Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their...

42
D/2013/6482/06 Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the financing of European new technolog-based firms ANDY HEUGHEBAERT TOM VANACKER SOPHIE MANIGART Date: June 2013 September 2012 Number: 3

Transcript of Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their...

Page 1: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

D/2013/6482/06

Institutional

frameworks, venture

capital and the

financing of

European new

technolog-based

firms

ANDY HEUGHEBAERT

TOM VANACKER

SOPHIE MANIGART

Date: June 2013

September 2012

2012/09

Number: 3

Page 2: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

2

INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORKS, VENTURE CAPITAL AND THE FINANCING OF

EUROPEAN NEW TECHNOLOGY-BASED FIRMS*

ANDY HEUGHEBAERT

Ghent University

TOM VANACKER

Ghent University

SOPHIE MANIGART

Vlerick Business School and Ghent University

Contact:

Sopie Manigart – Vlerick Business School – Reep 1 – 9000 Gent – e-mail: [email protected]

Page 3: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

3

ABSTRACT

Manuscript Type: Empirical

Research Question/Issue: We first study how cross-country differences in legal quality and personal

bankruptcy laws affect the financing of New Technology-Based Firms (NTBFs). Second, we study how

venture capital (VC) investors, as expert monitors and initiators of good governance practices in their

portfolio firms, moderate abovementioned relationships.

Research Findings/Insights: Using a unique longitudinal dataset comprising 6,813 NTBFs from six

European countries, we find that higher quality legal systems increase the use of outside financing.

Less forgiving personal bankruptcy laws decrease the use of outside financing. More importantly, VC

ownership strengthens the abovementioned relationships.

Theoretical/Academic Implications: This paper provides new evidence on the link between national

legal systems and the financing of NTBFs. More significantly, we address recent calls for more

research that integrates institutional and agency frameworks. Specifically, this paper shows that the

financing of NTBFs is the outcome of both national institutional frameworks and firm-level corporate

governance.

Practitioner/Policy Implications: NTBFs play a key role in employment and wealth generation in our

modern knowledge-based economies. Yet, access to sufficient and adequate financing is a critical

barrier in the development of these firms. This study informs policy makers on the role of national

institutions, firm-level corporate governance and their interaction on the financing strategies of

NTBFs.

Keywords: Corporate Governance, Financing, Legal Quality, Personal Bankruptcy Laws, Venture

Capital

Page 4: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

4

INTRODUCTION

A rich literature shows how the institutional framework of the country in which firms are

incorporated impacts their financing. Seminal work on law and finance, for instance, has shown that

countries with higher quality legal systems have larger and more developed equity and debt markets

(Armour & Cumming, 2006; Djankov, McLiesh, & Shleifer, 2007; Groh, von Liechtenstein, & Lieser,

2010; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny 1997). Higher quality legal systems increase the

supply of financing towards firms because they decrease the costs of investors to monitor

entrepreneurs and curb the scope for entrepreneurs to maximize private benefits (Cumming,

Schmidt, & Walz, 2010). A largely separate stream of research has focused on how firm-level

corporate governance systems relate to firms’ financing strategies. Agency theorists in particular

have, for example, focused on the role of large (and often public) shareholders as governance factors

that may reduce agency problems (Brush, Bromiley, & Hendrickx, 2000; Demsetz & Lehn, 1985;

Shleifer & Vishny, 1986), which influence firms’ financing strategies (Jensen & Meckling, 1976).

More recently, multiple scholars have called for an integration of the above research streams

because country-level institutional frameworks and firm-level corporate governance mechanisms

may operate as interdependent systems in controlling agency problems (Aguilera, Filatotchev,

Gospel, & Jackson, 2008; Strange, Filatotchev, Wright, & Buck, 2009). Several recent studies on Initial

Public Offerings (IPOs) have indeed demonstrated that the effectiveness of corporate governance

systems at the firm level is likely to differ significantly from country to country (Bruton, Filatotchev,

Chahine, & Wright, 2010; Chahine & Saade, 2011).

Most studies investigating the role of country-level institutional frameworks or corporate

governance systems on firms’ financing strategies focus on public firms. Nevertheless, it is generally

acknowledged that New Technology-Based Firms (NTBFs) contribute significantly to the development

of our modern knowledge-based economies in terms of exports, employment, innovations and the

like (e.g., Colombo & Grilli, 2005; Knockaert, Ucbasaran, Wright, & Clarysse, 2011; Storey & Tether,

1998). Due to high information asymmetries and agency problems, these firms face considerable

difficulties in raising sufficient outside financing (Berger & Udell, 1998). It is hence surprising that to

date, scholars have primarily focused on the independent effects of either country-level institutional

frameworks or firm-level corporate governance systems as mechanisms which may ease information

asymmetry and agency problems and as such facilitate access to outside financing for NTBFs. The

goal of the present paper is to integrate a country-level institutional perspective and a firm-level

agency perspective to explain financing strategies in NTBFs. More specifically, we ask the following

research questions: (a) how do cross-country differences in legal quality and personal bankruptcy

Page 5: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

5

laws influence financing strategies of NTBFs and (b) how does venture capital (VC) ownership as a

mitigating factor of agency risk influence these relationships?

We focus on VC ownership as an important firm-level governance mechanism in NTBFs

because VC investors are frequently described as initiators of good governance mechanisms in their

portfolio firms (Bottazzi, Da Rin, & Hellmann, 2008; Knockaert, Lockett, Clarysse, & Wright, 2006;

Lerner, 1995; Sapienza, Manigart, & Vermeir, 1996; Van den Berghe & Levrau, 2004). They are

typically more actively involved than non-management shareholders in public firms, including

institutional shareholders (Wright & Robbie, 1998), thereby actively monitoring entrepreneurs and

decreasing agency risks (Gompers, 1995). Furthermore, VC investors are often one of the most

important shareholders in NTBFs, ranked second behind entrepreneurs themselves (George,

Wiklund, & Zahra, 2005).

To address the research questions, we take advantage of a unique longitudinal database

comprising a sample of 6,813 NTBFs from six European countries (Belgium, Finland, France, Italy,

Spain and U.K.), of which 606 firms have VC investors as shareholders. While the countries in our

sample are geographically close to each other, they are characterized by significant differences in

institutional frameworks (Bruton et al., 2010). Furthermore, focusing on a more homogenous sample

of developed European countries helps to minimize unobserved heterogeneity among countries

(Armour & Cumming, 2006).

The contributions of our study are two-fold. First, this paper expands on previous research

that studied how cross-country differences in legal systems influence the financing strategies of

firms. Prior work has largely focused on the relationship between creditor or shareholder rights and

financing decisions in public firms (e.g., Acharya, Amihud, & Litov, 2011; Roberts & Sufi, 2009; Seifert

& Gonenc, 2012). This is unfortunate because the vast majority of firms never reach the stage where

they become public (Berger & Udell, 1998) and extant research has shown how financing decisions

are very different in public versus private firms (Brav, 2009). Moreover, given our focus on private

NTBFs, we focus on an important but often overlooked aspect of law, namely personal bankruptcy

laws, and study their impact on the financing of entrepreneurial firms. Although these laws have

been argued to be particularly relevant for influencing entrepreneurial activity (Armour & Cumming,

2008), we know little about their role in NTBFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and Cumming

(2006) show that more forgiving bankruptcy laws stimulate the development of VC markets at the

country level, they also call for more research that captures the firm-level effects of these laws. We

contribute to this call with the current study and show how personal bankruptcy laws influence the

financing strategies of NTBFs. Finally, previous research has studied how differences in the quality of

legal systems affect the financing behavior of VC investors (Cumming et al., 2010; Bottazzi, Da Rin, &

Hellmann, 2009, Lerner & Schoar, 2005). For this purpose, prior research has exclusively focused on

Page 6: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

6

VC-backed firms and the financing provided by VC investors, which raises important selection

problems (Cosh, Cumming, & Hughes, 2009; Cumming et al., 2010). We address this shortcoming in

the literature by studying the role of the quality of legal systems on the financing strategies of both

VC-backed and non-VC-backed firms.

A second major contribution of the present research is its contribution to a further

integration of institutional theory and agency theory (Filatotchev & Boyd, 2009). On the one hand,

studies drawing on institutional theory focus on those institutions which shape “the rules of the

game in a society” (North, 1990, p. 3) but largely ignore the impact of firm-level corporate

governance systems. In these studies, entrepreneurs are more or less passive, and may be

advantaged or disadvantaged based on the country from which they operate. On the other hand,

studies drawing on agency theory focus on how corporate governance mechanisms at the firm level

affect firm development but typically ignore the impact of different institutional frameworks. In

these studies, entrepreneurs are often assumed to operate within an institutional vacuum. Multiple

scholars have called for an integration of both perspectives, because our understanding of the

effectiveness of governance systems would benefit from viewing these systems as operating as a

bundle of interdependent systems (Aguilera et al., 2008; Filatotchev & Boyd, 2009). Nevertheless,

our understanding of the nature of these interdependencies is limited. This study is one of the first

that provides large sample evidence of the combined effect of national legal systems and firm-level

governance factors, such as VC ownership, on the financing of NTBFs. We argue and show that the

financing strategy of NTBFs is the complex outcome of both national legal systems and firm-level

corporate governance factors.

The rest of this article is organized as follows. In the following section, we provide the

theoretical background of this paper. Then, we develop specific hypotheses. Thereafter, we discuss

the method, including the sample, variables and econometric approach used. Next, we present the

main research findings. Finally, we conclude by discussing our results from both a theoretical and

practical perspective.

Page 7: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

7

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

Much of corporate governance research is concerned with the mechanisms that mitigate

agency problems (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). When NTBFs raise outside equity financing, two related

types of agency problems may emerge (Gompers, 1995). First, entrepreneurs may invest in projects

that have high personal returns but low expected monetary payoffs to outside shareholders. When

entrepreneurs have raised outside equity financing, they still receive all of the benefits related to the

consumption of perquisites but no longer bear all of the costs. Second, entrepreneurs who possess

private information may choose to continue investing in value destroying projects. Entrepreneurs, for

instance, may want to undertake inefficient continuation of their firms because they provide them

significant private benefits including independence. Additional agency problems may emerge when

firms raise outside debt financing (Myers, 1977). For instance, entrepreneurs may sell assets to pay

themselves dividends thereby leaving less value to debtors in case of bankruptcy; they may take

excessive risks of which the costs are primarily borne by debtors; or they may reject value creating

projects in which the proceeds would accrue primarily to debtors. Not surprisingly, such agency

problems make the financing of NTBFs a process fraught with difficulties (Cassar, 2004; Heyman,

Deloof, & Ooghe, 2008; Gompers, 1995).

To date, two largely separate streams of work have focused on the factors which may

mitigate agency problems when NTBFs raise outside financing. First, since the seminal work by La

Porta and colleagues (1997), a significant body of research has argued and shown that national laws

affect the costs and benefits of investors related to monitoring entrepreneurs and as such influence

the supply of outside sources of financing. Specifically, the costs associated with monitoring

entrepreneurs is lower in higher quality legal systems, which reduces the scope for entrepreneurs to

maximize private benefits (Cumming et al., 2010). This explains why both equity (including VC)

markets and debt markets are larger and more developed in countries with higher quality legal

systems (Armour & Cumming, 2006; Djankov et al., 2007; Groh et al., 2010; La Porta et al., 1997)

thereby increasing the supply of debt and equity financing.

Second, agency theorists have long considered the monitoring role of large outside

shareholders as a governance mechanism that may reduce specific agency problems (Brush et al.,

2000; Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Shleifer & Vishny, 1986). In NTBFs, VC investors are often one of the

most important owners next to entrepreneurs themselves (George et al., 2005). Unlike other

institutional investors, such as pension funds, insurance firms and banks, VC investors are more

active and act more like reference shareholders (Van den Berghe & Levrau, 2004). VC investors

engage in extensive monitoring of their portfolio firms through shareholders agreements,

Page 8: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

8

differentiated shareholders rights, board membership and intense relationships with management.

Besides monitoring, VC investors also provide value adding services, including the professionalization

of their portfolio firms (Hellmann & Puri, 2002; Sapienza et al., 1996). Finally, VC investors may signal

firm quality to other prospective investors, thereby making these investors more likely to contribute

financing (Janney & Folta, 2003).

Despite the value of these two separate streams of research, scholars increasingly argue that

the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms, including block ownership by VC investors,

differs significantly from country to country (Bruton et al., 2010; Chahine & Saade, 2012;

Dharwadkar, George, & Brandes, 2000; Douma, George, & Kabir, 2006; Hoskisson, Cannella, Tihanyi,

& Faraci, 2004). However, to date, we have only limited knowledge on how country-level and firm-

level corporate governance systems operate together and influence the financing strategies of

NTBFs. Indeed, ambiguous results in the corporate governance literature (e.g., Dalton, Daily, Certo, &

Roengpitya, 2003) have often been attributed to the lack of attention towards multiple governance

mechanisms which may interact with each other (Aguilera et al., 2008). Hence, Filatotchev and Boyd

(2009) state that “although the vast majority of previous corporate governance studies are

predominantly focused on organizational aspects in a single-country setting, future research should

also focus on national systems or corporate governance and their interactions with firm-level

governance factors” (p. 263).

A major question is whether national and firm-level systems act as substitutes or

complements. In a substitution framework, national governance mechanisms and firm-level

corporate governance mechanisms may substitute for one another (Dalton et al., 2003). Klapper and

Love (2004), for instance, show that firms can (partially) compensate for ineffective laws and

enforcement at the country level by establishing good corporate governance at the firm level. In

contrast, others suggest that country-level and firm-level governance mechanisms operate in a

complementary manner (Aguilera et al., 2008). Specifically, higher quality national laws and firm-

level corporate governance mechanisms may mutually enhance each other such that their combined

presence increases their effectiveness. Chahine and Saade (2012), for instance, confirm the existence

of a complementary relationship between the level of shareholder protection at the country level

and board independence at the firm level in reducing IPO underpricing.

In what follows, we first develop hypotheses on the relationship between country-level

institutional systems, focusing on the quality of a country’s legal system and on personal bankruptcy

laws, and the financing of NTBFs. Next, we discuss how VC investors may moderate abovementioned

relationships.

Page 9: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

9

HYPOTHESES

National Legal Systems and the Financing of NTBFs

As higher quality legal systems allow for more transparency and possibilities to enforce

contracts and thereby reduce the agency costs for outside investors associated with investing in

firms, higher quality legal systems lead to larger and more developed equity and debt markets (La

Porta et al., 1997). Much research in the law and finance tradition, however, has focused on the

development of public equity and debt markets which are only accessible for large and mature firms

(e.g., La Porta et al., 1997), and thereby ignoring those financial markets which are accessible for

NTBFs, such as the VC market.

Recently, Groh and colleagues (2010) showed that VC and private equity investment activity

is positively related to a country’s investor protection in Europe. Higher quality legal systems may

also be relevant for private debt investors. Djankov and colleagues (2007) investigate cross-country

determinants of private credit, using data on private and public credit registries. Their results suggest

that both creditor protection through the legal system and information-sharing institutions are

associated with higher ratios of private credit to gross domestic product. Higher quality legal

frameworks and corporate governance at the country level are hence expected to increase the

supply of outside financing, including outside equity and debt, to NTBFs.

Higher quality legal systems are not only likely to increase the supply of outside financing,

but may also stimulate the demand for outside financing. First, private equity transactions in

countries with higher quality legal systems have higher valuations (Lerner & Schoar, 2005). This

implies that for a given investment, entrepreneurs can retain a larger equity stake, which is

important because this determines their future financial return and their control over the firm.

Hence, VC will be more attractive for entrepreneurs operating in countries with higher quality legal

systems and higher ensuing valuations. Second, the search costs for entrepreneurs are lower in

countries with higher quality legal systems, as investors are likely to provide financing more quickly

(Cumming et al., 2010). Many NTBFs require significant amounts of outside financing to fund their

founding and subsequent development (Cosh et al., 2009; Robb & Robinson, 2012; Vanacker &

Manigart, 2010). The lower cost of outside financing combined with an increased supply of outside

financing in countries with higher quality legal systems may stimulate entrepreneurs to demand

more outside financing. Therefore,

Page 10: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

10

Hypothesis 1: Higher quality legal systems will be associated with the use of more outside

financing (including outside equity and debt) in NTBFs.

Prior academic research has related entrepreneurship to personal bankruptcy laws (Armour

& Cumming, 2008). Personal bankruptcy laws are widely regarded as having a direct influence on

entrepreneurs even when entrepreneurs are seeking to incorporate their firms as limited liability

firms. First, prior to incorporation entrepreneurs typically use their own sources of financing first

before raising outside financing (Berger & Udell, 1998). Second, creditors frequently demand

personal guarantees from entrepreneurs, which is tantamount to “contracting out” the liability shield

incorporation provides to entrepreneurs (Armour & Cumming, 2008). Hence, national personal

bankruptcy laws significantly influence the strategies of entrepreneurs. Countries with more forgiving

personal bankruptcy laws, reflected in the ability of bankrupt entrepreneurs to obtain a fresh start

(i.e., a discharge from pre-bankruptcy indebtedness) have larger VC markets (Armour & Cumming,

2008). Aggregate data on the development of VC markets as a whole, however, do not capture the

details of how individual entrepreneurs adjust their financing strategies in response to different

bankruptcy laws. Two opposing forces might be at work. On the one hand, outside investors may be

more willing to provide financing to entrepreneurial firms when bankruptcy laws are less forgiving, as

these enable investors to recuperate a larger fraction of their investment. On the other hand,

entrepreneurs may limit their demand for outside financing as a result of less forgiving bankruptcy

laws because these laws increase entrepreneurs’ personal risk when their firms go bankrupt.

We argue that demand-side arguments dominate, as there is significant evidence that

entrepreneurs have a strong influence on the financing policies of their firms. Eckhardt, Shane, and

Delmar (2006), for instance, show how outside investors can only invest in those firms where

entrepreneurs are willing to raise outside financing. Many entrepreneurs are reluctant to raise

outside financing because outside investors may limit the independence of entrepreneurs or may

even push their firms into bankruptcy under certain conditions (Manigart & Struyf, 1997; Sapienza,

Korsgaard, & Forbes, 2003). For instance, although banks do not intervene in the day-to-day

operations and strategic planning of firms, when firms are unable to fulfill fixed debt-related

payments (i.e., interest and principle amount) banks can push firms into bankruptcy (Balcaen,

Manigart, Ooghe, & Buyze, 2013). Equity investors such as VC investors limit the independence of

entrepreneurs through their active involvement, although they may also help entrepreneurs to

realize more than what would be possible when they go it alone. Further, outside shareholders have

a portfolio perspective and may decide to de-commit themselves from a portfolio firm when other

investments in their portfolio are expected to create more value. This may lead to bankruptcy

Page 11: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

11

(Cumming & Dai, 2012; Dimov & De Clercq, 2006), even if the focal firm would still be viable for the

entrepreneur. The above is especially problematic for entrepreneurs operating in countries with less

forgiving bankruptcy laws. For example, while in some countries entrepreneurs are discharged from

their firm’s liabilities after bankruptcy, in other countries they may be held personally liable for all

remaining liabilities for a number of years or even indefinitely (Armour & Cumming, 2008). The fact

that personal discharge is not available strongly increases the personal risk of entrepreneurs and

limits them to obtain a fresh start and become independent entrepreneurs in the future after having

experienced a bankruptcy. Hence, entrepreneurs will be less likely to seek outside equity or debt

financing for their NTBFs in countries with less forgiving bankruptcy laws.

Overall, although outside investors may be more willing to provide financing to

entrepreneurial firms when bankruptcy laws are less forgiving, we expect that entrepreneurial

motives will dominate. Specifically, entrepreneurs operating in countries with less forgiving

bankruptcy laws will be less likely to seek outside sources of financing. Thus,

Hypothesis 2: Less forgiving bankruptcy laws will be associated with the use of less outside

financing (including outside equity and debt) in NTBFs.

VENTURE CAPITAL AND THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NATIONAL LEGAL SYSTEMS

AND THE FINANCING OF NTBFS

We argued that higher quality and more forgiving legal systems will be associated with the

use of more outside financing. So far, however, we have ignored how firm-level governance systems

may influence the relationship between national legal systems and the use of outside financing. One

particular firm-level corporate governance system on which we focus in this study is VC ownership.

VC investors play a particularly important role in NTBFs not only because they are expert monitors,

but also because they influence the governance systems in their portfolio firms (Gompers, 1995;

Sapienza et al., 1996; Van den Berghe & Levrau, 2004). VCs are, for example, instrumental in

expanding the management teams of their portfolio firms with key employees (Jain & Kini, 1999),

replace them with more professional managers (Hellmann, 1998; Gorman & Sahlman, 1989;

Sahlman, 1990; Barry, Muscarella, & Peavy, 1990) and install more independent directors (Williams,

Duncan, & Ginter, 2006; Suchard, 2009) that reduce the agency risks related to entrepreneurs’

opportunism (Hellmann, 1998). We hence argue that VC ownership will influence the relationship

between the quality of national legal systems and the use of outside financing in a number of ways.

Page 12: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

12

Several arguments may be advanced to suggest that VC ownership substitutes for the quality

of legal systems at the country level. First, VC investors are known to write extensive contracts which

govern the relationship between entrepreneurs and outside shareholders (Kaplan & Strömberg,

2004). These contracts can cover gaps in national legal frameworks (Abdi & Aulakh, 2012) as VC

investors often have the flexibility to adopt or decline specific provisions which affect the level of

legal protection (Chahine & Saade, 2011; Klapper & Love, 2004). Specifically, the capacity of

contracting to establish the obligations (typically of entrepreneurs) and privileges (typically of VC

investors) in different aspects of the investment relationship can remedy for the absence of high

quality national laws. Consequently, VC-backed firms in countries with weak investor protection may

still be able to raise significant amounts of outside financing despite weak governance frameworks at

the country level.

Second, termination rights and contractual hostages are two mechanisms which may further

reduce the dependence on national legal frameworks (Abdi & Aulakh, 2012). Termination rights

entail that VC investors can unilaterally decide to stop providing further (financial) support to their

portfolio firms. VC investors typically do not provide all financing at once, but rather engage in staged

financing, which allows them to limit their losses when specific portfolio firms to not perform

according to expectations (Gompers, 1995). When inside VC investors decide not to provide

additional financing this often has far reaching consequences, as outside investors will interpret this

as a negative signal of firm quality, thereby limiting a firm’s ability to raise additional financing from

new financing sources. Contractual hostages entail that VC investors are often endowed with rights

to block particular decisions. Such hostages further relieve the dependence on legal frameworks,

since opportunistic behavior can be blocked directly with limited reliance on national legal systems

(Abdi & Aulakh, 2012). Thus,

Hypothesis 3A: VC ownership will decrease the positive relationship between higher quality

legal systems and the use of more outside financing in NTBFs (substitutive relationship).

A different stream of reasoning challenges the above claims and argues for a complementary

relationship between the quality of national legal systems and VC ownership. Inadequacies in the

legal enforcement of contracts entail that contractual provisions have a restricted capacity to cover

for gaps in national legal systems (Abdi & Aulakh, 2012). Contractual governance used by investors to

reduce agency problems is hence only valuable when investors have access to an effective national

legal system. Another reason why contractual provisions may be insufficient to cover for gaps in legal

systems is the incomplete nature of contracts themselves. Specifically, under high uncertainty, the

Page 13: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

13

parties involved in a contract are not able to include all contingencies (Hart, 1995). This explains why

the quality of national legal systems is expected to remain important even when investors are able to

write extensive contracts. The above entails that VC investors may be more effective in reducing

agency problems through contractual monitoring when they operate in countries with high quality

legal systems, which should benefit the likelihood that they will provide additional financial support

towards their portfolio firms in these countries. The additional financial resources provided by VC

investors may furthermore provide a positive signal to other prospective investors thereby increasing

their likelihood of contributing new financial resources as well (Janney & Folta, 2003). This leads to

the following alternative hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3B: VC ownership will increase the positive relationship between higher quality

legal systems and the use of more outside financing in NTBFs (complementary relationship).

We previously argued that less forgiving bankruptcy laws will be associated with the use of

less outside financing in entrepreneurial firms. VC investors, however, are expected to influence the

relationship between personal bankruptcy laws and the use of outside financing. Specifically, when

VC investors are present, we expect that entrepreneurial firms will use even less outside financing in

countries with less forgiving bankruptcy laws. Entrepreneurs typically invest a significant part of their

personal wealth in their own firms (Berger & Udell, 1998). Consequently, the wealth of

entrepreneurs is often linked to the outcome of one particular firm. Entrepreneurs will hence avoid

their firms going bankrupt with all means possible and may even prefer their firms to continue

although this is inefficient from an economic point of view. For VC investors, however, a specific

entrepreneurial firm is only one of their investment projects. VC investors are hence less affected

when one of their portfolio firms goes bankrupt. Indeed, VC investors typically get most of their

returns from only one or a few successful exits from their larger portfolio in which most investments

eventually turn out to be outright failures (Sahlman, 1990). When firms raise additional financing

from increasingly broader pool of equity investors, this may decrease the commitment by any

investor, thereby increasing the risk of bankruptcy (Dimov & De Clercq, 2006).

As VC investors are less concerned with the failure of one specific portfolio firm,

entrepreneurs who raised VC financing in the past might become extremely wary to raise additional

outside financing. For these firms, raising additional equity financing typically implies increasing the

size of the VC syndicate and hence reducing VC investors’ commitment, thereby increasing the risk of

bankruptcy (Dimov & De Clercq, 2006). This is especially detrimental for entrepreneurs in a context

where entrepreneurs are confronted with less forgiving personal bankruptcy laws. Moreover, all else

equal, the more outside financing is raised from outside investors the higher will be their power to

Page 14: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

14

push firms towards bankruptcy when (financial) problems emerge. While VC investors, for instance,

are known to support their portfolio firms, it is also well-established that they eventually focus most

of their attention towards those firms with the highest prospects and de-commit from portfolio firms

with poor prospects (Puri & Zarutskie, 2012). This may make entrepreneurs who previously raised VC

financing particularly wary to raise additional outside financing in countries with less forgiving

bankruptcy laws. Thus,

Hypothesis 4: VC ownership will increase the negative relationship between less forgiving

bankruptcy laws and the use of less outside financing in NTBFs.

METHOD

Sample and Data Sources

In order to test the hypotheses, a unique, hand-collected longitudinal dataset of 6,813 NTBFs from

six European countries (Belgium, Finland, France, Italy, Spain and the U.K.) is used1. NTBFs that

received VC financing were identified from several public data sources including press clippings, VC

websites, commercial databases (VentureXpert, Zephyr, country-specific databases). VC-backed

NTBFs were included if they satisfied four criteria at the time of their initial VC investment. First, the

initial VC investment occurred between 1994 and 2004. Initial VC investments were divided between

the pre-bubble, the bubble and the post-bubble investment period as VC investment strategies have

proven to be significantly different in each period (Gompers & Lerner, 2001) and to mitigate as such

potential biases due to the selection of VC-backed firms in only one single investment period.

Second, at the time of the initial VC investment all firms were maximum ten years old. This ensures

we study young firms that raised VC financing, rather than mature firms that raised buy-out financing

or other types of private equity financing. Third, firms were active in high-tech industries which were

identified from the NACE Rev2 classification system. The NACE Rev2 sectors were reclassified into

more aggregate sectors following the transformation guidelines provided by the European Venture

Capital and Private Equity Association (EVCA): Life Sciences (Biotech and Pharmaceutical),

Communication (Telecom), ICT (ICT Manufacturing), Internet Related (Internet and Web Publishing),

Software and Other (including Aerospace, Energy, Nanotech, Other R&D and Robotics). Fourth, firms

1 Data were gathered through the European VICO project, which is described in detail by Bertoni and Pellón

(2011). Germany is excluded from our study because almost no relevant accounting data, needed for the purpose of this study, is available on German firms.

Page 15: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

15

were independent at first investment, which implies they were not controlled (< 50 percent) by a

third party.

After the identification of the VC-backed NTBFs, a control group was randomly selected from

the population of NTBFs that did not receive VC funding, using similar criteria with respect to country

of origin, founding period (age), high-tech industries and independence as described above. The

population of NTBFs was derived from the country-specific economy-wide databases or Amadeus

(Bureau van Dijk). For each VC-backed firm, ten non-VC backed firms were selected. The ten-to-one

ratio reflects the importance of VC financing for NTBFs (Bottazzi & da Rin, 2002; Puri & Zarutskie,

2012). It was additionally checked whether firms in the control group had never received VC in any

form.

For each firm, yearly financial statement and employment data was collected through the

Amadeus database or an equivalent country specific database from the year the firms entered the

database until 2007 or until the firms disappeared (either through bankruptcy or through

acquisition). This procedure entails that we limit survival bias because our database also includes

firms which eventually fail. Further, yearly non-financial data such as the number of patent

applications (Patstat database) or important events that occurred during the period of analysis such

as Initial Public Offerings and Mergers and Acquisitions were registered. As our study focuses on the

financing strategies of private firms, 297 firm-year observations were excluded for reason that the

NTBFs transformed from private into public firms which is likely to have a significant impact on

financing strategies (Brav, 2009). Pre-IPO years, however, were kept in the database. Finally, 398

firm-year observations were excluded because of missing data. This results in a final sample of 6,813

NTBFs of which 606 raised VC, and 50,135 firm-year observations of which 3,734 from VC-backed

firms.

Insert Table 1 about here

Table 1 provides a description of the sample by breaking down the number of firm by

country, foundation period and sector. Nearly 25 percent of the firms in the sample are French,

closely followed by the U.K. (23 percent). Italian firms represent 15 percent of the sample, Belgian

and Spanish firms each 13 percent and Finnish firms 11 percent. Nearly 37 percent of all firms were

founded between 2000 and 2004, 31 percent between 1995 and 1999, 18 percent between 1990 and

1994 and 14 percent between 1984 and 1989. Most firms operate in the software industry (45

percent), followed by ICT (17 percent), internet (12 percent), life sciences (9 percent) and

Page 16: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

16

communication (5 percent). The other industries represent the remaining 12 percent. Obviously, VC-

backed NTBFs and the random sample of non-VC-backed NTBF will not perfectly match with each

other since entrepreneurs select their firms as candidates for receiving VC financing and VC investors

select firms in which they want to invest based on observable and unobservable firm characteristics

(Eckhardt, Shane, & Delmar, 2006). We control for such selection issues in our econometric models

(see more details below).

Dependent Variables

The dependent variables of interest in this study include measures of incremental financing

events and capital structure. Book values retrieved from balance sheets are used to calculate

different measures as market variables are unavailable for private firms (Brav, 2009). Previous

research has shown that the use of book values is not a serious limitation when studying outside

financing and capital structure decisions (Fama & French, 2002; Leary & Roberts, 2005).

Following previous research, multiple constructs are selected as dependent variables,

reflecting incremental finance decisions and capital structure (Brav, 2009; Cosh, Cumming, & Hughes,

2009). These include raising outside financing (External Financing), the amount of outside financing

raised (Ln External Financing), the choice between outside equity versus outside debt (Equity/Debt),

the amount of outside equity raised (Ln Equity) and the amount of outside debt raised (Ln Debt). We

further model capital structure decisions with the financial debt ratio (Leverage) as dependent

variable. While the measures reflecting financing events capture more the dynamics of financing

strategies at particular points in time, the capital structure of firms provides a snapshot of all

previous financing events (de Haan & Hinloopen, 2003).

External Financing is a dummy variable that takes the value of one if a firm raised external

finance in a given year T. Raising external finance is defined as a minimum five percent increase in

the total amount of outside debt and equity from year T-1 to year T, relative to pre-issue total assets.

The minimum threshold of five percent benefits the comparability of our study with prior research

and allows us to study significant financing events (Brav, 2009; de Haan & Hinloopen, 2003; Leary &

Roberts, 2010; Vanacker & Manigart, 2010). Firms may issue only outside debt, only outside equity or

both in year T. A second variable, Equity/Debt, is a dummy variable equal to one if firms raise outside

equity and zero if firms raise outside debt, treating equity and debt issues as mutually exclusive

financing events (see Helwege and Liang (1996) for a similar approach). The amount of outside

financing raised in any given firm-year—including both external equity and debt—(Ln External

Page 17: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

17

Financing), of external equity (Ln Equity) and of debt (Ln Debt) were log-transformed before they

were studied. Our construct for capital structure, Leverage, is defined as the ratio of total financial

debt on total assets.

Independent Variables

The main explanatory variables in the regression models are constructs that measure

country-level differences and firm-level differences in corporate governance systems. At the country-

level, we include differences in the quality of the legal framework (Legality Index) and differences in

the severity of personal bankruptcy law reflected by the ability of entrepreneurs to obtain a fresh

start after bankruptcy (Discharge Not Available). At the firm-level, we include the effectiveness of

corporate governance reflected by VC ownership (VC).

Legality Index. Legality Index is a measure for the quality of the legal framework in each

country. We use the legality index developed by Berkowitz, Pistor, and Richard (2003), which is the

weighted sum of legal measures derived from La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 2000), for several reasons.

First, Cumming, Fleming and Schwienbacher (2006) have shown that this legality index captures

differences in national corporate governance systems which are particularly relevant for NTBFs, more

specifically differences in IPO activity. Second, the legality index is positively related with firm-level

governance mechanisms like the screening and monitoring activities of VC investors (Cumming,

Schmidt, & Walz, 2010). Third, the legality index is derived from laws pertaining to investing, the

quality of enforcement and the need that they will need to be enforced (Cumming, Fleming, &

Schwienbacher, 2006) which are laws that are relevant for outside investors in NTBFs.

Discharge Not Available. The variable used to measure cross-country differences in personal

bankruptcy law, i.e. whether entrepreneurs are able or unable to obtain a fresh start after

bankruptcy, is based upon Armour and Cumming (2008) but extended to cover the period of study.

The variable Discharge Not Available is a dummy variable that indicates whether there is a discharge

from personal indebtedness for entrepreneurs after a bankruptcy or not. The dummy variable takes

the value one if there is no discharge available for entrepreneurs and thus no opportunity to obtain a

fresh start and takes the value zero if bankruptcy law foresees a discharge. Bankruptcy law was

relaxed and a fresh start was introduced during the period of analysis in Belgium (1998), Finland

(1993) and Italy (2006), so the Discharge Not Available dummy variable shifts from one to zero in the

year in which the reform took place.

VC. Prior research indicates that the mere presence of VC investors as shareholders

influences the operations and governance of firms (e.g., Hellmann & Puri, 2002; Puri & Zarutskie,

Page 18: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

18

2012). The variable VC is a dummy variable that captures VC ownership and is hence a construct that

measures firm-level differences in corporate governance systems. VC is equal to one from the year in

which the firm receives VC financing (if any), and zero otherwise. In addition, we calculate

interactions between the VC dummy variable and the country-level variables described above.

Control Variables

Control variables are used in the multivariate analyses, which are largely motivated by prior

research. They can be aggregated in different categories.

Firm Accounting Variables. Extant corporate finance literature (Leary & Roberts, 2005, 2010;

Brav, 2009, Fama & French, 2002) has shown that firm-level accounting variables are important

determinants of external finance decisions. The amount of internal resources available is defined as

the beginning year’s cash level plus the net operating cashflow minus the change in working capital

(Leary & Roberts, 2010). Internal resources are further split into Deficit Funds and Surplus Funds

where respectively negative values of internal resources are reported and positive values are set

equal to zero (deficit variable) or vice versa (surplus variable) (Leary & Roberts, 2010; Helwege &

Liang, 1996). We further control for Size (the logarithm of total assets), Net working capital (accounts

receivable + inventory – accounts payable), Tangible (asset tangibility), Short Term to Tot Debt (the

proportion of short term debt to total debt) and T-A Leverage (target minus actual leverage scaled to

total assets). Target leverage is defined as the predicted leverage obtained from a standard OLS

leverage regression (Brav, 2009). In our capital structure regression model, we substitute the amount

of internal funds by ROA (return on assets, defined as EBIT scaled to the average of current and

preceding total assets) and control for CAPEX (the amount of capital expenditures scaled to total

assets).

Firm Non-Accounting Variables. The second category of control variables are non-accounting

firm-level variables. We control for a firm’s growth in employees (Employee Growth) as high-growth

firms need more external financing (Gompers, 1995, Mande, Park, & Son, 2012). We further control

for firm age (Log Firm Age) and the cumulative number of patent applications (# of Patent

Applications), as both firm age and innovativeness (captured by the number of patent applications)

are indicators of a firm’s degree of asymmetric information which may affect outside finance options

(Myers, 1984).

Other Control Variables. Finally, country-level variables control for between-country

differences apart from personal bankruptcy law or legal quality. Differences in economic

Page 19: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

19

development (GDP Growth) and the development of capital markets (MSCI (Morgan Stanley Capital

International) index) that might affect entrepreneurial activity (Armour & Cumming, 2008) are

included. We further control directly and indirectly for differences in entrepreneurial activity by

including Self Employment as a percentage of total employment and Personal minus Corporate tax

rate (Groh, von Liechtenstein, & Lieser, 2010). Remaining time-variant effects and industry effects

are captured by year dummies and industry dummies.

Econometric Approach

Five regression specifications study outside financing decisions. Probit models are used for

the estimation of External Financing and Equity/Debt because the dependent variables are dummy

variables. Tobit models are used for the estimation of Ln External Financing, Ln Equity and Ln Debt.

Tobit models account for the fact that the log transformed variables of the amount of financing are

truncated below by zero (Cosh, Cumming, & Hughes, 2009). Capital structure is studied using

Leverage as dependent variable in a pooled OLS regression model. If the probability of attracting VC

is correlated with the residuals of outside finance decisions or capital structure, the reported results

might suffer from a selection bias. In all models we therefore include an Inverse Mills Ratio (obtained

from a probit model estimating the probability that firms raise VC financing). The Inverse Mills Ratio

corrects for possible selection biases that arise if firms self-select into VC financing or VCs select

particular firms based on observable and unobservable characteristics (Heckman, 1979).

The control variables Surplus Funds, Deficit Funds, Tangible, and CAPEX are scaled by total

assets to control for size effects and to mitigate heteroskedasticity (Brav, 2009). Size, Employee

Growth, Net Working Capital, Tangible, Short Term to Tot Debt, T-A Leverage, ROA and CAPEX are

lagged one year to limit potential endogeneity issues. The regressions also include a constant, year

and industry fixed effects.

All currency variables are in thousands of euros and corrected for inflation (2008=100). In

order to mitigate the impact of potential sample outliers, variables were winsorized at the five

percent level (one-tail winsorizing) if needed.

Firm-years are the unit of analysis. The coefficients of the regression models are corrected

for heteroskedasticity and correlation across observations of a given firm by the clustering technique

(Petersen, 2009). We report marginal effects to show the economic significance alongside the

statistical significance (Cosh, Cumming, & Hughes, 2009).

Page 20: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

20

RESULTS

Descriptive statistics and correlations

Table 2 reports descriptive statistics and the correlation matrix. Panel A reports correlations

per country-year observation (e.g., country X-1996; 97 observations in total), Panel B reports

correlations per firm-year observation (e.g., firm X-1996; 50,132 observations in total).

Insert Table 2 about here

The average value of Legality Index is 19.47. The index value for Finland (21.49), Belgium

(20.82), U.K. (20.41) and France (19.67) are above the average value, the index value for Italy (17.23)

and Spain (17.13) fall below the average value. The mean value of Discharge Not Available is 0.38,

which indicates that in 62 percent of the observations entrepreneurs could obtain a fresh start after

bankruptcy. VC ownership was reported in on average 7 percent of the firm-year observations. Firms

are on average 5 years old, have 13 percent of tangible assets and a 4 percent profit margin. External

Financing was raised in on average 38 percent of the firm-year observations. Conditional on raising

external financing, the average amount of external financing raised is 3.6 million. Equity (on average

4.1 million) accounts for 43 percent of all financing events, debt (on average 2.2 million) accounts for

57 percent. Leverage is on average 15 percent.

The Pearson correlation coefficients between on the one hand the Legality Index and on the

other hand debt financing (Equity/Debt), the amount of equity (Ln Equity Amount) and financial debt

ratios (Leverage) are significantly positive (p<5%). This is consistent with the first hypothesis.

Discharge not Available is a dummy variable and hence its correlations should be interpreted with

care. Keeping this caveat in mind, correlation coefficients are significantly negative (p<5%) between

Discharge not Available and the amount of external financing (Ln External Amount), the amount of

equity (Ln Equity Amount) and financial debt ratios (Leverage), which is consistent with the second

hypothesis.

Unreported Variance Inflation Factors (VIF) indicate that high correlations between the

Legality Index variable, the Discharge Not Available variable, the VC dummy and their respective

interactions may lead to multicollinearity problems (VIF>10). We therefore orthogonalize these

Page 21: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

21

variables in Stata (using the orthog procedure) and create new orthogonal variables that are used to

replace the original variables in the regression models. Pollock and Rindova (2003) provide more

details on this procedure.

Multivariate analyses

Controlling for selection issues at the firm-level. We first model the propensity of firms to

raise VC financing, as a first step in the two-step Heckman procedure; the outcome is shown in

Appendix. Following Eckhart, Shane, and Delmar (2006), the VC selection process is a two-stage

process in which entrepreneurs first self-select their firms as candidates for VC financing and in the

second stage VC investors select firms from the pool of firms willing to attract VC funding.

Irrespective of who selects whom (Hellmann, 2008), the first step of the Heckman correction method

reports estimates for the only observable outcome of this selection process, namely the event of

attracting VC financing.

The dependent variable in the selection equation, VC, is a dummy variable equal to one from

the moment the firm raises VC financing, zero otherwise. The independent variables that are

expected to influence the probability of VC financing are the amount of internal funds available,

disaggregated into Surplus Funds and Deficit Funds. Entrepreneurs are often reluctant to give up

control thus VC financing is typically viewed as a last resort type of outside financing (Vanacker &

Manigart, 2010). We therefore expect that the likelihood of the VC financing event increases when

internal resources are exhausted. Other control variables are Log Firm Age, Employee Growth, Size

and # of Patent Applications as VC financing is typically associated with NTBFs with significant growth

ambitions which are especially vulnerable to liabilities of newness and smallness (Zahra &

Filatotchev, 2004). As a last determinant, the lagged inflation-adjusted yearly inflow of capital in the

VC industry (VC inflowt-1) is included, which is likely to positively affect deal origination (Gompers &

Lerner, 1996) and thus also the initial VC financing event. Fixed effects are included to control for all

other country-, industry- and time specific factors that might affect the event of attracting initial VC

financing.

Consistent with expectations, the probability of attracting VC financing increases significantly

when deficit funds are larger and when firms are younger, report higher growth rates and have more

patent applications. Firm size is positively associated with the probability of raising VC financing. A

larger inflow of capital in the VC industry (VC Inflowt-1) also increases, as expected, the probability of

the VC financing event.

Page 22: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

22

In the subsequent section, we test our hypotheses after controlling for the propensity of

firms to raise VC financing. To do so, we estimate an Inverse Mills Ratio, based on the probit model

described above, which we include in all subsequent regression models.

Hypothesis Tests. To test Hypotheses 1 and 2, we run the multivariate regression models as

reported in Table 3. All models are significant (unreported). The number of observations in each

model is different, bounded by the number of observations of the dependent variable. For example,

the use of external financing is defined for all firm-year observations (almost 13,000), but the

amount of funding is conditional on raising outside finance, which was observed for 4,099 firm-year

observations.

Insert Table 3 about here

Hypothesis 1 predicts that higher quality legal systems will be associated with the use of

more outside financing in NTBFs, which is strongly supported (p<0.1%). An increase of the Legality

Index with one unit, which is approximately the difference between the U.K. (20.41) and Finland

(21.49), increases the probability of outside finance with 17 percent, the amount of outside finance

with approximately 50 percent (44 percent for outside debt) and 10 percent higher leverage. The

quality of legal systems does not impact the choice between equity and debt, however, as the

coefficient of Legality Index is insignificant in the Equity/Debt model. This suggests that equity and

debt finance become equally more important in higher quality legal systems.

Hypothesis 2 predicts that less forgiving bankruptcy laws will be associated with the use of

less outside financing in NTBFs. A change of the Discharge Not Available dummy variable from zero

(fresh start) to one (no fresh start) decreases the probability of outside finance with 3 percent

(p<5%), decreases the amount of external financing with approximately 9 percent (8 percent for debt

financing – p<1%) and leads to a 1 percent lower leverage (p<1%). These results thus empirically

support the second hypothesis. Interestingly, the economic impact of a better overall legal system is

higher than the impact of more forgiving personal bankruptcy laws.

VC ownership (VC) is also an important determinant of outside finance decisions. Compared

with non-VC-backed NTBFs, VC-backed NTBFs raise on average more often and higher amounts of

outside finance (both 3 percent), more often equity (5 percent) and higher amounts of equity (plus 4

percent) but less debt and lower amounts of debt (both 5 percent). Interestingly, leverage is not

significantly different between VC and non-VC-backed firms. The inverse Mills ratio is negative and

significant suggesting that there exists a negative association between the residuals of the selection

model and the residuals of the outside finance models. The unobserved factors that are likely to

Page 23: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

23

influence the probability of raising VC are thus negatively correlated with the unobserved factors

that are likely to influence outside finance decisions.

The effects of the other significant firm-specific variables are largely in line with previous

findings. More Surplus Funds lead to less outside finance but more Deficit Funds lead to more

outside finance. Larger firms (Size) raise less often outside finance but the amounts are larger; they

raise more equity (or less debt) (marginally significant). Firms with higher employee growth raise

more often outside finance and more often debt (or less equity). A higher net working capital

increases the amount of debt raised; more patent applications have a negative impact on outside

finance decisions (and especially debt raised). Asset tangibility, the proportion of short term debt,

firm age and capital expenditures are positively associated with debt financing, while return on

assets (ROA) is negatively associated with debt finance.

Some country-level variables also affect NTBFs’ financing strategies. A higher economic

development (GDP Growth) results in less outside finance but higher debt ratios. More developed

capital markets (MSCI) and higher levels of self-employment (Self Employment) are positively

associated with outside finance, a higher wedge between personal income tax and corporate tax

(Personal-Corporate Tax) is positively associated with equity finance.

To test Hypotheses 3 and 4, we add interaction terms to our models. VC*Legality Index is the

interaction between Legality Index and VC and provides a test of Hypotheses 3A & 3B. VC*Discharge

Not Available is the interaction between Discharge Not Available and VC and provides a test of

Hypothesis 4. The results of the models including the interaction terms are reported in Table 4.

Insert Table 4 about here

Hypothesis 3A (3B) predicts that VC ownership decreases (increases) the positive relationship

between higher quality legal systems and the use of more outside finance. The interaction term

VC*Legality Index is significant and positive in three models explaining the probability of the use of

outside finance (External Financing), the amount of outside finance (Ln external financing) and the

amount of equity (Ln Equity). The coefficient of the interaction term is insignificant in the models

explaining the choice between equity and debt, Equity/Debt, the amount of debt, Ln Debt and

leverage, Leverage. These results thus support hypothesis 3B: VC ownership complements with

higher quality legal systems. The positive association between higher quality legal systems and

outside funding is stronger for VC-backed firms as compared with non-VC-backed firms. Per unit

increase in legality index, VC-backed firms report a 1 percent additional increase in the use of outside

Page 24: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

24

finance, a 3 percent additional increase in the amount of outside finance raised and a 4 percent

additional increase in the amount of equity finance raised, as compared with non-VC-backed firms.

Hypothesis 4 predicts that VC ownership will increase the negative relationship between less

forgiving bankruptcy laws and the use of less outside financing. The coefficient of the interaction

between Discharge Not Available and VC is therefore expected to be significantly negative. We find a

significantly negative coefficient in the models explaining the amount of outside finance (Ln external

financing), and the amount of equity (Ln Equity). The coefficient of the interaction term is

insignificant in the other models. These findings support Hypothesis 4. VC ownership complements

with less forgiving bankruptcy laws: the negative relationship between less forgiving personal

bankruptcy laws and the use of outside finance is stronger for VC-backed firms as compared with

non-VC-backed firms. VC-backed firms report a 3 percent additional decrease in the amount of

outside finance raised and a 3 percent additional decrease in the amount of equity raised when

discharge is excluded from bankruptcy law, as compared with non-VC-backed firms.

The other variables remain robust. Higher quality legal systems (Legality Index) increase

outside finance, less forgiving bankruptcy laws (Discharge Not Available) decrease outside finance

and the VC dummy variable (VC) leads to more outside finance, more equity but lower amounts of

debt. The control variables remain largely the same as in Table 3.

Robustness Checks. Additional robustness checks were performed; the detailed results of

these tests are available upon request. Overall, the robustness tests confirm that outside finance

decisions are affected by country-level differences in corporate governance systems, firm-level

differences in corporate governance and the interaction between both, irrespective of the construct

used. In a first robustness test, the strength of investor protection index (Djankov et al., 2005)

replaced the legality index as a measure of the quality of a country’s legal system. This index

measures the strength of minority investor protection laws and is positively associated with VC

activity in European countries (Groh, von Liechtenstein, and Lieser, 2010). The same conclusions

hold. Second, the personal bankruptcy dummy variable (Discharge Not Available) is replaced by other

personal bankruptcy measures: time to discharge, minimum capital, exemptions, disabilities and

composition (Armour & Cumming, 2008). The results remain robust, but are somewhat less strong.

Our findings suggest that providing a fresh start versus no fresh start is the most important

dimension of personal bankruptcy law in relation with NTBFs’ finance strategies. In a third robustness

check, we more explicitly test how VC ownership and thus differences in corporate governance at the

firm-level affect outside finance decisions. We therefore added interaction terms between the VC

dummy variable and firm accounting variables to account for the fact that VC ownership may also

have an impact on the quality of financial reporting (Beuselinck, Deloof & Manigart, 2009). Since it is

further plausible that the distribution of accounting variables is different between VC and non-VC-

Page 25: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

25

backed firms, we also identified outliers for each subsample separately. Most of the interaction

terms were insignificant, however, and did not affect our conclusions. For reasons of conciseness, we

decided to report models without the interaction terms between the VC dummy variable and the

firm accounting variables.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS

Prior entrepreneurial finance research has mainly focused on either firm-level governance

effects or on the effects of country-level institutional frameworks on the aggregate supply of outside

financing. This paper expands on prior research and focuses on the joint effects of both country-level

legal frameworks and firm-level corporate governance. More specifically, this paper focuses on the

main effects of the quality of a country’s legal system and personal bankruptcy laws and their

interaction with VC ownership on the financing strategies of NTBFs. For this purpose, we use a large

longitudinal dataset comprising private NTBFs from six European countries.

Using the legality index (Berkowitz, Pistor, & Richard, 2003) and the availability of personal

discharge post-bankruptcy (Armour & Cumming, 2006) as proxies for cross-country differences in

legal institutions relevant for entrepreneurial firms, our empirical findings increase our

understanding of the role played by national legal frameworks in affecting NTBFs’ financing

strategies. Specifically, our results show that NTBFs operating in countries with a higher quality legal

system or with more forgiving personal bankruptcy laws have a higher probability of raising outside

finance, raise more external finance when they do so (both equity and debt) and have a higher

leverage. Second, differences in firm-level corporate governance systems also significantly affect

outside finance, as VC ownership results in a higher probability of raising outside finance, in more

outside equity when NTBFs engage in equity issues, but in less debt when they engage in debt issues.

Moreover, the positive association between a country’s legal system and the availability of outside

financing is stronger for NTBFs financed by VC investors, suggesting a complementary role played by

VC ownership and a country’s legal system. Further robustness tests using different indicators for a

country’s legal quality and personal bankruptcy law confirm these results.

Our research has some potential limitations that offer fruitful avenues for future research.

First, as our research design deals with European NTBFs operating in highly (e.g., U.K.) to moderately

developed (e.g., Spain) VC markets, we lack insight into the role played by those VCs in less

developed VC markets like Asia or South-America. Moreover, further exploring NTBFs’ financing

strategies in countries with lower quality of legal systems and the potential role of VC investors

Page 26: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

26

herein also remains important. Second, our research does not consider differences in the quality of

VC investors. Prior research indeed shows that the mere presence of VC investors may be enough to

influence the operations and governance of firms (e.g., Hellmann & Puri, 2002; Van den Berghe &

Levrau, 2004). Nevertheless, research also indicates that VC investors are heterogeneous, with high

quality VC investors having disproportionate positive effects on the development of their portfolio

firms through stronger monitoring and corporate governance practices (Sorensen, 2007). High

quality VC investors should hence have an even stronger positive effect on the availability of outside

financing for their portfolio firms. Further exploring the complementarity between the quality of VC

investors and a country’s legal system might hence be relevant. Another area of future research

consists of understanding the role played by different VC investors in syndicates (Devigne, Vanacker,

Manigart, & Paeleman, 2012). Syndicates comprising different VC investors might differently impact

their portfolio firms’ financing strategies and differently interact with the country’s legal framework.

Despite its limitations, this paper sheds light on the interaction between firm-level

governance systems and country-level institutional frameworks for the financing strategies of NTBFs.

Our findings suggest that NTBFs operating in countries with high quality and more forgiving legal

systems have access to more outside equity and debt, and this effect is even stronger in firms

financed with VC. We hereby address the recent call to study the interaction between firm-level

corporate governance factors and national systems of corporate governance. The key implication for

practice of our research is that a country’s institutional environment strongly affects the financing

options available to NTBFs, and that stronger firm-level corporate governance practices in the form

of VC financing enhance the positive effects of a higher quality and more entrepreneur-friendly legal

environment. Policy-makers, entrepreneurs as well as investors should consider how the quality of

the legal system and personal bankruptcy laws would affect the financing strategies of

entrepreneurial firms.

NOTES

*We acknowledge the data collection support of all VICO partners. This project was possible thanks

to financial support of the EU VII Framework Programme (VICO, Contract 217485), the Hercules Fund

(AUGE/11/013), and Belspo (SMEPEFI TA/00/41). We thank David Devigne for excellent research

assistance and Armin Schwienbacher for valuable comments on a previous version of the paper.

Page 27: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

27

REFERENCES

Abdi, M. & Aulakh, P. 2012. Do country-level institutional frameworks and interfirm governance

arrangements substitute or complement in international business relationships? Journal of International

Business Studies, 43: 477-497.

Acharya, V., Amihud, Y., & Litov, L. 2011. Creditor rights and corporate risk-taking. Journal of

Financial Economics, 102: 150-166.

Aguilera, R., Filatotchev, I., Gospel, H., & Jackson, G. 2008. An organizational approach to

comparative corporate governance costs, contingencies, and complementarities. Organization Science,

19: 475–492.

Armour, J. & Cumming, D. 2008. Bankruptcy law and entrepreneurship. American Law and

Economics Review, 10: 303-350.

Armour, J. & Cumming, D. 2006. The legislative road to Silicon Valley. Oxford Economic Papers, 58:

596-635.

Balcaen, S., Manigart, S., Ooghe, H., & Buyze, J. 2013. Firm exit after distress: Differentiating

between bankruptcy, voluntary liquidation and M&A. Small Business Economics, In Press.

Berger, A. & Udell, G. 1998. The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and

debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22: 613-673.

Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J. 2003. Economic development, legality, and the transplant

effect. European Economic Review, 47:165-195.

Bertoni, F. & Pellón J., Financing entrepreneurial ventures in Europe: The Vico dataset (September

30, 2011). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1904297

Beuselinck, C., Deloof, M., & Manigart, S. 2009. Private equity involvement and earnings quality.

Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 36: 587-615.

Bottazzi, L. & Da Rin, M. 2002. Venture capital in Europe and the financing of innovative companies.

Economic Policy, 17:230-269.

Bottazzi, L., Da Rin, M., & Hellmann, T. 2009. What is the role of legal systems in financial

intermediation? Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 18: 559-598.

Page 28: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

28

Bottazzi, L., Da Rin, M., & Hellmann, T. 2008. Who are the active investors?: Evidence from venture

capital.” Journal of Financial Economics, 89: 488–512.

Brav, O. 2009. Access to capital, capital structure, and the funding of the firm. Journal of Finance, 64:

263-308.

Brush, T., Bromiley, P., & Hendrickx, M. 2000. The free cash flow hypothesis for sales growth and

firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 21: 455-472.

Bruton, G., Filatotchev, I., Chahine, S., & Wright, M. 2010. Governance, ownership structure, and

performance of IPO firms: The impact of different types of private equity investors and legal

institutions in two European nations. Strategic Management Journal, 31: 491–509.

Cassar, G. 2004. The financing of business start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing, 19: 261-283.

Chahine, S. & Saade, S. 2011. Shareholders’ rights and the effect of the origin of venture capital firms

on the underpricing of US IPOs. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 19: 601-621

Colombo, M. & Grilli, L. 2005. Founders' human capital and the growth of new technologybased

firms: A competence-based view. Research Policy, 34: 795–816.

Cosh, A., Cumming, D., & Hughes, A. 2009. Outside entrepreneurial capital. The Economic Journal,

119: 1494–1533.

Cumming, D. & Dai N. 2012. Why do entrepreneurs switch venture capitalists? Entrepreneurship

Theory and Practice, In Press.

Cumming, D., Schmidt, D., & Walz, U. 2010. Legality and venture capital governance around the

world. Journal of Business Venturing, 25: 54–72.

Cumming, D., Fleming, G., & Schwienbacher, A. 2006. Legality and venture capital exits. Journal of

Corporate Finance, 12: 214-245.

Dalton, D., Daily, C., Certo, T., & Roengpitya, R. 2003. Meta-analyses of financial performance and

equity: Fusion or confusion. Academy of Management Journal, 46: 13-26.

de Haan, L. & Hinloopen, J. 2003. Preference hierarchies for internal finance, bank loans, bond and

share issues: evidence for Dutch firms. Journal of Empirical Finance, 10: 661-681.

Demsetz, H. & Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and

consequences.Journal of Political Economy, 93: 1155-1177.

Page 29: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

29

Devigne, D., Vanacker, T., Manigart, S., & Paeleman, I. 2012. The role of domestic and cross-border

venture capital investors in the growth of portfolio companies. Small Business Economics, In Press.

Dharwadkar, R., George, G., & Brandes, P. 2000. Privatization in emerging economies: An agency

theory perspective. Academy of Management Review, 25: 650-669.

Dimov, D. & De Clercq, D. 2006. Venture capital investment strategy and portfolio failure rate: A

longitudinal study. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 30: 207-223.

Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2005. The law and economics of self-

dealing. NBER Working Paper.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Shleifer, A. 2007. Private credit in 129 countries. Journal of Financial

Economics, 84: 299–329.

Douma, S., George, R., & Kabir, R. 2006. Foreign and domestic ownership, business groups, and firm

performance: Evidence from a large emerging market. Strategic Management Journal, 27: 637–657.

Eckhardt, J., Shane, S., & Delmar, F. 2006. Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures.

Management Science, 52:220-232.

Fama, E. & French, K. 2002. Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividends and

debt, Review of Financial Studies, 15: 1-33.

Filatotchev, I. & Boyd, B. 2009. Taking stock of corporate governance research while looking at the

future. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17: 257-265.

George, G., Wiklund, J., & Zahra, S. 2005. Ownership and the internationalization of small firms.

Journal of Management, 31: 210-33.

Gompers, P. 1995. Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital. Journal of

Finance, 50: 1461–1489.

Gompers, P., & Lerner, J. 2000. Money chasing deals? The impact of fund inflows on private equity

valuations. Journal of Financial Economics, 55:281-325.

Gompers, P., & Lerner, J. 2001. The venture capital revolution. Journal of Economic Perspectives,

15:145-168.

Gorman, M. & Sahlman, W. 1989. What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business Venturing, 4:

231–248.

Page 30: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

30

Groh, A., von Liechtenstein, H., & Lieser, K. 2010. The European venture capital and private equity

country attractiveness indices. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16: 205–224.

Hart, O. 1995. Corporate governance: Some theory and implications. The Economic Journal, 105:

678-689.

Heckman, J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47:153-161.

Hellmann, T., Lindsey, L., & Puri, M. 2008. Building relationships early: banks in venture capital. The

Review of Financial Studies, 21: 513-541.

Hellmann, T. & Puri, M. 2002. Venture capital and the professionalization of start-up firms: Empirical

evidence. Journal of Finance, 57: 169–197.

Hellmann, T. 1998. The allocation of control rights in venture capital contracts. The Rand Journal of

Economics, 29: 57–76.

Helwege, J. & Liang, N. 1996. Is there a pecking order? Evidence from a panel of IPO firms. Journal

of Financial Economics, 40: 429 -458.

Hoskisson, R., Cannella Jr., A., Tihanyi, L., & Faraci, R. 2004. Asset restructuring and business group

affiliation in French civil law countries. Strategic Management Journal, 25: 525-539.

Jain, B. & Kini, O. 1999. The life cycle of initial public offering firms. Journal of Business Finance

and Accounting, 26: 1281–1307.

Janney, J & Folta, T. 2003. Signaling through private equity placements and its impact on the

valuation of biotechnology firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18: 361-380.

Jensen, M. & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and

ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.

Kaplan, S. N., & Strömberg, P. (2004). Characteristics, contracts, and actions: Evidence from venture

capitalist analyses. Journal of Finance, 59, 2177–2210.

Klapper, L. & Love, I. 2004. Corporate governance, investor protection, and performance in emerging

markets. Journal of Corporate Finance, 10: 703-728.

Knockaert M., Ucbasaran D., Wright M., & Clarysse B. 2011. The relationship between knowledge

transfer, top management team composition, and performance: The case of science‐based

entrepreneurial firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 35: 777-803.

Page 31: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

31

Knockaert, M., Lockett, A., Clarysse, B., & Wright, M. 2006. Do human capital and fund

characteristics drive follow-up behaviour of early stage high tech VCs? International Journal of

Technology Management, 34: 7–27.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. 1997. Legal determinants of external

finance. Journal of Finance, 52: 1131–1150.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. 2000. Agency problems and dividend

policies around the world. Journal of Finance, 55:1-33.

Leary, M. & Roberts, M. 2005. Do firms rebalance their capital structure? Journal of Finance, 60:

2575–2619.

Leary, M. & Roberts, M. 2010. The pecking order, debt capacity and information asymmetry, Journal

of Financial Economics, 95: 332-355.

Lerner, J. & Schoar, A. 2005. Does legal enforcement affect financial transactions? The contractual

channel in private equity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120: 223-246.

Lerner, J. 1995. Venture capitalists and the oversight of private firms. Journal of Finance, 50: 301-318.

Mande, V., Park Y., & Son, M. 2012. Equity or debt financing: Does good corporate governance

matter? Corporate Governance: An International Review, 20:195-211.

Manigart, S., & C. Struyf. 1997. Financing high technology start ups in Belgium: An explorative

study. Small Business Economics, 9: 125–135.

Myers, S. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5: 147-175.

Myers, S. 1984. The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance, 39: 574–592.

North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

Pollock, T. & Rindova, V. 2003. Media legitimation effects in the market for initial public offerings.

Academy of Management Journal, 46: 631-642.

Puri, M., & Zarutskie, R. 2012. On the lifecycle dynamics of venture capital and non-venture capital

financed firms, Journal of Finance, forthcoming.

Robb, A. & Robinson, D. 2012. The capital structure decisions of new firms. Review of Financial

Studies, In Press.

Page 32: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

32

Roberts, M. & Sufi, A. 2009. Control rights and capital structure: An empirical investigation. Journal

of Finance, 64: 1657-1695.

Sahlman, W. 1990. The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations. Journal of

Financial Economics, 27: 473-521.

Sapienza, H., Korsgaard, A. & Forbes, D. 2003. The self-determination motive and entrepreneurs

choice of financing. In Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence and growth, eds. J. Katz & D.

Shepherd, 105–38. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Sapienza, H., Manigart, S., & Vermeir, W. 1996. Venture capitalist governance and value added in

four countries. Journal of Business Venturing 11: 439–469.

Seifert, B. & Gonenc, H. 2012. Creditor rights and R&D expenditures. Corporate Governance: An

International Review, 20: 3-20.

Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. 1986. Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of Political

Economy, 94: 461-488.

Sorensen, M. 2007. How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital.

Journal of Finance, 62: 2725-2762.

Storey, D. & Tether, B. 1998. New technology-based firms in the European Union: An introduction.

Research Policy, 26: 933-946.

Strange, R., Filatotchev, I., Buck, T., & Wright, M. 2009. Corporate governance and international

business. Management International Review, 49: 395-407.

Suchard, J.-A. 2009. The impact of venture capital backing on the corporate governance of Australian

initial public offerings. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33: 765–774.

Vanacker, T. & Manigart, S. 2010. Pecking order and debt capacity considerations for highgrowth

companies seeking financing. Small Business Economics, 35: 53-69.

Van den Berghe, L. & Levrau, A. 2002. The role of the venture capitalist as monitor of the company:

A Corporate governance perspective. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 10: 124-135.

Williams, D., Duncan, W., & Ginter, P. 2006. Structuring deals and governance after the IPO:

Entrepreneurs and venture capitalists in high tech start-ups. Business Horizons, 49: 303-311.

Wright, M. & Robbie, K. 1998. Venture capital and private equity: A review and synthesis. Journal of

Business Finance & Accounting, 25: 521-70.

Page 33: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

33

Zahra, A. & Filatotchev, I. 2004. Governance of the entrepreneurial threshold firm: A knowledge

based perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 41: 885-897.

Page 34: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

34

APPENDIX

Selection model estimating the probability of attracting VC funding

Probability of VC funding

Surplus Funds -0.02

[0.09]

Deficit Funds 1.44***

[0.15]

Size 0.15***

[0.02]

Employee Growth 0.18***

[0.02]

Log Firm Age -0.77***

[0.10]

# of Patent Applications 0.03*

[0.01]

VC Inflowt-1 0.01*

[0.00]

Country fixed effects YES

Year fixed effects YES

Industry fixed effects YES

# of Observations 18,035

R² 0.20 This table presents multivariate estimates of the probability that firms attract VC funding for the period under study. Firm years are the unit of analysis and coefficients are corrected for heteroskedasticity and correlation across observations of a given firm. The dependent variable is a binary variable equal to one from the year in which firms attract VC financing, zero otherwise. The regressions also include a constant, and control for year, country and industry effects (not reported). †, *, **,*** denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, 1 percent and 0.1 percent level correspondingly.

Page 35: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

35

TABLE 1

Description of the sample

Total Sample VC-backed firms Non VC-backed firms

Number % Number % Number %

Country

Finland 757 11.11 69 11.39 688 11.08

Spain 876 12.86 81 13.37 795 12.81

Belgium 913 13.40 90 14.85 823 13.26

Italy 1,055 15.49 97 16.01 958 15.43

UK 1,534 22.52 169 27.89 1,365 21.99

France 1,678 24.63 100 16.50 1,578 25.42

Foundation Period

1984-1989 983 14.43 21 3.47 962 15.50

1990-1994 1,204 17.67 89 14.69 1,115 17.96

1995-1999 2,136 31.35 249 41.09 1,887 30.40

2000-2004 2,490 36.55 247 40.76 2,243 36.14

Industry

Other 815 11.96 40 6.60 775 12.49

Communication 349 5.12 38 6.27 311 5.01

Life Sciences 631 9.26 102 16.83 529 8.52

Internet Related 801 11.76 117 19.31 684 11.02

ICT 1,137 16.69 102 16.83 1,035 16.67

Software 3,080 45.21 207 34.16 2,873 46.29

Total 6,813 100.00 606 100.00 6,207 100.00

Page 36: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

36

TABLE 2

Correlations and Descriptive Statistics

Mean S.D. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Panel A: country level correlations (# of observations = 97)

Discharge Not Available* (1) 0.38 0.49 1.00

Legality Index (2) 19.47 1.70 -0.75 1.00

GDP Growth (3) 2.50 1.47 -0.06 0.10

MSCI (4) 0.97 0.49 -0.36 0.06 0.15 1.00

Self Employment (5) 17.29 6.14 0.79 -0.73 -0.15 -0.32 1.00

Personal - Corporate Tax (6) 10.60 6.59 -0.18 0.23 -0.24 -0.20 -0.15

1.00

Panel B: firm level correlations (# of observations = 50,132)

External Financing*(7) 0.38 0.49 0.07 -0.10 0.02 0.03 0.08 -0.09 1.00

Ln External Amount (8) 5.41 2.21 -0.04 -0.01 0.06 0.12 -0.03 -0.05 NA 1.00

Equity/Debt*(9) 0.43 0.49 -0.02 -0.07 -0.11 -0.02 -0.01 0.04 NA 0.16 1.00

Ln Equity Amount (10) 5.49 2.34 -0.15 0.12 0.06 0.16 -0.15 0.03 NA 0.98 NA 1.00

Ln Debt Amount (11) 5.17 1.97 0.14 -0.21 0.08 0.09 0.23 -0.19 NA 0.95 NA 0.71 1.00

Leverage (12) 0.15 0.22 -0.03 0.15 0.10 -0.04 0.00 -0.09 0.37 0.08 -0.48 -0.06 0.30 1.00

VC* (13) 0.07 0.26 -0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 -0.03 0.16 0.25 0.17 0.26 0.19 0.04

Surplus Funds (14) 0.27 0.26 -0.13 0.13 0.06 0.02 -0.15 -0.01 -0.38 -0.31 -0.04 -0.29 -0.27 -0.25

Deficit Funds (15) 0.05 0.12 -0.03 0.03 -0.01 0.01 -0.02 0.01 0.45 0.32 0.21 0.29 0.22 0.26

Size (16) 6.25 1.98 0.04 -0.09 -0.02 0.04 0.02 0.00 -0.01 0.80 -0.02 0.80 0.83 0.06

Employee Growth (17) 1.21 0.77 0.03 -0.03 0.01 -0.01 0.00 -0.02 0.13 0.13 0.06 0.16 0.05 0.00

Net Working Capital (18) 0.13 0.31 0.02 -0.03 -0.01 -0.01 0.04 -0.01 -0.01 0.02 -0.02 0.00 0.04 0.03

# of Patent Applications(19) 0.40 6.12 -0.03 0.02 -0.01 0.03 -0.03 0.01 0.03 0.13 0.06 0.14 0.17 0.00

Tangible (20) 0.13 0.18 0.15 -0.04 0.10 -0.21 0.09 -0.09 0.03 0.00 -0.06 -0.04 0.06 0.22

Page 37: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

37

TABLE 2

Continued

Mean S.D. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Short Term to Tot Debt (21) 0.37 0.42 -0.18 0.09 -0.03 0.13 -0.26 0.12 0.09 0.07 -0.10 0.12 0.05 0.10

Log Firm Age (22) 0.81 0.32 -0.06 0.03 0.06 0.08 -0.03 -0.08 -0.21 0.07 -0.20 0.06 0.16 -0.01

T-A Leverage (23) 0.01 0.19 0.01 -0.03 0.00 0.02 -0.01 0.01 -0.09 0.02 -0.02 0.05 0.00 -0.54

ROA (24) 0.04 0.32 0.01 0.00 0.08 0.02 0.05 -0.05 -0.28 -0.24 -0.34 -0.24 -0.16 -0.15

CAPEX (25) 0.06 0.09 0.04 -0.04 -0.04 -0.04 0.04 0.00 0.14 0.11 0.03 0.10 0.09 0.10

(13) (14) (15) (16) (17) (18) (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) (24) (25)

VC* (13) 1.00

Surplus Funds (14) -0.09 1.00

Deficit Funds (15) 0.14 -0.39 1.00

Size (16) 0.15 -0.19 0.01 1.00

Employee Growth (17) 0.07 -0.03 0.09 0.07 1.00

Net Working Capital (18) -0.01 0.03 0.00 -0.01 0.01 1.00

# of Patent Applications(19) 0.04 -0.04 0.06 0.11 0.01 0.00 1.00

Tangible (20) -0.04 -0.13 0.02 0.05 -0.01 0.00 -0.01 1.00

Short Term to Tot Debt (21) -0.07 -0.08 0.03 0.18 0.01 0.01 0.02 -0.01 1.00

Log Firm Age (22) -0.08 0.03 -0.15 0.23 -0.25 0.00 0.01 -0.01 0.06 1.00

T-A Leverage (23) 0.01 0.08 -0.08 0.03 0.02 -0.02 0.01 -0.06 -0.04 -0.01 1.00

ROA (24) -0.29 0.28 -0.40 -0.12 -0.03 0.01 -0.05 -0.07 -0.03 0.13 0.06 1.00

CAPEX (25) 0.07 -0.09 0.09 0.09 0.21 0.00 0.01 0.22 0.03 0.00 -0.01 -0.07 1.00

Page 38: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

38

Table 2 reports the mean and standard deviation and Pearson correlation coefficients (two-tail) between all variables. Coefficients in bold denote statistical

significance at the 5 percent level.

Page 39: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

39

TABLE 3

Regression models: Main effects

External

financing

Ln external

financing

Equity/Debt Ln Equity Ln Debt Leverage

Legality Index 0.17*** 0.42*** 0.01 0.42*** 0.37*** 0.10*** [0.01] [0.03] [0.03] [0.05] [0.04] [0.01] Discharge not Available -0.03* -0.09** -0.02 -0.07 -0.08** -0.01** [0.01] [0.03] [0.02] [0.05] [0.03] [0.00] VC 0.03*** 0.03* 0.05*** 0.04** -0.05*** 0.00 [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Surplus Funds -0.63*** -0.52*** 0.05 -0.77*** -0.17+ [0.03] [0.08] [0.06] [0.14] [0.10] Deficit Funds 1.94*** 2.29*** 0.61*** 1.29*** 2.07*** [0.22] [0.13] [0.11] [0.18] [0.15] Size -0.06*** 0.74*** 0.02+ 0.75*** 0.77*** -0.02*** [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.02] [0.01] [0.00] Employee Growth 0.02** -0.05** -0.04** -0.07* -0.05** -0.02*** [0.01] [0.02] [0.02] [0.03] [0.02] [0.00] Net Working Capital 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.06* [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.03] # of Patent Applications -0.00 -0.01** 0.00 -0.00 -0.02*** -0.01** [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.00] Tangible -0.08 0.22*** [0.07] [0.02] Short Term to Tot Debt -0.13*** 0.06*** [0.03] [0.01] Log Firm Age -0.33*** 0.10*** [0.07] [0.01] T-A Leverage -0.09 [0.06] ROA -0.09*** [0.01] CAPEX 0.11*** [0.03] GDP Growth -0.02+ -0.08** -0.01 -0.12** -0.01 0.02*** [0.01] [0.03] [0.02] [0.05] [0.03] [0.00] MSCI 0.39*** 1.08*** 0.02 1.14*** 0.89*** 0.20*** [0.03] [0.08] [0.07] [0.13] [0.09] [0.02] Self Employment -0.00 0.01* 0.00 0.00 0.04*** 0.01*** [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Personal – Corporate Tax -0.00 0.01** 0.01** 0.02** -0.00 -0.00*** [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Inverse Mills Ratio -0.48*** -1.55*** 0.01 -1.63*** -1.04*** -0.17*** [0.03] [0.06] [0.07] [0.10] [0.07] [0.01] Year fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES Industry fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

# of Observations 12,977 4,099 2,546 1,947 2,686 13,467 R² 0.29 0.39 0.12 0.37 0.39 0.21

Page 40: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

40

Table 3 presents multivariate estimates of the outside finance decisions and leverage.

Firm year observations are the unit of analysis. The coefficients represent the average

partial effect of the coefficients, corrected for heteroskedasticity and correlation across

observations of a given firm to show the economic significance alongside the statistical

significance. The regressions also include a constant, and control for year and industry

effects (coefficients not reported). †, *, **,*** denote statistical significance at the 10

percent, 5 percent, 1 percent and 0.1 percent level correspondingly.

Page 41: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

41

TABLE 4

Regression models including VC interaction

External

financing

Ln external

financing

Equity/Debt Ln Equity Ln Debt Leverage

Legality Index 0.16*** 0.39*** -0.01 0.35*** 0.37*** 0.10*** [0.01] [0.04] [0.03] [0.06] [0.04] [0.01] Discharge not Available -0.02* -0.08** -0.02 -0.05 -0.08** -0.01** [0.01] [0.03] [0.02] [0.05] [0.03] [0.00] VC 0.03*** 0.03* 0.05*** 0.03* -0.05*** 0.00 [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.02] [0.01] [0.00] VC* Legality Index 0.01*** 0.03** 0.01 0.04** -0.00 -0.00 [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.02] [0.01] [0.00] VC* Discharge not Available 0.00 -0.03** -0.01 -0.03+ -0.01 0.00 [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Surplus Funds -0.63*** -0.52*** 0.05 -0.77*** -0.18+ [0.03] [0.08] [0.06] [0.14] [0.10] Deficit Funds 1.93*** 2.25*** 0.59*** 1.25*** 2.07*** [0.22] [0.13] [0.11] [0.18] [0.15] Size -0.06*** 0.74*** 0.02 0.75*** 0.77*** -0.02*** [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.02] [0.01] [0.00] Employee Growth 0.02* -0.05** -0.04** -0.07** -0.05** -0.02*** [0.01] [0.02] [0.02] [0.03] [0.02] [0.00] Net Working Capital 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.06* [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.03] # of Patent Applications -0.00 -0.01** 0.00 -0.00 -0.02*** -0.00** [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.00] Tangible -0.07 0.22*** [0.07] [0.02] Short Term to Tot Debt -0.13*** 0.06*** [0.03] [0.01] Log Firm Age -0.33*** 0.10*** [0.07] [0.01] T-A Leverage -0.09

Page 42: Institutional frameworks, venture capital and the ...€¦ · 2008), we know little about their role in NTFs’ financing decisions. While Armour and umming (2006) show that more

42

[0.06] ROA -0.09*** [0.01] CAPEX 0.11*** [0.03] GDP Growth -0.02 -0.08** -0.00 -0.12** -0.01 0.02*** [0.01] [0.03] [0.02] [0.05] [0.03] [0.00] MSCI 0.39*** 1.07*** 0.02 1.10*** 0.89*** 0.20*** [0.03] [0.08] [0.07] [0.13] [0.09] [0.02] Self Employment -0.00 0.01* -0.00 -0.00 0.04*** 0.01*** [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Personal – Corporate Tax -0.00 0.01** 0.01** 0.02* -0.00 -0.00*** [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] Inverse Mills Ratio -0.49*** -1.56*** -0.01 -1.66*** -1.04*** -0.17*** [0.03] [0.06] [0.07] [0.10] [0.07] [0.01] Year fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES Industry fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

# of Observations 12,977 4,099 2,546 1,947 2,686 13,467 R² 0.29 0.39 0.11 0.37 0.39 0.21

Table 4 presents multivariate estimates of the outside finance decisions and leverage adding the interaction terms between Legality Index and VC (VC* Legality Index) and between Discharge Not Available and VC (VC* Discharge not Available). Firm years are the unit of analysis. The coefficients represent the average partial effect of the coefficients, corrected for heteroskedasticity and correlation across observations of a given firm. The regressions also include a constant, and control for year and industry effects (coefficients not reported). †, *, **,*** denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, 1 percent and 0.1 percent level correspondingly.