Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in...

163
Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in Taiwan Stephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance over the last four decades has been attributed in part to its outward-oriented policy stance. 1 The apparent link between the sharp increase in exports in the early 1960s and an acceleration of growth is central to this assessment. Exports increased from just over 10 percent of GDP in 1960 to nearly 40 percent of GDP by the mid- 1 See, for example, Lin 1973, Haggard 1990, Wade 1990. 1

Transcript of Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in...

Page 1: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in Taiwan

Stephan Haggard and Yu Zheng

Taiwan’s strong economic performance over the last four decades has been attributed in

part to its outward-oriented policy stance.1 The apparent link between the sharp increase in

exports in the early 1960s and an acceleration of growth is central to this assessment. Exports

increased from just over 10 percent of GDP in 1960 to nearly 40 percent of GDP by the mid-

1970s. However, as Dani Rodrik has argued, investment exhibits a crucial inflection around the

same time as the export take-off.2 As can be seen from Figure 1, investment increased sharply

during the same period, from 20 percent to over 30 percent of GDP. Moreover, as we will

outline in more detail below, important shifts occurred in the role of the private sector in total

manufacturing output during this period as well. The expansion of exports and investment and

an increasing role for the private sector are best seen as components of a single process that

included reforms of the external sector and of the overall investment climate.

1 See, for example, Lin 1973, Haggard 1990, Wade 1990.2 Rodrik 1995.

1

Page 2: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 1

Investment and Export as Shares of GDP (1951-2005)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001

Year

Perc

enta

ge

Capital Formation as % of GDP Export as % of GDP

Source: Ministry of Economic Affairs, Economic Statistics Annual: Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various years

How important was foreign direct investment (FDI) in these policy and structural shifts?

At first glance, FDI may not appear significant and certainly did not play the role that it did in

Singapore’s economic development. Although FDI inflows increased drastically in real terms

(Table 1), they remained relatively small as a share of both GDP and overall capital formation.

Between 1952 and 2005, FDI inflows never exceeded 2.5 percent of GDP (Figure 2). As a

share of capital formation in the manufacturing sector, FDI has never exceeded 7.5 percent.

2

Page 3: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

However, as Figure 2 also shows, the period of the “take-off” of the early 1960s was also

accompanied by a particularly rapid growth in foreign direct investment. Overseas Chinese

investment and non-Chinese FDI, which was generally larger and more capital- and

technology-intensive,3 grew in tandem, maintaining roughly constant shares of total FDI

inflows through the 1960s (Table 1). The significance of non-Chinese investment stayed

roughly constant through the 1970s but has grown in relative importance since.

Table 1Foreign Direct Investment in Taiwan (US$ million)

Period Overseas Chinese Other Foreign Total

Value Percentage Value Percentage1952-55 3.0 26.1 8.6 73.9 11.61956-60 7.4 30.8 16.7 69.2 24.11961-65 32.2 32.5 66.9 67.5 99.11966-70 120.4 28.4 304.1 71.6 424.51971-75 247.3 29.2 598.7 70.8 846.01976-80 554.4 42.2 758.8 57.8 1313.21981-85 209.8 9.3 2047.1 90.7 2256.91986-90 779.3 9.6 7312.5 90.4 8091.81991-95 930.5 10.3 8078.9 89.7 9009.31996-2000 925.4 4.1 21380.0 95.9 22305.42001-05 131.2 0.7 20025.6 99.3 20156.8

Source: Ministry of Economic Affairs, Economic Statistics Annual: Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various years

3 In 1987, the average non-Chinese investment was $2.56 million, much larger than the average $0.74 million of overseas Chinese. See Schive 1990.

3

Page 4: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 2 FDI as a Share of GDP (1952-2005)

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001

Year

Perc

enta

ge

Source: GDP information from National Statistics of Republic of China, http://eng.stat.gov.tw;FDI information from Ministry of Economic Affairs, Economic Statistics Annual: Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various years, and Investment Commission, Ministry of Economic Affairs,http://w2kdmz1.moea.gov.tw/english/index.asp?P1=statistics_of_economic

The role of FDI is even more important than the statistics would suggest, however. The

outward orientation of the economy relied heavily on relations with foreign firms. Early

investments in manufacturing, particularly from Japan, had been largely import-substituting in

nature. By the mid-1970s, however, the foreign sector exported 40-55 percent of its total output

and accounted for 20 percent of Taiwan’s total exports. FDI also served as an important conduit

4

Page 5: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

for technology transfer.4 Through relationships with suppliers, foreign firms played an

important role in introducing new products and technologies in the auto and auto parts,

electrical and electronics, and plastic and plastic-products industries.5

The most important example of early FDI-related exports was in the electronics sector.6

Early Japanese investments and joint ventures were oriented toward the domestic market, in

part because of tariff protection and local content requirements. American electronics firms that

entered beginning in 1965, by contrast, were classic offshore operations oriented almost

entirely to production for foreign markets. Televisions were the most important segment. By

the early 1970s, virtually all of the American majors had operations in Taiwan: Philco (which

entered in 1965); Admiral (1966); RCA (1967), Motorola (1967) and Zenith (1971). As late as

1975, seven of the top ten foreign firms operating in Taiwan, as measured by sales, were TV

producers and two others—Texas Instruments and General Instrument—provided components

to the sector. Similar patterns were visible although on a smaller scale in a number of other

electronics segments including telephones, switchboards, tape recorders, radios, phonographs,

and increasingly in semiconductors and other electronic components.

The pattern of FDI-driven exports was also visible from the 1960s in a handful of non-

electrical machinery sectors, most notably sewing machines (dominated by Singer) and

bicycles (dominated by Giant). These sectors followed a somewhat different pattern than the

4 Schive 1990, Aw 2004.5 Schive 1990.6 This paragraph draws on Amsden and Chu 2003, 19-22.

5

Page 6: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

enclave production visible in electronics. In both sewing machines and bicycles, foreign firms

drew on dense networks of local parts suppliers, in part at the insistence of the government. For

example, Singer was subject to stringent local content requirements that could only be met

through effective technology transfer to suppliers.

But a focus on FDI grossly understates the importance of foreign firms in the industrial

transformation of Taiwan.7 Beginning in the 1960s, fundamental changes in the American, and

later European and Japanese, retail sector created strong incentives for foreign sourcing of a

variety of basic consumer goods. This demand included the sectors just noted—televisions and

bicycles—but also sectors in which foreign firms were central not through direct investment

but as buyers.8 The first firms to play this crucial intermediary role were the Japanese trading

companies (sogo shosha); by one account, these firms handled as much as one half of Taiwan’s

exports to third countries in the second half of the 1960s.9

By the early 1970s, these were supplemented and then largely displaced by American and

European retailers that placed orders directly. Sears had established a buying office in Taiwan

in 1967 and was followed in the early 1970s by Kmart, J.C. Penney, AMC, May Department

Stores and others.10 Levy’s analysis of the footwear industry shows that the early phases of

export expansion were based overwhelmingly on fulfillment of orders by Japanese trading

companies for the American market. These were soon supplanted by direct subcontracting

7 In particular, see Feenstra and Hamilton 2006, chapters 6 and 7. 8 Gereffi and Korzeniewicz (1994) call these “buyer-driven commodity chains.”9 Feenstra and Hamilton 2006, 263. 10 Gereffi and Pan 1994.

6

Page 7: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

relations with majors such as Nike and Reebok.11 Gereffi and Pan trace a similar process in the

garment sector.12 As Feenstra and Hamilton conclude, “it is difficult to find any major product

category that was not dominated by contract manufacturing or any major retailers that were not

involved in contract manufacturing in East Asia. Garments, household appliances, electronic

products, toys, and bicycles—the majority of these finished exports were sold under foreign-

owned brand names and product labels.”13

How did an authoritarian government in a poor country facing a vulnerable external

political environment succeed in attracting foreign investment and buyers, and in transforming

the investment climate for domestic firms as well? This paper argues that institutional factors

played an important role in this transformation. At the decision-making level, relatively

insulated institutions increased the influence of technocrats and American aid advisors who in

turn represented the interests of both foreign and domestic investors; outside influence played a

strongly supportive role in the reform process. At the implementation level, centralization and

coordination of investment screening and approval processes increased the credibility of

policy and eased foreign entry. Export processing zones were also an important institutional

component of the government’s strategy toward foreign investors, and for similar reasons. The

zones not only provided land and incentives, but simplified the business environment for

foreign firms as well.14 Finally, although formal consultative mechanisms were not present at

11 Levy 1991.12 Gereffi and Pan 1994.13 Feenstra and Hamilton 2006, 25114 Haggard 1990

7

Page 8: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

the peak industry level, sectoral business organizations also played a role in facilitating foreign

entry, operating in close collaboration with the government.

The sharp inflection in both domestic and foreign investment also appears to be correlated

with the introduction of high-powered incentives, particularly with respect to taxes. These

incentives were broadly neutral between foreign and domestic investors, but were by no means

laisser-faire. First, they reflected a clear set of preferences with respect to the type of

investment the government sought to attract; incentives were by no means neutral across

different economic activities. Second, as suggested in the brief consideration of the bicycle and

sewing machine sectors, these incentives were not neutral with respect to domestic and foreign

sources of input supply. The government routinely used local content, technology transfer and

even pricing requirements in order forge backward linkages between foreign firms and local

suppliers. The new incentives also favored the export sector over production for the domestic

market. This occurred not only through additional benefits for exporters, but through export

requirements as well, particularly in the EPZs. Nonetheless, these departures from neutrality

did not deter foreign entry because of the clear commitment on the part of the government to

the profitability of foreign investment.

We focus our attention primarily on the early period of Taiwan’s opening to foreign direct

investment. Over time, incentives were continually widened to encompass new activities,

following as well as leading the interests of foreign and domestic firms. Nonetheless, in

providing a brief overview of some important developments since the mid-1970s, focusing on

8

Page 9: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

some examples from the electronics sector, we show that the government continued to play an

active role in fostering linkages between foreign and domestic firms. They did this by

providing complementary sector-specific assets, such as R & D, that made Taiwan an attractive

investment site.

Export-led Industrialization and Labor-intensive Investment

Upon relocating to Taiwan after the defeat in the civil war in 1949, the KMT regime

quickly disciplined its own factions, reorganized the fragmented military and incorporated

social groups into party-controlled organizations. Even the pretext of constitutional rule had

been dropped under the exigencies of civil war; the country was formally ruled under martial

law. The political system might be described as “leaderist”: Chiang Kai-shek headed the army,

the political system, and an increasingly centralized party apparatus. Alternative centers of

political power—leftist and Formosan nationalist forces, labor, students, and landlords—were

crushed, displaced, or drawn into state-controlled organizational networks.

Authoritarian political institutions and the overwhelming power of the KMT eliminated

serious political challenges to the government; these conditions also limit in important ways

the lessons that can be drawn from the Taiwan case in the current era. Given both the structure

of the economy during the 1950s and 1960s and the political circumstances, industrial interest

groups and particularly labor were both too weak to have strong influence on policy.

9

Page 10: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

In principle, government technocrats enjoyed a certain amount of leeway as long as they

had the support of the president or other top political leaders; internal factional politics were

more important in deciding policy outcomes than constraints from civil society.15 For certain

factions in the government, the shock of past events on the mainland led them toward to focus

on economic reform and the development of the local Taiwanese private sector as a route to

political legitimacy and long-run control.16 However, these reformist factions, or technocrats,

were by no means ascendant in the government during the 1950s. Statist, military and political

factions—in effect, anti-reform forces--also played an important policy role and competed over

scarce resources. These factions included conservative forces that prioritized retaking the

mainland—and thus military expenditure--over local development as well as those that favored

a more statist approach to development, including through the use of the state-owned

enterprise. How did an authoritarian system of this sort move toward reform and avoid the

pitfalls that beset so many others?

The Decision-Making Structure

A distinguishing feature of the policy environment in Taiwan in the 1950s was the crucial

role played by U.S. aid. During the 1951-65 period, over $4 billion of U.S. aid flowed into

Taiwan. Although much of this was military, nonmilitary aid totaled $1.4 billion, equivalent to

over 6 percent of GNP and some 40 percent of both investment and imports. Of the total

15 Hsueh, Hsu, and Perkins 2001.16 Haggard 1990, 83.

10

Page 11: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

current account deficit of $1.3 billion between 1951 and 1962, U.S. aid financed $1.1 billion.17

U.S. aid was used to stabilize prices, rehabilitate and expand infrastructure, and support early

efforts to increase both agricultural and industrial productivity.

Given the weight of U.S. aid in the economy it is not surprising that the institutions

involved in disbursing and monitoring it played an important policy role. Aid was

administrated by the Mutual Security Mission to China of the International Cooperation

Administration (ICA, the precursor to the Agency for International Development [AID]) and

coordinated by a succession of institutions in which the Americans played a major and direct

role. After changes in US aid policy in 1955, the ICA gained the authority to review aid

programs down to the level of the individual project. The Council for United States Aid

(CUSA) had responsibility for the selection of aid projects, oversight of the local currency or

counterpart program, and maintaining a liaison with American aid officials.18 CUSA, along

with a number of other ad hoc cabinet boards and commissions, gave Chinese technocrats a

base for operating amid the confusion created by the preservation of duplicated ministries and

departments at central and provincial levels;19 the evolution of the more important planning

bodies is outlined in Figure 3 and Box 1. However, these bodies also provided the

organizational base for strong and direct influence by US officials. For example, the Economic

Stabilization Board formed in 1953 held its deliberations in English; the director of the US aid

17 Haggard 1990, 84.18 Cheng, Haggard, and Kang 1998. 19 On the Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction see Yager 1988.

11

Page 12: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

mission and the economic counselor of the U.S. embassy took part as if they were full

members. American officials played a similar role in the Joint Committee on Rural

Reconstruction, an agency with wide influence over the course of agricultural policy that

included not only aid expenditures but domestic expenditures as well.

12

Page 13: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 3Evolution of Taiwan’s Economic Planning Agencies

Committee on Economic and Financial Affairs

March 1951

Economic Stabilization Board (ESB)

June 1953

Council for United States Aid (CUSA)

September 1958

Council for International Economic Cooperation and

Development (CIECD)September 1963

Council for International Economic Cooperation and

Development (CIECD)July 1969

Economic Planning Council (EPC)

July 1973

Council for Economic Planning and Development

(CEPD)July 1973

Council for United States Aid (CUSA)

1948

Committee on Economic and Financial Affairs

March 1951

Industrial Development CommissionJune 1953

Financial, Economic and Monetary Conference

Five-man Finance and Economic Committee

(FEC)

13

Page 14: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Source: Pang 1988, 37

Box 1Evolution of Taiwan’s Core Economic Planning Agencies

The Council for U.S. Aid (CUSA) was established in July 1948 after the governments of the Republic of China and the U.S. signed the Sino-American Aid Agreement. Chaired by the premier, the CUSA was the peak economic coordination body between the various parts of the government and the U.S. Mission. It was also responsible for programming the use of U.S. aid funds.

At the suggestion of the United States, and Economic Stabilization Board (ESB) was created in 1953. As its name suggests, a main preoccupation of the board was the important stabilization effort of the first half of the 1950s. Chaired by the finance minister, the ESB also coordinated trade policy, approved all large loans, both domestic and foreign, screened private investment applications and oversaw the administration of the state-owned enterprise, which accounted for over half of total economic output. The ESB was was folded into the CUSA in 1958. A Foreign Exchange and Trade Control Commission was also established to deal with exchange rates and the allocation of foreign exchange. An Industrial Development Commission, finally, was formed in 1953 to implement the industrial components of the first plan and was also folded in CUSA in 1958.20

With the termination of U.S. aid, the CUSA was reorganized into the Council for International Economic Cooperation and Development (CIECD) in September 1963. Continuing to act as a super-ministry, the CIECD retained a wide range of responsibility, coordinating especially the Ministry of Economic Affairs (MEOA) and the Ministry of Finance (MOF). It was chaired by vice-president and premier.21

In 1969, the CIECD was partly reorganized under the leadership of the newly-appointed Vice Premier Chiang Ching-kuo. Some of its officials and functions were transferred to the Industrial Development Bureau under the Ministry of Economic Affairs. A coordinating agency—the Financial, Economic, and Monetary Conference—was irregularly held and presided over by Chiang.22

In August 1973, the CIECD was reorganized as the Economic Planning Council (EPC) and downgraded to vice-ministerial rank. At the same time, the Financial and Economic Committee (FEC), a remarkably informal and flexible policymaking group, was created by Chiang Ching-

20 Pang 1988, 35-40.21 Wade 1990.22 Pang 1988, 35-36

14

Page 15: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

kuo in January 1974. Its members included the minister of economic affairs, the minister of finance, the chief comptroller, the secretary general of the Executive Yuan, and the governor of the Central Bank who served as convener. The committee met each week to discuss policies coordinating the interests of the financial, economic, monetary, agricultural, and industrial sectors and then make policy recommendations directly to the premier.23

The EPC was merged with the FEC and reorganized as the Council for Economic Planning and Development (CEPD) in December 1977. The CEPD was on a par with the other ministries. The CEPD has twelve members, including the governor of the Central Bank, the ministers of economic affairs, finance, transportation and communications, the director-general of budget, accounts, and statistics, the chairpersons of the council of agriculture, the public construction commission, the council of labor affairs, secretary-general of the Executive Yuan, and the financial supervisory commission, and a minister without portfolio. Serving as an advisory capacity to the Executive Yuan, the CEPD is responsible for: 1) drafting overall plans for national economic development; 2) evaluating development projects, proposals, and programs submitted to the Executive Yuan; 3) coordinating the economic policymaking activities of related ministries and agencies; and 4) monitoring the implementation of development projects, measures, and programs.24

US aid in Taiwan was administrated outside of the budget. Placing aid administration and

finance in the hands of semi-autonomous agencies no doubt contributed to the efficiency of the

aid allocation process. First, it allowed development questions to be considered separately from

sensitive issues such as defense and domestic political circumstances.25 The pilot economic

planning agencies like CUSA (and later the Council on International Economic Cooperation

and Development) had an unusual organizational independence. Second, this organizational

independence was backed by financial independence. With their budget supported by US aid,

these institutions enjoyed some freedom from normal civil service regulations, which enabled

them to pay very much higher salaries (up to five times comparable salaries in the early 1950s),

23 Myers 1990, 53.24 Council for Economic Planning and Development, http://www.cepd.gov.tw. 25 Jacoby 1966, 222.

15

Page 16: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

recruit and train highly competent staff, and maintain an organizational esprit de corps.26

Finally, these agencies enjoyed autonomy not only from business and other societal interests

but even from other branches of the government itself because they were accountable to both

the executive and the Americans.27 Although reforms ultimately had to pass through the

representative bodies, these were directly controlled by the executive and party leadership and

thus did not pose the potential for serious conflicts over policy.28 As we will see in more detail

below, Taiwan did not have the formal consultative public-private bodies that have been

deemed important in other settings, and when such meetings were held on an ad hoc basis they

were for the purpose of informing the private sector of government policies rather than

formally consulting with it.

In 1963 the CUSA was reorganized into the Council on International Economic

Cooperation and Development (CIECD). This reorganization reflected in large measure the

impending termination of US economic aid in 1964.29 The CIECD was a centralized

development agency that amalgamated the CUSA and three planning groups (industrial,

agricultural, and communications). It was charged with the formulation, integration, and

coordination of economic development plans and negotiations for external financial and

technical assistance. During the period of the CIECD, economic technocrats and their extra-

bureaucratic niches were gradually incorporated into the regular bureaucracy and the line

26 Pang 1988, 40; Cheng, Haggard, and Kang 1998.27 See Yager 1988, 274-5 on the legal debates around these lines of accountability. 28 Chu 1994, 117.29 Some commodity assistance continued after that time, as well as lending through entities such as the Import-Export Bank. The US also facilitated borrowing through the World Bank.

16

Page 17: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

ministries expanded their functions.30

The passing of the first generation of political leaders and rise of Chiang Ching-kuo served

to weaken the CIECD, the primary institution guiding Taiwan’s economic planning between

the mid-1960s and the early 1970s. It was formally downgraded to vice-ministerial level and

renamed the Economic Planning Council (EPC) in 1973. As indicated by its name, the EPC’s

function was indicative economic planning. The CIECD’s technology cooperation,

international funds, and public relations sections were integrated into other ministries, in effect

normalizing the institutional arrangements that had generated the early economic reforms.31

One set of government organizations that is particularly relevant here are those dealing

directly with foreign investors. The government promulgated investment laws in 1954 and

1955 aimed at facilitating the inflow of foreign and overseas Chinese capital respectively.

However, inflows of foreign capital were not very impressive through most of the 1950s

(Figure 2). The Industrial Development and Investment Center (IDIC) was set up in 1959 to

address this issue by providing investment services; interestingly, it was placed in CUSA

specifically at the request of Premier Chen Cheng.32 The IDIC was charged with attracting

investment from foreign nationals and overseas Chinese and improving Taiwan’s investment

environment. Through its extensive network of both overseas liaison offices as well as local

committees in major cities, the IDIC established a platform to facilitate the interaction between

30 Cheng, Haggard, and Kang 1998.31 Wu 2005. With the outbreak of the first oil crises in the 1970s, the changing economic climate demanded more potent and effective tactics than the EPC could provide, and a new cabinet-level forum for economic policymaking was created: the Financial and Economic Committee (FEC).32 Haggard and Pang 1994

17

Page 18: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

the central government, foreign and domestic investors. Its location in CUSA also facilitated

direct contact with American embassy and aid officials with a stake in promoting the interests

of American investors.

The government also established an Overseas Chinese and Foreign Investment

Commission to screen investment proposals. Important organizational changes in this

Commission played a key role in facilitating the foreign investment process not simply by

coordinating the government’s response but by reducing the channels through which particular

investments might be slowed down or rejected.33 The commission was initially established

within the Ministry of Economic Affairs (MOEA), but did not have its own staff. The chairman

of the Commission was a vice minister of the MOEA and members of the commission were

department chiefs. In effect, the commission was a liaison agency for an initial screening of

proposals, which subsequently required direct approach to each of the separate government

authorities with jurisdiction over aspects of the investment.

At least some of these bodies had mixed motives. For example, the Foreign Exchange and

Trade Commission (FETC) controlled the issuance of import licenses for machinery,

equipment and raw materials and was subject to cross-cutting political pressures that could

militate against particular investments; the FETC also had to approve remittances of capital,

profits and royalties. Applications for tax and duty exemptions had to be filed with local tax

offices and customs houses, which had their own fiscal interests, and would require ultimate

33 The following draws on Overseas Chinese and Foreign Investment Commission 1972.

18

Page 19: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

approval by the Ministry of Finance, which was also concerned about the overall tax take.

Basic services such as visas and business registration were also decentralized.

In 1968, the government responded to growing disaffection with the screening process to

dramatically centralize the process; the new structure of the Commission is diagrammed in

Figure 4. Although it is difficult to demonstrate a cause and effect relationship, the formation

of the new set of procedures did appear to lead to an increase in FDI flows.

19

Page 20: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 4The Overseas Chinese & Foreign Investment Commission

Source: Overseas Chinese & Foreign Investment Commission 1972, 22.

First, the Commission was delegated full authority by the various government

organizations to the representatives of the Commission, who were upgraded to the Vice

Ministerial level. These representatives were authorized to approve all questions that

conformed with the relevant statute; where clearance was needed within the relevant ministry,

Ministry of Economic Affairs

Overseas Chinese & Foreign Investment Commission

Members: Vice Minister, MOEA (Chairman)Vice Minister, Ministry of FinanceVice Minister, Minister of Foreign AffairsVice Minister, Minister of CommunicationsVice Chairman, Overseas Chinese Affairs CommissionDeputy Governor, Central Bank of ChinaSecretary General, CIECDCommissioner, Taiwan Provincial Department of ReconstructionDirector, Taipei Municipal Bureau of Reconstruction

Executive Secretary

Secretariat Service Division

Foreign Transactions Division

Tax Division

Investment Operations Division

20

IDIC

Page 21: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

that task was now handled by the appropriate division of the Commission or by the

organization’s representative. Second, the Commission was granted staffing seconded from the

relevant ministries and other bodies, with administrative divisions corresponding to core

functions: Services, Foreign Transactions, Taxes, and Operations. With this reorganization, the

investment screening process approximated more closely the “one-stop shopping” model.

Although the commission in principle only had the authority to approve applications

conforming with statute, in effect it gained the discretion to bargain with the investor to

determine what was needed to attract a desired project: to weigh the total package of incentives

and performance requirements,34 and to commit other government agencies to the agreement.35

It is important to underscore that the simplification of procedure did not imply a liberal

investment regime; FDI still had to conform to the industrial policy objectives of the

government. For example, in the early 1960s the electronics industry became a government

favorite while the Investment Commission began to discourage investments in textiles. Even

FDI falling within the target categories was not automatically approved. The Investment

Commission held the authority to negotiate over key parameters including most notably local

content requirements, technology transfer, and export requirements.36

Business in the Policy Process

A final issue to consider about the decision-making structure is the role of the private

34 While the performance requirements were project-specific, they normally included local-content rates and export quota. See Schive (1990) for a detailed case study of Singer’s investment in Taiwan. 35 Wade 1990.36 Chao 2000.

21

Page 22: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

sector. To what extent did the government formally consult with or provide channels for private

sector representation in the decision-making process? Did deliberation councils play a role in

defining the course of policy, and the course of policy with respect to foreign investment in

particular?

In general, the literature on Taiwan emphasizes the distance between the government and

the local private sector, either as a result of culture (the Confucian gap between the status of

rulers and the commercial class); ethnicity (the divide between KMT mainlanders and the local

Taiwanese) or politics (KMT concern about the threat of political competition if business were

allowed to organize independently or gain formal representation).37 It is hard to find evidence

that consultative mechanisms played a meaningful role in influencing the overall direction of

investment policy. The state sanctioned a small number of interest groups including both peak

and sectoral business associations and gave them a monopoly of representation. Yet these

bodies initially were seen by the government as instruments of control, as Kuo shows clearly.38

They initially focused primarily on the provision of services to their member rather than

representing collective interests. For example, as a follow-up to the nineteen-point reform

program described in more detail below, the government organized a high-level economic and

financial conference in 1961. Major business leaders were invited to attend the conference,

where they were encouraged to express their grievances and propose policy suggestions.39

37 Cheng 1993 provides a compelling political economy account. 38 Kuo 1995, 70-71.39 Lin 1973.

22

Page 23: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

However, this conference was held after core statutes had already been promulgated and had

the objective of transmitting information to the private sector as much as eliciting its views.

The distance between the state and the local private sector had an underlying political

explanation. The KMT was dominated by mainlanders; outside of a relatively small number of

larger mainlander enterprises, most business establishments on the island were Taiwanese. The

KMT government—or at least some factions within it—were cautious about the consequences

of increased business power and influence; the KMT did therefore not pursue the strategy of

building “national champions” in the same way that Korean government did.40 These policy

preferences were reflected in the nature of the industrial structure. A number of Taiwanese

firms ultimately achieved significant scale.41 But small and medium enterprises (SMEs)

initially played an important role in the acceleration of industrial production and exports: as

subcontractors in sectors such as garments and shoes and as suppliers in sectors such as sewing

machines, bicycles and later electronic components.42

However, this characterization of an arms-length relationship between the state and the

private sector is also misleading in important respects. Detailed sectoral studies note an abiding

interest on the part of the industrial policy agencies in the development of the local private

sector. Moreover, both government officials and local business organizations had an interest in

forging linkages between foreign firms and local companies. Detailing these relationships takes

40 This difference was manifest in very different approaches to the financial sector; government-directed finance was a crucial policy instrument contributing to the growth of the chaebol in Korea. See Cheng 1993. 41 Amsden and Chu 1993.42 Wu 2005.

23

Page 24: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

us beyond the central focus of this paper, but two examples provide insight into the business-

government relationship at the micro level and the importance of business associations with

respect to both foreign and domestic investment and exports.43

As early as 1950 sectoral plans had been launched to support the textile industry, with

technical assistance from an American consulting firm, imported power looms from Japan and

raw cotton from the US aid program. CUSA’s textile subcommittee, cooperating later with the

IDC, acted directly to promote linkages between different segments of the industry by

allocating raw cotton and yarn through industry associations. Loans were available for plant

expansion through CUSA (which distributed as much as 20 percent of its aid directly to local

business). When price controls were cautiously lifted in the late-1950s, the industry

experienced a shakeout that forced increased cooperation through the Taiwan Cotton Spinners

Association (TCSA). Through the association, and with government agreement, the industry

reduced production, collectively purchased cotton, set prices and agreed to export a stipulated

share of output (effectively subsidized by domestic sales).

The industry cooperated with government in a number of ways to increase exports and the

attractiveness of Taiwan’s products to foreign buyers. These included laws allowing for the

establishment of bonded factories, the formulation of guidelines for the creation of export

syndicates and the codification of inspection criteria in order to increase quality control, a key

43 The following cases are drawn from Haggard 1990, 89 and Kuo 1995, 95-111 and 169-191. Parallel cases can be found in Simon 1980, Gold 1981, Levy 1991, Amsden and Chu 2003, and in early studies by the government itself, for example Kao 1969 on the machinery sector, Chu 1966 and Schive 1990 on sewing machines.

24

Page 25: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

issue in maintaining reputation with foreign buyers. In 1961, the MOEA formed a Working

Committee on Cotton Textile Exports, which was followed shortly by the promulgation of

special Measures for Rescuing the Textile Industry and Export Promotion. Throughout the

1960s, the local press reported ongoing meetings between the industry and government

officials around issues such as export quotas and other policy measures.

The Taiwan Electric Appliance Manufacturers’ Association (TEAMA) was established in

1948, and initially played a role on Taiwan in allocating scarce imports among members.

Larger producers with political connections tended to receive favorable treatment while small

manufacturers survived on the basis of their own capital and local sales networks. The influx of

foreign direct investment in the sector in the early 1960s posed a major challenge and forced

TEAMA to become more active. Many of TEAMA’s activities could be considered market-

related. For example, TEAMA played an important intermediary role in matching foreign firms

with domestic suppliers and became involved in activities such as survey groups to foreign

invested factories. According to Kuo, “several production satellite systems, which connected

local producers and FDIs as well as small producers and larger assemblers, emerged as a

consequence of this effort.”44 TEAMA also became involved in issues such as quality control

and the diffusion of managerial know-how.

However TEAMA also interacted with government officials on a number of policy issues.

For example, TEAMA lobbied to make sure that local content requirements were maintained

44 Kuo 1995, 172

25

Page 26: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

and to influence government procurement. It represented the industry with respect to the

setting of tariff schedules on imports, and cooperated with the government in identifying and

shutting down non-registered or underground firms. Beginning in 1967, the CIECD called a

formal consultative meeting with the industry to discuss the outlines of more active electronics

promotion strategy that included both liberalizing measures (for example, with respect to tariffs

and tax rebates) but also more active supports; these efforts carried forward into the more

recent period and are discussed briefly below.

In sum, the core or “pilot” agencies did not directly accommodate private sector

participation. However, from very early the government had developed highly specialized ad

hoc bodies that conferred both formally and informally with private sector representatives over

both the general business climate and sectoral issues. These institutions played an important

role with respect to policy but also served directly to facilitate exports (in the textile case) and

inward investment (in the electronics example).

The Course of Economic Reform

By the mid-1950s, Taiwan had exhausted the “easy stage” of import substitution and the

economy was experiencing a number of difficulties including market saturation, slowed growth

and investment and the overvaluation of the exchange rate and sluggish export performance.

The United States was concerned about these developments, but also about the ongoing aid

burden. It was very clear that the U.S. could not continue to subsidize the economy at the same

rate going forward; the U.S. thus had a very direct interest in promoting both exports and

26

Page 27: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

investment that would substitute for the gradual winding down of foreign aid. A cable from the

Ambassador in mid-1960 captures these concerns for an “accelerated program” of economic

reform:

Sustained rise in export [of] finished or semi-finished goods provides major hope for

buying food imports which will be increasingly necessary. No automatic limits exist in

increasing such exports, but sustained rise will probably occur only if there are fundamental

institutional changes in economy to lower costs and to make industrial investment attractive to

entrepreneurs. Such changes are among [the] objectives of [the] accelerate program.45

Following the end of the second cross-Straits crisis over Quemoy and Matsu (August 23,

1958-January 1, 1959), U.S. embassy and aid officials began to outline a package of reforms

that would achieve these objectives and ultimately allow Taiwan to graduate from foreign aid

in 1964. In subsequent negotiations over the program, American officials continually

underlined the unsustainable nature of current levels of aid as an inducement to reform. At the

same time, however, AID promised the government an additional program loan of $20-30

million upon a prompt implementation of the Program.46

The reforms initially had eight core components:

limiting resources devoted to the military;

non-inflationary fiscal and monetary policies;

tax reforms to encourage private sector investment;

a uniform and realistic exchange rate;

45 Drumwright 1960. 46 Jacoby 1966, 135.

27

Page 28: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

liberalized trade and exchange controls; 47

formation of a utilities commission to overseas utility pricing;

reorganization of the banking system;

the sale of public enterprises to the private sector and a reduction of the state role in

activities in which the private sector could compete.48

These reforms were packaged with a number of others into a Nineteen Point Program of

Economic and Financial Reform in 1960 that became the defining feature of the third Four-

Year Economic Plan (1961-64). Not all elements of this program were implemented with equal

dispatch; in particular, the efforts to hold military spending constant as well as the pressure to

privatize state-owned enterprises ran up against core KMT constituencies within the

government itself.

As we have seen, the government included important factions that were preoccupied

with regaining the mainland and were not at all sympathetic to the Taiwanese private sector.

Portions of the military and bureaucracy favored a statist approach to development; this had

included nationalizing Japanese enterprises and running them as state-owned companies.49 In

1953, the government committed to transfer public enterprises to private ownership, but

exempted “monopoly” enterprises, industries vital to national defense and producers of

47 Although the reforms reduced tariffs on imported inputs, reduced exchange controls and unified the multiple exchange rate system they should not be confused with wholesale liberalization. For example, tariff barriers continued to be used for industrial policy purposes but were offset for exporters through import duty rebates. Cheng 200148 Lewis 1993, 221.49 Jacoby 1966, 136.

28

Page 29: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

upstream intermediates that ended up playing a very substantial role in the government’s

overall industrial policy. Four large state-owned enterprises—the Taiwan Cement Corporation,

Taiwan Pulp and Paper Corporation, Taiwan Industrial and Mining Corporation and Taiwan

Agricultural and Forestry Development Corporation—were transferred to private ownership to

compensate dispossessed landlords under the land reform (Land-to-the-Tiller) program, but

effective control of these firms remained in government hands because of the dispersion of

private ownership. As can be seen in Figure 5, even with the reforms of the early 1960s, and

the rapid growth of output and investment, the public sector share of fixed capital formation

remained high and didn’t really begin to trend down until the late-1980s; privatization was the

one component of the reforms of the 1960s that did not fully meet American expectations.

The government not only walled off the “commanding heights” of the economy from

private participation, but used a variety of other means to prevent the formation of the type of

integrated business groups visible in Japan and Korea. Prior to the 1980s, for example,

Taiwan’s laws prevented the formation of enterprise conglomerates by limiting the amount of

its capital one company could invest in another.50

50 The Company Act stipulated that the ceiling a company can invest in any one other company is 40 percent of its own paid-in capital.

29

Page 30: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 5Public and Private Enterprises as a Share of Fixed Capital Formation (1952-2003)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

1952 1957 1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002

Year

Percentage

Private Enterprises Public Enterprises

Source: Industry of Free China 1958-1973; Economic Statistics Annual Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various issues.

However, the limited success of the US in pressing for limits on military spending and

direct privatization ultimately proved much less significant than the policy measures designed

to support the development of the local private sector; privatization took place not through the

direct transfer of assets but through the rapid growth of the domestic private sector. In addition

to the well-known macroeconomic reforms that have attracted attention in the literature on

Taiwan, U.S. aid officials saw three problems that were deterring both domestic entrepreneurs

and foreign companies: the tax burden; the complexity of the procedures governing investment

30

Page 31: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

licensing; and the acquisition of plant sites.51 The crucial statute for addressing these issues was

the Statute for Encouragement of Investment (SEI) passed in August 1960. Premier Chen

Cheng assigned CUSA the major role in drafting the Statute for the Encouragement of

Investment (SEI) precisely because he sought a coordinated approach and wished to avoid the

interference, conflicting goals, and resistance from particular interests that would have affected

the course of the law if drafted through other channels. The Statute includes important

provisions easing the acquisition of land. The government’s dramatic land reform efforts of the

early 1950s had been extremely successful in equalizing land ownership, but policies design to

prevent a reconcentration of land assets had the unintended consequence of also limiting the

acquisition of industrial plant sites. The new law eased these constraints, and in conjunction

with investment in rural infrastructure and the establishment of industrial parks set in train a

dramatic expansion of rural industry that became a hallmark of the Taiwan model.52

The main incentives under the SEI centered on taxes and included:

a five year tax holiday on corporate income tax, and a 10 percent reduction

thereafter for new businesses conforming to criteria;

a reduction in the maximum corporate tax rate from 32.5 percent to 18 percent;

deduction from taxable income of reinvested earnings up to 25 percent of the total

income of the taxable year;

51 Haggard and Pang 1994.52 See Ho 1982 on rural industrialization. Between 1963 and 1988, the government designated 21,884 hectares of land for industrial use of which 74 percent was developed into industrial parks. Hsueh et al. 2001, 31.

31

Page 32: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

deduction from taxable income of 2 percent of annual export proceeds as an export

incentive;

waiver of customs duties for equipment imported and used by “basic industries”

with a minimum initial capitalization.53

Several features of these incentives are noteworthy. First, although foreign investors had

gained the right to100 percent foreign ownership and management, and guarantees against

expropriation, the Statute did not explicitly differentiate between domestic and foreign

investors.54 Second, the focus of incentives on new businesses rather than existing ones had the

(probably unintended) consequence of generating new start ups and contributing to the gradual

emergence of economic groups on Taiwan; Chung shows that the period following the SEI was

characterized by particularly rapid growth of new firms and groups.55

However, not all activities were open to these incentives; as with FDI, the government

sought to channel investment into a particular list of industries in line with its changing

industrial policy objectives. As a result, the number of firms actually qualifying for these

incentives—or able to overcome remaining administrative barriers in applying for them—was

relatively small. In a study conducted in 1967, Cheng Hang-sheng found that only 474

enterprises—out of 240,000 enterprises on the island--enjoyed the various tax exemptions

granted by the SEI, and of those firms not all were able to qualify for all of the various

53 Dao 1965. 54 Under the law no venture with 51 percent or more foreign investment can be nationalized for a period of 20 years after the venture is established. Expropriation can be justified only for national defense needs and “reasonable” compensation must be given.55 Chung 2001.

32

Page 33: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

incentives. Nonetheless, these firms were estimated to account for 16 percent of total turnover

and 27 percent of total business investment. Although this was to widen over time, it is

suggestive of the directive nature of the new incentives and the fact that the government did in

the end back larger firms to a greater extent than is typically believed.56

Export Processing Zones

Although both foreign and domestic investment began to respond to the reforms of 1960

relatively quickly, a key institutional factor in attracting a new wave of foreign investors was

the establishment of the export processing zones (EPZs). The original idea for setting up EPZs

was put forward by the Economic Stabilization Board (ESB) as early as 1956, but met

resistance from a number of sources. Among the stated reasons for this opposition were

concerns about sovereignty and the exploitation of labor,57 but as with the coordination of

investment screening, ministerial and intergovernmental concerns loomed large. The Ministry

of Finance worried about the effects of the zones on the collection of customs receipts, the

Foreign Exchange and Trade Commission had doubts about the potential leakage with respect

to trade and exchange controls and local governments expressed concern about loss of control

in their jurisdictions.58

As a result, Taiwan’s experience with EPZs did not begin until a decade later in 1966 with

the establishment of the Kaohsiung Export Processing Zone (KEPZ) and the promulgation of

56 Cheng 1970, 3657 K.T. Li 1988.58 Lam 1992.

33

Page 34: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

the Statute for the Establishment and Management of Export Processing Zones.59 From its

inception, the zone was designed not only to increase industrial development and create jobs

but to increase exports and bring in new technologies as well.60 In pursuing these objectives,

the EPZs became an important element in Taiwan’s export-oriented growth phase.

Taiwan’s EPZs were established based on an idea that was at least relatively innovative for

the time but which has subsequently become more commonplace: to combine the advantages

of a free trade zone and an industrial estate with all of the relevant administrative functions of

the government.61 This approach was innovative in two ways: it had an integrated, simplified

administration; and it put primary stress on production for export (rather than processing that is

essentially a transshipping activity). Infrastructural support needed for export businesses, such

as customs clearance, banks, and telecommunications were also made readily available within

the zone. Even standard factories could be ordered.

The CIECD, together with the MOEA, drafted the rules and regulations pertaining to the

enforcement of the Statute, including those concerning the priority of export enterprises

admissible for establishment in the zone, criteria for the screening of applications, control of

foreign exchange and trade, and administration of the zone.62 However, the legislature

centralized the administrative responsibility and authority for the zones in the zone’s

59 Two major concerns delayed the implementation of EPZ plan. First, there was a concern that Taiwan would yield sovereignty in the zones to foreign investors. The other concern was that relatively cheap Taiwanese labor would be exploited for the benefit of foreign investors. See K.T. Li 1988.60 Simon 1980, 371.61 Scott 1979.62 K.T. Li 1976.

34

Page 35: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

administrative body. The MOEA was given jurisdiction through an agency specifically created

for the purpose. Even more directly than with the Investment Commission, several government

agencies closely related to the operation and management of the EPZs had some of their

functions and authority delegated to the zone administration.

In addition to the tax incentives accorded under the SEI, firms established in the zones

enjoyed additional benefits. They were entitled to import intermediate inputs duty-free; they

did not need to go through the time-consuming tax rebate procedures; and duty exemption of

imported plant equipment was granted to all plants without exception.63 However, these were

not given with complete neutrality; the government again had industrial policy objectives even

if they were not narrowly defined. To reduce the likelihood of competition between EPZ and

domestic firms, the MOEA only allowed seventeen industries to be located in EPZs.64 The

initial regulations also required that products manufactured in the EPZs could not be sold in the

domestic market. In contrast to other export-processing zones that invited pure processing

activities, Taiwan maintained its commitment to local-content requirements to generate

backward linkages in the local economy. Nine products of the electrical and electronics and the

machinery industries were required to meet certain local-content rates.65

Later on, regulations were loosed to permit limited sales in the domestic market upon

63 By contrast, outside firms were only entitled to get tax rebate for imported inputs used in the finished products; five-year deferral of import duties on plant equipment was only applied to a number of export industries with foreign investments or participation. See Lin 1973, 107.64 In general, only industries with a high value-added ratio (generally 20 percent of total costs of the finished product) and those did not need much land space were welcome in the EPZs. See Lin 1973, 107.65 These products included televisions, radios, refrigerators, transformers, cars, motorcycles, diesel engines, tractors, and air conditioners. See Schive 1990.

35

Page 36: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

approval and payment of customs duty. However at the same time other aspects of the rules

governing the zones became more restrictive. In 1972 and 1973, when demand for labor was

particularly strong, the government stopped giving tax holidays to labor-intensive investments

and turned to encourage more capital- and technology-intensive industries. Partly because of

this policy, the capital/labor ratio in the Nantze and Taichung zones has averaged between two

and six times the average of the KEPZ.66 One reason for the preference for technology-

intensive firms, again, has been the desire to avoid competition with Taiwan’s existing export

industries. It was for this reason that manufacturers of cotton textiles or garments either were

not allowed into the zones or their products were not allowed to be exported to markets where

imports from Taiwan were placed under a quota.67

The exact timing of the founding of the first zone is noteworthy; it came just prior to the

1968 reforms of the Investment Commission. For foreign investors, a key advantage of the

zones was therefore avoidance of red tape, including in particular the relatively time-

consuming process of securing rebates on taxes on inputs or outputs but also the broader

process of licensing investments.68 Manufacturing plants established in the EPZs could enjoy

all of the tax benefits accorded to export industries, in addition to having ready access to well-

developed infrastructure and facilities at very low cost.

66 Scott 1979.67 Lin 1973, 108.68 The tax rebate system was initiated in 1951 and was later extended to cover all export goods. Before the EPZs were created, the government processed tax rebate applications by first taxing imported supplies and later refunding companies when they exported end products. The cumbersome procedure produced some financial costs even if no taxes were actually paid. See Lin 1973, 100-103.

36

Page 37: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

The KEPZ was an immediate success. Between 1966 and 1970, it attracted a total of $32.7

million in FDI, constituting 80 percent of total investments (domestic and foreign) in EPZs.69

By the end of the 1960s, the saturation of the space within the KEPZ stimulated the

government to establish two additional zones, the Nantze EPZ in southern Taiwan and the

Taichung EPZ in central Taiwan. Both were established in 1969 and were open for production

in 1971.

It is also worth noting that the EPZs were in principle open to investment by both foreign

and domestic firms, although they were much more successful in attracting foreign than local

Chinese investors. One reason for this was that certain administrative measures adopted by the

EPZs were not available to local producers. However, it was also extremely difficult for local

firms in sectors open to investment to compete with foreign firms in terms of both scale and

technology.70

By 1978, the three EPZs had attracted $240.9 million, exceeding the original target of

$55.5 million by over four times. By 1986, cumulative investment had reached $459 million,

more than twenty times the initial expectation in 1966, and almost 10 percent of private foreign

and overseas Chinese investment in Taiwan for the period 1966-83.71 Total exports from EPZ-

based firms in 1966-1978 were $3.7 billion, and averaged about 9-10 percent of Taiwan’s

exports for any given year. FDI concentrated in a few sectors, most notably in electronics and

69 Schive 1990, 11.70 Simon 1980, 378.71 K.T. Li 1988.

37

Page 38: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

to a much lesser degree in plastics and garments; electronics products constituted 57 percent of

all zone exports. The majority of investors within the zones came from Japan, which accounted

for 42 percent of total number of firms and 38 percent of total investment respectively.

Japanese investors tended to comprise small and medium companies. The second largest

investment source country was the U.S., which accounted for 13 percent of total number of

firms in the EPZs.72 American investors were generally large MNCs, which set up wholly

owned subsidiaries to cut costs on goods targeted at the U.S. market. The third type of foreign

investor was Overseas Chinese, generally from Hong Kong and Southeast Asia. They invested

in light industries that transferred little technology and competed with the exports of Taiwan’s

own investors; over time, these investments fell out of favor with the government.73

The incremental improvement in the overall investment climate in Taiwan gradually

reduced the advantages initially offered by the zones. These changes were partly the result of

crisis. In the early 1970s, rapid growth put strong pressure on Taiwan’s labor market. Labor

costs increased and profit margins narrowed. In 1974-75, the oil crisis hit and the economy fell

into recession. In the KEPZ alone, 13,000 workers were laid off. At the same time, foreign

investors began to regard government regulations with respect to local-content requirements

and export quotas as limiting and burdensome when compared to the rules that pertained

outside of the zones.74 Each firm in the zones was allocated an export quota in proportion to its

72 Simon 1980.73 Gold 1986.74 It is indicated by the higher growth of local-content rates for foreign firms in the EPZs though foreign firms in EPZs have constantly had lower rates than those outside EPZs in the 1970s. See Schive 1990, 73-75.

38

Page 39: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

output, and was required to pay a penalty to the cooperative fund if its export sales fall short. 75

By the late 1970s, firms in the zones argued that there were only two major benefits left: the

simplified government procedures and duty-free imports of machinery, equipment, raw

materials, and intermediate inputs. But the former had eroded with the increased efficiency of

the investment review process set in train after 1968 while the latter advantage became less

compelling as Taiwan liberalized the domestic market.76 Between 1966 and 1970, 13.8 percent

of foreign investment went into the EPZs, but this proportion declined to 11 percent in 1976-80

and to 4.7 percent in 1986-1990. EPZs’ contribution to exports also declined over time. (Table

2). This decline and the changing nature of Taiwan’s comparative advantage combined to

produce an altogether different approach to industrial zones in the 1980s and 1990s.

Table 2: Investment in Taiwan’s Export Processing Zones

YearNo. of Firms

Total Accumulative Investment (million $)

Domestic (%)

Overseas Chinese (%)

Foreign (%)

Joint Ventures (%)

EPZ FDI as a share of Total77

EPZ Exports as a share of Total

1966 51 10 20 30 47 3 .. 1.21970 183 55 10 13 51 26 13.8 7.41975 291 177 12 10 61 18 11.5 8.51980 296 309 12 6 65 18 11.0 7.21985 252 398 10 3 46 41 4.8 6.1

75 Lin 1973, 108.76 K.T. Li 1988.77 FDI as a share of total is the average number in five-year period. For example, 11.5 percent in 1975 means that FDI inflows in EPZs accounted for 11.5 percent of total FDI inflows between 1971 and 1975. The net FDI inflows in EPZs are calculated by using the sum of overseas, foreign, and JV’s investment in present year minus the sum in the previous year.

39

Page 40: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

1990 235 797 15 1 44 40 4.7 5.21993 233 914 20 0 35 44 0.9 5.12002 305 5920 41 0 7 51 .. 4.72005 401 6817 34 0 11 55 .. 4.0

Source: Export Processing Zones Essential Statistics, cited from Xiao Fengxiong (1994), Taiwan’s Experience: the Industrial Policy and Industrial Development (Taiwan de jing yan: wo guo chan ye zheng ce yu chan ye fa zhan), Taipei: Council for Economic Planning and Development, pp. 310; Export data from Economic Statistics Annual: Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various year, Ministry of Economic Affairs, Taiwan

Changing the Investment Climate: a Reprise

The foregoing account highlights several features that may be of wider relevance in

thinking about reform of the investment climate:

1. Facing a variety of political as well as economic constraints, Taiwan opted for a

relatively concentrated set of reforms that addressed a variety of constraints on its

investment climate in a relatively compressed amount of time (1959-60).

2. These reforms were crafted by relatively centralized agencies, working very closely

with foreign advisors but insulated to an important extent from inter-ministerial

conflicts.

3. These institutions enjoyed some independence from standard civil service practices.

4. At the implementation level, the reforms centralized and streamlined both the

application and screening process for investors and created institutions that could

coordinate the provision of government investment services.

5. The government did not discriminate de jure between domestic and foreign firms,

although some incentives effectively benefited foreign investors disproportionately (for

40

Page 41: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

example, because of sectoral restrictions on certain incentives in the zones).

6. Export-processing zones that enjoyed additional incentives and provided specialized

infrastructure played an important role in attracting investment at the outset of the

reforms, but declined in significance over time. The zones enjoyed dedicated

administration.

7. A major incentive for these policy and institutions reforms was the anticipation that aid

would be reduced.

Second Stage: Attracting Investment for Industrial Upgrading

It is beyond the scope of this study to trace the subsequent development of the

government’s strategies for continuing to attract foreign investment in any detail. Yet it is

worthwhile underlining two apparently contradictory trends that are visible in the three decades

since the mid-1970s. On the one hand, we can see a strong trend toward liberalization of the

investment regime, driven by external economic shocks, international political calculations,

and new political pressures associated with democratization. On the other hand, the

government has by no means abdicated its effort to both attract and channel such investment

through targeted, sector-specific supports. As with many other countries in the region, the

government has shifted toward what might be called an “open economy industrial policy.”

These policies place less emphasis on protection and subsidization of favored sectors and more

emphasis on creating conditions that are favorable for foreign investors. However these

conditions are not simply permissive ones, but continue to involve an active strategy of

41

Page 42: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

providing complementary physical and intellectual assets and specialized infrastructure

designed to induce clustering in particular sectors.

The origins of a more liberal investment regime can be traced in the first instance to

vulnerabilities inherent in the export-oriented strategy itself that emerged in the early-1970s. In

addition to the oil shocks of the 1970s and early 1980s, Taiwan’s trading partners raised

protectionist barriers against its exports; rising labor costs put competitive pressures on mature

industries; and other less-developed countries, particularly in Southeast Asia, began to hone in

on Taiwan’s markets. In 1974, Taiwan experienced its first trade deficit since 1970, and GNP

grew only 1.1 percent.78 FDI inflows dropped 50 percent in 1973-75. The extended global

slowdown that followed the second oil crisis once again hit Taiwan hard. FDI inflows dropped

again in 1981 after five years of consecutive growth. Shocks of this sort quite naturally pushed

the government to liberalize restrictions on FDI.

A second factor contributing to a more liberal posture was the emergence of new

international political vulnerabilities. The Nixon administration’s opening to China was a major

political shock. Taiwan’s international position gradually eroded along with the transfer of U.S.

diplomatic recognition from Taipei to Beijing in 1978. However, this political vulnerability

reinforced liberal policy biases. The government felt a strong need to maintain and foster as

wide a set of international economic ties as possible as a surrogate for political ones.79 Growing

political isolation meant greater efforts to secure and insure foreign investors’ commitment to

78 Gold 1986.79 Haggard 1990.

42

Page 43: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Taiwan.80

Somewhat similar political concerns influenced policy toward foreign direct investment

into the 1990s and 2000s as China became an important destination for foreign investment,

including from Taiwan itself. Growing cross-Straits investment ties and fears of the “hollowing

out” of the industrial base contributed to a sense of urgency in securing foreign investment that

would contribute to upgrading Taiwan’s industrial and service capabilities.

A third factor influencing the course of government policy was dramatic political change.

Beginning in the mid 1980s, Taiwan’s system entered a period of transition to more democratic

rule. During the transition, the President continued to wield substantial authority. Nonetheless,

the Executive branch (or Yuan) and the ministries gradually lost lawmaking and policy making

power, and in several distinct ways. First, the Legislative Yuan, historically an inactive and

underperforming body, became increasingly significant in the policymaking process. In 1991,

old members of the Legislative Yuan were forced to abandon their seats and the legislature was

filled with newly elected members who were under pressure to represent constituent interests.81

As electoral and partisan competition began to exercise influence over the policy process,

power naturally shifted away from insulated, technocratic agencies toward elected officials,

with important implications for the institutions described in the previous section. (See Box 1)

In 1977, the EPC was merged with the FEC and reorganized as the Council for Economic

80 Taiwan’s domestic private sector also revealed a hesitancy to make new capital investments in the face of an uncertain political future. This too provided incentives for the government to adjust its strategies to promote investment.81 Chen 2001.

43

Page 44: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Planning and Development (CEPD). The CEPD became a permanent government organization

in 1985 when the Legislative Yuan approved its rules of organization. Yet although the formal

functions of the CEPD were expanded when compared to the CUSA, CIECD, or EPC, it did

not have the comparable power, resources and policy instruments of its predecessors.82 As an

advisory body to the cabinet, the CEPD was not headed by the premier or vice president but by

a minister. Nor did it have executive authority of its own; the staff advised the council and the

council advised the cabinet, where real authority was concentrated. The ministries gained more

power to formulate their own plans and implement them. Formally independent bodies were

brought under more direct political control, and subject to new political and interest group

oversight. For example, the Industrial Development and Investment Center (IDIC), the major

foreign investment promoting agency, was reintegrated into the MOEA.

However the most important political development for our purposes has to do with the

increased political clout of the private sector. With the formation of the opposition Democratic

Progressive Party (DPP) in 1986 and the lifting of Martial Law in 1987, newly formed interest

groups gained a greater degree of autonomy in articulating their interests. (See Box 2) In

particular, private sector interest came to play a much more central role in the political process.

Both the KMT and the opposition sought out business support. The KMT in particular remade

itself as a pro-business party (with attendant charges of corruption).

82 Like some of its predecessors, the CEPD was outside the ordinary machinery of government, and thus could attract higher-quality talent by paying higher salary and bypassing the usual civil service examination.

44

Page 45: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Box 2: Evolution of the Relations between Government and Private Sector

1. Formative stage (1951-60): During this period, the economy was centered around agriculture, and with the exception of public enterprises, industrial and commercial firms were small in scale. The state-owned enterprises had a monopoly or near monopoly in a large number industrial sectors including energy, public utilities, and the defense sector, but also fertilizer, sugar refining, tobacco and wine, and construction. However, government efforts contributed to the growth of private manufacturing in sectors such as textiles and apparel.

2. Growth stage (1961-73): With the shift from ISI to export-led industrialization, private industrial and commercial enterprises grew rapidly. The predominant industries were textiles, building materials, food products, hardware and plastic processing. Although the significance of state- and party-owned enterprises declined in the overall economy, they continued to control the commanding heights of most industrial sectors; privatization did not occur through sale of state assets but through the growth of the private sector. The state-sponsored industrial associations were the formal channels for communication between government officials and private sectors.

3. Retrenchment stage (1974-81): Faced with the external shocks and domestic economic difficulties, the government began to encourage mergers, increase the allowable amount of cross-investment, and allowed private firms to establish insurance companies and trust companies and thus to enter the financial sector. Business groups strengthened their structure through retrenchment, initiating mergers among some of their member companies and dissolving others. State enterprises were still the major vehicle for the development of capital-intensive sectors and new ones were formed during this period.

4. Liberalization stage (1982-): Economic recovery, coupled with economic and political liberalization, allowed private sector actors unprecedented opportunities for expansion. The private sector was increasingly incorporated into the formation of economic policy. A number of new institutional channels for policy consultation such as the Industrial Policy Advisory Board were established. The expansion of electoral politics and growing importance of the legislature also provided the domestic business elite with new opportunities to exercise influence.

Source: Fields 1990; Chu 1994

These external environmental and political changes contributed to a marked trend toward

the liberalization of the regime governing both foreign and domestic investment. At the time of

45

Page 46: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

the first oil-shock, there were debates within the government over the appropriate course for

industrial policy; some argued that state-owned enterprises should lead a push into industrial

deepening in sectors such as steel, heavy machinery and petrochemicals. The government did

in fact invest in several of these activities, but the policy emphasis quickly shifted toward

technology-intensive industries and those that were less intensive in the use of energy.83 The

CEPD devised a new incentive package to channel capital into industries such as computers,

telecommunications, and robotics. In 1976, the Investment Commission of the MOEA declared

that it would give priority to technology-intensive investments and in 1978, the Ministry of

Finance allocated NT$200 million to a program encourage foreign and domestic experts to

generate new technology-intensive businesses in Taiwan.84

Concurrently with these institutional and overall policy changes, the government also

redrafted its investment guidelines. Since it was promulgated in 1960, the Statue for

Encouragement of Investment (SEI) had served as a central policy instrument for encouraging

particular industrial activities. From 1960 through 1990, the government revised the Statute no

fewer than fifteen times; these revisions, summarized in Table 3, constitute a shorthand history

of the government’s industrial policy. In the 1960s, the SEI was revised three times to

encourage the establishment and growth of the export sector, particularly following the

termination of US aid in 1964. In the 1970s, the SEI was modified eight times to discourage

labor-intensive foreign investments and emphasize more capital- and technology-intensive

83 Democratization also brought environmental calculations to the fore. 84 Hsueh, Hsu, and Perkins 2001.

46

Page 47: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

activities. In the 1980s, the SEI was modified four times to promote industrial upgrading.85 For

example, the revision of 1981 removed most export and local-content conditions but required

industries receiving benefits under the statute to devote a certain share of revenue to R&D.86

As can be seen in Table 3, the total number of items eligible for incentives has shown a secular

upward trend. But this increase has not been uniform across sectors; the electronics industry

saw a much more dramatic increase in encouraged activities than other sectors.

Table 3:Manufactured Products Receiving Encouragement under the Statute for the

Encouragement of Investment, 1961-1990 (Unit: products)

Industry 1961 1969 1973 1979 1986 1990

Food & beverage 9 8 16 9 9 9

Lumber 2 3 2 0 0 0

Paper & printing 15 15 8 4 5 1

Rubber products 3 5 6 1 2 0

Chemical products 53 47 40 81 95 84

Non-metallic minerals 6 9 11 9 6 5

Basic metal 15 16 15 23 13 12

Machinery 13 17 16 20 57 54

Electrical machinery 14 26 18 15 52 51

Electronics 0 0 11 55 122 98

Transportation equipment 2 3 6 17 34 34

Porcelain 5 3 4 4 3 2

Textile 5 5 3 4 3 5

Construction 0 2 1 1 3 2

Film 0 0 0 0 4 4

Miscellaneous 8 17 11 11 10 9

85 Xiao 1994, 149-164.86 Gold 1986.

47

Page 48: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Total 150 176 173 259 418 370

Source: Xiao 1994, 175.

However, the SEI continued to involve extensive administration because its incentives

were based on a positive list system: a long list of specific products and components drawn up

and updated from time to time by the government. In 1991, the industry-oriented SEI was

replaced by the more functionally-oriented Statute for Upgrading Industries (SUI). The SUI

does not single out specific industries for special tax treatment, but provides tax benefits to all

industries for certain generic types of investment, such as R&D, manpower training and anti-

pollution measures.87

A parallel process of liberalization is visible in the rules governing foreign direct

investment. In 1984, Premier Yu Kuo-hua made “economic liberalization, internationalization,

and institutionalization” the three basic policy guidelines of his premiership. An important shift

in this regard came in May 1988. Prior to that time, the government had maintained a positive

list system for FDI applications. With the 1988 reform the government shifted toward a

negative list policy for FDI applications, following the trend noted in the broader statutes for

encouraging investment. The negative list was revised in 1990, 1996 and 1997, considerably

reducing the number of industries restricted to investment by foreign nationals and overseas

Chinese. Liberalization has reduced the list to less than one percent of manufacturing

categories.

87 Smith 1997.

48

Page 49: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Taiwan’s accession to the WTO provided an additional impetus to the liberalization of

foreign investment, including in both agriculture and services. A number of well-protected

service sectors were monopolized by state- and party-owned enterprises and closed not only to

foreigners but to domestic private firms as well. These restrictions were gradually lifted,

including for foreign investors; by the mid-2000s the negative list covered less than five

percent of service industries although restrictions remained in a number of important segments

including in telecommunications, power distribution and generation, airlines and television.88

The WTO also resulted in important changes in the intellectual property regime in Taiwan,

which had important implications for high-technology industries in particular.89

Open Economy Industrial Policy: Electronics and the Hsinchu Science Park

Just as the reforms of the late-1950s and 1960s found a mirror in the establishment of the

export processing zones, so the reforms of the 1980s and 1990s found reflection in the

development of new efforts to build agglomeration economies. Again, the electronics industry

can be used to provide an example of these new government-business processes.

By the early 1970s, the electronics sector had expanded dramatically, rooted primarily in

final consumer goods (most notably televisions) and semiconductor packaging. However, the

industry was still dominated by assembly and faced loss of competitiveness in the international

88 U.S. Department of State 2005. 89 . Patent and copyright laws were amended in November 2001 and the copyright law strengthened again through amendments in 2003 and 2004. An Optical Media Law of October 2001 provided the basis for clamping down on CD/DVD piracy, supported in a 2002 IPR Action Plan for 2003-2005 that expanded enforcement.

49

Page 50: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

market because of rising labor costs. Moreover, the small scale of most local firms meant they

were unlikely to achieve significant technological upgrading on their own. To overcome these

barriers, the government took a particularly direct approach: with capital provided by the

government and technology licensed from abroad, it established a demonstration factory for

semiconductor manufacturing that became an important incubator for personnel and process

engineering and even design skills. Later, the government invested capital, manpower, and

management teams to direct the establishment of some flagship companies and fostered a wave

of private investment in the electronics industry.

To help local firms to overcome the hurdles associated with conducting R&D, training,

and marketing, the government set up two institutions to assist them: the Industrial Technology

Research Institute (ITRI) and the Institute for the Information Industry (III). The ITRI was

established in 1973 and was placed under the MOEA, taking over the electronics R&D from a

telecommunications laboratory in the Ministry of Communications. ITRI was composed of

several functionally distinct institutes. The most important one was the ERSO which developed

and licensed new technologies to the private sector. ITRI and ERSO originally were entirely

funded by the state, but the private sector later became an important source of funds. By 1988,

ERSO received only about 20-25 percent of its funds from the government, with the rest

coming from the private sector in the form of fees from companies for developing products. In

contrast, ITRI remained dependent on the government for 55 percent of its financing. The

50

Page 51: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

initiative for long-term projects developed by ITRI came from the government while the

private sector generally brought short-term projects to ITRI’s labs.90

The III was established in 1979. Its major mission included introducing and developing

software, assisting government agencies and public enterprises in computerization, training and

educating information professionals, supplying market and technological information related to

the information industry, and promoting the development and use of computer-related

technologies.91 In addition to ITRI and III, the NSC was charged with designing research

strategy and plans, promoting basic research, pioneering applied agencies. It was also the

principal grantor of funds for researchers in Taiwan’s universities.92 (Figure 6)

Yet it was recognized from the outset that domestic efforts were unlikely to succeed—

either technologically or with respect to marketing and branding—in the absence of a strong

foreign presence; from the outset domestic efforts were coupled with new inducements to

foreign investment. In 1980, the National Science Council (NSC) took the decision to create

the Hsinchu Science Park. In deciding on the location, the availability of suitable manpower

and technical support were vital preconditions. The park was located near two leading

technical universities, National Tsinghua and Chiao Tung, and the state-run Industrial

90 ITRI’s budget was screened within the MOEA and approved by the Executive Yuan and the Legislative Yuan. Two other entities, the NSC and the Science and Technology Advisory Group (STAG) also exercised oversight. Meaney 1994.91 Lee and Pecht 1997, 19.92 Lee and Pecht 1997, 23.

51

Page 52: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Technology and Research Institute (ITRI) and its Electronics Research Service Organization

(ERSO) division were also moved to this area.93

Although the original idea behind the creation of the Hsinchu Science Park was a high-

technology version of an EPZ, the Park rested on a model that was actually quite different than

the standard EPZ. The government did not just use the Park to attract foreign high-technology

companies. More importantly, it tried to create an interacting cluster that included domestic

firms in order to capture the spillover from the presence of foreign high-tech firms through

training, technology transfer, and direct co-operation with local firms, including as suppliers

and subcontractors.

93 Saxenian 2001.

52

Page 53: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Figure 6Policymaking Structure in High-Technology Industrial Policy94

Note:

indicates direct supervisionindicates technological supportindicates financial supportindicates support of market & commercial information

94 Liao 1994, 127.

Executive Yuan

CEPD STAG

MOEANSC MOF

CTBIDB OST

III ITRI

ERSO

HSBIP

Public-private Ventures (UMC, TSMC) Private FirmsMNCs

53

Page 54: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

CTB: Chiao Tung BankHSBIP: Hsinchu Science-Based Industrial ParkIII: Institute for Information IndustryIDB: Industrial Development BureauOST: Office of Science and Technology

The government offered generous incentives to companies located in the Park based on a

company’s design, development, and manufacturing capabilities.95 According to the Statute for

the Science-based Industrial Park Establishment and Administration, companies established

within the Park would be offered five year tax holidays, exemptions from import duty,

commodity tax and business tax for equipment, raw materials, parts and semi-finished products

imported from abroad, and a variety of other tax incentives measures. An upper limit of a 22

percent corporate income tax would be applied, instead of the regular 35 percent applied

elsewhere, should the tax holiday expire.96 These incentives were available equally to both

domestic and foreign firms. In contrast to the earlier period, the government did not set

performance requirements with respect to local-content or exports, but the Statute required the

enrolled firms to be “science-based,” defined in terms of R&D expenditure. (See Appendix 2)

In addition to the standard economic incentives, the government also worked to build up

the capabilities of firms and the general industrial infrastructure through its R&D apparatus:

licensing foreign technologies, negotiating the licensing on behalf of Taiwanese firms, and

granting subsidies to encourage local firms to enter high technology markets.97 In particular,

95 Simon 1996.96 Saxenian 2001.97 Fuller 2002.

54

Page 55: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

the ITRI and ERSO were deeply involved in the nurturing of Taiwan’s semiconductor industry,

including providing technical support to local manufacturers and serving as the training ground

for young engineers, which facilitated the diffusion of spin-offs and start-ups. Many ERSO

personnel who had been trained in EC design were later transferred to private industry or

established their own businesses. The best examples were the establishment of the United

Microelectronics Corporation (UMC) in 1980 and Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing

Corporation (TSMC) in 1987, both of which are regarded as very successful semiconductor

companies. The government not only held the largest share in these companies, but also

“invited” some major private enterprises to take stakes in the new venture. In UMC’s case, the

government contributed 49 percent of the initial capital investment of $14 million through a

state-owned bank and forced some domestic private firms to contribute small amounts. In

TSMC’s case, the government contributed 48.3 percent of the initial capital formation of $206

million and persuaded Philips to sponsor a significant share (27.5 percent).98

In contrast to the early EPZs, the Hsinchu Science Park was not an immediate success. It

took almost 10 years to fill up the space and became a major agglomeration of PC

subcontractors.99 In 1990, 121 companies located in the Park had a total turnover of NT$65.6

billion but relatively low value-added computer products, particularly peripherals, accounted

for 56 percent of the sales revenue. However, the Park took off when integrated circuit (IC)

companies started to generate more substantial agglomeration effects. By 2004, the IC industry

98 Simon 1996, Fuller 2002, Chen 2005.99 Chen 2005.

55

Page 56: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

accounted for 70 percent of the total sales revenue of NT$1086 billion. The companies being

attracted to the Park were not only, or even mainly, foreign companies. The dominant investors

are companies founded by those from Taiwan who had gone abroad for training. The share of

foreign investments fell from 40 percent in the mid 1980s to less than 10 percent in the late

1990s. (Table 4)

56

Page 57: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Table 4Statistics of Hsinchu Science Park

YearNo. of

company

Sales Revenue(NT$ billion) Accumulative Investment

Total IC Share

(%)PC Share

(%)Total

(NT$ billion)Domestic

% Foreign %Overseas

Chinese %

1981 17 .. 0.7 .. .. ..1982 26 .. 1.2 .. .. ..1983 37 30 2.0 .. .. ..1984 44 95 3.2 .. .. ..1985 50 105 4.1 .. .. ..1986 59 170 19 70 5.7 62.0 32.7 5.31987 77 275 14 72 10.6 70.0 26.4 3.61988 94 490 14 72 15.8 68.9 24.2 6.91989 105 559 21 62 28.2 70.6 23.7 5.71990 121 656 22 56 42.7 74.7 20.7 4.61991 137 777 30 48 55.1 74.6 20.7 4.71992 140 870 37 44 62.8 75.7 19.9 4.41993 150 1,290 43 42 66.9 78.5 17.0 4.51994 165 1,778 47 40 93.5 87.1 10.3 2.71995 180 2,992 49 41 147.7 87.9 10.4 1.71996 203 3,181 49 38 258.5 87.3 11.6 1.01997 245 3,996 50 35 375.6 87.7 11.6 0.71998 272 4,550 51 35 510.6 90.1 9.4 0.51999 292 6,509 55 31 566.0 92.2 7.3 0.42000 289 9,293 62 23 694.5 95.1 3.4 1.52001 312 6,625 57 24 858.8 92.7 7.0 0.32002 334 7,054 65 18 910.0 92.3 7.5 0.22003 369 8,578 66 16 992.5 91.6 8.2 0.22004 384 10,859 68 13 1053.7 90.5 9.2 0.3

Source: Hsinchu Science Park, http://eweb.sipa.gov.tw/en/dispatch.jsp?disp_to=11

57

Page 58: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Conclusion

The effort to increase investment requires a difficult combination of credible policy and

the ability to respond flexibly to changing circumstances. Particularly for a small economy

with little track record, institutional reforms played a major role in balancing these objectives.

We argued that at least in the early period, prior to the transition to democratic rule, insulated

decision-making bodies with strong participation by foreigners played an important role in the

reform process. Institutional “investments” created sunk costs and identified the government

strongly with the new policy course while delegation of substantial authority allowed these

institutions flexibility in implementation. The authoritarian political system gave political elites

the independence to initiate a set of policy incentives to create a capital-friendly policy

environment. But authoritarian rule would have been a minus without parallel investment in

“small” institutions governing the FDI nexus.

While institutional innovation as well as incentives played a pivotal role in the first period

of economic reform in Taiwan, a somewhat more decentralized institutional structure

characterized the second period of economic reform. In the 1980s, Taiwan’s political

institutions experienced a fundamental transition as the authoritarian system gradually gave

way to democratic forces. Powerful industrial groups had a growing influence on the policy-

making process. These constraints, along with external shocks and constraints, shifted the

nature of government interventions toward a direction more consistent with an economy driven

58

Page 59: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

mainly by both market forces and the standard problems of rent-seeking. However, even

during this second period we find certain continuities in institutional form and in the effort of

the government to play a coordinating function. These efforts can be seen most clearly in the

Hsinchu Science Park and in the ongoing granting of selective incentives to particular

industries. There can be little question that Taiwan’s FDI policy has become more liberal, but it

would be misguided to see it as altogether laisser-faire, particularly in its efforts to generate

technology-intensive investments.

59

Page 60: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

References

Aw, Bee-Yan (2004), “Firm-level productivity and foreign direct investments in Taiwan,” Conference on Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Development: Lessons from the East Asian Experience, World Bank.

Chao, Wen-heng, (2000), “A Reassessment of State-led Development: the State and Economic Weaknesses in Taiwan and South Korea,” Unpublished Ph. D. Dissertation, University of Maryland.

Chen, Tain-Jy (2001), “Democratization and trade liberalization,” in Taiwan’s Economic Success since 1980, edited by Chao-Cheng Mai and Chien-Sheng Shih, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Chen, Tain-Jy (2005), “the successful factors for an industry cluster: the experience of Hsinchu Science Park,” APEC Symposium on Industrial Clustering for SMEs.

Cheng, Hang-sheng (1970), “An analytical study of the results of enforcement of the Statue for Encouragement of Investment,” Industry of Free China (June), pp. 31-44

Cheng, Tun-jen (1993), “Guarding the Commanding Heights: The State as Banker in Taiwan,” in Stephan Haggard, Chung H. Lee and Sylvia Maxfield, eds. The Politics of Finance in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Cheng, Tun-jen (2001), “Transforming Taiwan’s economic structure in the 20 th century,” The China Quarterly, 165, pp. 19-36.

Cheng, Tun-jen, Stephan Haggard, and David Kang (1998), “Institutions and growth in Korea and Taiwan: the bureaucracy,” Journal of Development Studies, 34, 6, pp. 87-111.

Chu, Yun-han (1994), “the realignment of business-government relations and regime transition in Taiwan,” in Business and Government in Industrial Asia, edited by Andrew MacIntyre, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Chung, Chi-Nien. 2001. “Markets, Culture and Institutions: the Emergence of Large Business Groups in Taiwan, 1950s-1970s,” Journal of Management Studies 38,5 (July): 719-745.

Council for Economic Planning and Development, http://www.cepd.gov.tw

60

Page 61: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Dao, S. Y. (1965), “Investment incentive and promotion measures,” Industry of Free China (May), pp. 43-50

Drumwright (no first name). (1960). “Telegram 52 from Taipei, July 27. Report on GRC economy and progress of accelerated development program.” Secret. DOS, CF 893.00/7-2760. Foreign Relations of the United States, 1958-1960. v. XIX (microfiche).

Feenstra, Robert C. and Gary G. Hamilton (2006), Emergent Economies, Divergent Paths: Economic Organization and International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Fields, Karl (1990), “Developmental Capitalism and Industrial Organization: Business Groups and the State in Korea and Taiwan,” unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, UC Berkeley.

Fuller, Douglas (2002), “Globalization for nation building: industrial policy for high-technology products in Taiwan,” the MIT Japan Program, Working Paper 02.02, http://web.mit.edu/cis/Publications/Japan_Working_Paper_9.pdf.

Gereffi, Gary and Miguel Korzeniewicz, eds. (1994), Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism. Westport CT: Greenwood Press.

Gereffi, Gary and Mei-Lin Pan (1994), “The Globalization of Taiwan’s Garment Industry,” in Edna Bonacich, et. al. Global Production: the Apparel Industry in the Pacific Rim. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

Glass, Sheppard (1963), “Some aspects of Formosa’s economic growth,” The China Quarterly, No. 15, pp. 12-34.

Gold, Thomas (1981) “Dependent Development in Taiwan,” unpublished PhD dissertation, Department of Sociology, Harvard University.

Gold, Thomas (1986), State and Society in the Taiwan Miracle, New York: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.

Haggard, Stephan (1990), Pathway from the Periphery: the Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

61

Page 62: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Haggard, Stephan, and Chien-Kuo Pang (1994), “the transition to export-led growth in Taiwan,” in The Role of the State in Taiwan’s Development, edited by Joel Aberbach, David Dollar, and Kenneth Sokoloff, New York: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.

Ho, Ming-yu (2003), “In service of growth: legal regimes, FDI and Taiwan’s economic development,” the International Institute for Asian Studies (IIAS) Newsletter 32, http://www.iias.nl/iiasn/32/RR_in_service_of_growth.pdf.

Ho, Samuel. 1982. “Economic Development and Rural Industry in Taiwan,” World Development, 10, 11: 973-990.

Hsinchu Science Park, http://eweb.sipa.gov.tw/en/dispatch.jsp?disp_to=11.

Hsueh, Li-min, Chen-kuo Hsu, and Dwight Perkins (2001), Industrialization and the State: the Changing Role of the Taiwan Government in the Economy, 1945-1998, Harvard Studies in International Development.

Industrial Development & Investment Center (2005), The Investment Environment of the ROC on Taiwan, Taiwan: Ministry of Economic Affairs (MOEA).

Jacoby, Neil (1966), U.S. Aid to Taiwan: a Study of Foreign Aid, Self-Help, and Development, New York: Praeger Publishers.

Kuo Cheng-tian (1995), Global competitiveness and industrial growth in Taiwan and the Philippines, Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

Kuo, Shirley, Gustav Ranis, and John Fei (1979), The Taiwan Success Story: Rapid Growth with Improved Distribution in the Republic of China, 1952-1979, Boulder: Westview Press.

Lam, Danny Kin-kong (1992), “Explaining Economic Development: a Case Study of State Policies towards the Computer and Electronics Industry in Taiwan (1960-1990),” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Carleton University.

Lee, Chung-shing and Michael Pecht (1997), The Taiwan Electronics Industry, New York: CRC Press

Lewis, Reese Phillip (1993), “The Origin of Taiwan’s Trade and Industrial Policies,” unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbia University.

62

Page 63: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Levy, Brian. 1991. “Transactions Costs, the Size of Firms and Industrial Policy: Lessons from a Comparative Study of the Footwear Industry in Korea and Taiwan,” Journal of Development Economics 34: 151-178.

Li, K.T. (1976), The Experience of Dynamic Economic Growth on Taiwan, New York: Mei Ya Publications, Inc.

Li, K.T. (1988), The Evolution of Policy behind Taiwan’s Development Success, New Haven: Yale University Press.

Lin, Ching-Yuan (1973), Industrialization in Taiwan, 1946-72: Trade and Import-Substitution Policies for Developing Countries, New York: Praeger Publishers.

Lin, Steven A.Y. (2002), “Roles of foreign direct investments in Taiwan’s economic growth,” in Taiwan in the Global Economy: From an Agrarian Economy to an Exporter of High-Tech Products, edited by Peter C. Y. Chow, New York: Praeger Publishers.

Liao, Kun-Jung (1994), “High Technology Development and the State: the Case of Taiwan,” unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Kentucky.

Meaney, Constance S. (1994), “State policy and the development of Taiwan’s semiconductor industry,” in The Role of the State in Taiwan’s Development, edited by Joel Aberbach, David Dollar, and Kenneth Sokoloff, New York: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.

Ministry of Economic Affairs, Economic Statistics Annual: Taiwan Area, the Republic of China, various years.

Myers, Ramon (1990), “The economic development of the Republic of China on Taiwan, 1965-1981,” in Models of Development: a Comparative Study of Economic Growth in South Korea and Taiwan, edited by Lawrence Lau, An International Center for Economic Growth Publication, San Francisco.

Overseas Chinese and Foreign Investment Commission (1972), “An introduction to the overseas Chinese & Foreign Investment Commission,” Industry of Free China (January), pp. 21-38.

Pang, Chien-kuo (1988), “The State and Economic Transformation: the Taiwan Case,” unpublished PhD dissertation, Department of Sociology, Brown University.

63

Page 64: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Rodrik, Dani (1995), “Getting interventions right: how South Korea and Taiwan grew rich,” Economic Policy, Vol. 10, No. 20, pp. 53-107.

Saxenian, AnnaLee (2001), “Taiwan’s Hsinchu Region: Imitator and Partner for Silicon Valley,” Stanford University, Stanford Institute for Policy Research, working paper, No.00-44.

Schive, Chi (1990), The Foreign Factor: the Multinational Corporation’s Contribution to the Economic Modernization of the Republic of China, Stanford: Hoover Institution Press.

Scott, Maurice (1979), “Foreign trade,” in Economic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan: the Postwar Experience of the Republic of China, edited by Walter Galenson, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Simon, Dennis Fred (1980), “Taiwan, Technology Transfer, and Transnationalism: the Political Management of Dependency,” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, UC Berkeley.

Simon, Denis Fred (1996), “Charting Taiwan’s technological future: the impact of globalization and regionalization,” The China Quarterly, No. 148, pp. 1196-1223.

Smith, Heather (1997), “Taiwan’s industrial policy in the 1980s: an appraisal,” Asian Economic Journal, 11, 1, pp. 1-33.

Tien, Hung-mao, and Tun-jen Cheng (1997), “Crafting democratic institutions in Taiwan,” China Journal, No. 37, pp. 1-27.

U.S. Department of State (2005), “2005 Investment Climate Statement: Taiwan,” http://www.state.gov/e/eb/ifd/2005/42132.htm.

Wade, Robert (1990), Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Wu, Yongping (2005), A Political Explanation of Economic Growth: State Survival, Bureaucratic Politics, and Private Enterprises in the Making of Taiwan’s Economy, 1950-1985, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Xiao Fengxiong (1994), Taiwan’s Experience: the Industrial Policy and Industrial Development (Taiwan de jing yan: wo guo chan ye zheng ce yu chan ye fa zhan), Taipei: Council for Economic Planning and Development.

64

Page 65: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Yager, Joseph (1988), Transforming Agriculture in Taiwan: the Experience of the Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

65

Page 66: Institutional Innovation and Private Investment in …siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEXPCOMNET/Resources/... · Web viewStephan Haggard and Yu Zheng Taiwan’s strong economic performance

Appendix 1:Conditions for Investment in Hsinchu Science Park

Investment Requirements Minimum Capital Suitable Industries Incentives1. Engaged in high-tech

industrial product development.

2. Investment plan must conform to the Taiwan’s industrial development and must include training for additional domestic scientific and technical personnel.

3. At least a certain percentage of operating revenue is committed to R&D.

4. Possesses significant research instruments and equipment; does not create pollution.

Must be a limited liability company established in accordance with the Company Act with minimum capital of NT$1 million.

1. Integrated circuits2. Computers and

peripheral equipment 3. Communications 4. Optoelectronics 5. Precision machinery6. Biotechnology, etc.

1. Tax incentives (i.e., five-year tax holiday, investment tax credit)

2. Government participation in investment

3. Exchange of technology for equity

4. Low-interest loans5. R&D incentives6. Relevant incentive

measures provided in the Statute for Upgrading Industries.

Source: Industrial Development & Investment Center 2005, 38

66