International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

95
International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006

Transcript of International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Page 1: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

International Trade

Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models

October 17, 2006

Page 2: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

International trade is more complicated than domestic trade.

There are no national borders to be crossed when, say, California wine is shipped to Delaware. The consumer in Newark pays with Dollars, just the currency that the wine maker in California wants.

Page 3: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

If that same vintner ships her wine to Europe, however, consumers there will have only Euros with which to pay, rather than the Dollars the wine maker in California wants. Thus, for international trade to take place, there must be some way to convert one currency into another.

Page 4: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The exchange rate states the price in

terms of one currency at which such conversions are made. There is an exchange rate between every pair of currencies.

Page 5: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For example the British Pound in 2002 was the equivalent of about $1.40. The exchange rate between the Pound and the Dollar, then, may be expressed as roughly "$1.40 to the Pound" (meaning that it costs $1.40 to buy a Pound) or about "71 pence to the Dollar" (meaning that it costs 71 British pence to buy a Dollar).

(Currently the rate is $1.86 and .57 respectively)

Page 6: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

A nation’s currency is said to appreciate when the exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy more units of a foreign currency.

A nation’s currency is said to depreciate when the exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy fewer units of a foreign currency.

Page 7: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For example if the cost of a Pound rises from $1.40 to $2.00, the cost of a U.S. dollar in terms of pounds simultaneously falls from 71 pence to 50 pence.

The UK has experienced an appreciation while the U.S. has experienced a depreciation in its currency.

Page 8: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

When an officially set exchange rate is altered so that a unit of a nation’s currency can buy fewer units of foreign currency, we say that a devaluation of that currency has taken place. When the exchange rate is changed so that the nation’s currency buys more units of a foreign currency, a revaluation has taken place.

Page 9: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION IN A FREE

MARKET

Page 10: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Assume that the Dollar and the Euro are the only currencies on earth, so the market needs to determine only one exchange rate.

Figure 1 depicts the determination of this exchange rate at the point in the figure where demand curve D1 crosses supply curve S1.

Page 11: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

At this price ($0.90 per euro), the number of Euros demanded is equal to the number of Euros supplied.

Page 12: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$/Euro$/Euro

DD11

.90.90

00QQ of Euros of Euros

Euro MarketEuro Market

SS11

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Figure 1Figure 1

Page 13: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Why does anyone demand Euros?

1. International trade in goods and services. (In general, demand for Europe’s exports leads to demand for its currency, Euros)

2. International trade in financial instruments such as stocks and bonds. (In general demand for Europe’s financial assets leads to demand for it’s currency, Euros)

Page 14: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

3. Purchases of a country’s (Europe’s) physical assets such as factories and machinery overseas by foreigners (e.g. U.S. citizens). (In general, direct foreign investment leads to demand for Europe’s currency, the Euro)

Page 15: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Where does the supply of Euros come from?

1. Europeans want to buy U.S. goods (the other side of 1 above)

2. Europeans want to buy U.S. stocks and bonds (the other side of 2 above)

3. Europeans purchase physical assets in the U.S. (the other side of 3 above)

(can use the supply and demand graphs we have already created)

Page 16: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

To illustrate the usefulness of even this simple supply and demand analysis, think about how the exchange rate between the Dollar and the Euro should change if Europeans become attracted by the prospects of large gains on the U.S. stock markets.

Page 17: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

To purchase U.S. stocks, foreigners will first have to purchase U.S. Dollars, which means selling some of their Euros.

Page 18: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In terms of the supply-demand diagram in Figure 2, the increased desire of Europeans to acquire U.S. stocks would shift the supply curve for Euros out from S1 to S2 . Equilibrium would shift from point Q1 to point Q4, and the exchange rate would fall: e.g. from $0.90 per Euro to $0.80 per Euro.

Page 19: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$$//EuroEuro

DD11

.90.90

00QQ of Euros of Euros

Market for EurosMarket for Euros

SS11

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Page 20: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$$//EuroEuro

DD11

.90.90

00Q of Q of EurosEuros

SS11

SS22

.80.80

QQ44

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Market for EurosMarket for Euros

Page 21: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Thus the increased supply of Euros by European citizens would cause the Euro to depreciate relative to the dollar. This is what happened during the U.S. stock market boom of the late 1990s.

Page 22: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Summary: Suppose that Europeans have an interest in investing in the

U.S. stock market.

(straight forward supply and demand) To purchase stocks, Europeans need to

purchase $ => selling Euros. (supply curve for Euros shifts to the right =>

causing the $ price of the Euro to fall) 

Page 23: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The Short Run

Main determinant in the short run: interest rates, in particular interest rate differentials, and financial flows.

Page 24: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

As an example, suppose the Italian government bonds pay a 5 percent rate when yields on equally safe U.S. government securities rise to 7 percent.

Page 25: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Italian investors will be attracted by the higher interest rates in the United States and will offer Euros for sale.

Why? To buy Dollars and use those Dollars to buy

U.S. securities. At the same time, U.S. investors will find it

more attractive to keep their money at home, so fewer Euros will be demanded by Americans.

Page 26: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$$//EuroEuro

DD11

PP11

00QQ of Euros of Euros

Euro MarketEuro Market

SS11

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Figure 3Figure 3

Page 27: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$$//EuroEuro

DD11

PP11

00Q of EurosQ of Euros

SS11

SS22

PP44

QQ44

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Euro MarketEuro MarketFigure 3Figure 3

Page 28: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$$//EuroEuro

DD11

PP1 1 ==

1.201.20

00Q of EurosQ of Euros

SS11

SS22

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Euro MarketEuro MarketFigure 3Figure 3

DD22

PP22=1=1

.10.10

QQ22

Page 29: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

When the demand schedule shifts inward and the supply curve shifts outward, the effect on price is predictable.

Page 30: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The Euro will depreciate, as Figure 3 shows. In the figure, the supply curve of Euros shifts outward from S1 to S2 when Italian investors seek to sell Euros in order to purchase more U.S. securities.

Page 31: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

At the same time, American investors wish to buy fewer Euros because they no longer desire to invest as much in Italian securities. Thus, the demand curve shifts inward from D1 to D2.

Page 32: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The Result:

In our example, there is a depreciation of the Euro from $1.20 to $1.10.

Exercise: Suppose that interest rates are higher in Europe than in the U.S. Demonstrate using supply and demand curves that this would cause the Euro to appreciate.

Page 33: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In general Other things equal, countries that offer

investors higher rates of return attract more capital than countries that offer lower rates.

Thus, a rise in interest rates often will lead to an appreciation of the currency, and a drop in interest rates will lead to a depreciation of the currency.

Page 34: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Interest rate differentials certainly played a predominant role in the stunning movements of the U.S. Dollar in the 1980s.

In the early 1980s, American interest rates rose well above comparable interest rates abroad.

As a result, foreign capital was attracted to the U.S. American capital stayed at home, and the Dollar soared. That is, the Dollar appreciated.

Page 35: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Similarly, a nation that suffers from capital flight, as did Argentina in 2001, must offer extremely high interest rates to attract foreign capital.

Page 36: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The Medium Run

The medium run is where the theory of exchange rate determination is most unsettled.

Page 37: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Economists once reasoned as follows: Because consumer spending increases when income rises and decreases when income falls, the same thing is likely to happen to spending on imported goods.

So a country's imports will rise quickly when its economy booms and rise only slowly when its economy stagnates.

Page 38: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For the reasons illustrated in Figure 4, a boom in the United States should shift the demand curve for Euros outward as Americans seek to acquire more Euros to buy more European goods and services.

And that, in turn, should lead to an appreciation of the Euro (depreciation of the Dollar). In the figure, the Euro rises in value from P1 to P2 Dollars per Euro.

Page 39: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$/Euro$/Euro

DD11

PP11

00QuantityQuantity of Euros of Euros

Euro MarketEuro Market

SS11

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Figure 4Figure 4

Page 40: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$/Euro$/Euro

DD11

PP11

00QuantityQuantity of Euros of Euros

SS11

DD22

PP22

QQ22

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Euro MarketEuro MarketFigure 4Figure 4

Page 41: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

However, if Europe was booming at the same time, Europeans would be buying more American exports, which would shift the supply curve of Euros outward.

Europeans must offer more Euros for sale to get the Dollars they need for purchasing U.S. goods and services.

Page 42: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

QQ11

$/Euro$/Euro

DD11

PP11

00 QuantityQuantity of Euros of Euros

SS11

DD22

D shifts to the rightD shifts to the right

D shifts to the leftD shifts to the left

S shifts to the rightS shifts to the right

S shifts to the leftS shifts to the left

Euro MarketEuro MarketFigure 4Figure 4

PP33

QQ33

SS22

Page 43: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

On balance, the value of the Dollar might rise or fall. It appears that what matters is whether exports are growing faster than imports.

Page 44: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

A country whose aggregate demand grows faster than the rest of the world's normally finds its imports growing faster than its exports.

Thus, its demand curve for foreign currency shifts outward more rapidly than its supply curve. Other things equal, that will make its currency depreciate.

In the context of figure 4 if the U.S. is growing faster than Europe, D1 will shift out by a larger amount than S1, leading to an appreciation of the Euro.

Page 45: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Conclusion:

This reasoning is sound - so far as it goes. And it leads to the conclusion that a "strong economy" might produce a "weak currency."

But the three most important words in the preceding statement are "other things equal."

Page 46: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Usually, they are not. Specifically, a booming economy will normally offer more attractive prospects to investors than a stagnating one -- higher interest rates, rising stock market values, and so on.

Page 47: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

This difference in prospective investment returns, as we have seen, should attract capital and boost its currency value. So there appears to be a kind of "tug of war."

Page 48: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

As we see, thinking only about trade in goods and services leads to the conclusion that faster growth should weaken the currency.

But thinking about trade in financial assets (such as stocks and bonds) leads to precisely the opposite conclusion: Faster growth should strengthen the currency. Which side will win this "tug of war"?

Page 49: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In the modern world, the evidence seems to say that trade in financial assets is the dominant factor.

Rapid growth in the United States in the second half of the 1990s led to a sharply appreciating Dollar even though U.S. imports soared.

Why? Investors from all over the world brought funds to America.

Page 50: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

We conclude that:

Stronger economic performance appears to lead to currency appreciation because it improves prospects for investing in the country.

Page 51: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Purchasing Power Parity Theory: The Long Run

Page 52: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In the long run, an apparently simple principle ought to govern exchange rates. As long as goods can move freely across national borders, exchange rates should eventually adjust so that the same product costs the same amount of money, whether measured in Dollars in the United States, Euros in Germany, or Yen in Japan -- except for differences in transportation costs and the like.

Page 53: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

This simple statement forms the basis of the major theory of exchange rate determination in the long run:

The purchasing-power parity theory of exchange rate determination holds that the exchange rate between any two national currencies adjusts to reflect differences in the price levels in the two countries.

Page 54: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Example: Suppose German and American steel is

identical and that these two nations are the only producers of steel for the world market.

Suppose further that steel is the only tradeable good that either country produces.

Page 55: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Question: If American steel costs $180 per ton and German steel costs 200 Euros per ton, what must be the exchange rate between the dollar and the euro?

Page 56: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Answer: Because 200 Euros and $180 each buy a ton of steel, the two sums money must be of equal value. Hence, each Euro must be worth $0.90.

The Dollar price of the Euro is $.90

Page 57: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Why? Any higher price for a Euro, such as $1, would mean that steel would cost $200 per ton (200 Euros at $1 each) in Germany but only $180 per ton in the United States.

Page 58: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In that case, all foreign customers would buy their steel in the United States -- which would increase the demand for Dollars and decrease the demand for Euros.

In our diagram for the market for Euros the supply of Euros would shift to the right and the result would be a lower Dollar price of the Euro.

Page 59: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Similarly, any exchange rate below $0.90 per Euro would send all the steel business to Germany, driving the value of the Euro up toward its purchasing-power parity level.

Page 60: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Exercise: Show why an exchange rate of $0.80 per Euro is too low to lead to an equilibrium in the international steel market.

Page 61: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Exercise (continued)

Dollar price of Euro: $.80

$/Euro =.80

At this exchange rate the:

cost of steel in Germany is $160

cost of steel in the U.S. is $180

Page 62: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The purchasing-power parity theory is used to make long-run predictions about the effects of inflation on exchange rates.

Page 63: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

To continue our example, suppose that steel (and other) prices in the United States rise while prices in Europe remain constant. The purchasing-power parity theory predicts that the Euro will appreciate relative to the Dollar. It also predicts the amount of the appreciation.

Page 64: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

After the U.S. inflation, suppose that the price of American steel is $220 per ton, while German steel still costs 200 Euros per ton.

For these two prices to be equivalent, 200 Euros must be worth $220, or one Euro must be worth $1.10.

The Euro, therefore, must have risen from $0.90 to $1.10.

Page 65: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

According to the purchasing-power parity theory

differences in domestic inflation rates are a major cause of

exchange rate movements. If one country has higher inflation

than another, its exchange rate should be depreciating.

Page 66: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For many years, this theory seemed to work tolerably well. Although precise numerical predictions based on purchasing-power parity calculations were never very accurate (see "Purchasing Power Parity and the Big Mac"), nations with higher inflation did at least experience depreciating currencies.

Page 67: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

But in the 1980s and 1990s, even this rule broke down.

For example, although the U.S. inflation rate was consistently higher than both Germany's and Japan's, the Dollar nonetheless rose sharply relative to both the German Mark and the Japanese Yen from 1980 to 1985.

The same thing happened again between 1995 and 2000.

Page 68: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Clearly, the theory is missing something. What?

Many things. But perhaps the principal failing of the purchasing-power parity theory is, once again, that it focuses too much on trade in goods and services.

Page 69: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Financial assets such as stocks and bonds are also traded actively across national borders -- and in vastly greater dollar volumes than goods and services.

In fact, the astounding daily volume of foreign exchange transactions, more than $1.5 trillion, exceeds an entire month’s worth of world trade in goods and services.

Page 70: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The vast majority of these transactions are financial. If investors decide that, say, U.S. assets are a better bet than Japanese assets, the Dollar will rise, even if our inflation rate is well above Japan's.

Page 71: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For this and other reasons: Most economists believe that other

factors are much more important than relative price levels for exchange rate determination in the short run. But in the long run, purchasing-power parity plays an important role.

Page 72: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Market Determination of Exchange Rates: Summary

You may have noticed a theme here.

International trade in financial assets: certainly dominates short-run exchange

rate changes, may dominate medium-run changes,

and also influences long-run changes.

Page 73: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

We can summarize this discussion of exchange rate determination in

free markets as follows: 1. We expect to find appreciating

currencies in countries that offer investors higher rates of return because these countries will attract capital from all over the world.

Page 74: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

2. To some extent, these are the countries that are growing faster than average because strong growth tends to produce attractive investment prospects. However, such fast-growing countries will also be importing relatively more than other countries, which tends to pull their currencies down.

Page 75: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

3. Currency values generally will appreciate in countries with lower inflation rates than the rest of the world's, because buyers in foreign countries will demand their goods and thus drive up their currencies.

Page 76: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Reversing each of these arguments, we expect to find depreciating currencies in countries with relatively high inflation rates, low interest rates, and poor growth prospects.

Page 77: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Some exchange rates today are truly floating, determined by the forces of supply and demand without government interference.

Many others are not. Some people claim that exchange rate

fluctuations are so troublesome that the world would be better off with fixed exchange rates.

Page 78: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

For these reasons, we turn next to a system of fixed exchange rates, or rates that are set by governments.

Naturally, under such a system the exchange rate, being fixed, is not closely watched.

Instead, international financial specialists focus on a country’s balance of payments to gauge movements in the supply of and demand for a currency.

Page 79: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

I. Defining the Balance of Payments in Practice

The preceding discussion makes it look simple to measure a nation's balance of payments position:

count up the private demand for and supply of its currency

and subtract quantity supplied from quantity demanded.

Go to discussion of AD

Page 80: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Conceptually, that is all there is to it. But in practice the difficulties are great

because we never directly observe the number of dollars demanded and supplied.

Page 81: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Actual market transactions show that the number of, say, U.S. Dollars purchased always equals the number of U.S. dollars sold. Unless someone has made a bookkeeping error, this must be so.

How, then, can we recognize a balance of payments surplus or deficit?

Page 82: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Easy, you say. Just look at the transactions of the central bank, whose purchases or sales must make up the difference between private demand and private supply.

If the Federal Reserve is buying dollars, its purchases measure our balance of payments deficit.

If the Fed is selling, its sales represent our balance of payments surplus.

Page 83: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Thus, the idea is to measure the balance of payments by excluding official transactions among governments.

That is, more or less, what is done.

Page 84: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In practice, the balance of payments accounts come in two main parts.

The current account balance account totals up exports and imports of goods and services, cross-border payments of interest and dividends, and cross-border gifts.

The United States has been running large current account deficits for years.

Page 85: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

But that represents only one part of our balance of payments, for it leaves out all purchases and sales of assets.

Purchases of U.S. assets by foreigners bring foreign currency to the United States, and

purchases of foreign assets cost us foreign currency.

Page 86: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Netting the capital flows in each direction gives us our surplus or deficit on capital the account.

In recent years, this part of our balance of payments accounts has registered large surpluses as foreigners have acquired U.S. assets.

Page 87: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In what sense, then does the overall balance of payments balance?

There are two possibilities. If the exchange rate is floating, all

private transactions, that is, current account plus capital account, must add up to zero

(dollars purchased = dollars sold).

Page 88: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

But if, instead, the exchange rate is fixed, as shown in the Figures below, the two accounts need not balance one another.

Government purchases or sales of foreign currency make up the surplus or deficit in the overall balance of payments.

Page 89: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Equilibrium is where Qd = Qs

Price of Euros

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

1.00

0.90

0.80

0.70

0.60

0.50

0.40

0.30

0.20

0.10

0

D

S

5

Billions of Billions of Euros/YearEuros/Year

Page 90: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Equilibrium is where QS = QD

Price of Euros

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

1.00

0.90

0.80

0.70

0.60

0.50

0.40

0.30

0.20

0.10

0

D

S

5

Balance of Balance of payments deficitpayments deficit

Billions of Euros per Billions of Euros per yearyear

Page 91: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

Equilibrium is where Qs = Qd

Price of Euros

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

1.00

0.90

0.80

0.70

0.60

0.50

0.40

0.30

0.20

0.10

0

D

S

5

.33.33Balance of Balance of payments payments surplussurplus

Billions Billions of Euros of Euros per yearper year

Page 92: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

This simple analysis helps us understand why the U.S. trade deficit grew so enormously in the late 1990s.

Page 93: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The international value of the Dollar began to climb in 1995.

According to the reasoning we have just completed, within a few years such an appreciation of the Dollar should have boosted U.S. imports and damaged U.S. exports.

That is precisely what happened.

Page 94: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

In constant Dollars, American imports soared by 40 percent between 1997 and 2000, while American exports rose just 15 percent.

Page 95: International Trade Exchange Rates and Open Macroeconomic Models October 17, 2006.

The result was that a $113 billion net export deficit in 1997 turned into a monumental $399 billion deficit by 2000.