Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity...

58
1 Centre for Globalization Research School of Business and Management Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance to the frontier matters CGR Working Paper 86 Sabine D’Costa Enrique Garcilazo Joaquim Oliveira Martins Abstract Using a panel of 265 regions from 24 OECD countries from 1997 to 2007, we explore the impact of nation-wide macroeconomic and structural policies on the productivity growth of subnational regions. We find that average relationships between nation-wide policies and the growth of regions can hide strong differentiated effects according to the distance to the frontier: relaxing employment protection legislation on temporary contracts, lowering barriers to trade and investment as well as increasing trade openness enhances productivity growth in lagging regions, whereas reducing barriers to entrepreneurship or higher levels of government debt has a positive effect on regions that are closer to the productivity frontier. Keywords: structural reforms; regional growth; lagging regions. JEL codes: R11, R58, O18 http://www.busman.qmul.ac.uk/cgr CGR Working Paper Series

Transcript of Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity...

Page 1: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

1

Centre for Globalization Research School of Business and Management

Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance to the

frontier matters

CGR Working Paper 86

Sabine D’Costa Enrique Garcilazo

Joaquim Oliveira Martins

Abstract Using a panel of 265 regions from 24 OECD countries from 1997 to 2007, we explore the impact of nation-wide macroeconomic and structural policies on the productivity growth of subnational regions. We find that average relationships between nation-wide policies and the growth of regions can hide strong differentiated effects according to the distance to the frontier: relaxing employment protection legislation on temporary contracts, lowering barriers to trade and investment as well as increasing trade openness enhances productivity growth in lagging regions, whereas reducing barriers to entrepreneurship or higher levels of government debt has a positive effect on regions that are closer to the productivity frontier. Keywords: structural reforms; regional growth; lagging regions. JEL codes: R11, R58, O18

http://www.busman.qmul.ac.uk/cgr

CG

R W

orki

ng P

aper

Ser

ies

Page 2: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

1

Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance to the frontier matters

Sabine D’Costa a Enrique Garcilazo b

Joaquim Oliveira Martins b

a University of Westminster, London, UK and SERC b OECD1, 2 rue André Pascal, 75116 Paris, France

Abstract:

Using a panel of 265 regions from 24 OECD countries from 1997 to 2007, we explore the impact of nation-wide macroeconomic and structural policies on the productivity growth of subnational regions. We find that average relationships between nation-wide policies and the growth of regions can hide strong differentiated effects according to the distance to the frontier: relaxing employment protection legislation on temporary contracts, lowering barriers to trade and investment as well as increasing trade openness enhances productivity growth in lagging regions, whereas reducing barriers to entrepreneurship or higher levels of government debt has a positive effect on regions that are closer to the productivity frontier.

Keywords: structural reforms; regional growth; lagging regions.

JEL codes: R11, R58, O18.

1 The views expressed are those of the authors and do not reflect those of the OECD or its Member countries.

Page 3: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

2

1. Introduction

This paper aims at analysing the impact of macro-structural factors on the productivity

growth of regions. These economy-wide factors may be defined in a uniform way for all

regions in a given country, but their impact region by region can be very asymmetric. In this

way, we aim at bridging the gap between the national and the regional dimensions in the

study of economic growth, as well as in economic policy. On the one hand, at the country

level, the neoclassical literature investigating economic growth based on Cobb-Douglas

production functions (Solow, 1956 and Swan, 1956) which evolved towards the endogenous

growth framework (Lucas, 1988 and Romer, 1986) focused on understanding the country-

level drivers of national growth, including country-level policies. On the other hand, the

literature investigating economic growth dynamics at the regional level explains regional

growth based on regional factors. This includes studies of regional convergence (Sala-i-

Martin, 1996, Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 2004) and more recently models of regional growth

using frameworks from the New Economic Geography (Minerva and Ottaviano, 2009,

Desmet and Rossi-Hansberg, 2010)2 . There is still a gap between these two bodies of

literature and as a result the link between country-level factors and regional economic growth

needs to be better understood. Recent work has advanced our understanding of how the

regional dimension maps into and contributes to aggregate growth (see OECD, 2011). Che

and Spilimbergo (2012) using a limited set of structural reform indicators analysed how they

impact regional convergence; however the study of how country-wide factors influence

performance at the regional level is still nascent.

2 See Breinlich et al. (2013) and OECD (2009) for a review.

Page 4: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

3

The country-level factors we examine comprise a broad package of structural policies,

including product market regulation and labour market legislation, as well as macroeconomic

factors such as trade exposure, the level of inflation and government debt. We consider their

effect on the productivity growth of OECD regions, measured as growth in GDP per worker.

In particular we seek to explore how this impact might vary across regions depending on their

productivity gap with the most productive region in their country (the frontier region). We

also examine the pass-through effect by estimating how productivity growth in the frontier

region affects productivity growth in other regions within a country and the catching-up effect

by estimating whether regions that are farther from the frontier (lagging regions) grow faster.

The fact that we are using regional data enables to control for fixed-effects without creating

the usual collinearity problems with country-wide policy variables, which also may also

enable to estimate better the effects of these policies.

We believe our work carries important conclusions for both macro-structural and

regional policies. Regional policy has evolved over the past decades from a paradigm

dominated by temporary subsidies and short-term corrections in regional imbalances to a

modern approach focusing on competitiveness and growth with an aim to boost the overall

performance of countries.3 A criticism of EU regional transfers has been made for example in

Boldrin and Canova (2001) who find that productivity in poorer regions was unaffected by the

amount of transfers received. The authors conclude that these policies simply have a

redistributive role without enhancing either aggregate growth or that of lagging regions in the

EU. More recently, Breidenbach et al. (2016) found that the disbursement of EU structural

funds is negatively correlated with regional growth and does not seem to contribute

3 See McCann and Ortega-Argiles (2013) for a detailed description of the changes to EU cohesion policy for example.

Page 5: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

4

effectively to foster income convergence across regions. Other work on EU regional transfers

has highlighted the fact that their overall efficiency could be improved by reallocating these

transfers towards a select group of target regions (Becker et al., 2012). Our paper aims to

contribute to the current debate over the conditionality of regional transfers whereby

unconditional transfers have been deemed insufficient and transfers are now increasingly tied

to specific structural improvements.4 Our results indicate that lagging regions differ from

leading regions in their response to structural reforms and therefore that regionally

differentiated policies could have a significant role to play in national growth policy. We find

that average relationships between nation-wide policies and the growth of regions can hide

strong differentiated effects according to the distance to the frontier: relaxing employment

protection legislation on temporary contracts, lowering barriers to trade and investment as

well as increasing trade openness enhances productivity growth in lagging regions, whereas

reducing barriers to entrepreneurship or higher levels of government debt has a positive effect

on regions that are closer to the productivity frontier.

The paper is structured around six sections. In the next section we provide an

overview of the literature and of our conceptual framework. The third section describes the

model and Section 4 is dedicated to the data. Section 5 presents the results of our estimates as

well as robustness checks. The final section presents our conclusions.

4 The heterogeneity of the effect of transfers on regional growth is analysed in Becker et al. (2013), who find that regions with better governance and human capital enjoy greater growth in response to EU transfers.

Page 6: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

5

2. Conceptual framework and review of the literature

Our empirical model is inspired by the model in Bourlès et al. (2013). This is a

version of the neo-Schumpeterian endogenous growth model by Aghion et al. (1997), which

highlights the costs of market restrictions (e.g. regulatory barriers) in upstream sectors have

an impact on the productivity growth of downstream sectors. The conclusion of their model is

that the (induced) lack of competition in upstream sectors leads to lower productivity growth

in downstream sectors.

In addition, Bourlès et al. (2013) shows the relevance of two factors that have been

identified in the endogenous growth literature as influencing positively sector productivity

growth. First, growth at the international technological frontier for a given sector has a

positive effect on growth in lagging country-sectors: this is called technological pass-through.

Second, by a catching-up effect, the efficiency gap between this frontier sector and the

follower sectors also enhances growth in the follower sectors. As highlighted in Acemoglu et

al. (2006) and Aghion and Howitt (2006), productivity growth in follower countries increases

in the productivity growth at the world technological frontier (pass-through effect) owing to

technological spillovers from the frontier and also increases in the productivity gap between

the follower country and the technological frontier owing to technological adoption (catching-

up effect). A result of this is that regulations that curb competition between firms will reduce

the incentive for firms to adopt the technology available at the frontier. This will slow down

the catching-up of follower countries that are far from the technological frontier. Therefore

the speed of catching-up depends not only on the distance to the frontier, but also indirectly

on regulations or policies that might affect the distance to the frontier (Bourlès et al., 2013).

Another consequence is that, as shown in Griffith et al. (2004), countries that invest in R&D

Page 7: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

6

benefit from a double productivity boost, through greater catching-up possibilities owing to

innovation and also through easier technological adoption from the frontier.

The structural policies that our and previous papers consider can affect productivity

through two separate and opposing effects, the escape entry effect and the discouragement

effect.5 In the context of deregulation leading to heightened competition between firms, the

escape entry effect would prevail in countries with a significant proportion of firms with

productivity levels near the productivity frontier, and the discouragement effect would prevail

in countries where most firms are far away from the frontier. In that case, in follower

countries far from the frontier, the discouragement effect would prevent innovation taking

place and reduce catching-up. Conversely, where the escape entry effect prevails, competition

will increase average productivity. This effect may in fact prevail too in lagging countries or

regions far from the frontier, where higher domestic or foreign competition may increase

firms’ incentives to adopt better technologies.

Recent work on the causes of the generalised productivity slowdown in OECD

countries has also highlighted that there is an apparent average decline of productivity

catching-up at the firm and sectoral level (OECD, 2015). This stylised fact is also confirmed

when observing productivity trends in frontier and lagging regions (OECD, 2016). Among the

drivers that could promote or hinder catching-up, OECD (2015) stresses the relative openness

of economies to trade and investment, with an essential component associated with the

participation in global value-added chains (GVCs); the existence of barriers that generate

disincentives for up-scaling of firms, which in turn prevent firms from reaching the size

required to face the fixed costs to adopt innovation or enter new markets; and finally, the

5 See Aghion et al. (2004, 2006).

Page 8: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

7

existence of market restrictions that may also prevent the necessary firm selection and

reallocation mechanisms from fully operating.

We transpose the country-sector framework of Bourlès et al. (2013) at the regional

level, examining the impact of nation-wide structural policies and macroeconomic factors on

regional productivity growth, while simultaneously examining the pass-through and the

catching-up effects. For the former effect we determine whether regional productivity growth

increases with the growth of the country’s frontier region (i.e. the region with the highest

productivity level in its country in a given year) and for the latter we determine whether

regional growth increases in distance to the frontier region.

Shifting the analysis from the sectoral level to the region level of course means that

the relevant explanatory variables present in the growth regressions that we undertake will be

different. In the rest of this section, we explain our choice of explanatory variables.

Our paper is concerned with the relationships between economic growth and levels of

product market regulation, which have been studied before at the country level by Nicoletti

and Scarpetta (2003) for OECD countries. The results in Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2003)

indicate that differences in regulatory reform explain part of the cross-country growth

disparities. They find that lower levels of entry barriers and state control enhance productivity

growth, particularly in countries that lag behind in technology adoption. They also find

productivity gains from privatization. This leads us to ask whether such reforms might explain

differences in the growth of subnational regions. In addition, we also consider the impact of

employment protection legislation (EPL) on regional growth.

Our approach is also related to that of Bassanini and Scarpetta (2001), who build a

country-level “policy-augmented” growth model analysing the effects of macroeconomic

Page 9: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

8

policies such as inflation targeting, fiscal policy or international trade on national economic

growth in OECD countries. Their findings suggest that high inflation hinders output growth,

possibly due to its negative effect on investment and capital accumulation. They also find a

negative effect of the size of government on growth, whereas trade exposure is found to be

positively associated with output growth.

As highlighted in Bassanini and Scarpetta (2001), government deficit can affect

country-level growth by reducing private sector investment, and by implying a level of

taxation that changes the efficient allocation of resources in the economy. In spite of the

positive effects of public spending, medium to high levels of deficit tend to curb economic

growth. The magnitude of the effect depends on the type of financing of the deficit (i.e. how

distortionary the taxes are) and the type of public investment undertaken (i.e. how productive

it is). At the regional level, in contrast to Bassanini and Scarpetta (2001), by estimating the

effect of local taxes and public expenditures on regional economic growth in Korea, Kim

(1997) finds that overall the positive effect of local government investment on regional

growth outweighs the negative effect of local taxes. Rodriguez-Pose and Fratesi (2003) also

find a small positive impact of European structural funds on regional growth in the EU. As

regional policy funds are typically targeted on gaps of regional GDP per capita, depending on

the distance to the frontier, the balance between positive and negative effects may change.

International trade can also enhance economic growth, by reinforcing the efficient

allocation of resources according to patterns of comparative advantage, by increasing the

scale of production, facilitating the flow of technologies and knowledge, and increasing levels

of competition. The New Economic Geography and growth literature, in particular Martin and

Ottaviano (1999) suggest there is a permanent effect of trade integration on economic growth.

Page 10: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

9

In contrast, Minniti and Parello (2011), using a spatial model of endogenous growth, predict

that trade integration has only a short term impact on growth, which is positive when there are

positive R&D spillovers. In terms of empirical evidence, Sachs et al. (2002), aiming to

explain the differences in economic performance across Indian states, find that after the

reforms of 1991 the surge in international trade has been a positive factor of growth.

Concerning inflation, despite evidence of its growth effects at the country level

(Bassanini and Scarpetta, 2001), no clear predictions can be made on its effects on regional

productivity. We include it more as control variable given its importance as one of the

macroeconomic stabilisation indicators.

Among the structural policies we include in our analysis are reforms aimed at

lowering employment protection legislation, state control, barriers to entrepreneurship and

barriers to trade and investment. All these structural variables may affect regional

productivity in a differentiated way depending on the distance to the frontier.

From the outset, it could be noted that the majority of the frontier regions in the

OECD contain large cities, whereas most lagging regions are located in intermediate and

predominantly rural areas (OECD, 2016). In this context, lagging regions may be particularly

sensitive to barriers to entrepreneurship precisely because they do not fully benefit from

density and agglomeration effects associated with the presence of other firms allowing for

specialisation or knowledge spillovers. Indeed, Stephens et al. (2013), focusing on lagging

rural regions of the Appalachians in the USA, find that, in such regions, employment growth

is better enhanced by the presence of creative workers or a tradition of self-employment and

entrepreneurship in the area than by knowledge-based factors such as the presence of

universities, a greater proportion of patents or higher high-technology employment shares.

Page 11: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

10

The openness of international trade and investment may also affect regions differently.

OECD (2016) finds that exposure to tradable sectors appears to be one of the main drivers of

the regional productivity catching-up in lagging regions. A possible explanation is that in

tradable sectors (mainly industry), the international competitive pressures generate a sort of

unconditional convergence (Rodrik, 2013), which is less dependent on specific country or

regional conditions. The barriers to trade and investment could then be particularly

detrimental for the productivity performance of the lagging regions.

State control can have different effects on regional growth depending on the form it

takes and on the distance to the frontier. The extent of state ownership with direct control on

public employment and investment can be a strong factor of growth in regions farther away

from the frontier. On the other hand, state involvement in business operations, such as price

controls and regulation can also reduce the efficient allocation of resources and affect

incentives to innovate, with a detrimental impact on growth in frontier regions.

High levels of employment protection legislation (EPL) can have a limiting effect on

competition and on creative destruction by reducing the flexibility of firm size: this can

restrict up-scaling of firms but also limit the exit or downsizing of inefficient firms. By

lowering the quality of job-market matching, it can also prevent effective resource

reallocation with a detrimental effect on aggregate productivity growth. Lowering restrictions

on temporary contracts can have a stronger effect on growth for regions that are farther away

from the frontier, as these generally have thinner labour markets and are therefore more

vulnerable to labour market rigidities.

We limit our analysis to the main structural reform and macroeconomic indicators.

This is both motivated by the existence of institutional data and composite indicators that

Page 12: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

11

allow for a comparative analysis across countries and, also, by the fact that these macro-

structural variables have been used to implement ex-ante conditionalities associated with EU

regional policy funds.

Our empirical framework focuses on pass-through, catching-up and structural

framework conditions. It also accounts for time-invariant regional drivers of growth. It does

not explicitly control for other time-varying region-level drivers of regional growth such as

physical and human capital and innovation. Although at the country level both the

neoclassical theory of growth (starting with Solow, 1956 and Swan, 1956) and endogenous

growth models (Romer, 1986 and 1990, Lucas, 1988 and Aghion and Howitt, 1998)

emphasise the role of physical and human capital accumulation on economic growth, the

evidence at the regional level is mixed. Chandra and Thompson (2000) and Michaels (2008)

find that improved access to interstate highways in rural US counties increased firm earnings

and Duranton and Turner (2011) find that population growth in US Metropolitan Statistical

Areas responds positively to increases in the road network. However Crescenzi and

Rodriguez-Pose (2012) fail to find a role for transport infrastructure in regional economic

growth among EU regions. Turning to human capital, although empirical evidence on the

importance of human capital for regional growth can be found in Glaeser et al. (1995),

Henderson et al. (1995) and Rauch (1993), we do not find such evidence in our dataset. This

may be due to the fact that investment in education has been relatively uniform across

countries, at least at the TL2 level, thus it cannot really discriminate between the fast and slow

growing regions within countries. Similarly, we do not find in our data a relationship between

innovative activity and regional productivity growth.6

6 For evidence on the convergence of R&D policies across regions see OECD (2016).

Page 13: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

12

Our paper is part of a limited set of studies that have combined the notions of

macroeconomic policies, regional economic growth and convergence. Studying the case of

Indian states, Ahluwalia (2000) discusses the reasons for inter-state differences in economic

growth in India in the 1990s. He finds that variations in growth are best explained by

variations in certain state-specific characteristics. However, he does not provide empirical

evidence on how nation-wide structural reforms can have different impacts on states as these

differ in their characteristics. More recently, related work by Che and Spilimbergo (2012) has

estimated the effect of structural reforms on the speed of convergence between regions in

developed and developing countries, concluding that financial development, trade openness,

sound institutions and some labour market reforms favour regional convergence.

3. Description of the model

As previously explained, our model is based on a modified version of Bourlès et al.

(2013) adapted to the regional context. Our policy-augmented growth model is based on a

regional production function rather than a national one, as is often done in the regional growth

literature. It allows us to estimate the effects of macroeconomic and structural policies on

regional productivity growth and simultaneously measure how this effect varies with respect

to a region’s distance to the “frontier” or most productive region in the country (the catching-

up effect) and the direct impact of the frontier region on productivity growth (the pass-

through effect). Our hypothesis is that regional productivity growth is positively related to the

productivity growth of the frontier region within the country and positively related to the

productivity gap with the frontier region (in other words productivity growth increases with

distance to the productivity frontier as lagging regions catch up).

Page 14: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

13

In terms of structural policies, we consider labour market legislation, the level of state

control, barriers to entrepreneurship and barriers to trade and investment, which are described

in the next section. Our macroeconomic variables are trade exposure, government debt and

inflation.

We estimate the following reduced form equation:

∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡 = 𝛽𝛽1∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶 ,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝛽𝛽3𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐶𝐶,𝑡𝑡−1 +

𝛽𝛽4𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐶𝐶,𝑡𝑡−1 .𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝛾𝛾𝑟𝑟 + 𝜁𝜁𝑡𝑡 + 𝜀𝜀𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 (1)

∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡 is the percentage growth in region r’s productivity between t-1 and t

(productivity measured as GDP per worker), ∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶,𝑡𝑡 is the percentage growth of the

country frontier region’s productivity in year t and 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1 is the lagged productivity

gap with the country’s frontier region.

The variable ∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶 ,𝑡𝑡 is equal to zero if the region r is a frontier region in the given year.

This is because otherwise if r is a frontier region, there would be perfect collinearity between

the dependent variable and ∆ ln𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶 ,𝑡𝑡 and the estimate of 𝛽𝛽1 obtained would be biased

towards the share of frontier regions in our dataset (8%). By doing this, we obtain an estimate

for 𝛽𝛽1 that is estimated only over the non-frontier regions. We expect 𝛽𝛽1 to be positive as the

growth of the country frontier region has a positive effect on that of other regions in the same

country.

The productivity gap variable 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1 is defined as ln � 𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶,𝑡𝑡−1

�. The gap is equal to

zero at the frontier and becomes increasingly negative for regions farther away from the

frontier. 𝛽𝛽2 indicates the (hypothetical) effect of increasing the productivity gap by one unit

Page 15: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

14

when policy indicators are set to zero. We expect the marginal effect of 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 to be

negative: as 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡 takes negative values, increasing 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡 is equivalent to

decreasing the distance to the frontier, which we expect to reduce the catching-up effect on

regional growth.

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐶𝐶,𝑡𝑡−1 is the lagged level of the policy variable in country C. In order to facilitate the

interpretation of the coefficients, we normalise the structural policy indicators (see below).

Higher values of labour market legislation, state control and barriers to entrepreneurship or

barriers to trade variables are indicative of lower levels of regulation. Since we are interested

in the impact of nation-wide factors on different types of regions, and in particular on regions

depending on their distance to the country’s productivity frontier, each nation-wide policy

variable is interacted with the productivity gap variable. In our full specification, we include

all the structural policies together and the three macroeconomic indicators together. We obtain

the marginal effects of each policy, 𝛽𝛽3 + 𝛽𝛽4.𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1 as well as the corresponding

confidence intervals. 𝜁𝜁t are year-specific effects and γr region fixed-effects that account for

time-invariant regional factors that influence regional productivity growth.

We estimate the model using OLS with fixed effects. However the variable

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟,𝑡𝑡−1includes a term which is the lagged dependent variable that in its transformed

form is correlated with the transformed error term. This would lead to estimation by fixed

effects being biased. In order to address this, and given the serial correlation in our variables

and the relatively small number of years in our dataset, we follow Blundell and Bond (1998)

and also estimate our model using a system-GMM method.

Page 16: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

15

Noteworthy, the fact that we are using regional data enables to control for fixed-

effects without creating the usual collinearity problems with the country-wide policy

variables, which often do not display strong time variability.7

4. The data

Our data consist of a panel of 265 regions from 24 OECD countries8 defined at Territorial

Level 2 (TL2), taken from the OECD Regional Database and covering the period 1997 to

2007.9 We observe regional productivity since 1996, defined as GDP per worker, deflated

with base year 2000 and PPP adjusted in US dollars. We use this measure to compute yearly

regional productivity growth in percentages. Using the regional productivity data we are able

to identify the regions which are at the productivity frontier in their country in each year. This

allows us to compute the productivity growth of the frontier region (∆ ln 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝐹𝐹𝐶𝐶 ) and the

distance between a given region and the country frontier region (𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃).

Turning to our country-year level policy and macroeconomic variables, our measures of

regulation are drawn from the OECD’s Product-Market Regulation (PMR) Database.10 The

7 This is a recurrent problem in many cross-country econometric growth studies using structural policy variables that do not display a time dimension or have low time variability. To circumvent this problem, researchers often have to revert to pooled or the GLS estimates that may generate bias on their own.

8 We do not use the full set of OECD countries and regions due to restrictions on data availability. The countries covered are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and USA.

9 We prefer to restrain our sample to the pre-crisis period in order to capture the structural effects of policies. During an economic depression, structural reforms may have temporary deflationary effects counteracting their long-run benefits. This may generate a bias in the estimates of the gains from structural reform.

10 See Wolfl et al. (2009) for a detailed description of the PMR data as well as Koske et al. (2015) for a more recent update on the PMR data.

Page 17: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

16

PMR indicators are a comprehensive and internationally comparable set of indicators that

measure the degree to which policies promote or inhibit competition in areas of the product

market where competition is viable. They measure the economy-wide regulatory and market

environments in 34 OECD countries as well as in Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Russia and

South Africa. They are consistent across time and countries. In the original data, the values

for each indicator vary between 1 and 6, with higher values indicating higher levels of

restrictions. To make their interpretation more comparable with the other structural indicators,

we use the PMR with a reverse scale (i.e. higher values mean lower restrictions). Data are

gathered and the indicators calculated according to a common method, so as to ensure

consistency across time and comparability across space and across sectors. We use the three

main PMR components rather than the composite indicator because the latter combines quite

different dimensions, possibly affecting regional growth in a very diverse manner. The first is

State control that measures the extent of state ownership (scope of public enterprise, direct

control over business enterprises and government involvement in network sectors) and the

state’s involvement in business operations (price controls, use of command and control

regulation). The second are Barriers to entrepreneurship that measures regulatory and

administrative opacity, administrative burdens on start-ups and barriers to competition.

Finally, Barriers to trade and investment encompasses barriers to FDI, tariffs, discriminatory

procedures and regulatory barriers to trade and investment.

Our second structural policy area is that of labour market legislation. We use the

employment protection legislation (EPL) indicator constructed by the OECD’s Directorate for

Labour and Social Affairs, which varies from 1 to 6 (like for the PMR, we are using here a

reverse scale, which increases with labour market deregulation). EPL measures the procedures

and costs involved in dismissing or hiring workers, based on information provided by officials

Page 18: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

17

in the OECD member countries and expert opinions from the International Labour

Organization (ILO). EPL indicators are available for all 35 OECD countries as well as for 39

non-OECD countries and territories. Two EPL indicators were available to us: the first one,

pertaining to regular contracts, was not retained in our analysis due to the lack of time and

cross-country variation in this measure; the second one, pertaining to temporary contracts,

presents considerable variation as this form of employment contracts has been subject to

reform in many countries in the period we consider.

In terms of macroeconomic variables, we consider trade openness, captured by total trade

flows as a percentage of GDP, government debt to GDP ratio, and inflation (measured as the

rise in the consumer price index). All macroeconomic data are drawn from OECD sources.

Table 1 provides summary statistics of the variables. Annual productivity growth has an

average value of 1.7% and ranges from -7.8% to +13.9%. Outlier observations with

productivity growth lower than -8% or greater than 14% have been removed from the sample,

although the frontier region growth is allowed to exceed these values. The productivity gap

takes on negative values. It is equal to zero for regions at the productivity frontier of their

country, and becomes increasingly negative for regions further away from the frontier.

5. Results

5.1 Impact of structural reforms

Table 2 reports our results on the effects of structural variables using regional fixed

effects, pooled OLS and system GMM methods. The first six columns in Table 2 report the

estimates from fixed effects regressions. In column (1), the positive and statistically

Page 19: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

18

significant coefficient on Frontiergrowth indicates that increasing the productivity growth of

the country frontier region has a positive effect on the growth of the other regions, as

expected. The 0.05 coefficient means that a 1 percentage point increase in the annual

productivity growth of the country frontier region is associated with a 0.05 percentage point

increase in regional productivity growth. Although the effect is positive and significant, it is

of small magnitude: the frontier region is the region with the highest productivity level in the

country and may not have particularly high growth. We further investigate the pass-through

effect from the frontier in our robustness checks. Turning to the prodgap coefficient, this is

negative and statistically significant as expected and means that one standard deviation

increase in the distance to the frontier is associated with a 2.9% higher regional growth.

In column (6), we include the four policy variables together as well as all interaction terms

with the productivity gap in a fixed effects specification. The coefficient on Frontiergrowth

remains unchanged, while the coefficient of -13.95 on the productivity gap represents a

fictitious case where the value of all the structural variables would be at zero, meaning the

highest possible levels of regulation. The overall effect of the productivity gap however,

computed at average levels of the structural variables, is -9.2, meaning that increasing the

productivity gap by one standard deviation would increase regional growth by 4%.

Column (7) presents, as a means of comparison, the results obtained from a pooled OLS

estimation. Without region-specific effects, the effect of the frontier is no longer significant.

The cross-section effects dominate, capturing agglomeration forces rather than convergence

forces. Indeed, regional growth can be the result of convergence and agglomeration forces.

The former tend to favour lagging or poorer (often low-density, rural) areas. Conversely, the

agglomeration forces favour the dense, urbanised areas (see Garcilazo and Oliveira Martins,

Page 20: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

19

2013). The fixed effects and system GMM with region effects methods however capture the

convergence forces.

Figure 1 below represents the marginal effects with 95% confidence intervals of each of

our four structural reforms, based on the estimations underlying the results reported in column

(6) of Table 2. Each panel of Figure 1 represents, along the left vertical axis, the marginal

effect of a one-point increase in the value of the variable (i.e. greater deregulation) on regional

productivity growth, at different levels of the productivity gap with the frontier region. In

addition, each panel shows, according to the right vertical axis, the histogram of the

productivity gap variable. This enables us to see the magnitude and the significance of the

marginal effects, over a meaningful range of the productivity gap.

Figure 1 shows that deregulating temporary contracts EPL has a small negative effect on

the productivity growth of regions that are near the frontier, whilst the effect is large and

positive for a relatively small number of regions with a productivity gap lower than -0.6. The

positive effect on growth increases in the productivity gap. For the middle range of regions,

the marginal effect of deregulating EPL is not significantly different from zero. Deregulating

State Control seems to have no significant effect on regions close to the frontier, while there

is an increasingly negative impact on growth points for regions with a productivity gap

smaller than -0.4 as they get further from the frontier. Turning to barriers to entrepreneurship,

in this specification deregulation appears to have no significant effect on the growth of most

regions (with a productivity gap greater than -0.6) while there is a positive and significant

effect on lagging regions that increases with distance to the frontier. Finally, reducing barriers

to trade and investment has a negative and significant effect for the middle range of regions,

with a larger negative impact on regions as their distance to the frontier increases.

Page 21: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

20

Figure 1: Marginal effects of structural reforms, OLS

As explained in Section 3, our preferred estimation method is system GMM. The

corresponding results in column (8) of Table 2 confirm the pass-through effect of the frontier

region with a highly significant coefficient of +0.07 on the frontier region growth. The graphs

in Figure 2 below represent the marginal effects obtained from this specification. The system

GMM estimation yields very similar results for EPL. Intuitively, this differential impact of

labour market legislation among different kinds of regions can be driven by agglomeration

effects. Labour markets in regions close to the frontier are likely to be “thicker”, with larger

and more diverse populations of workers. Other things being equal, labour-market rigidities

are likely to be less costly in thicker labour markets and in those that are better endowed with

skills, because skill supply and matching are likely to be easier under any given regulatory

Page 22: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

21

regime. Regulatory rigidities in labour markets are likely to exact a much higher price in

regions farther from the frontier.

Figure 2: Marginal effects of structural reforms, GMM

In this preferred specification, the effects of deregulating state control, barriers to

entrepreneurship and barriers to trade and investment on regional growth are no longer

significant over the entire range of productivity gap. We now investigate this further by using

an alternative definition of the frontier as well as checking for sample selection issues.

Robustness checks

Our results may be sensitive to specificities of our data or to the way in which we have

defined a single frontier region for each country. We first consider the possibility that the

Page 23: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

22

presence of frontier regions in our dataset for analysis may influence our results. We remove

from our data all the observations that correspond to a country’s frontier region in any given

year. As a result, we are left with 2,281 observations for which the productivity gap is not

zero. Results are presented in Table 3. The marginal effects computed from the results of the

OLS and system GMM specifications of columns (6) and (7) respectively are shown

graphically in Figures 3 and 4 below.

Page 24: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

23

Figure 3: Exclusion of frontier regions, OLS

Figure 4: Exclusion of frontier regions, system GMM

Page 25: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

24

Results from the OLS with fixed effects specification are similar to those obtained

previously. Focusing on our GMM results (Figure 4), the positive effect of labour market

deregulation on lagging regions is confirmed, while deregulating barriers to trade and

investment now has a positive and significant effect on lagging regions, that increases with

distance to the frontier.

Similarly, in Table 4 we remove the observations corresponding to the three regions with

the highest productivity in each country in each year. This estimates the effects of the frontier

and of structural policies on the periphery. The pass-through and catching-up effects are

robust as indicated by the coefficients in column (1). Figures 5 and 6 below represent the

marginal effects obtained from the OLS and GMM estimations of columns (6) and (7).

Again, the fixed effects results are very similar to those obtained from the whole sample,

with more pronounced effects of EPL and barriers to trade (Figure 5). Turning to the GMM

results in Figure 6, we find that again reducing labour market rigidities on temporary

contracts has a positive effect on growth for lagging regions; reducing barriers to

entrepreneurship has a positive and significant effect for a range of regions close to the

productivity frontier, with the largest effect closer to the frontier, and reducing barriers to

trade and investment still has a clear positive and significant impact on growth for lagging

regions. The effect of state control again is not significant for lagging regions although there

is a negative and significant effect of deregulating state control on growth near the frontier.

Page 26: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

25

Figure 5: Excluding the top three regions, OLS.

Figure 6: Excluding the top three regions, GMM.

Page 27: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

26

Another possible important bias may come from our definition of the frontier regions.

Instead of using the region with the highest productivity in region r’s country, we propose an

alternative definition of the frontier by creating a synthetic frontier where the productivity is

equal to the average productivity in the three most productive regions in the country in a

particular year. We also compute an alternative measure of the distance to the frontier, which

is now equal to the difference between the log of productivity of region r and the log of the

average productivity of the three most productive regions. We then remove from our dataset

the three regions that were used in order to create the synthetic frontier region. This is to

avoid having a positive productivity gap between the highest productivity region and the

synthetic average and to capture the effect of this synthetic frontier and of the policies on

those regions that are not part of this frontier.

The results in Table 5 show that regional growth increases in the growth of the synthetic

frontier, it also increases in the distance to the synthetic frontier, as presented in our base

results in Table 2. It is noteworthy that the pass-through effect estimated here is much larger

than that identified in Table 2 with the full sample or even in Table 4 without the top three

regions: a one percentage point increase in the growth of the synthetic frontier is associated

with a 0.3 point increase in regional growth for the other regions. For all regions except the

three most productive, the pass-through of the economic core of the country is more

meaningful than that of the single frontier region. We therefore focus on this particular

definition of the frontier and the results associated with it.

The marginal effects are depicted in Figure 7 (OLS with region fixed effects) and Figure 8

(GMM) below. Given the new definition of the frontier and the exclusion of the top three

regions, the distribution of the productivity gap variable has changed, with a higher minimum

Page 28: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

27

(-2.94) and a lower maximum (-0.003). This is reflected in the horizontal axis and in the

histograms represented on both figures.

Figure 7: Alternative frontier region, excluding the top three regions, OLS.

Page 29: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

28

Figure 8: Alternative frontier region, excluding the top three regions, GMM.

Figure 8 above confirms the patterns found on EPL. For lagging regions, the reduction in

rigidities in temporary contracts acts in favour of reallocation and labour market

experimentation, while for regions near the frontier, deregulating temporary contracts might

in fact prevent the accumulation of specific capital in firms. For a region with a productivity

gap of -0.7, a one-point increase in the EPL indicator (just less than one standard deviation) is

associated with an increase in productivity growth of 1 percentage point. For a region with a

productivity gap of -1.5, the same amount of deregulation is associated with an increase in

growth of 4.8 points.

While the marginal effect of deregulating state control is positive and increasing in

distance to the frontier, it is still insignificant. This could be due to the different aspects of

state control in this variable having counteracting effects. We also find that reducing barriers

Page 30: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

29

to entrepreneurship has a positive and significant effect on regional growth for a large range

of regions with productivity gap greater than -0.9. This effect increases for regions closer to

the frontier. For example, for a region with a productivity gap of -0.5, increasing the policy

indicator by one point (roughly two standard deviations) is associated with a 3.4 point

increase in productivity growth, whilst for a region with a productivity gap of -0.3, the

marginal effect is 4.3 growth points. For regions farther from the frontier, contrary to our

expectations, the effect of reducing barriers to entrepreneurship is insignificant: The

discouragement effect may be prevailing in these regions as competition increases with the

lowering of these barriers.

Turning to barriers to trade and investment, as expected, a reduction of this type of

rigidities has a positive and significant effect on growth for the range of regions farther away

from the frontier (with a productivity gap less than -0.5). For example, for a region with a

productivity gap of -0.5, increasing the policy indicator by one point (here also roughly two

standard deviations) is associated with a 1.2 point increase in productivity growth. For a

region with a productivity gap of -1, the effect of the same increase in the policy indicator is a

4.64 point increase in productivity growth. Although the effects estimated on lagging regions

are very large, they remain of a more realistic magnitude over the main range of regions in

our dataset.

Finally, given the time period of our analysis it could be argued that Poland, Ireland and

Spain could have an overly important weight on the results. During the pre-crisis period, these

three countries experienced particularly rapid growth and undertook important structural

reforms. Accordingly, we replicated our base estimates after removing Polish, Irish and

Spanish regions from our sample (see Table 6). Marginal coefficients represented in Figures

9-11 show that our results are robust to the exclusion of these countries.

Page 31: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

30

Figure 9: Excluding Spanish regions.

−20

24

68

1012

1416

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f EPL

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−12

−10

−8−6

−4−2

02

46

810

12

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Sta

te C

ontr

ol

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−6−5

−4−3

−2−1

01

23

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to E

ntre

pren

eurs

hip

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−4−2

02

46

810

1214

16

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to T

rade

and

Inve

stm

ent

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

Structural policies − GMM − Spanish regions excludedMarginal effects on productivity growth

Page 32: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

31

Figure 10: Excluding Polish regions.

Figure 11: Excluding Irish regions.

−20

24

68

1012

1416

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f EPL

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−12

−10

−8−6

−4−2

02

46

8

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Sta

te C

ontr

ol

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−12

−10

−8−6

−4−2

02

4

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to E

ntre

pren

eurs

hip

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−50

510

1520

2530

3540

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to T

rade

and

Inve

stm

ent

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

Structural policies − GMM − Polish regions excludedMarginal effects on productivity growth

−20

24

68

1012

1416

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f EPL

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−10

−8−6

−4−2

02

46

810

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Sta

te C

ontr

ol

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−6−5

−4−3

−2−1

01

23

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to E

ntre

pren

eurs

hip

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

−4−2

02

46

810

1214

16

Mar

gina

l effe

ct o

f Bar

riers

to T

rade

and

Inve

stm

ent

02

46

810

1214

1618

20Pe

rcen

tage

of o

bser

vatio

ns

−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −.5 0

Productivity gap

Structural policies − GMM − Polish regions excludedMarginal effects on productivity growth

Page 33: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

32

5.3 Impact of macroeconomic factors

We now turn to the analysis of the macroeconomic variables. Table 7 reports our base results

using the full dataset and the single frontier region. The first three robustness checks,

including the alternative definition of the frontier, are offered in Table 8. Table 9 shows the

results obtained once we exclude Polish, Spanish and Irish regions. Again, the coefficient on

frontier region growth is highly significant and robust across specifications. We show below

in Figures 12-18 the marginal coefficients obtained from our preferred GMM estimations.

Figures from the OLS with region fixed effects estimations are included in the appendix.

Figure 12 corresponds to the results from column (7) in Table 7. As expected,

increasing trade exposure has a positive and significant effect on regions with large

productivity gaps (values less than -1.3). For a region with a productivity gap of -1.5,

increasing trade openness by one standard deviation is associated with a 4.32 point increase in

growth. However, we also find a negative and significant effect on regions close to the

frontier (values greater than -0.6). For a region with a productivity gap of -0.5, increasing

trade openness by one standard deviation is associated with a 1.76 point decrease in growth.

These results are similar to and consistent with those found on the effects of liberalising trade

and investment (Figures 2 and 8) and they are robust to our modifications in the sample and

the definition of the frontier presented in Figures 13-18 and Tables 8 and 9. They however go

against the theory that, in regions close to the productivity frontier, heightened competition

brought about by greater trade and investment would stimulate the escape entry effect, raising

productivity. In our less stringent, alternative definition of the frontier however (Figure 15),

the negative effect of trade exposure is only significant for a smaller range of regions very

close to the frontier. Overall, both estimates on structural policies and on macroeconomic

Page 34: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

33

factors support the hypothesis that exposure to international trade has an enhancing effect on

regional productivity growth, at least for regions far enough from the frontier. As explained in

Section 2, a possible explanation could be related to the role of the tradable sector as an

engine of unconditional growth (Rodrik, 2013).

Figure 12: Marginal effects of macroeconomic variables, GMM.

Government debt has a positive and significant effect on regional growth that

increases with distance to the frontier.11 In the base results, for a region with a productivity

gap of -0.5, increasing government debt (as a percentage of GDP) by one standard deviation

is associated with a 1.1 point increase in growth. For a region farther from the frontier, with a

productivity gap of -1.5, the same increase in government debt would yield a 1.7 point

increase in growth. In our alternative specifications, although the effect of debt remains

11 Note that this is the effect of increases in debt over time due to the inclusion of region fixed effects.

Page 35: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

34

positive and significant and of similar magnitude for a range of regions not too far from the

frontier, the effect is now (very mildly) decreasing with distance to the frontier. As shown in

Figure 15, when we use the average frontier and exclude the top three regions, the effect of

government debt is positive and significant for regions with values of the productivity gap

greater than -1.3 and the effect is no longer precisely estimated for the small number of

regions farther from the frontier. For a region with a productivity gap of -0.5, increasing

government debt by one standard deviation is associated with a 1.5 point increase in growth.

As can be seen from our results in Figures 12-18, the positive effect of government debt on

regional growth for a meaningful range of regions is robust across our specifications. It is

puzzling that, when we remove the frontier regions, we are not able to find a significant

positive effect of debt on lagging regions, whilst these regions are most likely to be on the

receiving end of public investment.

Finally, throughout our estimations, we do not find evidence of a significant role of

inflation in regional growth. This is not due to a lack of time variation in our data. Rather, as

explained in Section 2, this variable is included as one of the macroeconomic imbalance

indicators but there is no clear prediction on its differential effect on regional growth. For

example, inflation in lagging regions may affect export competitiveness due to the price of

their exports increasing, while at the same time reducing the cost of imported intermediates. If

lagging regions are particularly sensitive to increases in trade openness, as our results show,

we may expect inflation increases to affect their productivity growth, but the net effect would

be unclear.

Page 36: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

35

Figure 13: Excluding frontier regions.

Figure 14: Excluding top three regions.

Page 37: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

36

Figure 15: Alternative frontier region.

Figure 16: Excluding Spanish regions.

Page 38: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

37

Figure 17: Excluding Polish regions.

Figure 18: Excluding Irish regions.

Page 39: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

38

6. Conclusions

Our analysis measures the effects of country-wide macroeconomic and structural

factors on regional performance. We consider both the effects of regulatory policies and

macroeconomic factors on regional productivity using a panel covering 265 regions from 24

OECD countries over the period 1997-2007 representing roughly three business cycles. We

find strong statistical links between economy-wide macroeconomic and structural policies and

regional productivity that are not homogenous across regions; they tend to vary with respect

to the distance of regions to their national productivity frontier, with typically lagging regions

being the most affected by rigidities in product and labour markets. In addition, our analysis

finds evidence of a catching up effect with faster productivity growth in lagging regions and

evidence of a pass-through effect where growth in the frontier regions boosts the productivity

growth of the other regions. In particular, the effect of the frontier is more pronounced for

peripheral regions than for regions immediately following the frontier in terms of

productivity. We also find that the top three most productive regions, which we can consider

the core of each country, have a stronger effect on regional growth than the single most

productive region.

Our estimates reveal that deregulating employment protection legislation in temporary

contracts or reducing the level of barriers to trade and investment has a strong positive effect

on the growth of lagging regions and that this increases in distance to the frontier. The

increase in regional growth from deregulating EPL of temporary contracts by one point on the

indicator scale (0.8 of a standard deviation) varies from 1 to 4.8 growth points between a

region at a productivity gap of -0.7 and another region at a productivity gap of -1.5.

Deregulating barriers to trade and investment by one point (roughly two standard deviations)

Page 40: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

39

is associated with 1.2 point higher regional growth for a region with a productivity gap of -0.5

and 4.64 points for a region with a productivity gap of -1.

The effect of international trade is confirmed in our separate results on macroeconomic

factors: increasing trade openness (expressed as trade volume as a percentage of GDP) at the

country level increases regional growth of regions that are far from the productivity frontier,

with a more pronounced effect for lagging regions.

On the other hand, reducing barriers to entrepreneurship increases productivity growth for

regions closer to the frontier: for a region with a productivity gap of -0.5, deregulating

barriers to entrepreneurship by one point (roughly two standard deviations) is associated with

a 3.4 point increase in growth. This effect is larger for regions nearer the frontier but in our

GMM results we do not find a significant effect on regions that are the most lagging. We also

fail to find a significant effect of reducing state control on regional growth, across the range

of regions with our GMM specification.

Our findings also indicate that government debt has a positive and significant effect on

growth for most regions with values of the productivity gap greater than -1.3. For a region

with a productivity gap of -0.5, increasing government debt by one standard deviation is

associated with a 1.5 point increase in growth and the magnitude of the effect is larger for

regions nearer the frontier.

These findings reveal a strong link between the national and the regional dimension which

carries important policy implications. First, they help to understand how national factors have

a differentiated impact across regions enabling us to better assess their overall effects. Our

results also suggest that structural and macroeconomic policies should account for these

Page 41: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

40

regional effects in their design by complementing these policies with policies targeted to

specific regions to enhance their effects or restrain their negative effects.

Finally, arguments against regulatory reform have been made on the basis of harming

vulnerable or strategic regions. Our results do not warrant these views. On the contrary,

macro-structural policies tend to support catching-up of the lagging regions. This also

provides some basis to justify conditionalities associated with structural reforms. Our results

tell us that regulatory effects tend to vary according to regions’ distance to the frontier, they

also highlight the fact that different forms of regulation have different regional impacts.

Page 42: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

41

References

Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P. and F. Zilibotti (2006), ‘‘Distance to Frontier, Selection and Economic Growth,’’ Journal of the European Economic Association 4(1): 37–74.

Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. and S. Prantl (2004), ‘‘Entry and Productivity Growth: Evidence from Microlevel Panel Data,’’ Journal of the European Economic Association 2: 265–276.

Aghion, P., Burgess, R., Redding, S. and F. Zilibotti (2006), ‘‘The Unequal Effects of Liberalization: Evidence from Dismantling the License Raj in India,’’ American Economic Review 98: 1397–1412.

Aghion, P., Harris, C., Vickers, J. (1997), “Competition and growth with step-by-step innovation: An example”. European Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 41: 771-782.

Aghion, P., Howitt, P. (1998), “Endogenous Growth Theory”. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (2006), ‘‘Joseph Schumpeter Lecture: Appropriate Policy Growth: A Unifying Framework,’’ Journal of the European Economic Association 4: 269–314.

Ahluwalia, M. (2000), “State level performance under economic reforms in India”, Centre for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform Conference on Indian Economic Prospects: Advancing Policy Reform.

Barro, R., Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004), “Economic Growth” (Second Edition). MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Bassanini, A., Scarpetta, S. (2001), “The driving forces of economic growth: panel data evidence for the OECD countries”. OECD Economic Studies No. 33.

Becker, S., Egger. P., von Ehrlich, M. (2012), “Too much of a good thing? On the growth effects of the EU’s regional policy”. European Economic Review 56(4): 648-668.

Becker, S., Egger. P., von Ehrlich, M. (2013), “Absorptive capacity and the growth and investment effects of regional transfers: A regression discontinuity design with heterogeneous treatment effects”. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5(4): 29-77.

Boldrin, M., Canova, F. (2001), “Inequality and convergence in Europe’s regions: reconsidering European regional policies”. Economic Policy, April 2001: 207-253.

Page 43: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

42

Bourlès, R., Cette, G., Lopez, J., Mairesse, J., Nicoletti, G. (2013), “Do product market regulations in upstream sectors curb productivity growth? Panel data evidence for OECD countries”. The Review of Economics and Statistics 95(5): 1750-1768.

Breidenbach, P., Mitze, T., Schmidt, C. (2016), “EU Structural Funds and Regional Income Convergence - a Sobering Experience”. CEPR Discussion Paper Series no. 11210.

Breinlich, H., Ottaviano, G., Temple, J. (2014), “Regional Growth and Regional Decline”. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 2, Elsevier.

Chandra, A., Thompson, E. (2000), “Does public infrastructure affect economic activity? Evidence from the rural interstate highway system”. Regional Science and Urban Economics 30(4): 457-490.

Che, N. X., Spilimbergo, A. (2012), “Structural reforms and regional convergence”. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8951.

Crescenzi, R., Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012), "Infrastructure and regional growth in the European Union". Papers in Regional Science 91(3): 487-513.

Desmet, K., Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2010), “On Spatial Dynamics”. Journal of Regional Science 50(1): 43-63.

Duranton, G., Turner, M. (2011), “The fundamental law of road congestion: Evidence from US cities”. American Economic Review 101(6): 2616-52.

Garcilazo, E., Oliveira Martins, J. (2013), “The Contribution of Regions to Aggregate Growth in the OECD”. Economic Geography 91(2): 205–221.

Glaeser, E. L., Scheinkman, J. A., Shleifer, A. (1995), “Economic growth in a cross-section of cities”. Journal of Monetary Economics 36(1): 117-143.

Griffith, R., Redding, S. and J. van Reenen (2004), ‘‘Mapping the Two Faces of R&D: Productivity Growth in a Panel of OECD Countries,’’ Review of Economics and Statistics 86(4): 883–895.

Henderson, V., Kuncoro, A., Turner, M. (1995), “Industrial development in cities”. Journal of Political Economy 103: 1067-1090.

Kim, S. T. (1997), “The role of local public sectors in regional economic growth in Korea”. Asian Economic Journal 11(2): 155-168.

Koske, I., Wanner, I., Bitetti, R., Barbiero, O. (2015), "The 2013 update of the OECD's database on product market regulation: Policy insights for OECD and non-OECD

Page 44: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

43

countries". OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1200, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Lucas, R. E. (1988), “On the mechanics of economic development”. Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 3-42.

Martin, P., Ottaviano, G. I. P. (1999), "Growing locations: Industry location in a model of endogenous growth". European Economic Review 43(2): 281-302.

McCann, P., Ortega-Argiles, R. (2013), “Transforming European regional policy: a results-driven agenda and smart specialization”. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 29(2): 405–431.

Michaels, G. (2008), “The effect of trade on the demand for skill – Evidence from the interstate highway system”. Review of Economics and Statistics 90(4): 683-701.

Minerva, G. A., Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2009), “Endogenous growth theories: Agglomeration benefits and transportation costs”. In: Capello, R., Nijkamp, P. (eds), Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.

Minniti, A., Parello, C. (2011), “Trade integration and regional disparity in a model of scale-invariant growth”. Regional Science and Urban Economics 41: 20-31.

Nicoletti, G., Scarpetta, S. (2003), “Regulation, productivity and growth. OECD Evidence”. Economic Policy April 2003: 9-72.

OECD (2009), How Regions Grow: Trends and Analysis. OECD, Paris.

OECD (2011), Regional Outlook, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2016), Regional Outlook, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Rauch, J. E. (1993), “Productivity gains from geographical concentration of human capital: evidence from the cities”. Journal of Urban Economics 34: 380-400.

Roberts, M. (2010), "Endogenous Regional Growth: A Critical Survey". In: Setterfield, M. (ed), Handbook of Alternative Theories of Economic Growth, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.

Rodrik, D. (2013), Unconditional Convergence in Manufacturing. The Quarterly Journal of Economics: 65–204.

Rodriguez-Pose, A., Fratesi, U. (2003), “Between development and social policies: the impact of European structural funds in Objective 1 regions”. EEG Working Paper no. 28/2003.

Page 45: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

44

Romer, P. (1986), “Increasing returns and long-run growth”. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002-1037.

Romer, P. (1990), “Endogenous technological change”. Journal of Political Economy 98: 71-101.

Sianesi, B., Van Reenen, J. (2003), “The returns to education: Macroeconomics”. Journal of Economic Surveys 17(2):157-200.

Solow, R. M. (1956), “A contribution to the theory of economic growth”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65-94.

Sachs, J., Bajpai, N., Ramiah, A. (2002), “Understanding regional economic growth in India”. CID Working Paper No.88.

Sala-i-Martin, X. (1996), "Regional cohesion: Evidence and theories of regional growth and convergence". European Economic Review 40(6): 1325-1352.

Stephens, H., Partridge, M., Faggian, A. (2013), “Innovation, entrepreneurship and economic growth in lagging regions”. Journal of Regional Science 53(5): 778-812.

Swan, T. (1956), “Economic growth and capital accumulation”. Economic Record 32: 334-61.

Wolfl, A., Wanner, I., Kozluk, T., Nicoletti, G. (2009), “Ten years of product market reform in OECD countries – Insights from a revised PMR indicator”. OECD Economics Department working paper No. 695.

Page 46: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

45

Tables

Table 1: Summary statistics

Mean Std. dev. Min Max

Productivity levels (US$ constant prices) 60730.7 36522.7 14169.69 609012.8

Productivity growth 1.69 3.04 -7.84 13.9

Frontier region growth 3.66 6.42 -10.57 64.68

Productivity gap -0.43 0.43 -3.7 0

EPL temporary contracts 4.47 1.21 1.25 5.75

PMR state control 3.52 0.79 1.76 4.85

PMR barriers to entrepreneurship 3.71 0.54 2.55 4.56

PMR barriers to trade and investment 5.14 0.53 2.85 5.77

Trade openness (X+M)/GDP 31.17 16.05 9.48 92.37

Debt as % of GDP 66.77 28.13 12.6 175.27

Inflation rate (in %) 2.36 1.65 -0.9 14.15

Source: Own calculations using data from OECD Regional Database, OECD PMR Database, OECD EPL Database and OECD Economic Outlook Database.

Page 47: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

46

Table 2: Structural reforms and regional growth

Dependent variable: regional

productivity growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

FE FE FE FE FE FE Pooled OLS

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.05** 0.03 0.07***

(0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.017) (0.021)

Productivity gap t-1 -6.80*** 1.48 -2.37 -4.77*** -5.52* -13.95** 7.28** 12.59

(1.310) (1.877) (2.499) (1.419) (2.952) (5.996) (2.889) (9.414)

EPL temp t-1

-0.95***

-1.19*** 0.30* -1.51***

(0.254)

(0.292) (0.169) (0.403)

EPL temp X prodgap t-1

-2.27***

-2.51*** -0.66* -3.95***

(0.384)

(0.459) (0.349) (0.607)

Statecontrol t-1

-0.72**

0.20 -0.22 -0.45

(0.339)

(0.463) (0.220) (0.643)

Statecontrol X prodgap t-1

-1.29**

2.87*** 0.58 -0.71

(0.609)

(0.902) (0.440) (1.561)

Barrierstoentr t-1

-0.43

0.18 -0.75*** 1.02

(0.408)

(0.516) (0.259) (0.716)

Barrierstoentr X prodgap t-1

-0.64***

-1.08** -0.15 0.91

(0.163)

(0.456) (0.265) (0.667)

Barrierstotrade t-1

-0.19 0.17 -0.94*** -1.30**

(0.355) (0.631) (0.263) (0.640)

Barrierstotrade X prodgap t-1

-0.25 1.92* -1.18** -2.37*

(0.517) (1.161) (0.576) (1.361)

N 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492

R2 0.087 0.103 0.089 0.091 0.087 0.110 0.112

AR(1)

0.000

AR(2)

0.115

Sargan

0.000

Number of instruments

337

Number of regions 265 265 265 265 265 265 265

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 48: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

47

Table 3: Sensitivity of the results to the exclusion of frontier regions

Dependent variable: regional

productivity growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

FE FE FE FE FE FE System GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.08***

(0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.020) (0.019) (0.019) (0.022)

Productivity gap t-1 -7.31*** 1.68 -1.83 -5.37*** -6.25** -16.90*** 21.74**

(1.402) (1.948) (2.635) (1.511) (3.089) (6.436) (10.801)

EPL temp t-1

-1.12***

-1.48*** -1.95***

(0.259)

(0.337) (0.439)

EPL temp X prodgap t-1

-2.48***

-2.85*** -4.48***

(0.390)

(0.511) (0.678)

Statecontrol t-1

-0.85**

0.44 -0.72

(0.340)

(0.502) (0.696)

Statecontrol X prodgap t-1

-1.62**

3.14*** -1.43

(0.639)

(0.969) (1.702)

Barrierstoentr t-1

-0.34

0.52 1.70**

(0.439)

(0.592) (0.838)

Barrierstoentr X prodgap t-1

-0.65***

-1.15** 1.61**

(0.172)

(0.500) (0.774)

Barrierstotrade t-1

-0.12 0.52 -2.06**

(0.376) (0.703) (0.865)

Barrierstotrade X prodgap t-1

-0.21 2.47** -3.89**

(0.543) (1.245) (1.698)

N 2,281 2,281 2,281 2,281 2,281 2,281 2,281

R2 0.094 0.114 0.098 0.099 0.095 0.123

AR(1)

0.000

AR(2)

0.182

Sargan

0.000

Number of instruments

321

Number of regions 249 249 249 249 249 249 249

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 49: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

48

Table 4: Sensitivity of the results to the exclusion of the top 3 productivity regions

Dependent variable:

regional productivity

growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

FE FE FE FE FE FE

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.07*** 0.09***

(0.020) (0.019) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.023)

Productivity gap t-1 -6.37*** 2.90 1.25 -5.02*** -5.69 -16.23** 43.15***

(1.603) (2.035) (2.829) (1.706) (3.453) (7.987) (16.085)

EPL temp t-1

-1.38***

-1.92*** -2.48***

(0.275)

(0.388) (0.497)

EPL temp X prodgap t-1

-2.62***

-3.12*** -4.69***

(0.397)

(0.551) (0.749)

Statecontrol t-1

-1.25***

-0.11 -2.50***

(0.323)

(0.543) (0.823)

Statecontrol X prodgap t-1

-2.28***

2.57** -4.64*

(0.690)

(1.140) (2.458)

Barrierstoentr t-1

0.04

1.64** 3.72***

(0.479)

(0.725) (0.992)

Barrierstoentr X prodgap t-1

-0.54***

-0.79 3.41***

(0.167)

(0.611) (1.087)

Barrierstotrade t-1

-0.03 0.69 -3.62***

(0.436) (0.936) (1.265)

Barrierstotrade X prodgap t-1

-0.13 2.77* -6.75***

(0.607) (1.577) (2.526)

N 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856

R2 0.098 0.124 0.105 0.104 0.098 0.139

AR(1)

0.000

AR(2)

0.123

Sargan

0.000

Number of instruments

288

Number of regions 216 216 216 216 216 216 216

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors

are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 50: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

49

Table 5: Sensitivity of the results to an alternative definition of frontier regions

Dependent variable:

regional productivity growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

FE FE FE FE FE FE System GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.27*** 0.26*** 0.27*** 0.30*** 0.28*** 0.30*** 0.32***

(0.035) (0.035) (0.036) (0.035) (0.036) (0.034) (0.038)

Productivity gap t-1 -16.71*** -8.65*** -10.81*** -17.76*** -14.88*** -21.50** 30.86

(1.954) (2.360) (4.046) (1.976) (4.065) (8.996) (20.563)

EPL temp t-1

-1.07***

-1.67*** -2.39***

(0.275)

(0.374) (0.497)

EPL temp X prodgap t-1

-2.09***

-2.78*** -4.81***

(0.487)

(0.663) (0.811)

Statecontrol t-1

-0.95***

-0.85 -2.64***

(0.356)

(0.556) (0.901)

Statecontrol X prodgap t-1

-1.79*

1.71 -7.08*

(0.984)

(1.753) (3.688)

Barrierstoentr t-1

1.63***

3.45*** 5.62***

(0.435)

(0.609) (0.807)

Barrierstoentr X prodgap t-1

-0.13

0.37 4.46***

(0.212)

(0.639) (1.309)

Barrierstotrade t-1

0.15 0.23 -2.25**

(0.411) (0.708) (0.964)

Barrierstotrade X prodgap t-1

-0.41 1.27 -6.89***

(0.670) (1.461) (2.613)

N 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856

R2 0.184 0.194 0.187 0.195 0.185 0.219

AR(1)

0.000

AR(2)

0.477

Sargan

0.000

Number of instruments

288

Number of regions 216 216 216 216 216 216 216

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 51: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

50

Table 6: Sensitivity of the results to the removal of Spanish, Irish and Polish regions

Dependent variable: regional

productivity growth Without Spain Without Poland Without Ireland

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.04** 0.06*** 0.04** 0.06*** 0.05** 0.07***

(0.020) (0.023) (0.019) (0.022) (0.019) (0.021)

Productivity gap t-1 -14.86** 11.53 -24.73** 22.11 -14.11** 11.77

(5.747) (9.411) (10.877) (16.490) (5.981) (9.382)

EPL temp t-1 -1.45*** -1.64*** -1.44*** -1.87*** -1.23*** -1.52***

(0.300) (0.419) (0.293) (0.370) (0.293) (0.405)

EPL temp X prodgap t-1 -2.75*** -4.01*** -2.12*** -3.80*** -2.54*** -3.96***

(0.468) (0.628) (0.473) (0.589) (0.461) (0.609)

Statecontrol t-1 1.30* 0.29 -0.27 -0.51 0.23 -0.41

(0.675) (0.939) (0.426) (0.586) (0.465) (0.643)

Statecontrol X prodgap t-1 3.96*** -0.08 2.33*** 0.15 2.99*** -0.56

(1.007) (1.711) (0.855) (1.386) (0.905) (1.562)

Barrierstoentr t-1 -0.06 0.83 0.26 1.45* 0.17 1.01

(0.518) (0.732) (0.513) (0.746) (0.517) (0.716)

Barrierstoentr X prodgap t-1 -1.20*** 0.77 -1.66** 1.92 -1.09** 0.86

(0.436) (0.668) (0.816) (1.193) (0.454) (0.664)

Barrierstotrade t-1 0.20 -1.16* 2.39*** -0.84 0.13 -1.28**

(0.583) (0.644) (0.828) (1.242) (0.629) (0.637)

Barrierstotrade X prodgap t-1 1.78 -2.29* 4.57* -5.33 1.91* -2.28*

(1.081) (1.317) (2.360) (3.363) (1.156) (1.355)

N 2,309 2,309 2,355 2,355 2,474 2,474

R2 0.099

0.115

0.109

AR(1)

0.000

0.000

0.000

AR(2)

0.205

0.148

0.116

Sargan

0.000

0.000

0.000

Number of instruments

318

321

335

Number of regions 246 246 249 249 263 263

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 52: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

51

Table 7: Macroeconomic factors and regional growth

Dependent variable: regional

productivity growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

FE FE FE FE FE Pooled OLS

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.06*** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.03** 0.06***

(0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.017) (0.020)

Productivity gap t-1 -6.80*** -0.45 -5.91*** -7.74*** -2.76 0.97 2.48

(1.310) (2.240) (1.375) (1.348) (1.996) (0.825) (3.598)

Trade t-1

-0.19***

-0.18*** 0.01 -0.30***

(0.048)

(0.045) (0.008) (0.073)

Trade X prodgap t-1

-0.19***

-0.12** -0.03* -0.38***

(0.058)

(0.048) (0.016) (0.109)

Debt t-1

0.01

0.02* -0.01*** 0.03*

(0.012)

(0.012) (0.003) (0.016)

Debt X prodgap t-1

-0.03***

-0.02* -0.01* -0.02

(0.006)

(0.008) (0.005) (0.013)

Inflation t-1

0.09 -0.04 0.11 -0.00

(0.072) (0.080) (0.074) (0.121)

Inflation X prodgap t-1

0.39*** 0.05 0.23 -0.07

(0.135) (0.132) (0.142) (0.207)

N 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492 2,492

R2 0.087 0.100 0.100 0.091 0.110 0.083

AR(1)

0.000

AR(2)

0.137

Sargan

0.000

Number of instruments

335

Number of regions 265 265 265 265 265 265

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 53: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

52

Table 8: Robustness checks for the macroeconomic variables

Dependent variable:

regional productivity

growth

Removing

frontier regions Removing top 3 regions

Alternative frontier region -

removing top 3

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.06*** 0.07*** 0.06*** 0.07*** 0.28*** 0.27***

(0.019) (0.021) (0.020) (0.022) (0.038) (0.043)

Productivity gap t-1 -1.81 5.71 -1.09 5.68 -14.52*** -2.83

(2.114) (3.896) (2.655) (4.560) (3.120) (6.392)

Trade t-1 -0.24*** -0.45*** -0.26*** -0.52*** -0.07 -0.37***

(0.049) (0.086) (0.067) (0.099) (0.064) (0.102)

Trade X prodgap t-1 -0.17*** -0.52*** -0.20** -0.63*** -0.11 -0.87***

(0.055) (0.142) (0.085) (0.135) (0.104) (0.191)

Debt t-1 0.04** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.07*** 0.05*** 0.06***

(0.015) (0.019) (0.017) (0.022) (0.016) (0.021)

Debt X prodgap t-1 -0.01 -0.00 -0.00 0.02 -0.00 0.01

(0.008) (0.014) (0.009) (0.014) (0.011) (0.019)

Inflation t-1 -0.10 -0.04 -0.11 0.08 -0.07 0.09

(0.092) (0.157) (0.125) (0.186) (0.097) (0.151)

Inflation X prodgap t-1 -0.05 -0.10 -0.07 0.07 0.01 0.22

(0.146) (0.265) (0.180) (0.288) (0.203) (0.350)

N 2,281 2,281 1,856 1,856 1,856 1,856

R2 0.125

0.129

0.206

AR(1)

0.000

0.000

0.000

AR(2)

0.181

0.169

0.259

Sargan

0.000

0.000

0.000

Number of instruments

319

286

286

Number of regions 249 249 216 216 216 216

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 54: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

53

Table 9: Further robustness checks for the macroeconomic variables

Dependent variable: regional

productivity growth Without Spain Without Poland Without Ireland

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM FE

System

GMM

Frontiergrowth 0.05** 0.05** 0.05** 0.06*** 0.05*** 0.06***

(0.020) (0.021) (0.019) (0.020) (0.019) (0.020)

Productivity gap t-1 -2.17 3.33 -2.33 2.07 -2.13 3.08

(2.035) (3.614) (1.948) (3.455) (1.986) (3.637)

Trade t-1 -0.17*** -0.29*** -0.14*** -0.26*** -0.20*** -0.33***

(0.045) (0.073) (0.046) (0.076) (0.045) (0.075)

Trade X prodgap t-1 -0.12** -0.38*** -0.12** -0.37*** -0.13*** -0.40***

(0.049) (0.109) (0.047) (0.113) (0.050) (0.113)

Debt t-1 0.02 0.02 0.02* 0.03* 0.02* 0.03*

(0.014) (0.019) (0.012) (0.016) (0.013) (0.016)

Debt X prodgap t-1 -0.02** -0.02 -0.01* -0.01 -0.01* -0.01

(0.008) (0.013) (0.008) (0.012) (0.008) (0.013)

Inflation t-1 -0.01 0.02 -0.03 0.11 -0.05 -0.01

(0.079) (0.121) (0.080) (0.128) (0.079) (0.124)

Inflation X prodgap t-1 0.08 -0.04 0.14 0.18 0.03 -0.08

(0.132) (0.206) (0.132) (0.212) (0.132) (0.211)

N 2,309 2,309 2,355 2,355 2,474 2,474

R2 0.095

0.107

0.112

AR(1)

0.000

0.000

0.000

AR(2)

0.245

0.135

0.131

Sargan

0.000

0.000

0.000

Number of instruments

316

319

333

Number of regions 246 246 249 249 263 263

Dependent variable is regional productivity growth at the TL2 level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered by region. ***, **, * indicate significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.

Page 55: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

54

Appendix

Fixed effects estimates of marginal effects of the macroeconomic variables:

Figure A1: Marginal effects of macroeconomic variables, OLS.

Page 56: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

55

Figure A2: Excluding frontier regions, OLS.

Figure A3: Excluding top three regions, OLS.

Page 57: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

56

Figure A4: Alternative frontier region, OLS.

Figure A5: Excluding Spanish regions, OLS.

Page 58: Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity ...webspace.qmul.ac.uk/pmartins/CGRWP86.pdf · Impact of macro-structural reforms on the productivity growth of regions: distance

57

Figure A6: Excluding Polish regions, OLS.

Figure A7: Excluding Irish regions, OLS.