive or companies to grow through

    acquisition rather than organically.

    As the acquisition wave grew, the golden para-

    chute trend continued to pick up steam. By 1981,

    15 percent o the 250 largest US corporations

    had such plans in place, according to Organization

    Science. Congress became increasingly concerned

    over some o these arrangements.

    Members o Congress worried that, in some

    situations, these arrangementsalthough board-

    approvedwere hindering corporate acquisitions by

    increasing the cost o acquisitions and dissuading

    interested buyers. Other times, these payments

    tended to encourage the executives involved to avor

    a takeover that might not be in the best interests

    o the companys shareholdersthe very group

    they were hired to serve. In either event, Congress

    was concerned that payments to shareholders were

    being reduced.

    PLAN DEPLOYED

    Congress decided to deal with the problem by

    discouraging transactions that would reduce

    amounts that might otherwise be paid to company

    shareholders, according to a report by the Joint

    Committee on Taxation at the time.

    How did congressional representatives set about

    discouraging these arrangements?

    By providing that excess parachute payments

    would be nondeductible to the corporation and

    imposing a 20 percent excise tax on the executive.

    What qualiied as an excess parachute

    payment? One that was

    1. in the nature o compensation (including a

    non-compete agreement);

    2. paid to an ofcer, shareholder, or highly

    compensated individual; and

    3. deployed only with a change in control o a

    corporationbut only to the extent that the

    payment exceeded three times the average

    amount o compensation the individual had

    earned in the fve years preceding

    the acquisition.

    The eect? An almost immediate increasein

    parachute arrangements, which until then were still

    rareand the introduction o gross up clauses,

    under which companies pay the 20 percent excise

    tax on behal o the executives.

    Executives who did not have parachute arrange-

    ments argued that their pay should be consistent

    with that o their peers. They sought to have para-

    chute payments added to their compensation

    arrangements, and many boards agreed.

    In our countrys recent history, Congress has tried at times to solve problemson its own, spurred by corporate governance issues that (it elt) were notsufciently addressed by state laws. Nowhere is this more evident than inexecutive compensation.

    ARTICLE BY

    DAVID J. KAUTTER

    & ANDREW R. ZANK

    THE KOGOD TAX

    CENTER IS A NON-

    PARTISAN CENTER

    THAT PROMOTES

    INDEPENDENT

    RESEARCH ON TAX

    POLICY, PLANNING,

    AND COMPLIANCE

    ISSUES IMPACTING

    SMALL BUSINESSES,

    ENTREPRENEURS,

    AND MIDDLE-INCOME

    TAXPAYERS.

    GOLDEN PARACHUTESGET A LIFT FROMCONGRESS

    KOGOD TAX CENTER

    Meanwhile, executives who already had golden

    parachute arrangements ell into two categories:

    First, those with payments that were less

    than three times their base amount sought,

    and oten received, an increase in the

    amount o their payments to 2.99 timestheir base amount. They pointed out that at

    that level, the payments would still be ully

    deductible by the corporation (and no excise

    tax would be imposed on the recipients).

    Those who had parachute payment agree-

    ments in excess o three times their base

    amount sought, and oten received, tax

    gross up payments. This means that ater

    the gross up payment was received, included

    in income, and the 20 percent excise tax

    paid on the gross up amount, the executive

    received the amount he would otherwise have

    been let with had there been no excise tax

    on the underlying payment (see Figure 1).

    CRASH LANDING

    Golden parachute agreements remain to this day a

    common part o executive contracts, ensuring about

    two to three years o salary and bonus, according

    to a recent Wall Street Journalarticle. Despite

    Congresss eort, golden parachutes are continu-

    ally being deployed.

    In 2011, at least our CEOs o target companies

    were in line or a payout o more than $50 million,

    including $100 million to ormer Nabor IndustriesCEO Eugene Isenberg; our more CEOs were in

    line or payouts o more than $30 million; and

    many more executives expected payouts in the tens

    o millions.

    It seems pretty clear that Congresss attempt

    to implement a change in corporate governance to

    reduce the trend 25 years ago has not discouraged

    the practice. I anything, these arrangements are

    more widespread todayand more generous in

    their termsthan they were when the legislation

    was enacted.

    POLITICAL AIRS

    I at frst Congress didnt succeed, it tried again

    this time by limiting the deductibility o compensa-

    tion paid to executives.

    In the early 1990s, inormation on the lack o

    correlation between executive compensation and

    economic perormance became increasingly avail-

    able, thanks to the introduction o United Share-

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    19

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    18

    Company Pfzer Inc.Executive Hank A. McKinnell Jr.

    Term 2001-2006Payout $188,329,553

    There are 21 CEOs who received walk-away

    packages greater than $100 million, according to a

    recent report rom corporate governance consulting

    frm GMI. Collectively, the top dogs total earnings

    exceeded almost $4 billion. Too many golden

    parachutes and too many retirement packages areo a size that clearly seems only in the interest o

    the departing executive, the report postulated.

    Below are a sample o fve such payouts in a

    variety o industry segments: health care, retail,

    digital, oil & gas, and banking.

    Company Target Corporation

    Executive Robert J. UlrichTerm 1994-2008

    Payout $164,162,612

    Company eBay Inc.Executive Margaret C. Whitman

    Term 1998-2008Payout $120,427,360

    Company ExxonMobil Corp.

    Executive Lee R. Raymond

    Term 1993-2005

    Payout $320,599,861

    Company Merrill Lynch & Co. Inc.

    Executive E. Stanley ONealTerm 2002-2007

    Payout $161,500,000

    WALK-AWAYPACKAGES

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    12/27

    EXAMPLE OFPARACHUTEPAYMENT WITHGROSS UP

    EXCESSPARACHUTE

    PAYMENT

    holder Association Compensation Surveys and

    increasingly active corporate shareholders.

    As more data on executive compensation came

    to light, public outrage began to sweep the country;

    by 1992, CEO compensation had become a key

    presidential campaign issue, as then-candidate Bill

    Clinton debated incumbent George H. W. Bush orthe countrys attention.

    As more citizens voiced concern over the contin-

    uously rising compensation or top executives, and

    politicians looked to take action, heated debates

    began in Washington. Some critics argued that

    certain executives were increasing their own salaries

    without input rom shareholders, and without ties

    to the companys economic perormance. The high

    pay, they argued, was unearned.

    Others believed that the large disparity in pay

    between the executives and lower-level employees,

    as well as a similar disparity between US execu-

    tives and oreign executives, was inexcusable and

    clear evidence o the need or ederal intervention.

    CHANGING AIM

    In 1993, Congress responded by enacting Section

    162(m) o the Internal Revenue Code. Under this

    provision, the corporate tax deduction or compensa-

    tion paid to the CEO and the our other highest-paid

    executives o a publicly held corporation was limited

    to $1 million each.

    An exception was made or perormance-based

    compensation: to the extent that payments in excess

    o $1 million in one year meet goals set by the BoardCompensation Committee, and are approved by a

    majority o the shareholders in a separate vote, then

    the compensation is ully deductible.

    The House Ways and Means Committee stated

    its belie very clearly that excessive compensation

    would be reduced ollowing this action. With the

    new restraints on deductions in place, Congress

    believed it had taken an important step toward

    pushing domestic corporations to adopt more

    responsible, perormance-based executive compen-

    sation systems.

    Section 162(m) also attempted to introduce a

    level o accountability that had been missing, by

    providing opportunity or more shareholder input.

    So what happened? A study o the eects o

    Section 162(m) calculated that between 1992 and

    1997, the median compensation or covered execu-

    tives increased17 percent, and executive bonus

    and long-term incentive plans (as well as grants o

    restricted stock) nearly doubled.

    The study, by Tod Perry and Marc Zenner, also

    showed that many executives with compensation

    below $1 million saw pay raises; 75 percent to 84

    percent o executives earning $900,000 or below

    got a salary bump ollowing the implementation o

    Section 162(m). Perry and Zenner determined that

    many others, with pay already above $1 million,

    saw no change at all.

    Quite simply, in response to Section 162(m),many corporations locked in fxed compensation

    or executives right around the $1 million mark

    and created perormance-based bonuses to urther

    compensate executives beyond their fxed salaries.

    Congress wasnt the only injured party. A 2006

    study by the Joint Committee on Taxation ound

    that Section 162(m) eliminated millions o dollars

    in deductions, reducing profts and, in many cases,

    adversely aecting company shareholders.

    The study concluded that, by making peror-

    mance-based pay an exception to the $1 million cap,

    there was a resulting increase in executive compen-

    sation, and the provision led to more executives

    looking to manipulate earnings to demonstrate a

    better earnings pattern and, in turn, earn higher pay.

    Although the consequences o the $1 million

    cap were ar rom the results Congress had antici-

    pated, the legislation has increased executive

    accountability to corporate shareholders.

    BAG IT?

    As these experiences illustrate, trying to implement

    corporate governance policies through the Internal

    Revenue Code has, at best, a mixed record.

    Using the tax law to encourage (or discourage)behavior has worked eectively in some parts o the

    economy. For example, enactment o the Research

    and Development tax credit has been considered

    successul in encouraging greater research.

    On the other hand, corporate governance does

    not appear to lend itsel to a ederal tax solution.

    Yet despite the uneven results with respect to past

    eorts, when Congress sees other corporate gover-

    nance issues it believes are not being addressed

    adequately, it is likely to continue taking matters

    into its own hands.

    An election year in which taxation is a para-

    mount issue, and ormer CEOs are vying or the

    countrys top spot, presents the opportunity to

    make a choice to stop legislating through changes

    to the tax code. It has only made the tax law more

    complicated, interposed the IRS between executives

    on the one hand and corporate boards and share-

    holders on the other, and ailed to solve any o the

    problems with which Congress was concerned.

    $800,000AVERAGE COMPENSATIONPAID DURING PERIOD(BASE AMOUNT / 5)

    $3,000,000PARACHUTE PAYMENT

    $4,000,000TOTAL COMPENSATIONPAID DURING PERIOD

    $3,000,000PARACHUTE PAYMENT

    $120,000EXCISE TAX (20%)

    $2,400,0003X BASE AMOUNT

    EXCESS PARACHUTEPAYMENT

    ASSUMEFederal Tax 35%State Tax 7%Fed Excise Tax 20%Total Tax Rate 62%

    GROSS UP PAYMENT:

    Excise Tax:20% x $600,000 $120,000

    Gross Up Payment Calculation:$120,000 (1 - 62%) $316,000

    TAX ON GROSS UP PAYMENT:Fed (35%) (110,600)State (7%) (22,120)Excise (20%) (63,200)Total (196,000)

    $316,000 $196,000

    $120,000(amount needed to pay excise tax)

    KOGOD TAX CENTER

    2007

    $700,000$750,000

    $800,000$850,000

    $900,000

    2009

    0

    $1M

    $1.2M

    FIG 1

    $800K

    $600K

    $400K

    $200K

    2010 20112008

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    21

    KOGODNOWSPRING

    2012

    |kogodnow.com

    20

  • 7/31/2019 KN_spring2012_RD5

    13/27

    O course, the days o overt KGB control

    are long gone; in todays Russia, order

    seemingly prevails over the repression

    o an earlier era. And yet, more than 20

    years ater the all o the Soviet Union,

    intimidation and corruption against busi-

    ness owners is rampant.

    Media reports estimate that up to

    70,000 cases o corporate raiding

    reiderstvo in Russianoccur each

    year. The sophisticated orm o white-

    collar crime involves the seizure and

    rapid resale o a company or its liquid

    assets: private frms and businesses are

    dismembered, and the parts sold to the

    highest bidder.

    Valeriy Filatov, a Russian-born US

    citizen and BSBA 12, coauthored a

    research article analyzing the phenom-enon with Claudio Carpano, a ormer

    executive-in-residence. His research

    discovered that the annual fnancial gains

    made rom Russian raids were estimated

    at a whopping $4 billion in 2010.

    Raiding is mainly perormed by

    bureaucrats and mid-size-business

    ownersthose who didnt do it in time

    or the frst divvying up o the pie during

    the 1990s, Filatov asserted, reerring

    to the privatization o state assets ater

    the breakup o the Soviet Union.

    In countries with well-established

    institutions, such as the United States,

    corporate raids (also known as hostile

    takeovers) are usually carried out in

    accordance with strict guidelines. They

    are used to restore stability and competi-

    tive advantage to edgling companies.

    In Russia, the reverse is true: the

    most successul businesses, or those

    that have valuable assets in the orm

    o fxed capital or real estate, are at the

    greatest risk o raiding.

    Certainly, capital accumulation ater

    the all o the Soviet Union was uneven;

    some benefted more than others. But

    that's not why such great disparity

    between the haves and have-nots exists.

    Without clear rules o competi-

    tion and a mechanism or transerring

    property to more efcient owners, the

    system never evolved. Instead, a process

    o negative selection has emerged, where

    the strongest and most proftable busi-

    nesses are picked o, stiing growth and

    damaging the larger economy.

    In Vladimir Putin's Russia, where

    the power hungry politician was recently

    elected to a third presidential term, theclout o the bureaucratnot the wealth o

    the ownerguaranteed ownership o an

    asset. Its difcult to change duplicitous

    legal and political systems in an environ-

    ment that rewards those who exploit it,

    said Filatov.

    SYSTEMIC RISK

    In 2009, Evgeniy Konovalov, the owner

    o an agricultural company in southern

    Russia, ound himsel in pretrial deten-

    tion. Though the charges were abri-

    catedit was eventually proved in court

    that orged documents were used to

    purchase his frmhe spent a year under

    arrest. During this time he ought the

    raid executed by his long-time business

    associate and was eventually named the

    rightul owner. His business was returned

    to him in 2011.

    Despite overwhelming evidence o

    violations o Russian law by [Konovalovs

    business associate], his accomplices,

    and complicit government ofcials, none

    o the parties have been punished,

    Filatov wrote in his award-winning paper.

    Similar stories abound.

    It used to be gangsters who ran

    rackets, and now its consultants and

    lawyers wearing ties, who are civilized on

    the surace but carry out the same black-

    mail, Andrei Girev, the general director

    o a Russian cell phone company, told

    Bloomberg Businessweek.

    One in six Russian businessmen has

    been prosecuted or an alleged economic

    crime over the past decade, according

    to The Economistmost at the hands o

    corrupt police, prosecutors, and courts.

    The Russian legal system isextremely complex and ull o contra-

    dictions, Filatov said. Almost everyone

    in business is breaking the law on a daily

    basis, so its easy to leverage the law in

    support o illicit activities.

    While Russian law no longer allows

    or pretrial sentencing in economic cases,

    as in Konovalovs casethis changed

    in 2010the surprise element hinders

    business owners ability to fght well-

    organized, authority-backed raids.

    Filatov believes that corporate raiding

    is under-reported and unaddressed or a

    slew o reasons: law enorcement doesnt

    want to appear incompetent, the media

    attempts to remain impartial, and the

    government is disinterested or too corrupt

    to seek reorm.

    Another reason the Russian govern-

    ment is not ocused on creating good

    conditions or private businesses? The

    ARTICLE BY

    ANNA MIARS

    RUSSIAS CORRUPTFREE MARKET

    In Russia, corporate raiding is simply the latest incarnation o propertyredistribution. The tactics have modernized over time: the use o hiredmuscle in the days o racketeering has been replaced by exploitation o legalloopholes and loose regulations. But the participation o government ofcials,which makes the whole system possible, remains intact.

    proit gap between state-run oil and

    natural gas companies and other indus-

    tries. High tax rates on oil and natural gasprovide a majority o the countrys budget

    revenue, making the independent busi-

    ness community a distant second priority.

    HOW RAIDING WORKS

    There is a Russian saying: a fsh starts

    rotting rom the head, said Filatov. I

    corruption wasnt sanctioned at the top,

    then it wouldnt be accepted at lower

    levels as well.

    Financial compensation is a strong

    incentive or participation, or at least

    passive tolerance. Everyone rom police

    ofcers to judges and governors stands

    to beneft by collecting a perormance

    bonus, accepting a bribe, or pocketing

    a uture avor.

    I think, increasingly, people who are

    doing the dirty work have been co-opted by

    government ofcials who are oten the end

    beneactor o the scheme, said Filatov.

    Each o the three types o raiding

    requires an inside man, a government

    ofcial who can provide the necessary

    leverage to accomplish a raid.So-called black raids are what movies

    are made o: violence, including coercion,

    threats, and kidnapping. Gray raids call

    or a mixture o legal and quasi-legal

    means, such as calling legitimate share-

    holder meetings using orged documents.

    Finally, white raids are perormed to the

    letter o the law, though they oten violate

    its spirit, according to Filatov.

    Capitalizing on regulation violations

    is a common method associated with

    white raiding. An anonymous report

    submitted to the court system can indi-

    cate complicity and result in the removal

    o executives or fnancial damage such as

    fnes or suspension o business activities,

    causing internal instability and devaluing

    the companys shares.

    Although violent acts against busi-

    nessmen, or black raids, have largely

    subsided, administrative methods that

    achieve the same ends are still prevalent.

    Raiding is more damaging to busi-

    nesses than racketeering because oits goal to acquire complete ownership,

    rather than just capture a portion o

    the proft, Filatov said.

    Filatov identiied the our most

    common approaches to raiding in Russia:

    Letter o the Law. Raiders uncover

    and expose regulatory inractions

    in order to destabilize the company

    and prime it or the taking.

    By Force. Raiders use administra-

    tive sanctions or abricate criminal

    cases to acilitate takeovers.

    Hit Em Where it Hurts. Bank-

    ruptcy schemes are eective ways

    to undermine a business.

    Dispute Ownership. By manipu-

    lating the stockholder registry,

    raiders can call the very ownership

    o the company into question.

    In general, inormation-based busi-

    nesses and service providers are at alesser risk o raiding than those in the

    fnance, retail, dining, construction, and

    agriculture industries. However, there are

    risk actors that cut across all industries.

    For example, the dispersal o stock-

    holder ownership aects whether raiders

    will be able to abuse rules at stockholder

    meetings. The presence o fxed capital

    investmentssuch as valuable land, or

    actoriesalso establishes the potential

    or raiders proft. Finally, a companys

    level o debt plays a role: frms with a

    high debt burden are more vulnerable to

    bankruptcy tactics.

    There are a lot o interested parties,

    said Filatov. The raiders themselves;

    those who know about the raid but look

    the other way; and the individuals that

    commissioned the raid.

    COLLECTIVE RESPONSIBILITY

    Although Russian governmental agen-

    cies are supposed to unction in a waythat ensures checks and balances, in

    reality, ofcials are reluctant to incrimi-

    nate their colleagues.

    People advance by helping one

    another in small groups, Filatov said.

    Its known as krugovaya poruka, which

    translates to solidarity or collective

    responsibility. This is particularly preva-

    lent within industry sectors.

    The arrangement o mutual assis-

    tance, a cultural carryover rom Soviet

    rule, provides raiders who already have a

    motive with the means and opportunity.

    The environment is ripe or corruption.

    Government support is essential to a

    companys survival. One Russian corpo-

    rate lawyer concludes,