Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

download Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

of 42

Transcript of Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    1/42

    Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and

    Optimal Monetary Policy

    Teruyoshi KobayashiDepartment of Economics, Chukyo University

    Many recent empirical studies have reported that the pass-through from money-market rates to retail lending rates is far

    from complete in the euro area. This paper formally showsthat when only a fraction of all the loan rates is adjusted inresponse to a shift in the policy rate, fluctuations in the aver-age loan rate lead to welfare costs. Accordingly, the centralbank is required to stabilize the rate of change in the averageloan rate in addition to inflation and output. It turns out thatthe requirement for loan rate stabilization justifies, to someextent, the idea of policy rate smoothing in the face of a pro-ductivity shock and/or a preference shock. However, a drastic

    policy reaction is needed in response to a shock that directlyshifts retail loan rates, such as an unexpected shift in the loanrate premium.

    JEL Codes: E44, E52, E58.

    1. Introduction

    Many empirical studies have shown that in the majority of indus-trialized countries, a cost channel plays an important role in the

    I would like to thank Yuichi Abiko, Ippei Fujiwara, Ichiro Fukunaga, HibikiIchiue, Toshiki Jinushi, Takeshi Kudo, Ryuzo Miyao, Ichiro Muto, Ryuichi Naka-gawa, Masashi Saito, Yosuke Takeda, Peter Tillmann, Takayuki Tsuruga, KazuoUeda, Tsutomu Watanabe, Hidefumi Yamagami, other seminar participants atKobe University and the University of Tokyo, and anonymous referees for theirvaluable comments and suggestions. A part of this research was supported by

    KAKENHI: Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B) 17730138. Author contact:Department of Economics, Chukyo University, 101-2 Yagoto-honmachi, Showa-ku, Nagoya 466-8666, Japan. E-mail: [email protected]. Tel./Fax: +81-52-835-7943.

    77

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    2/42

    78 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    transmission of monetary policy.1 Along with this, many authorshave attempted to incorporate a cost channel in formal models of

    monetary policy. For example, Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans(2005) introduce a cost channel into the New Keynesian frameworkin accounting for the actual dynamics of inflation and output inthe United States, while Ravenna and Walsh (2006) explore optimalmonetary policy in the presence of a cost channel.

    However, a huge number of recent studies have also reported that,especially in the euro area, shifts in money-market rates, includingthe policy rate, are not completely passed through to retail lend-ing rates.2 Naturally, since loan rates are determined by commercialbanks, to what extent shifts in money-market rates affect loan ratesand thereby the behavior of firms depends on how commercial banksreact to the shifts in the money-market rates. If not all of the com-mercial banks promptly respond to a change in the money-marketrates, then a policy shift will not affect the whole economy equally.3

    Given this situation, it is natural to ask whether or not the presenceof loan rate sluggishness alters the desirable monetary policy com-pared with the case in which a shift in the policy rate is immediately

    followed by changes in retail lending rates. Nevertheless, to the bestof my knowledge, little attention has been paid to such a normativeissue since the main purpose of the previous studies was to estimatethe degree of pass-through.

    The principal aim of this paper is to formally explore opti-mal monetary policy in an economy with imperfect interest ratepass-through, where retail lending rates are allowed to differ acrossregions. Following Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992), Christiano,

    Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005), and Ravenna and Walsh (2006),

    1See, for example, Barth and Ramey (2001), Angeloni, Kashyap, and Mojon(2003), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005), Chowdhury, Hoffmann, andSchabert (2006), and Ravenna and Walsh (2006).

    2Some recent studies, to name a few, are Mojon (2000), Weth (2002), Angeloni,Kashyap, and Mojon (2003), Gambacorta (2004), de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla(2005), Kok Srensen and Werner (2006), and Gropp, Kok Srensen, and Licht-enberger (2007). A brief review of the literature on interest rate pass-through is

    provided in the next section.3Possible explanations for the existence of loan rate stickiness have been con-

    tinuously discussed in the literature. Some of those explanations are introducedin the next section.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    3/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 79

    it is assumed in our model that the marginal cost of each produc-tion firm depends on a borrowing rate, since the owner of each firm

    needs to borrow funds from a commercial bank in order to com-pensate for wage bills that have to be paid in advance. A novelfeature of our model is that there is only one commercial bank ineach region, and each commercial bank does business only in theregion where it is located. Since loan markets are assumed to begeographically segmented, each firm owner can borrow funds onlyfrom the corresponding regional bank. In this environment, retailloan rates are not necessarily the same across firms. The commercialbanks problem for loan rate determination is specified as Calvo-typepricing.

    It is shown that the approximated utility function takes a formsimilar to the objective function that frequently appears in the litera-ture on interest rate smoothing. An important difference, however,is that the central bank is now required to stabilize the rate of changein the average loan rate, not the rate of change in the policy rate. Thenecessity for the stabilization of the average loan rate can be under-stood by analogy with the requirement for inflation stabilization,

    which has been widely discussed within the standard Calvo-typestaggered-price model. Under staggered pricing, the rate of inflationshould be stabilized because price dispersion would otherwise takeplace. Under staggered loan rates, changes in the average loan ratemust be dampened because loan rate dispersion would otherwisetake place. Since loan rate dispersion inevitably causes price disper-sion through the cost channel, it consequently leads to an inefficientdispersion in hours worked.

    It turns out that the introduction of a loan rate stabilizationterm in the central banks loss function causes the optimal policyrate to become more inertial in the face of a productivity shock anda preference shock. This implies that the optimal policy based ona loss function with a loan rate stabilization term is quite consis-tent with that based on the conventionally used loss function thatinvolves a policy rate stabilization term. Yet, this smoothing effectappears to be limited quantitatively.

    On the other hand, the presence of a loan rate stabilization termrequires a drastic policy response in the face of an exogenous shockthat directly shifts retail loan rates, such as an unexpected change inthe loan rate premium. For example, an immediate reduction in the

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    4/42

    80 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    policy rate is needed in response to a positive loan premium shocksince it can partially offset the rise in loan rates. This is in stark

    contrast to the policy suggested by conventional policy rate smooth-ing. The case of a loan premium shock is an example for which itis crucial for the central bank to clearly distinguish between policyrate smoothing and loan rate smoothing.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next sectionbriefly reviews recent empirical studies on interest rate pass-through.Section 3 presents a baseline model, and section 4 summarizesthe equilibrium dynamics of the economy. Section 5 derives autility-based objective function of the central bank, and optimalmonetary policy is explored in section 6. Section 7 concludes thepaper.

    2. A Review of Recent Studies on Interest RatePass-Through

    Over the past decade, a huge number of empirical studies havebeen conducted in an attempt to estimate the degree of interest

    rate pass-through in the euro area. In the literature, the terminol-ogy interest rate pass-through generally has two meanings: loanrate pass-through and deposit rate pass-through. In this paper, wefocus on the former since the general equilibrium model describedbelow treats only the case of loan rate stickiness. Although it issaid that deposit rates are also sticky in the euro area, constructinga formal general equilibrium model that includes loan rate stick-iness is a reasonable first step to a richer model that could also

    take into account the sluggishness in deposit rates. This sectionbriefly reviews recent studies on loan rate pass-through in the euroarea.4

    Although recent studies on loan rate pass-through differ in termsof the estimation methods and the data used, a certain amount ofbroad consensus has been established. First, at the euro-area aggre-gated level, the policy rate is only partially passed through to retailloan rates in the short run, while the estimates of the degree of

    4de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005) and Kok Srensen and Werner (2006)also provide a survey of the literature on the empirical study of interest ratepass-through, including deposit rate pass-through.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    5/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 81

    pass-through differ among researchers. For example, according totable 1 of de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005), the estimated degree

    of short-run (i.e., monthly) pass-through of changes in the marketinterest rates to the loan rate on short-term loans to firms variesfrom .25 (Sander and Kleimeier 2002; Hofmann 2003) to .76 (Heine-mann and Schuler 2002). Gropp, Kok Srensen, and Lichtenberger(2007) argued that interest rate pass-through in the euro area isincomplete even after controlling for differences in bank soundness,credit risk, and the slope of the yield curve. On the other hand,there is no general consensus about whether the long-run interestrate pass-through is perfect or not.5

    Second, although the degree of interest rate pass-through sig-nificantly differs across countries, the extent of heterogeneity hasbeen reduced since the introduction of the euro (de Bondt 2002;Toolsema, Sturm, and de Haan 2001; Sander and Kleimeier 2004).At this point, it also seems to be widely admitted that the speed ofloan rate adjustment has, to some extent, been improved (de Bondt2002; de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla 2005).

    While there is little doubt about the existence of sluggishness in

    loan rates, there is still much debate as to why it exists and why theextent of pass-through differs across countries. For instance, Gropp,Kok Srensen, and Lichtenberger (2007) insisted that the competi-tiveness of the financial market is a key to understanding the degreeof pass-through. They showed that a larger degree of loan rate pass-through would be attained as financial markets become more com-petitive. Schwarzbauer (2006) pointed out that differences in finan-cial structure, measured by the ratio of bank deposits to GDP and

    the ratio of market capitalization to GDP, have a significant influ-ence on the heterogeneity among euro-area countries in the speedof pass-through. de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005) argued thatretail bank rates are not completely responsive to money-marketrates since bank rates are tied to long-term market interest rateseven in the case of short-term bank rates. From a different point

    5For instance, Mojon (2000), Heinemann and Schuler (2002), Hofmann (2003),

    and Sander and Kleimeier (2004) reported that the long-run pass-through of mar-ket rates to interest rates on short-term loans to firms is complete. On the otherhand, Donnay and Degryse (2001) and Toolsema, Sturm, and de Haan (2001)argued that the loan rate pass-through is incomplete even in the long run.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    6/42

    82 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    of view, Kleimeier and Sander (2006) emphasized the role of mone-tary policymaking by central banks as a determinant of the degree

    of pass-through. They argued that better-anticipated policy changestend to result in a quicker response of retail interest rates.6

    In the theoretical model presented in the next section, we con-sider a situation where financial markets are segmented and thuseach regional bank has a monopolistic power. While the well-knownCalvo-type staggered pricing is applied to banks loan rate settings,it turns out that the degree of pass-through depends largely on thecentral banks policy rate setting. Moreover, a newly charged loanrate can be interpreted as a weighted average of short- and long-term market rates, where the size of each weight is dependent onthe degree of stickiness. Thus, although our way of introducing loanrate stickiness into the general equilibrium model is fairly simple,the models implications for the relationship between loan rates andthe policy rate seem quite consistent with what some of the previousstudies have suggested.

    3. The Model

    The economy consists of a representative household, intermediate-goods firms, final-goods firms, financial intermediary, and the centralbank. The representative household consumes a variety of final con-sumption goods while supplying labor service in the intermediate-goods sector. Each intermediate-goods firm produces a differentiatedintermediate good and sells it to final-goods firms. Following Chris-tiano and Eichenbaum (1992), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans(2005), and Ravenna and Walsh (2006), we consider a situation inwhich the owner of each intermediate-goods firm has to pay wagesin advance to workers at the beginning of each period. The ownerthereby needs to borrow funds from a commercial bank since theycannot receive revenue until the end of the period. Final-goods firmsproduce differentiated consumption goods by using a composite ofintermediate goods.

    6For a more concrete discussion about the source of imperfect pass-through,see Gropp, Kok Srensen, and Lichtenberger (2007). As for the heterogeneity inthe degree of pass-through, see Kok Srensen and Werner (2006).

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    7/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 83

    3.1 Households

    The one-period utility function of a representative household is given

    as

    Ut = u(Ct; t)

    10

    v(Lt(i))di

    =(tCt)

    1

    1

    10

    Lt(i)1+

    1 + di,

    where Ct 1

    0 Ct(j)

    1

    dj 1

    , and Ct(j) and Lt(i) are the con-sumption of differentiated good j and hours worked at intermediate-goods firm in region i, respectively. Henceforth, index i is usedto denote a specific region as well as the variety of intermediategoods. Since there is only one intermediate-goods firm in each region,this usage is innocuous. t represents a preference shock with meanunity, and (>1) denotes the elasticity of substitution between thevariety of goods. It can be shown that the optimization of the

    allocation of consumption goods yields the aggregate price indexPt

    10

    Pt(j)1dj

    11

    .

    Assume that the household is required to use cash in pur-chasing consumption goods. At the beginning of period t, theamount of cash available for the purchase of consumption goods

    is Mt1 +10

    Wt(i)Lt(i)di10

    Dt(i)di, where Mt1 is the nominal

    balance held from period t 1 to t, and

    1

    0Wt(i)Lt(i)di represents

    the total wage income paid in advance by intermediate-goods firms.The household also makes a one-period deposit Dt(i) in commercialbank i, the interest on which (Rt) is paid at the end of the period. Itis assumed that the household has deposits in all of the commercialbanks. Accordingly, the following cash-in-advance constraint mustbe satisfied at the beginning of period t:7

    1

    0

    Pt(j)Ct(j)dj Mt1 + 1

    0

    Wt(i)Lt(i)di 1

    0

    Dt(i)di.

    7With this specification, it is implicitly assumed that financial markets openbefore the goods market.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    8/42

    84 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    The households budget constraint is given by

    Mt = Mt1 +

    1

    0

    Wt(i)Lt(i)di

    1

    0

    Dt(i)di

    1

    0

    Pt(j)Ct(j)dj

    + Rt

    10

    Dt(i)di + t Tt,

    where t denotes the sum of profits transferred from firms andcommercial banks, and Tt is a lump-sum tax.

    The demand for good j is expressed as

    Ct(j) =

    Pt(j)

    Pt

    Ct. (1)

    The budget constraint can then be rewritten as

    Mt = Mt1 +10 W

    t(i)Lt(i)di10 D

    t(i)di PtCt

    + Rt

    10

    Dt(i)di + t Tt.

    In an equilibrium with a positive interest rate, the followingequality must hold:

    PtCt = Mt1 +

    1

    0

    Wt(i)Lt(i)di

    1

    0

    Dt(i)di. (2)

    This implies that the amount of total consumption expenditure isequal to cash holdings as long as there is an opportunity cost of hold-

    ing cash. Then, the budget constraint leads to Mt = Rt10

    Dt(i)di +t Tt. Eliminating the money term from equation (2) yields analternative expression of the budget constraint:

    PtCt = Rt1

    10

    Dt1(i)di+

    10

    Wt(i)Lt(i)di

    10

    Dt(i)di+t1Tt1.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    9/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 85

    The first-order conditions for the households optimization prob-lem are

    1t Ct

    Pt= RtEt

    1t+1 C

    t+1

    Pt+1

    , (3)

    Wt(i)

    Pt=

    Lt(i)

    1t Ct

    , (4)

    where and Et are the subjective discount factor and the expecta-tions operator conditional on information in period t, respectively.

    3.2 Intermediate-Goods Firms

    Intermediate-goods firm i (0, 1) produces a differentiated interme-diate good, Zt(i), by using the labor force of type i as the sole input.The production function is simply given by

    Zt(i) = AtLt(i), (5)

    where At is a countrywide productivity shock with mean unity.The owners of intermediate-goods firms must pay wage bills beforegoods markets open. Specifically, the owner of firm i borrows funds,Wt(i)Lt(i), from commercial bank i at the beginning of period tat a gross nominal interest rate Rit. At the end of the period,intermediate-goods firm i must repay RitWt(i)Lt(i) to bank i, so thatthe nominal marginal cost for firm i leads to M Ct(i) = R

    itWt(i)/At.

    Here, it is assumed that firm i can borrow funds only from the

    regional bank i since loan markets are geographically segmented.This assumption prohibits arbitrages, and thereby lending rates areallowed to differ across regional banks. Although such a situationmight overly emphasize the role of the financial markets segmenta-tion, a number of studies have found evidence of lending rate dis-persion across intranational and international regions that cannotbe explained by differences in riskiness.8

    8For instance, see Berger, Kashyap, and Scalise (1995), Davis (1995), andDriscoll (2004) for the United States and Buch (2001) for the euro area. Buch(2000) provides a survey of the literature on lending-market segmentation in theUnited States.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    10/42

    86 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    It is assumed for simplicity that intermediate-goods firms areable to set prices flexibly. The price of Zt(i) will then be given by

    Pzt (i) =z

    (z 1)(1 + m)

    RitWt(i)

    At, (6)

    where m is a subsidy rate imposed by the government in such away that zR/[(z 1)(1 +

    m)] = 1. It should be noted that sinceintermediate-goods firms borrow funds, the borrowing rates becomean additional production cost. Thus, a rise in borrowing rates has adirect effect of increasing intermediate-goods prices.9 Note also thatsince borrowing rates are allowed to differ across firms, it wouldbecome a source of price dispersion.

    3.3 Final-Goods Firms

    Each final-goods firm uses a composite of intermediate goods as theinput for production. The production function is given by

    Yt(j) =

    10

    Zjt (i)z1z di

    zz1

    , z > 1,

    where Yt(j) and Zjt (i) represent a differentiated consumption good

    and the firm js demand for individual intermediate good i, respec-tively. Optimization regarding the allocation of inputs yields the

    price index Pzt 1

    0Pzt (i)

    1zdi 11z

    . Accordingly, the firm js

    demand for intermediate good i is expressed as follows:

    9m eliminates the distortions stemming both from monopolistic power and apositive steady-state interest rate (R). Here, a positive steady-state interest rateis distortionary since the marginal cost would no longer be equal to v/u.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    11/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 87

    Zjt (i) =

    Pzt (i)

    Pzt

    z

    Yt(j).

    Since Zt(i) =10

    Zjt (i)dj must hold in equilibrium, the demandfunction leads to

    Zt(i) =

    Pzt (i)

    Pzt

    z 1

    0

    Yt(j)dj

    = Pzt (i)

    Pz

    tz

    YtVyt , (7)

    where Yt 1

    0Yt(j)

    1 dj

    1

    and Vyt 10

    (Yt(j)/Yt)dj. Note that

    Vyt becomes larger than unity if Yt = Yt(j) for some j.It is assumed that final-goods firms are unable to adjust prices

    freely. Following Calvo (1983), we consider a situation in which afraction 1 of firms can change their prices, while the remain-

    ing fraction cannot. The price-setting problem of final-goods firmsleads to

    maxPt

    Et

    s=0

    st,t+s

    (1 + f)Pt Pzt+s

    PtPt+s

    Ct+s, (8)

    where Pt is the price of final goods set by firms that can adjust prices

    in period t, and t,t+s s u

    (Ct+s;t+s)Ptu(Ct;t)Pt+s denotes the stochastic dis-

    count factor up to period t + s. f represents a subsidy rate, wheref = 1/( 1).10

    Log-linearizing the resultant first-order condition leads to

    t = Ett+1 + Fpzt pt

    , (9)

    10Note that firms that can adjust prices in the same period set an identicalprice. Although different intermediate-goods firms may set different prices, mar-ginal costs for final-goods firms are identical since the allocations of intermediateinputs are the same.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    12/42

    88 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    where F (1)(1)/ and t ptpt1. Henceforth, for anarbitrary variable Xt, xt log(Xt/X), where X denotes the steady-

    state value. Equation (9) is a version of the New Keynesian Phillipscurve that has been used in numerous recent studies. Note that theterm pzt pt is equivalent to the real marginal cost of producing afinal good, which is common across firms. Evidently, pzt pt becomeszero if final-goods prices are fully flexible.

    3.4 Financial Intermediary

    Intermediate-goods firm i needs to borrow funds from commercial

    bank i at the start of each period in order to compensate for wagebills that must be paid in advance. At the beginning of period t,commercial bank i receives deposit Dt(i) and money injectionMtMt1 Mt from the household and the central bank, respec-tively. The former becomes the liability of the commercial bank,while the latter corresponds to its net worth. On the other hand,commercial bank i lends funds, Wt(i)Lt(i), to intermediate-goodsfirm i. Therefore, the following equality must hold in equilibrium:

    Dt(i) + Mt = Wt(i)Lt(i), i (0, 1). (10)

    The left-hand side and right-hand side can also be interpreted asrepresenting the supply and the demand for funds, respectively. Atthe end of the period, commercial bank i repays its principle plusinterest, Rt(Wt(i)Lt(i) Mt), to the household. The householdalso indirectly receives the money injection from the central bankthrough the profit transfer from commercial banks.

    As is shown in appendix 1, firm is demand for funds can beexpressed as

    Wt(i)Lt(i) = (Rit)

    (1+)z1+z t

    Rit; t

    ,

    where t is a function of aggregate variables that individual firmsand commercial banks take as given. Obviously, firm is demand forfunds, (Rit; t), decreases in R

    it since an increase in R

    it raises the

    marginal costs and thereby reduces its production.Now let us specify the profit-maximization problem of commer-

    cial banks. It is assumed here that in each period, each commercialbank can adjust its loan rate with probability 1 q. The probability

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    13/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 89

    of adjustment is independent of the time between adjustments. Theproblem for commercial bank i is then given by

    maxRit

    Et

    s=0

    qst,t+s

    (1 + b)Rit

    Rit; t+sRt+s

    Rit; t+s

    ,

    (11)

    where b represents a subsidy rate such that (1 + )z/[(z 1)(1 +b)] = 1. The commercial bank in region i takes into account theeffect of a change in Rit on Wt(i)Lt(i), while taking as given Pt, P

    zt ,

    Yt, Ct, Vyt , Mt, and Rt. The second term in the square bracket

    is according to the equilibrium condition (10), which implies that,given the value of Mt, a change in Wt(i)Lt(i) must be followed bythe same amount of change in Dt(i).

    It can be shown that the first-order condition for this problem isgiven by

    Et

    s=0(q)s

    Ct+s1t+s t+s

    Pt+s Rit Rt+s

    = 0.

    Log-linearizing this condition yields

    rit = rt = (1 q)Et

    s=0

    (q)srt+s. (12)

    This optimality condition implies that all the commercial banks thatadjust in the same period impose an identical loan rate, rt. It should

    be pointed out that the newly adjusted loan rates depend largely onthe expectations of future policy rate as well as the current policyrate. The weight on the current policy rate is only 1 q, whilethe weights on future policy rates sum up to q. This is the well-known forward-looking property stemming from staggered pricing.If one interprets the banks problem as price determination underconventional Calvo pricing, the value of q is simply considered asrepresenting the degree of stickiness. From a different point of view,however, the newly adjusted loan rates expressed as (12) could beregarded as an outcome of a long-term contract, where commercialbanks lend funds by charging a fixed interest rate with the provisothat there is a possibility of revaluation with probability 1 q. In

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    14/42

    90 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    this case, the length of maturity is expressed as a random variablethat has a geometric distribution with parameter 1 q. In fact, as

    is shown below, there is a close relation between the newly adjustedloan rates and long-term market interest rates.In order to obtain model-consistent long-term interest rates, sup-

    pose for the moment that the length of maturity is known withcertainty. The representative commercial banks problem for thedetermination of an n-period loan rate will be given by11

    maxRn,t

    Et

    n1

    s=0

    t,t+s[(1 + b)Rn,t(Rn,t; t+s) Rt+s(Rn,t; t+s)].

    The first-order condition is

    Et

    n1s=0

    sCt+s

    1t+s t+s

    Pt+s(Rn,t Rt+s) = 0.

    It follows that

    rn,t =

    n1s=0

    s

    1

    Etn1s=0

    srt+s. (13)

    While this is an expression of loan rates of maturity-n, this canalso be interpreted as the n-period market interest rates since thebank will set rn,t in such a way that the expected return equalsthe expected cost as long as there are neither adjustment costs nordefault risk.12 Because the bank faces no uncertainty in regard tothe length of periods between adjustments, rn,t must be an effi-cient estimate of the per-period cost of funds from period t to t + n.Unsurprisingly, this endogenously derived relation, (13), takes a formknown as the expectations theory of the term structure. Here, theconsumers subjective discount factor, , is used as the discountfactor on expected future short-term rates.

    11Index i is now dropped for brevity since the following hypothetical problem

    is common to all banks.12In order to consider a competitive equilibrium of market interest rates, dis-

    tortion stemming from the monopolistic market power is removed by governmentsubsidies.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    15/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 91

    Figure 1. Weights on Long-Term Interest Rates

    Using expression (13), we can present the following proposition.

    Proposition 1. If the n-period market interest rate is written as(13), then the newly adjusted loan rates, rt, can be expressed as

    rt = (1 q)(1 q)(rt + 1r2,t + 2r3,t + . . .),

    where k =qk(1k+1)

    1 for k 0, and

    k=0 k = ((1q)(1q))1.

    Moreover, k+1 < k holds for all k 0 if and only if q < (1 + )1.

    Proof. See appendix 2.

    This proposition states that the newly adjusted loan rate can beexpressed as a weighted average of long-term market interest rates ofvarious maturities. It turns out that the weights on long-term ratesare largely dependent on the probability of revaluation.13 Figure 1illustrates examples ofs. As is clear from the figure, the weights onshort-term rates decrease with larger q. This reflects the fact thatthe currently adjusted loan rates will be expected to live for longerperiods as the revaluation probability becomes lower.

    13Interestingly, if one interprets as the time-varying discount factor, it takesa form of hyperbolic discounting, where the discount rate itself decreases as thematurity increases.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    16/42

    92 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    4. Equilibrium Dynamics

    Before proceeding, let us summarize the key equilibrium relationsin preparation for succeeding analyses. Appendix 3 shows that thereal marginal cost of final-goods firms, pzt pt, can be expressed as

    pzt pt = rlt + ( + )xt, where r

    lt and xt denote an average loan rate

    and an output gap, respectively. The New Keynesian Phillips curve(NKPC) can thus be written as

    t = Ett+1 + F( + )xt + Frlt. (14)

    As was pointed out by Ravenna and Walsh (2006), the differencebetween the standard NKPC and the NKPC with the cost-channeleffect lies in the presence of an additional interest rate term. Yet,our expression differs from theirs in that the interest term in (14)is expressed by the average loan rate, not by the policy rate. Sinceour model incorporates profit-maximization behavior of commercialbanks, retail loan rates are distinguished from the policy instrument

    in an endogenous manner.14

    It turns out that the average loan rate,rlt, becomes a determinant of inflation because a rise in the averageloan rate leads to a higher marginal cost for final-goods production.

    An obvious outcome of this modification is that as long as q > 0,the cost-channel effect is weakened compared with the case of per-fect pass-through. This is not only because only a fraction (1 q)of commercial banks reset their loan rates each period, but alsobecause a newly charged loan rate differs from the policy rate in thatperiod. Since the correlation between the policy rate and the mar-ginal cost of intermediate-goods firms becomes weaker as q increases,the influence of a policy shift on final-goods prices will be reducedaccordingly.15

    14Chowdhury, Hoffmann, and Schabert (2006) also make distinctions between amoney-market rate and a lending rate in a model similar to ours, but their distinc-tion depends fully on the assumption that there exists a proportional relationshipbetween the two interest rates.

    15Recently, Tillmann (2007) estimated the NKPC of the form (14) using thedata for the United States, the United Kingdom, and the euro area. He showedthat inflation dynamics can be better explained if the short-term rate thatappeared in the Ravenna-Walsh NKPC is replaced with lending rates.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    17/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 93

    The standard aggregate demand equation can be obtained bylog-linearizing the Euler equation (3):

    xt = Etxt+1 1

    rt Ett+1 rr

    nt

    , (15)

    where rrnt ((1+)/(+))Etat+1+((1)/(+))Ett+1)

    denotes the natural rate of real interest, where t log(t).Now we turn our attention to the determination of the average

    loan rate. By the nature of commercial banks loan rate setting, theaverage loan rate is given by

    rlt = qrlt1 + (1 q)rt.

    The current average loan rate can be expressed as a weighted aver-age of the newly adjusted loan rate and the previous average loanrate. Eliminating rt from (12) yields

    rlt = Etrlt+1 + B

    rt r

    lt

    , (16)

    where rlt rlt r

    lt1 and B (1 q)(1 q)/q. Equation (16)

    says that a shift in the average loan rate will be caused by a discrep-ancy between the policy rate and the average loan rate as well asa change in the expectation of future loan rate. This equation canalso be written as

    rlt =

    1 + + BEtr

    lt+1 +

    B1 + + B

    rt +1

    1 + + Brlt1.

    Intuitively, the average loan rate is expressed as a weighted averageof the expected loan rate, the current policy rate, and the previous

    loan rate.16 It states that the relative weights on the expected loanrate and the previous loan rate increase as the sluggishness of loanrates deteriorates. Conversely, the current loan rate approaches thecurrent policy rate as q goes to zero.

    In an environment where the central bank controls rt, equations(14), (15), and (16) and a policy rule describe the behavior of , x,rl, and r. We next explore the central banks optimal policy ratesetting in the following sections.

    16After I finished writing this paper, I found that Teranishi (2008) also obtainedsimilar results in a different setting. We arrived at the similar results completelyindependently of each other.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    18/42

    94 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    5. Social Welfare

    This section attempts to obtain a welfare-based objective functionfor monetary policy by approximating the households utility func-tion up to a second order. Appendix 4 shows that the one-periodutility function can be approximated as

    Ut =L1+

    2( + )

    x2t +

    +

    varjpt(j)

    + z

    (1 + z)( + )

    varir

    i

    t

    + t.i.p., (17)

    where an upper bar means that the variable denotes the correspond-ing steady-state value, and t.i.p. represents terms that are indepen-dent of policy, including terms higher than or equal to third order.A notable feature of equation (17) is the presence of the variance ofloan rates. This result is quite intuitive given that the determinationof loan rates is specified as Calvo-type pricing. Equation (17) reveals

    that the variance of lending rates reduces social welfare in the samemanner as the variance of final-goods prices does.

    Woodford (2001, 2223) shows that the present discounted valueof the variance of prices can be expressed in terms of inflationsquared. That is,

    s=0

    svarjpt+s(j) = 1F

    s=0

    s2t+s.

    It is straightforward to apply this result to rewriting the presentdiscounted value of the variance of lending rates. It follows that

    s=0

    svaririt+s =

    1B

    s=0

    s

    rlt+s2

    .

    It turns out that the present discounted value of the variance oflending rates can be expressed in terms of a change in the averageloan rate.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    19/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 95

    Consequently, the social welfare function can be rewritten as

    Et

    s=0

    sUt+s = L

    1+

    2 ( + )Et

    s=0

    s

    x2t+s + 2t+s

    + r

    rlt+s2

    + t.i.p., (18)

    where /[F(+)] and r z/[B(1+z)(+)] representthe relative weights on inflation and the rate of change in the averageloan rate, respectively. Equation (18) states that fluctuations in theaverage loan rate will reduce social welfare when commercial banks

    adjust loan rates only infrequently. This finding is closely parallel toa well-known result obtained under staggered goods prices. Understaggered goods prices, the rate of inflation enters into the welfarefunction because a nonzero inflation gives rise to price dispersion.Under staggered loan rate contracts, the rate of change in the aver-age loan rate enters into the welfare function because changes in theaverage loan rate inevitably entail loan rate dispersion.

    It might also be noted that equation (18) closely resembles a

    conventional loss function that has been frequently employed inthe recent literature on monetary policy for the purpose of cap-turing actual central banks interest rate smoothing (i.e., policy ratesmoothing) behavior. Specifically, in many previous studies it hasbeen assumed that a monetary authority tries to minimize a lossfunction of the form17

    Lossct = x2t +

    2t + (rt)

    2.

    This expression essentially differs from ours in that the third term isexpressed in terms of the policy instrument rather than the averageloan rate. Here, the relation between rt and r

    lt can be written

    from proposition 1 as

    rlt = (1 q)(1 q)2[rt + 1r2,t + . . .

    + q(rt1 + 1r2,t1 + . . .) + . . .].

    17See, for example, Rudebusch and Svensson (1999), Rudebusch (2002a,2002b), Levin and Williams (2003), and Ellingsen and Soderstrom (2004). SeeSack and Wieland (2000) and Rudebusch (2006) for a survey of studies on interestrate smoothing.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    20/42

    96 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    Thus, rt constitutes only a fraction (1q)(1q)2 of rlt. The rest

    of the components of rlt are expressed by the past policy shifts and

    the current and past changes in long-term rates. Notice that equa-tion (18) and the conventional loss function never coincide sincethe loan rate smoothing term will disappear in the limiting case ofq = 0, where rlt = rt holds. Nevertheless, the desirability of policyrate smoothing might be retained in that it contributes to the sta-bilization of loan rates through the stabilization of long-term rates.A further discussion about the relationship between loan rate stabi-lization and the central banks policy rate smoothing will be givenin the next section.

    6. Monetary Policy in the Presence of Loan RateStickiness

    This section attempts to explore desirable monetary policy in thepresence of incomplete interest rate pass-through, focusing on thequestion of how the desirable path of the policy rate will be mod-

    ified once loan rate stickiness is taken into account. Provided thatthe central bank tries to maximize social welfare function (18), thepresence of loan rate stickiness affects inflation and output throughtwo channels. On one hand, the presence of loan rate stickiness mit-igates the cost-channel effect of a policy shift on inflation. On theother hand, the central bank has to put some weight on loan ratestabilization in the face of loan rate stickiness. It is shown belowthat the former effect tends to reduce the desirability of policy rate

    smoothing since there is less need for the central bank to pay atten-tion to the undesirable effect that a policy shift has on inflation.In contrast, the latter effect increases the desirability of policy ratesmoothing since the stabilization of the policy rate leads, at least tosome extent, to loan rate stability. These two aspects are thoroughlyexamined in the succeeding subsections.

    In the following, we consider two alternative policy regimes: stan-dard Taylor rule and commitment under a timeless perspective. Inaddition, we also investigate optimal policy in the face of a loan pre-mium shock, which directly alters the markup in loan rate pricing. Itis shown that the role of the loan rate stability term depends largelyon the underlying nature of shocks.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    21/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 97

    6.1 Baseline Parameters

    The baseline parameters used in the analysis are as follows: = .99,

    = 1.5, = 1 (Ravenna and Walsh 2006), and = 7.88 (Rotembergand Woodford 1997). We set the elasticity of substitution for inter-mediate goods at the value equal to , thus z = 7.88. Following Galand Monacelli (2005), we specify the process of productivity shock asat = .66at1 +

    at , where the standard deviation of

    at is set at .007.

    As for the preference shock, we specify the process as t = .5t1+t ,

    where the standard deviation of t is set at .005.18 The degree of

    price stickiness, , is chosen such that the slope of the Phillips curve

    is equal to .58, the value reported by Lubik and Schorfheide (2004).It follows that = .623 ((1 )(1 )( + )/ = .58), whichleads to = 13.582.

    As mentioned in section 2, recent studies reported different esti-mates of the degree of loan rate pass-through at the euro-area aggre-gated level. Here, three alternative values are considered: qL, qM, andqH. According to table 1 of de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005), thelowest value of the estimated degree of loan rate pass-through for

    short-term loans to enterprises is .25 (Sander and Kleimeier 2002;Hofmann 2003), while the largest one is .76 (Heinemann and Schuler2002). Since these estimates are obtained from monthly data, wehave to convert them to their quarterly counterparts. For example,in the case of the largest degree of pass-through, qL is set such that1 qL = .76+(1 .76).76+(1 .76)

    2.76, which leads to qL = .014.Likewise, qH is set at .422. Finally, qM is set at .177, the averageof all the estimates reported by thirteen studies cited in table 1 ofde Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005). This implies that the relativeweight on the loan rate, r, is .445, .092, and .005 if q = qH, qM,and qL, respectively.

    6.2 Policy Rate Smoothing and the Degree of Interest Rate

    Pass-Through

    Before investigating optimal policy, it should be pointed out thatthe degree of interest rate pass-through is heavily dependent on the

    18The essential results shown below will never change in the absence of thepreference shock.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    22/42

    98 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    policy rate behavior. The impact of a policy shift on retail loanrates can vary not only with the frequency of loan rate adjustments

    but also with the expectation of future policies. It is useful to gain abetter understanding of the relation between policy rate smoothnessand the degree of interest rate pass-through.

    Suppose for exposition that the policy rule is expressed as

    rt+1 = rt + t+1,

    where [0, 1) describes the degree of policy rate inertia. t+1 isa white noise, which represents an unpredictable component of the

    policy rate. Then, the average loan rate is given as

    rlt =(1 q)(1 q)

    1 qrt + qr

    lt1.

    In this case, the degree of instantaneous interest rate pass-throughcan be expressed as

    rlt

    rt=

    (1 q)(1 q)

    1 q

    .

    This implies that the impact of a policy shift on the current averageloan rate will become larger as the degree of policy inertia increases.

    More generally, it can be shown that the impact of a currentpolicy shift on the s-period-ahead average loan rate leads to

    rlt+srt

    =(1 q)(1 q)(s+1 qs+1)

    (1 q)( q).

    Accordingly, the degree ofcumulative interest rate pass-through canbe given as

    s=0

    rlt+srt

    =1 q

    (1 q)(1 ).

    Notice that under an inertial policy rule, current policy rate has animpact on future average loan rate not only through the persistentdynamics in the average loan rate but also through the policy ratedynamics itself. Since commercial banks loan rate determination ismade in a forward-looking manner, a policy shift can have a largerimpact on loan rates as the shift becomes more persistent.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    23/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 99

    Figure 2. Responses of the Average Loan Rate and thePolicy Rate under Alternative Policy Rules

    Now, let us reexamine the above implications by using a moregeneral policy rule. We employ the following standard Taylor rule:

    rt = rt1 + (1 )

    rrt + t + (x/4)xt

    , (19)

    where and x are set at 1.5 and .5, respectively. is set at .9under an inertial policy, while = 0 under a non-inertial policy.Figure 2 illustrates impulse responses to a one-standard-deviationproductivity shock.19 The figure shows that there is an appreciabledifference between the two cases in the reaction of the average loanrate to the policy rate. Under the inertial policy rule, the paths of rtand rlt are shown to be very close. Specifically, the spread betweenthe two paths on impact is only .02 percent, where the instanta-neous interest rate pass-through turns out to be 84.2 percent. Underthe non-inertial policy rule, on the other hand, the initial spreadamounts to .34 percent, where the instantaneous interest rate pass-

    through is 77.3 percent. Thus, the property that a lagged policy rate

    19Henceforth, interest rate responses are illustrated in annual rate.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    24/42

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    25/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 101

    available at that time.20 It should be noted that not only expecta-tion errors in the current period but also expectation errors made in

    the past cause a change in the current average loan rate. The rea-son for this is as follows: suppose that the policy rate has not beenchanged since m periods ago, and the last policy shift had not beenanticipated at that time. In the current period, given that the policyrate is still expected to be constant in the future, loan rates betweenthe ages of 1 and m need not be changed even if they have a chanceof adjustment, because the last policy shift is already incorporated.In contrast, loan rates that have not been adjusted for the past mperiods need to be readjusted in the current period since they havenot yet incorporated the unexpected policy shift that occurred mperiods ago. Since a certain fraction of all the loan rates is neces-sarily over the age of m, their readjustments inevitably occur andcause a shift in the current average loan rate.

    It is evident that once the central bank changes the policy rate,the resultant loan rate readjustments will persist forever. These loanrate readjustments will never end, even if the policy rate is (and isexpected to be) kept unchanged from then on. However, such per-

    sistent effects would be alleviated if the policy shift was correctlyanticipated in advance. Of course, even if a policy shift is incor-porated in advance, a revision of expectation necessarily occurs atleast to some extent (unless the entire policy rate path was fullyincorporated at the initial period). Nevertheless, the extent of anexpectation revision can be made smaller as the timing of incorpo-ration becomes earlier since the corresponding adjustments of loanrates will be dispersed over some periods. In this sense, it could be

    said that the forecastability of future policy rates becomes anotherkey to loan rate stability. Policy rate smoothing will contribute toloan rate stability by revealing some information regarding futurepolicy rates.21

    20In fact, Svensson (2003) notes that the central bank should minimize thesurprise in the policy rate. He proposed the (ad hoc) central banks loss functionof the form Lt = V ar(xt) + V ar(t) + V ar(Et1rt rt).

    21The necessity of the central banks communicability is stressed by Kleimeier

    and Sander (2006). They argue that the impact of policy rate shifts on retaillending rates tends to be large in countries in which the central bank communi-cates well with the public. See also Woodford (2005) for a discussion of centralbank communication.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    26/42

    102 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    6.3 The Role of the Loan Rate Stabilization Term

    In this section, we address the issue of how the presence of a loan

    rate stabilization term, r(rlt)2, affects the desirable policy. To thisend, we especially focus on its relation with conventional policy ratesmoothing or policy inertia. In investigating policy inertia under var-ious degrees of loan rate stickiness, we have to explicitly distinguishbetween policy inertia and intrinsic inertia. To isolate policy inertia,we need to know to what extent current policymaking depends onthe previous policy decision. Thus, we measure here the desirabledegree of policy inertia by the size of the coefficient on the lagged

    policy rate in the case of a simple rule, and by the size of the relativeweight on the policy rate smoothing term in the case of commitment.

    6.3.1 Simple Rule

    As a policy rule, we again employ (19). Here, optimal combinationsof (, , x) are searched for under alternative values of q, , andr. Since we want to know the effects of introducing the loan ratestabilization term on the optimal value of , the relative weight on

    the loan rate, r, is set either at the endogenously determined valueor at zero.

    Optimal combinations of (, , x) are given in table 1.22 It

    shows that, given the values of q and , the optimal value of

    Table 1. Optimal Combinations of (, , x)

    (, r) (13.58, r) (13.58, 0) (4, r) (4, 0)

    q = qL (.35, 3, 0) (.35, 3, 0) (.35, 1, 0) (.35, 1, 0)Relative Lossa 1.225 1.225 1.004 1.004q = qM (.35, 3, 0) (.35, 3, 0) (.4, 1.65, 0) (.35, 1.15, 0)Relative Loss 1.116 1.116 1.004 1.008q = qH (.3, 3, 0) (.25, 3, 0) (.4, 2.6, 0) (.35, 3, 0)Relative Loss 1.027 1.054 1.021 1.046

    aThe denominator of relative loss is the value of social loss that would be attained

    under commitment policy with the appropriate loan rate smoothing objective.

    22The examined parameter ranges are as follows: [0, .95] for , [0, 3] for ,and [0, 1] for x. The increment size of the grid is .05.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    27/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 103

    under loan rate stabilization is greater than or equal to that underr = 0. This implies that the introduction of a loan rate smoothing

    term into the welfare function tends to strengthen the desirability ofpolicy rate smoothing, although this smoothing effect seems to belimited, especially when loan rate stickiness is not severe. This argu-ment is also confirmed by the value of social loss under an optimalpolicy rule relative to the loss under timeless commitment. It turnsout that the cost of putting a too-small weight on the previouspolicy rate is at most 2.6 percent.

    6.3.2 Commitment

    Next, let us turn to the case of commitment. Under commitment,the central bank is assumed to minimize a given loss function. Inorder to investigate the desirability of policy inertia, we specify herethe central banks one-period loss function as follows:

    Lsmootht = x2t +

    2t + r(rt)

    2.

    In this case, the value of r that minimizes social loss can be

    interpreted as a proxy for the optimal degree of policy inertia.The optimal values of r under alternative values ofq are shown

    in table 2. It shows that as long as the value of q is not that small,the optimal value of r tends to be larger under loan rate stabiliza-tion than under r = 0. This reconfirms the previous result that theintroduction of a loan rate stabilization term justifies conventionalpolicy rate smoothing. However, the quantitative importance of thissmoothing effect is again not very large. The cost of ignoring policy

    rate stability is at most 3.6 percent.

    Table 2. Optimal Weights on (rt)2

    (, r) (13.58, r) (13.58, 0) (4, r) (4, 0)

    q = qL 0 0 0 0Relative Loss 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000q = qM .05 0 .05 0

    Relative Loss 1.001 1.014 1.001 1.026q = qH .05 0 .05 0Relative Loss 1.007 1.026 1.014 1.051

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    28/42

    104 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    Figure 3. Policy Rate Responses under Commitment

    Figure 3 illustrates the policy rate responses under timeless com-mitment. It turns out that the optimal policy rate responses under

    alternative values ofq differ only slightly. Nevertheless, it can be saidfrom the figure that the initial reduction of the policy rate is largest(smallest) when q = qH (qL). This is because an increase in q mit-igates the cost-channel effect, the direct impact of a policy changeon inflation. A reduction in the policy rate is needed in the face of apositive productivity or preference shock, but such an expansionarypolicy necessarily entails a negative effect on inflation due to thepresence of the cost channel. As q increases, however, such an unde-

    sirable aspect becomes less important, and thereby the central bankcan set the policy rate at a level closer to the natural rate of interest.The figures show that the cost-channel effect is quantitatively moreinfluential than the policy rate smoothing effect, which stems fromthe change in the value of r.

    In order to clarify the strength of the policy rate smoothing effect,figure 4 illustrates policy rate responses under commitment with andwithout loan rate smoothing.23 It can be confirmed that the initialreduction in the policy rate is smaller in the presence of loan rate

    23The obtained results are essentially the same in the case of a preference shockas well.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    29/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 105

    Figure 4. Policy Rate Responses to a Productivity Shock

    stabilization. As expected, however, the difference between the twocases is not significantly different.

    In summary, in the face of a productivity shock and/or a prefer-ence shock, the presence of a loan rate stabilization term itself sup-ports, to some extent, the idea of conventional policy rate smooth-

    ing. However, it appears that the optimal policy is more stronglyinfluenced by the cost-channel effect than the policy rate smoothingeffect that stems from the presence of a loan rate stabilization term.In the next section, we reexamine the role of loan rate stabilizationby introducing a loan rate premium shock, which directly changesthe markup in loan rates.

    6.4 Undesirability of Policy Rate Smoothing: The Case of a

    Loan Rate Premium ShockIn the above analysis, we investigated the optimal policy responsein the face of a productivity shock or a preference shock. In such

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    30/42

    106 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    an environment, retail loan rates are determined solely by the pol-icy rate, although those shocks have an indirect influence through

    the policy rate. In practice, however, it is usual for loan rates tofluctuate for reasons that are not directly linked to the policy ratebehavior. One possible case is a shift in the loan rate premium trig-gered by changes in financial market conditions. While here we donot emphasize a particular cause of loan premium fluctuations, opti-mal policy in the face of such kinds of shocks is worth considering.A loan rate premium shock can be introduced by modifying thefirst-order condition of the commercial banks problem as follows:

    Ets=0

    (q)sCt+s1t+s t+s

    Pt+s

    Rit t+sRt+s

    = 0,

    where t+s > 0 and E[t+s] = 1. It follows that

    rlt = Etrlt+1 + B

    rt r

    lt

    + Bt,

    where t log(t). t is actually a shock to the change in the loan

    rate but can also be interpreted as a shock to the level of the loanrate once redefined as t B

    1+B+t.

    24

    Figure 5 illustrates optimal policy rate responses under commit-ment to a 1 percent (at the annual rate) positive loan rate premiumshock. It is assumed that this shock is a temporary one. It clearlyshows that the presence of a loan rate stabilization term now plays acritical role in the conduct of monetary policy. Under optimal poli-cies with a loan rate stabilization objective, the policy rate needs tobe drastically reduced in the face of a rise in the loan rate premium.This is because a reduction in rt can partially offset a rise in t,as is evident from the above equation. On the other hand, such adrastic policy rate reduction cannot be observed when the central

    24Another way of introducing an exogenous loan rate shock is to assume atime-varying subsidy rate, bt . Provided that E[

    bt+s] =

    b, then the modifiedloan rate adjustment equation leads to

    rlt = Etrl

    t+1 + B

    rt rl

    t

    B bt ,

    where bt = log((1 + bt )/(1 +

    b)). In this case, a below-the-average subsidy ratewill act as a positive loan rate shock. See also Woodford (2003, ch. 6) for adiscussion of time-varying markups in goods prices.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    31/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 107

    Figure 5. Impulse Responses to a 1 Percent LoanPremium Shock

    bank conducts optimal policy rate smoothing, which is incorrectfrom the point of view of welfare maximization. In fact, since theoptimal weight on the policy rate is very small (.05), this result willalso hold even in the case where the central bank pays no attentionto policy rate smoothing.

    Figure 5 also illustrates the behavior of the average loan rate.As is clear from the figure, the response of the average loan rate is

    mitigated as q increases, since the fraction of newly adjusted loanrates declines. Along with this, the required amount of policy ratereduction turns out to be smaller under q = qH than under q = qM.Although a rise in q has the effect of requiring more drastic policyshifts by increasing the size of the relative weight on the loan rate,such an effect is relatively small.

    To sum up, the role of a loan rate stabilization term fundamen-tally alters according to the underlying nature of shocks. In the faceof a shock that would directly shift inflation and output, the presenceof the loan rate stabilization objective itself requires inertial policy.This is because loan rates are determined based only on the policyrate, in which case the only way to avoid fluctuations in loan rates is

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    32/42

    108 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    to avoid fluctuations in the policy rate. However, a shock that woulddirectly give rise to loan rate fluctuations should be dampened by

    a drastic policy shift. Policy rate smoothing is not needed (and infact is even harmful) when there is requirement for loan rate stabi-lization. From this point of view, it can be said that conventionalpolicy rate smoothing is no longer a panacea. The case of a loanrate premium shock is an example for which policy rate smoothingshould be abandoned.

    7. Concluding Remarks

    The main findings of this paper can be summarized as follows. First,when the pass-through from the policy rate to retail loan rates isincomplete, fluctuations in the average loan rate will reduce socialwelfare. This is because shifts in the average loan rate immediatelygive rise to a loan rate dispersion across firms, which ultimatelyyields an inefficient dispersion in hours worked. Accordingly, the cen-tral bank faces a policy trade-off in stabilizing inflation, an outputgap, and the rate of change in the average loan rate.

    Second, the introduction of a loan rate stabilization term in thecentral banks loss function causes the optimal policy rate to becomemore inertial in the face of a productivity shock and a preferenceshock. In this sense, loan rate smoothing is closely parallel to con-ventional policy rate smoothing. However, such a smoothing effectturned out to be less influential than the cost-channel effect.

    Third, the presence of a loan rate stabilization term requires adrastic policy reaction in the face of an exogenous shock that directly

    shifts retail lending rates, such as a shift in the loan rate premium.This result is counter to the conventional wisdom that the policyrate must be adjusted gradually in short steps. However, given thefact that the standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium modelusually ignored the cost of loan rate dispersion, this disagreement isnot so surprising. The case of a loan premium shock is an examplefor which the central bank has to clearly distinguish between policyrate smoothing and loan rate smoothing.

    We conclude by noting several points that should be addressedin future research. First, a more realistic framework for long-terminterest contracts should be introduced. In the present paper, loanrate determination is specified as Calvo-type pricing. However, a

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    33/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 109

    more plausible situation would be that the length of maturity isdetermined at the time of contract and is allowed to differ across bor-

    rowers. Second, although our model treats the frequency of loan rateadjustments as exogenous, there is a possibility that the frequency ofloan rate adjustments depends on the policy rate behavior. Finally,stickiness in deposit rates as well as in loan rates should also beconsidered, since many previous studies have reported that depositrates are also sticky. Although this paper treats deposit rates asequivalent to the policy rate, the relaxation of this assumption mayaffect the desirability of policy rate smoothing.

    Appendix 1. Derivation of the Demand for Funds

    From (4), (5), and (7), labor wage Wt(i) can be expressed as

    Wt(i) = 1t PtC

    t L

    t (i)

    = 1t PtCt

    Zt(i)

    At

    = 1t PtCt

    Pzt (i)

    Pzt

    zYt (V

    yt )

    At

    tPzt (i)

    z . (20)

    Inserting this equality into (6) gives

    Pzt (i) =tR

    itP

    zt (i)

    z

    RAt

    =

    tRitRAt

    11+z

    . (21)

    Therefore, the amount of funds demanded by intermediate-goodsfirm i, Wt(i)Lt(i), leads to

    Wt(i)Lt(i) = 1t PtC

    t Lt(i)

    1+

    = 1

    t PtC

    tPzt (i)

    Pztz(1+) Y1+t Vyt 1+

    A1+t

    Rit(1+)z

    1+z t,

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    34/42

    110 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    where t 1t PtC

    t A

    (1+)(z1)1+z

    t (Pzt )

    (1+)z(YtVyt )

    1+(1+)z1+z

    t

    R(1+)z1+z .

    Appendix 2. Proof of Proposition 1

    Given the definition of long-term interest rates, the newly adjustedloan rate, rt, should be expressed as

    rt = (1 q)Et[rt + qrt+1 + (q)2rt+2 + . . .]

    =

    s=0

    s1

    Et

    rt + 1

    rt + rt+11 +

    + 2

    rt + rt+1 +

    2rt+21 + + 2

    + . . .

    .

    Accordingly, comparing the coefficients on rt and on Etrt+1, respec-tively, yields

    1 q =

    s=0

    s

    1

    1 +1

    1 + +

    21 + + 2

    + . . .

    and

    (1 q)q =

    s=0s

    1

    1

    1 + +

    2

    1 + + 2+ . . .

    .

    Summarizing these two equations leads to

    s=0

    s

    1

    = (1 q)(1 q).

    Therefore, comparing the coefficients on Etrt+k and on Etrt+k+1,respectively, yields

    (1 q)(q)k = (1 q)(1 q)

    k

    kks=0

    s+

    k+1kk+1

    s=0 s

    + . . .

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    35/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 111

    and

    (1 q)(q)k+1 = (1 q)(1 q)

    k+1k+1k+1

    s=0 s +

    k+2

    k+1k+2s=0

    s + . . .

    for all k 1. Summarizing these two equations, we have

    k = qk

    ks=0

    s,

    which is the desired result.Next, let us derive a condition that attains k+1 < k for all

    k 0, where 0 1. From the expression of k, we have

    k k+1 = qk

    ks=0

    s qkk

    s=0

    s

    =qk

    1 [1 k+1 q(1 k+2)].

    Then, the following condition has to be satisfied for this to be posi-tive for all k 0:

    q 0, and (0) = (1 + )1. Therefore, the condition k+1 < k is

    satisfied for all k 0 if and only if q(1 + ) < 1.

    Appendix 3. Derivation ofpzt pt = r

    l

    t+ ( + )xt

    From the households optimality condition (4), it is obvious that

    wt(i)pt = yt + lt(i) (1 )t.

    Using this equality and the pricing rule of intermediate-goods firms,(6), we have

    pzt pt rlt + at = yt + lt (1 )t. (22)

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    36/42

    112 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    A linear approximation of (7) leads to zt = yt, and the productionfunction (5) implies lt = ztat. Notice that, as is shown in Gal and

    Monacelli (2005), the term vyt = d log10

    Pt(j)Pt

    dj is of second

    order. It follows that

    lt = yt at.

    Inserting this condition into equation (22) yields

    pzt pt = rlt + ( + )

    yt

    1 +

    +

    at

    1

    +

    t

    . (23)

    Let us define zft as the flexible-price equilibrium of an arbitraryvariable zt. It follows from (23) that

    yft +

    1

    +

    rlft =

    1 +

    +

    at +

    1

    +

    t yt

    f.

    Let us call ytf the quasi-flexible-equilibrium output. This rela-

    tion states that the sum of the flexible-equilibrium output and the

    flexible-equilibrium loan rate can be expressed in terms of a pro-ductivity shock and a preference shock. By defining xt yt yt

    f,equation (23) can be rewritten as

    pzt pt = rlt + ( + )xt.

    Appendix 4. Derivation of Equation (17)

    A second-order approximation of u(Ct) and v(Lt(i)), respectively,leads to

    u(Ct; t) = uC

    ct +

    1

    2(1 )c2t +

    ucuc

    ctt

    + t.i.p. (24)

    v(Lt(i)) = vL

    lt(i) +

    1

    2(1 + )l2t (i)

    + t.i.p.

    From the relation lt(i) = zt(i) at, the latter can be written as

    v(Lt(i)) = vL

    zt(i) +

    1

    2(1 + )z2t (i) (1 + )atzt(i)

    + t.i.p.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    37/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 113

    It immediately follows that

    10

    v(Lt(i))di = vL

    [1 (1 + )at]10

    zt(i)di

    +1

    2(1 + )

    10

    z2t (i)di

    + t.i.p. (25)

    It turns out that the disutility of labor depends on10

    zt(i)di and

    1

    0z2t (i)di. We focus on these expressions in turn.

    From a second-order approximation of the definition ofintermediate-goods price index, we have

    10

    pzt (i)di = pzt

    1 z

    2

    varip

    zt (i).

    Inserting this into a linearized version of equation (7) yields

    10

    zt(i)di = z(1 z)2 varipzt (i) + yt + vyt . (26)

    Thus, the total intermediate goods can be expressed as a functionof the variance of individual prices, varip

    zt (i).

    Next, we show that the variance of intermediate-goods price canbe written in terms of the variance of loan rates. Based on equation(6), we can establish that

    pzt (i) = rit + wt(i) at

    = rit at (1 )t +pt + ct + lt(i)

    = rit at (1 )t +pt + ct + z

    pzt (i)p

    zt

    + yt at

    ,

    where the second and the third equalities follow from (4) and (7),respectively. Since only pzt (i) and r

    it are dependent on index i, the

    variance of pzt (i) leads to

    varipzt (i) =

    1

    1 + z

    2varir

    it. (27)

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    38/42

    114 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    Meanwhile, the term10

    z2t (i)di can be rewritten as follows:

    10

    z2t (i)di = varizt(i) +1

    0

    zt(i)di2

    = varizt(i) + y2t

    = 2zvaripzt (i) + y

    2t

    =

    z

    1 + z

    2varir

    it + y

    2t , (28)

    where the last line comes from (27).Therefore, from equations (25)(28), the disutility of labor leads

    to 10

    v(Lt(i))di =vL

    2

    (1 + )

    y2t 2atyt

    + 2yt + 2v

    yt

    + z

    1 + z varirit + t.i.p.

    Since uC = vL holds in the efficient steady state, the utility of therepresentative household can be expressed as

    Ut = u(Ct; t)

    10

    v(Lt(i))di

    =vL

    2 (1 )y2t +

    2ucuc

    tyt (1 + )y2t 2atyt

    2vyt

    z

    1 + z

    varir

    it

    + t.i.p.

    = vL

    2

    ( + )

    y2t 2

    1 +

    +

    atyt 2

    uc/u

    c

    +

    tyt

    + 2vyt +

    z

    1 + z

    varir

    it

    + t.i.p.

    Note that vyt can be approximated as (/2)varjpt(j). In addition,the specification of the total utility function yields uc/u

    c = 1

    and vL = L1+, which establishes equation (17).

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    39/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 115

    References

    Angeloni, I., A. K. Kashyap, and B. Mojon, eds. 2003. MonetaryPolicy Transmission in the Euro Area. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Barth, M. J., and V. Ramey. 2001. The Cost Channel of MonetaryTransmission. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, ed. B.Bernanke and K. Rogoff. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Berger, A. N., A. K. Kashyap, and J. M. Scalise. 1995. The Trans-formation of the U.S. Banking Industry: What a Long, StrangeTrip Its Been. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 26 (2):

    55218.Buch, C. M. 2000. Financial Market Integration in the U.S.: Lessons

    for Europe? Kiel Institute for the World Economy.. 2001. Financial Market Integration in a Monetary Union.

    Working Paper No. 1062, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.Calvo, G. A. 1983. Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Frame-

    work. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3): 38398.Chowdhury, I., M. Hoffmann, and A. Schabert. 2006. Inflation

    Dynamics and the Cost Channel of Monetary Transmission.European Economic Review 50 (4): 9951016.

    Christiano, L. J., and M. Eichenbaum. 1992. Liquidity Effects andthe Monetary Transmission Mechanism. American EconomicReview 82 (2): 34653.

    Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans. 2005. Nomi-nal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to MonetaryPolicy. Journal of Political Economy 113 (1): 145.

    Davis, L. E. 1995. Discussion: Financial Integration within andbetween Countries. In Anglo-American Financial Systems,ed. M. D. Bordo and R. Sylla, 41555. New York: IrwinPublishing.

    de Bondt, G. 2002. Retail Bank Interest Rate Pass-Through: NewEvidence at the Euro Area Level. ECB Working Paper SeriesNo. 136.

    de Bondt, G., B. Mojon, and N. Valla. 2005. Term Structure andthe Sluggishness of Retail Bank Interest Rates in Euro Area

    Countries. ECB Working Paper Series No. 518.Donnay, M., and H. Degryse. 2001. Bank Lending Rate Pass-

    Through and Differences in the Transmission of a Single EMU

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    40/42

    116 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    Monetary Policy. Discussion Paper No. 0117, Katholicke Uni-versiteit Leuven Center for Economic Studies.

    Driscoll, J. C. 2004. Does Bank Lending Affect Output? Evidencefrom the U.S. States. Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (3):45171.

    Ellingsen, T., and U. Soderstrom. 2004. Why Are Long Rates Sen-sitive to Monetary Policy? IGIER Working Paper No. 256.

    Gal, J., and T. Monacelli. 2005. Monetary Policy and ExchangeRate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Review of EconomicStudies 72 (3): 70734.

    Gambacorta, L. 2004. How Do Banks Set Interest Rates? NBERWorking Paper No. 10295.

    Gropp, R., C. Kok Srensen, and J. Lichtenberger. 2007. TheDynamics of Bank Spreads and Financial Structure. ECB Work-ing Paper Series No. 714.

    Heinemann, F., and M. Schuler. 2002. Integration Benefits onEU Retail Credit MarketsEvidence from Interest Rate Pass-Through. ZEW Discussion Paper No. 02-26.

    Hofmann, B. 2003. EMU and the Transmission of Monetary Pol-

    icy: Evidence from Business Lending Rates. ZEI University ofBonn.

    Kleimeier, S., and H. Sander. 2006. Expected versus UnexpectedMonetary Policy Impulses and Interest Rate Pass-Through inEuro-Zone Retail Banking Markets. Journal of Banking andFinance 30 (7): 183970.

    Kok Srensen, C., and T. Werner. 2006. Bank Interest Rate Pass-Through in the Euro Area: A Cross Country Comparison. ECB

    Working Paper No. 580.Levin, A. T., and J. C. Williams. 2003. Robust Monetary Pol-icy with Competing Reference Models. Journal of MonetaryEconomics 50 (5): 94575.

    Lubik, T. A., and F. Schorfheide. 2004. Testing for Indeterminacy:An Application to U.S. Monetary Policy. American EconomicReview 94 (1): 190217.

    Mojon, B. 2000. Financial Structure and the Interest Rate Channelof ECB Monetary Policy. ECB Working Paper No. 40.

    Ravenna, F., and C. E. Walsh. 2006. Optimal Monetary Policywith the Cost Channel. Journal of Monetary Economics 53 (2):199216.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    41/42

    Vol. 4 No. 3 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through 117

    Rotemberg, J. J., and M. Woodford. 1997. An Optimization-BasedEconometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy.

    In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, ed. B. S. Bernanke andJ. J. Rotemberg, 297346. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Rudebusch, G. D. 2002a. Assessing Nominal Income Rules for Mon-

    etary Policy with Model and Data Uncertainty. Economic Jour-nal 112 (479): 40232.

    . 2002b. Term Structure Evidence on Interest Rate Smooth-ing and Monetary Policy Inertia. Journal of Monetary Econom-ics 49 (6): 116187.

    . 2006. Monetary Policy Inertia: Fact or Fiction? Interna-tional Journal of Central Banking 2 (4): 85135.

    Rudebusch, G. D., and L. E. O. Svensson. 1999. Policy Rules forInflation Targeting. In Monetary Policy Rules, ed. J. B. Taylor.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Sack, B., and V. Wieland. 2000. Interest-Rate Smoothing and Opti-mal Monetary Policy: A Review of Recent Empirical Evidence.Journal of Economics and Business 52 (12): 20528.

    Sander, H., and S. Kleimeier. 2002. Asymmetric Adjustment of

    Commercial Bank Interest Rates in the Euro Area: An Empir-ical Investigation into Interest Rate Pass-Through. Kredit undKapital 2: 16192.

    . 2004. Convergence in Euro-Zone Retail Banking? WhatInterest Rate Pass-Through Tells Us about Monetary PolicyTransmission, Competition and Integration. Journal of Inter-national Money and Finance 23 (3): 46192.

    Schwarzbauer, W. 2006. Financial Structure and Its Impact on the

    Convergence of Interest Rate Pass-Through in Europe: A Time-Varying Interest Rate Pass-Through Model. Economics Series191, Institute for Advanced Studies.

    Svensson, L. E. O. 2003. What Is Wrong with Taylor Rules? UsingJudgment in Monetary Policy through Targeting Rules. Journalof Economic Literature 41 (2): 42677.

    Teranishi, Y. 2008. Optimal Monetary Policy under Staggered LoanContracts. BIMES Discussion Paper Series No. 2008-E-8, Bankof Japan.

    Tillmann, P. 2007. Do Interest Rates Drive Inflation Dynamics?An Analysis of the Cost Channel of Monetary Transmission.Forthcoming in Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control.

  • 8/2/2019 Incomplete Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy

    42/42

    118 International Journal of Central Banking September 2008

    Toolsema, L. A., J. Sturm, and J. de Haan. 2001. Convergence ofMonetary Transmission in EMU: New Evidence. CESifo Work-

    ing Paper No. 465.Weth, M. A. 2002. The Pass-Through from Market Interest Ratesto Bank Lending Rates in Germany. Deutsche Bundesbank,Economic Research Centre Discussion Paper 11/02.

    Woodford, M. 2001. Inflation Stabilization and Welfare. NBERWorking Paper No. W8071.

    . 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Mon-etary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    . 2005. Central-Bank Communication and Policy Effective-ness. In The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future. FederalReserve Bank of Kansas City.