Heckman - The Importance of Noncognitive Skills Lessons From the GED Testing Program

6
American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review. http://www.jstor.org American Economic Association The Importance of Noncognitive Skills: Lessons from the GED Testing Program Author(s): James J. Heckman and Yona Rubinstein Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred Thirteenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 2001), pp. 145-149 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2677749 Accessed: 01-04-2015 20:21 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

description

It is common knowledge outside of academicjournals that motivation, tenacity, trustworthiness,and perseverance are important traits forsuccess in life. Thomas Edison wrote that "geniusis 1 percent inspiration and 99 percentperspiration."M ost parents read the Aesop fableof the "Tortoise and The Hare" to theiryoung children at about the same time they readthem the story of "The Little Train That Could."Numerous instances can be cited of high-IQpeople who failed to achieve success in lifebecause they lacked self discipline and low-IQpeople who succeeded by virtue of persistence,reliability, and self-discipline. The value oftrustworthiness has recently been demonstratedwhen market systems were extended to EasternEuropean societies with traditions of corruptionand deceit.

Transcript of Heckman - The Importance of Noncognitive Skills Lessons From the GED Testing Program

  • American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American EconomicReview.

    http://www.jstor.org

    American Economic Association

    The Importance of Noncognitive Skills: Lessons from the GED Testing Program Author(s): James J. Heckman and Yona Rubinstein Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred

    Thirteenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 2001), pp. 145-149Published by: American Economic AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2677749Accessed: 01-04-2015 20:21 UTC

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of contentin a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

  • THE BENEFITS OF SKILLt

    The Importance of Noncognitive Skills: Lessons from the GED Testing Program

    By JAMES J. HECKMAN AND YONA RUBINSTEIN*

    It is common knowledge outside of academic journals that motivation, tenacity, trustworthi- ness, and perseverance are important traits for success in life. Thomas Edison wrote that "ge- nius is 1 percent inspiration and 99 percent perspiration." Most parents read the Aesop fa- ble of the "Tortoise and The Hare" to their young children at about the same time they read them the story of "The Little Train That Could." Numerous instances can be cited of high-IQ people who failed to achieve success in life because they lacked self discipline and low-IQ people who succeeded by virtue of persistence, reliability, and self-discipline. The value of trustworthiness has recently been demonstrated when market systems were extended to Eastern European societies with traditions of corruption and deceit.

    It is thus surprising that academic discussions of skill and skill formation almost exclusively focus on measures of cognitive ability and ig- nore noncognitive skills. The early literature on human capital (e.g. Gary Becker, 1964) con- trasted cognitive-ability models of earnings with human capital models, ignoring noncogni- tive traits entirely. The signaling literature (e.g., Michael Spence, 1974), emphasized that educa-

    tion was a signal of a one-dimensional ability, usually interpreted as a cognitive skill. Most discussions of ability bias in the estimated re- turn to education treat omitted ability as cogni- tive ability and attempt to proxy the missing ability by cognitive tests. Most assessments of school reforms stress the gain from reforms as measured by the ability of students to perform on a standardized achievement test. Widespread use of standardized achievement and ability tests for admissions and educational evaluation are premised on the belief that the skills that can be tested are essential for success in schooling, a central premise of the educational-testing movement since its inception.

    Much of the neglect of noncognitive skills in analyses of earnings, schooling, and other life- time outcomes is due to the lack of any reliable measure of them. Many different personality and motivational traits are lumped into the cat- egory of noncognitive skills. Psychologists have developed batteries of tests to measure noncog- nitive skills (e.g., Robert Sternberg, 1985). These tests are used by companies to screen workers but are not yet used to ascertain college readiness or to evaluate the effectiveness of schools or reforms of schools. The literature on cognitive tests ascertains that one dominant fac- tor ("g") summarizes cognitive tests and their effects on outcomes. No single factor has yet emerged to date in the literature on noncogni- tive skills, and it is unlikely that one will ever be found, given the diversity of traits subsumed under the category of noncognitive skills.

    Studies by Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gin- tis (1976), Rick Edwards (1976), and Roger Klein et al. (1991) demonstrate that job stability and dependability are traits most valued by em- ployers as ascertained by supervisor ratings and questions of employers although they present no direct evidence on wages and educational

    t Discussants: Susan Mayer, University of Chicago; Cecilia Rouse, Princeton University; Nan Maxwell, Califor- nia State University-Hayward; Janet Currie, University of California-Los Angeles.

    * Heckman: Department of Economics, University of Chi- cago, 1126 E. 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, and American Bar Association (e-mail: [email protected]); Rubinstein: Department of Economics, University of Chicago (e-mail: [email protected]). This research was sup- ported by grants fiom NIH:RO1-HD32058-03, and NIH:RO1- HD34958-01, NSF-SBR-93-21-048, NSF 97-09-873, the Spencer Foundation, the Mellon Foundation, and the Donner Foundation. We are grateful for research assistance from Jingjing Hsee.

    145

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

  • 146 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2001

    attainment. Perseverance, dependability, and consistency are the most important predictors of grades in school (Bowles and Gintis, 1976).

    Self-reported measures of persistence, self- esteem, optimism, time preference, and the like are now being collected, and some of the papers in this session discuss estimates of the effects of these measures on earnings and schooling out- comes. These studies shed new light on the importance of noncognitive skills. Yet they are not without controversy. For example, ex post assessments of self-esteem may be as much the consequence as the cause of the measures being investigated.

    This paper avoids these problems by using evidence from the General Educational Devel- opment (GED) testing program in the United States to demonstrate the quantitative impor- tance of noncognitive skills in determining earnings and educational attainment. The GED program is a second-chance program that ad- ministers a battery of cognitive tests to self- selected high-school dropouts to determine whether or not they are the academic equiva- lents of high-school graduates.

    We summarize major findings reported in Heckman et al. (2000). The GED exam is suc- cessful in psychometrically equating GED test- takers with ordinary high-school graduates who do not go on to college. Recipients are as smart as ordinary high-school graduates who do not go on to college, where cognitive ability is measured by an average of cognitive compo- nents of the Armed Forces Qualifying Test (AFQT) or by the first principle component (g). By these same measures, GED recipients are smarter than other high-school dropouts who do not obtain a GED (see Fig. 1 for white males). The pattern is the same for other groups. GED recipients earn more than other high-school dropouts, have higher hourly wages, and finish more years of high school before they drop out. This is entirely consistent with the literature that emphasizes the importance of cognitive skills in determining labor-market outcomes.

    Controlling for measured ability, however, GED recipients earn less, have lower hourly wages, and obtain lower levels of schooling than other high-school dropouts. Some unmea- sured factor accounts for their relatively poor performance compared to other dropouts. We identify this factor as noncognitive skill, recog-

    - High school graduates 25--

    -*-GEDs

    0

    M- L/ 10-

    -2.5 -2.0 --1.5 --1.0 -0.5 0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 Age-Adjusted AFQT

    FIGURE 1. DENSITY OF AGE-ADJUSTED AFQT SCORES FOR WHITE MALE GED RECIPIENTS AND HIGH-SCHOOL

    GRADUATES WITH 12 YEARS OF SCHOOLING

    nizing that a subsequent analysis should parcel out which specific noncognitive factors are the most important.

    The GED is a mixed signal. Dropouts who take the GED are smarter (have higher cognitive skills) than other high-school dropouts and yet at the same time have lower levels of noncog- nitive skills. Both types of skill are valued in the market and affect schooling choices. Our find- ing challenges the conventional signaling liter- ature, which assumes a single skill. It also demonstrates the folly of a psychometrically oriented educational evaluation policy that as- sumes cognitive skills to be all that matter. Inadvertently, a test has been created that sep- arates out bright but nonpersistent and undisci- plined dropouts from other dropouts. It is, then, no surprise that GED recipients are the ones who drop out of school, fail to complete college (Stephen Cameron and James Heckman, 1993) and who fail to persist in the military (Janice Laurence, 2000). GED's are "wiseguys," who lack the abilities to think ahead, to persist in tasks, or to adapt to their environments. The performance of the GED recipients compared to both high-school dropouts of the same ability and high-school graduates demonstrates the im- portance of noncognitive skills in economic life.

    I. Evidence from the GED Program

    David Boesel et al. (1998) present a compre- hensive review of evidence on the GED pro- gram. Currently one in two high-school dropouts and one in five high-school graduates,

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

  • VOL. 91 NO. 2 THE BENEFITS OF SKILL 147

    as classified by the U.S. Census, is a GED recipient.' In a series of papers using National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) data (Cameron and Heckman, 1993; Heckman et al., 2000), the following facts have been established about white males: (i) In unadjusted cross- sectional comparisons, GED recipients eam hourly wage rates and annual earnings substan- tially less than those of high-school graduates and earn slightly more than other high-school dropouts. GED recipients also have slightly more years of schooling than other dropouts. Accounting for their higher years of schooling, and for their higher AFQT scores, GED recip- ients earn less than other high-school dropouts and have lower hourly wages. These results are statistically significant. (ii) Controlling for fixed effects, longitudinal studies reveal that there is no evidence of a permanent effect of GED cer- tification on wages, employment, or job turn- over for persons who take the GED after age 17. GED recipients are more likely to change jobs, both before and after taking the exam. (iii) Both cognitive and noncognitive skills promote edu- cational attainment. (iv) Persons with higher AFQT scores take the GED earlier. This ac- counts for an larger initial positive effect of GED certification on earnings for younger re- cipients that disappears with age. (v) In a model that explicitly accounts for both unmeasured (or badly measured) cognitive and noncognitive skills, in the short run GED certification appears to have an effect of boosting wages for persons who take the GED exam at young ages (younger than age 20), holding constant noncognitive skills, by signaling greater cognitive ability of workers. This effect fades quickly as employers rapidly learn about cognitive ability. In the long run, holding ability constant, GED recipients earn lower wages as their adverse noncognitive characteristics are revealed. (vi) The story for white females is slightly different. Girls who drop out of school because of pregnancy typi- cally do so with fewer years of schooling at- tained than other girls who drop out. Girls who

    drop out for reasons other than pregnancy are like teenage boys who drop out (i.e., they earn less than other dropouts, conditioning on AFQT or schooling). As for teenage mothers, GED recipients earn the same as other high-school dropouts once AFQT scores and years of schooling are accounted for. (vii) There is some suggestion that white male GED recipients show the highest level of participation in (al- most) every category of participation in illegal activity, compared to other high-school drop- outs. This is true even when the outcomes are not adjusted for differences in AFQT and edu- cational attainment. It is also true when we drop persons who acquire the GED in prison, or all persons who have been in prison, to avoid a spurious causal relationship arising from pris- oners, and hence people with a greater partici- pation in crime, acquiring the GED (see Table 1). The same applies for white females, except for teenage mothers, who are much less likely to get the GED in prison. GED recipients are more likely to participate in illegal drug use, drug- selling, fighting in school, vandalism, shoplift- ing, theft, robberies, and school absenteeism than are other dropouts.2 (viii) The labor-force participation and employment rates of GED re- cipients are lower than those of other dropouts.3 Their turnover rates are higher. These rates do not change with the acquisition of the GED. Hence, GED recipients accumulate less work experience over the life cycle. (ix) The correla- tion between AFQT scores and an index of participation in illicit activity defined in Heck- man et al. (2000) is statistically significantly negative in the population at large (see Table 2). Individuals with higher AFQT scores are less likely to participate in illicit behavior. Yet this relationship does not hold within education groups. The correlation between AFQT scores and our index among all high-school dropouts and among high-school graduates (with 12 years of schooling) is positive and statistically significant. It is especially strong for all drop- outs, suggesting that, among high-school drop- outs, the higher the AFQT score, the more likely

    1 When GED recipients are counted as dropouts, the U.S. high-school dropout rate increased between 1975 and 1988 (see Heckman et al., 2000). In Heckman et al. (2000), we also document that the growth in GED certification among minorities accounts for a substantial component of the gap between black and white high-school graduates.

    2 Excluding GED recipients, the rate of illegal and de- linquent behavior decreases monotonically as education lev- els rise.

    3Conditional on AFQT scores and years of schooling completed.

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

  • 148 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2001

    TABLE 1-ILLICIT ACTIVITY BY WHITES, SHOWN SEPARATELY FOR HIGH-SCHOOL DROPOUTS, GED

    RECIPIENTS, AND HIGH-SCHOOL GRADUATES

    Behavior HSD GED HSG

    Males:

    Index of illicit activity 0.11 0.18* 0.05 (ILA) (0.012) (0.017) (0.006)

    Particular questions: Skipped school in 0.13 0.10 0.00

    last year (0.023) (0.030) (0.011) Shoplifted last year 0.05 0.15* 0.01

    (0.027) (0.039) (0.014) Used drugs last year 0.10 0.26* 0.03

    (0.026) (0.039) (0.013) Ever stopped by 0.16 0.25* 0.09

    police (0.028) (0.039) (0.014) Females: Index of illicit activity -0.01 0.05* -0.04

    (ILA) (0.013) (0.015) (0.004) Particular questions:

    Skipped school in 0.00 0.13* 0.00 last year (0.030) (0.035) (0.011)

    Shoplifted last year 0.00 0.17* -0.03 (0.038) (0.045) (0.014)

    Used drugs last year 0.09 0.24* 0.03 (0.038) (0.045) (0.013)

    Ever stopped by -0.03 0.00 -0.09 police (0.030) (0.035) (0.009)

    Notes: The table shows means (with standard errors in parentheses) from the NLSY for 22 yes/no questions re- garding illegal and delinquent behavior, surveyed in 1980. Responses are age-adjusted and standardized to 0 mean in the population sample. ILA is the average score on the 22 yes/no questions regarding illicit and delinquent behavior. The male subsample excludes males reporting being in prison, for any period of time, in the years 1979-1994. The female subsample excludes teenage mothers. Abbrevia- tions: HSD = high-school dropouts who do not get a GED degree; GED = GED recipients; HSG = high-school graduates who do not take further schooling (12 years of schooling).

    * Significantly different from HSD figures at the 5- percent level.

    is participation in illicit activity. Such a trade- off is entirely consistent with the view that both cognitive and noncognitive traits play important roles in determining graduation from high school.

    II. Implications for Policy and Research

    There are three main conclusions that we draw from our analysis apart from the conclu-

    TABLE 2-NoRMALIZED REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS OF AFQT SCORES ON INDEX OF ILLICIT ACTIVITY (ILA)

    FOR WHITE MALES

    All All dropoutsa HSGb

    Variable (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) ILA -0.114 0.076 0.205 0.209 0.109

    (0.031) (0.028) (0.069) (0.063) (0.05) Schoolingc 0.639 0.362

    (0.025) (0.061)

    Notes: ILA is the average score on 22 yes/no questions regarding illicit and delinquent behavior from the NLSY. The table reports results for a subsample of white males aged 16-18 when behavior was surveyed (1980). The sub- sample excludes people reporting being in prison, for any period of time, in the years 1979-1994. Standard errors are given in parentheses.

    a GED recipients and other high-school dropouts. b High-school graduates who do not take further

    schooling. c For all dropouts, highest grade completed when they

    dropped out; for all others, highest grade completed (in 1994).

    sion that the GED is a mixed signal that char- acterizes its recipients as smart but unreliable. (i) Current systems of evaluating educational reforms are based on changes in scores on cog- nitive tests. These tests capture only one of the many skills required for a successful life (see Heckman, 1999). A more comprehensive eval- uation of educational systems would account for their effects on producing the noncognitive traits that are also valued in the market. There is substantial evidence that mentoring and motiva- tional programs oriented toward disadvantaged teenagers are effective. Much of the effective- ness of early-childhood interventions comes in boosting noncognitive skills and in fostering motivation (see Heckman [2000] for a compre- hensive review of the literature). It has long been conjectured that the greater effectiveness of Catholic schools comes in producing more motivated and self-disciplined students (James Coleman and Thomas Hoffer, 1983). It has also been conjectured that the decline in discipline in inner-city public schools is a major source of their failure. It would be valuable to gather more systematic information on noncognitive effects of alternative education systems. (ii) IQ is fairly well set by age 8. Motivation and self discipline are more malleable at later ages (Heckman, 2000). Given the evidence on the

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

  • VOL. 91 NO. 2 THE BENEFITS OF SKILL 149

    quantitative importance of noncognitive traits, social policy should be more active in attempt- ing to alter them, especially for children from disadvantaged environments who receive poor discipline and encouragement at home. This would include mentoring programs and stricter enforcement of discipline in the schools. Such interventions will benefit the child and the larger society but at the same time may conflict with the liberal value of the sanctity of families that undervalue self-discipline and motivation and resent the imposition of middle-class values on their children. (iii) A more technical conclu- sion concerns the formulation of signaling models. Much of the current literature on labor- market signaling assumes a single hidden skill that is partially revealed by a test or a choice. Our evidence suggests that the GED is a mixed signal and conveys information about both cog- nitive and noncognitive skills. Mixed signals pose a challenge to economic theory because in general the "single crossing property" is vio- lated. This requires a reformulation of signaling theory. Aloisio Araujo and Humberto Moreira (1999) develop such a reformulation.

    This paper is written in the spirit of "dark matter" research in astrophysics. We have es- tablished the quantitative importance of non- cognitive skills without identifying any specific noncognitive skill. Research in the field is in its infancy. Too little is understood about the for- mation of these skills or about the separate effects of all of these diverse traits currently subsumed under the rubric of noncognitive skills.4 What we currently know, however, sug- gests that further research on the topic is likely to be very fruitful.

    REFERENCES

    Araujo, Aloisio and Humberto, Moreira. "Ad- verse Selection Problems without the Spence-Mirlees Condition." Unpublished manuscript, Institute of Pure and Applied Mathematics (IMPA), Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, Summer 1999.

    Becker, Gary. Human capital; a theoretical and

    empirical analysis, with special reference to education. New York: Columbia University Press, 1964.

    Boesel, David; Alsalam, Nabeel and Smith, Thomas. Educational and labor market per- formance of GED recipients. Washington, DC: National Library of Education, Office of Educational Research and Improvements, U.S. Department of Education, February 1998.

    Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert. Schooling in capitalist America. New York: Basic Books, 1976.

    Cameron, Stephen and Heckman, James. "The Nonequivalence of High School Equiva- lents." Journal of Labor Economics, January 1993, 11(1), pp. 1-47.

    Coleman, James and Hoffer, Thomas. Public and private high schools. New York: Basic Books, 1983.

    Edwards, Rick. "Individual Traits and Organiza- tional Incentives: What Makes A 'Good' Worker?" Journal of Human Resources, Winter 1976, 11(1), pp. 51-68.

    Heckman, James. "Education and Job Training: Doing It Right." Public Interest, Spring 1999, (135), pp. 86-107.

    . "Policies to Foster Human Capital." Research in Economics, Spring 2000, 54(1), pp. 3-56.

    Heckman, James; Hsee, Jingjing and Rubinstein, Yona. "The GED is a Mixed Signal." Unpub- lished manuscript presented at American Economic Association meeting, Boston, Massachusetts, January 2000.

    Klein, Roger; Spady, Richard and Weiss, Andrew. "Factors Affecting the Output and Quit Pro- pensities of Production Workers." Review of Economic Studies, October 1991, 58(2), pp. 929-54.

    Laurence, Janice. "Use of the GED by the United States Armed Forces." Unpublished manuscript presented at Midwest Economics Association Meeting, March, 1998; in James Heckman, ed., The GED. Unpublished manu- script, University of Chicago, 2000.

    Spence, Michael. Market signalling. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1974.

    Sternberg, Robert J. Beyond IQ: A triarchic the- ory of human intelligence. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1985.

    4 Heckman et al. (2000) note that GED recipients are more likely to come from affluent, but broken, homes than are other dropouts.

    This content downloaded from 200.130.19.173 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 20:21:45 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    Article Contentsp. 145p. 146p. 147p. 148p. 149

    Issue Table of ContentsAmerican Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, May, 2001Front Matter [pp. i - 458]Editor's Introduction [p. vii]Sherwin Rosen: In Memoriam [p. viii]Richard T. Ely LectureStruggling to Understand the Stock Market [pp. 1 - 11]

    Human Capital: Growth, History, and Policy: A Session to Honor Stanley EngermanHuman Capital and Growth [pp. 12 - 17]The Legacy of U.S. Educational Leadership: Notes on Distribution and Economic Growth in the 20th Century [pp. 18 - 23]Black-White Achievement Differences and Governmental Interventions [pp. 24 - 28]

    Development and History: A Session to Honor Stanley EngermanInput Trade and the Location of Production [pp. 29 - 33]Why Did Productivity Fall So Much during the Great Depression? [pp. 34 - 38]Market Trade in Patents and the Rise of a Class of Specialized Inventors in the 19th-Century United States [pp. 39 - 44]

    Robustness to UncertaintySharing Ambiguity [pp. 45 - 50]Pitfalls of a Minimax Approach to Model Uncertainty [pp. 51 - 54]Minimax Estimation and Forecasting in a Stationary Autoregression Model [pp. 55 - 59]Robust Control and Model Uncertainty [pp. 60 - 66]

    Economics and Social BehaviorDo People Mean What They Say? Implications for Subjective Survey Data [pp. 67 - 72]In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies [pp. 73 - 78]Growing up in the Projects: The Economic Lives of a Cohort of Men Who Came of Age in Chicago Public Housing [pp. 79 - 84]

    Youths and Risky BehaviorYouth Smoking in the 1990's: Why Did It Rise and What Are the Long-Run Implications? [pp. 85 - 90]Behavioral Policies and Teen Traffic Safety [pp. 91 - 96]Going to College to Avoid the Draft: The Unintended Legacy of the Vietnam War [pp. 97 - 102]

    New Developments in Evaluating Social ProgramsDesigning Programs for Heterogeneous Populations: The Value of Covariate Information [pp. 103 - 106]Policy-Relevant Treatment Effects [pp. 107 - 111]Reconciling Conflicting Evidence on the Performance of Propensity-Score Matching Methods [pp. 112 - 118]Propensity-Score Matching with Instrumental Variables [pp. 119 - 124]

    Between Parents and Children: Child Support and Child DisabilityInteractions between Unmarried Fathers and Their Children: The Role of Paternity Establishment and Child-Support Policies [pp. 125 - 129]The Effect of Child-Support Policies on Visitations and Transfers [pp. 130 - 134]New Estimates of the Impact of Child Disability on Maternal Employment [pp. 135 - 139]Signals of Child Achievement as Determinants of Child Support [pp. 140 - 144]

    The Benefits of SkillThe Importance of Noncognitive Skills: Lessons from the GED Testing Program [pp. 145 - 149]As Ye Sweep, So Shall Ye Reap [pp. 150 - 154]Incentive-Enhancing Preferences: Personality, Behavior, and Earnings [pp. 155 - 158]Understanding, Speaking, Reading, Writing, and Earnings in the Immigrant Labor Market [pp. 159 - 163]

    Racial Dynamics in Labor Markets: Exogenous or Endogenous?Black-White Earnings Differentials: Privatization versus Deregulation [pp. 164 - 168]Market Structure and Racial Earnings: Evidence from Job-Changers [pp. 169 - 173]Racial Differences in Transportation Access to Employment in Chicago and Los Angeles, 1980 and 1990 [pp. 174 - 177]Annual Income and Identity Formation among Persons of Mexican Descent [pp. 178 - 183]

    The Scope of the Firm: New Empirical DirectionsAssessing the Property Rights and Transaction-Cost Theories of Firm Scope [pp. 184 - 188]Empirical Strategies in Contract Economics: Information and the Boundary of the Firm [pp. 189 - 194]Do Firm Boundaries Matter? [pp. 195 - 199]

    Organizational EconomicsOrganizational Design: Decision Rights and Incentive Contracts [pp. 200 - 205]The Influence of the Financial Revolution on the Nature of Firms [pp. 206 - 211]Bringing the Market Inside the Firm? [pp. 212 - 218]

    Recent Advances in Monetary-Policy RulesInterest Rates and Inflation [pp. 219 - 225]NAIRU Uncertainty and Nonlinear Policy Rules [pp. 226 - 231]The Taylor Rule and Optimal Monetary Policy [pp. 232 - 237]

    Exchange Rates and the Choice of Monetary-Policy RegimesFewer Monies, Better Monies [pp. 238 - 242]Why Not a Global Currency? [pp. 243 - 247]Optimal Monetary Policy in Open versus Closed Economies: An Integrated Approach [pp. 248 - 252]

    Quantitative Policy Implications of New Normative Macroeconomic ResearchShould Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? [pp. 253 - 257]Should Monetary Policy Respond Strongly to Output Gaps? [pp. 258 - 262]The Role of the Exchange Rate in Monetary-Policy Rules [pp. 263 - 267]

    Price and Quality MeasurementPrice and Quality of Desktop and Mobile Personal Computers: A Quarter- Century Historical Overview [pp. 268 - 273]The Acceleration in Variety Growth [pp. 274 - 280]Productivity Change in Health Care [pp. 281 - 286]

    Interconnection and Access in Telecom and the InternetInternet Peering [pp. 287 - 291]Advances in Routing Technologies and Internet Peering Agreements [pp. 292 - 296]Access Pricing, Bypass, and Universal Service [pp. 297 - 301]Cable Modems and DSL: Broadband Internet Access for Residential Customers [pp. 302 - 307]

    E-Commerce E-ConomyDo We Have a New E-Conomy? [pp. 308 - 312]Projecting the Economic Impact of the Internet [pp. 313 - 317]E-Commerce: Measurement and Measurement Issues [pp. 318 - 322]

    Technology, Education, and Economic GrowthSchooling Data, Technological Diffusion, and the Neoclassical Model [pp. 323 - 327]Cross-Country Technology Diffusion: The Case of Computers [pp. 328 - 335]Why Wait? A Century of Life Before IPO [pp. 336 - 341]

    Conflict and the EconomyAppeasement: Can It Work? [pp. 342 - 346]The Creation of Effective Property Rights [pp. 347 - 352]Guns, Butter, and Openness: On the Relationship between Security and Trade [pp. 353 - 357]

    Fragmentation, Diversification, and International TradeCommercial Policy in a "Fragmented" World [pp. 358 - 362]The Role of International Fragmentation in the Development Process [pp. 363 - 366]Trade and Exposure [pp. 367 - 370]International Trade and Business Cycles: Is Vertical Specialization the Missing Link? [pp. 371 - 375]

    Currency UnionsCoping with Terms-of-Trade Shocks: Pegs versus Floats [pp. 376 - 380]Dollarization [pp. 381 - 385]National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union [pp. 386 - 390]

    Exchange-Rate Exposure of Firms and WorkersExchange-Rate Hedging: Financial versus Operational Strategies [pp. 391 - 395]A Reexamination of Exchange-Rate Exposure [pp. 396 - 399]Gender Differences in the Labor-Market Effects of the Dollar [pp. 400 - 405]

    Precautionary SavingsThe Empirical Importance of Precautionary Saving [pp. 406 - 412]How Important Are Idiosyncratic Shocks? Evidence from Labor Supply [pp. 413 - 417]Interest Elasticity in a Life-Cycle Model with Precautionary Savings [pp. 418 - 421]

    Financial IntermediariesBanks and Liquidity [pp. 422 - 425]Venture Capitalists as Principals: Contracting, Screening, and Monitoring [pp. 426 - 430]A Reason for Quantity Regulation [pp. 431 - 435]Financial Intermediation without Exclusivity [pp. 436 - 439]

    New Research in Economic EducationResearch in Economic Education: Five New Initiatives [pp. 440 - 445]Teaching Economics at the Start of the 21st Century: Still Chalk-and-Talk [pp. 446 - 451]Assessing the Economic Understanding of U.S. High School Students [pp. 452 - 457]

    Proceedings of the Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting [pp. 459 - 511]Back Matter [pp. i - xxiv]