HE311 Term Paper

download HE311 Term Paper

of 36

description

A preliminary report of cost benefit analysis on the tax increase on tobacco and alcohol in 2014 in Singapore. Completed as a part the academic requirement for HE311 - Cost and Benefit Analysis

Transcript of HE311 Term Paper

  • 1

    HE311 Cost-Benefit Analysis

    Term Paper

    AY2013/2014 Semester 2

    Topic

    Cost-Benefit Analysis on Sin Tax

    Name Matriculation Number

    Alan Dai Sheng U1030562D

    Lee Liang Tian U1030042J

    Lee Yee Jia Jamie U1030852A

    Ong Soo Yue U1030677L

    Wong Li Ting U1030590D

    Yap Hon Looi Jensen U1030257G

  • 2

    SECTION 1: INTRODUCTION 1 SECTION 2: TOBACCO - INDIVIDUAL COSTS AND BENEFITS 3 2.1 ADDICTED SMOKERS 3 2.2 NON-ADDICTED/POTENTIAL SMOKERS 3 2.3 COSTS 4 2.3.1 DISUTILITY & DISSATISFACTION 4 2.3.2 LOSS OF ENJOYMENT 6 2.3.3 LOSS OF SOCIAL OPPORTUNITIES 6 2.3 BENEFITS 7 2.3.1 PERSONAL SAVINGS 7 2.3.2 REDUCED HEALTH RISK 7 SECTION 3: LIQUOR INDIVIDUAL COSTS AND BENEFITS 10 3.1 COSTS 10 3.1.1 LOSS OF CONSUMER SATISFACTION 10 3.1.2 PARTIAL LOSS OF HEALTH BENEFITS 12 3.2 BENEFITS 13 3.2.1 INCREASE PRODUCTIVITY 13 3.2.2 PERSONAL SAVING 14 3.2.3 HEALTH BENEFITS 14 SECTION 4: SOCIAL COSTS 16 4.1 MARKET INEFFICIENCY 16 4.2 REDUCTION IN TOTAL SURPLUS 17 4.3 THE CIGARETTE BLACK MARKET 17 4.4 INCOME DISPARITY 19

  • 3

    SECTION 5: SOCIAL BENEFIT 20 5.1 ADDITIONAL TAX REVENUE 20 5.2 DETERRENCE OF NEW ENTRANTS 21 5.3 SAVING ON PRODUCTIVITY LOSS 22 5.4 FEWER EXTERNALITIES 23 5.4.1 FEWER TRAFFIC ACCIDENTS 23 5.4.2 LESSER AIR POLLUTION 25 5.5 REDUCTION OF EMOTION DISTRESS 25 6. CONCLUSION 26 APPENDIX: INDIVIDUAL CONTRIBUTIONS 29 BIBLIOGRAPHY 31

  • 1

    SECTION 1:

    INTRODUCTION

    On 21 February 2014, Singapore Government announced its Budget statement

    for 2014. The statement introduced a so-called sin tax increase on tobacco and

    alcohol (Chang, 2014). The excise duties for cigarettes and other tobacco products

    were raised with immediate effect by 10% and for all liquor products, 25%.

    Combined, the increases in the sin tax are to yield additional revenue of

    approximately 200 million for the government. (Ministry of Finance, 2014)

    According to Deputy Prime minister Tharman Shanmugaratnam, the objective

    of such increases is to discourage excessive consumption of both products (Channel

    News Asia, 2014). It has been almost a decade since the last increase. The previous

    increase in tobacco duties was introduced in 2005, while the excise duties on liquor

    products have remained constant (Ministry of Finance, 2014).

    During the past decade from 2006 to 2012, alcoholic beverage and tobacco

    consumption has seen has been growing at a rate of 5.66% annually at 2005 constant

    price, outpacing the annual total population growth rate of 3.19% (Department of

    Statistics, Singapore, 2013). The per capita consumption of tobacco and alcohol

    products has certainly gone up. On the other hand, the growth in consumption has

    led to 33.15% more jobs, equivalent to an annual increase of 4.89%, in the related

    industry during the same time period (Department of Statistics, Singapore, 2013).

    The percentage of smoking population in Singapore has seen an upward trend,

    starting from 12.6% in 2004, to 14.3% in 2010, and eventually reaching 16% in 2012

    (Abraham, 2012). Among those who smoke, 4.5% are reported to be addicted. Over

    35% of the smoking addicts are between 18 and 35 years old (Ministry of Health,

  • 2

    2012). Alcohol consumption is of a different nature because non-excessive drinking

    might bring net benefit. Nonetheless, as reported by World Health Organization,

    1.59% of the Singapores population suffered from alcohol use disorder in 2006.

    Besides, among every 100,000 people, 4.4 cases of liver cirrhosis, a recognized

    consequence of excessive drinking, are reported (World Health Organisation, 2011).

    The imposition of higher excise duties is expected to reduce the consumption of

    both demerit goods. However, the impact of higher taxes goes beyond the reduction

    of health risks among individuals and extends to other socioeconomic aspects.

    Leveraging the tool of cost-benefit analysis, this report aims to provide a

    comprehensive albeit preliminary view of how the increase in excise duties for

    tobacco and alcohol affect various aspects of the economy. For the purpose of

    discussion, the report begins with individual cost-benefit analyses of tobacco and

    liquor tax respectively, before diving into social costs and benefits of the sin tax

    increase as a whole.

  • 3

    SECTION 2:

    TOBACCO - INDIVIDUAL COSTS AND BENEFITS

    The recent Budget 2014 has announced a 10% increase in tax for tobacco

    product, which is aimed to reduce the prevalence of smoking among Singaporeans.

    This section presents a cost-benefit analysis of the tobacco tax increase from an

    individuals perspective. For the purpose of the analysis, smokers are classified into

    two categories, namely (i) addicted smokers and (ii) non-addicted smokers.

    2.1 ADDICTED SMOKERS

    Addicted smokers are defined as those highly addicted to the habit of smoking

    and certainly have the expenditure on cigarettes integrated in their consumption

    decision model. Their demand for cigarettes is presumed to be highly inelastic.

    Therefore, a 10% increase in tax, equivalent to a price increase of $0.7 to $1.1 per

    pack of cigarettes, is unlikely to alter their consumption pattern. This suggests that

    the tax policy is ineffective in deterring the smoking habits of this group. In other

    words, this tax policy is predicted to only result in additional costs to this group,

    without generating remarkable benefits.

    2.2 NON-ADDICTED/POTENTIAL SMOKERS

    Non-addicted smokers include those who smoke socially and lightly, those who

    just started to smoke, and those who might start to smoke in the near future. Young

    adults account for the majority of this category, with a certain percentage being

    students and other low-income demographic groups. They are yet addicted, which

    allows them to refrain from smoking rather easily. For those with relatively low

  • 4

    income, the increase in tax further move them up their elastic demand curves,

    prompting them to discontinue the habit.

    2.3 COSTS

    2.3.1 DISUTILITY & DISSATISFACTION

    According to National Health Survey 2010, the mean number of cigarettes

    consumed by an addicted smoker is 12 cigarettes per day. With the tax increase, the

    price of cigarette per stick is expected to increase by 3.6 cents (Ministry of Finance,

    2014). It is calculated that the estimated increment in a regular smokers expenditure

    per month is 12.96 dollars.

    Estimated total increment in individual expenditure on cigarettes per month

    = 12 x $0.036 x 30 = $12.96

    As shown in Figure 2.1 below, the demand curve has a steep slope due to the

    highly inelastic demand of regular smokers. Thus, when a tax is imposed, price has a

    noticeable jump from P1 to P2, while the decrease in the number of cigarettes

    consumed daily is relatively smaller in scale. This effect is most pronounced in the

    short-term, where the demand is virtually close to perfectly inelastic. In such an

    extreme case, there is only jump in price with no reduction in quantity consumed.

    Therefore, for an addicted smoker, an increment in the expenditure on cigarettes is

    certainly taking place and cannot be easily avoided without a change in his

    consumption pattern.

  • 5

    FIGURE 2.1 HIGHLY INELASTIC DEMAND (ADDICTED SMOKER)

    Figure 2.2 illustrates the impact of the tax on an addicted smoker with perfectly

    inelastic demand. The shaded area represents the decrease in consumer surplus,

    which is equivalent to the increment in the consumers expenditure in this case, at

    $12.96. In reality, with imperfectly inelastic demand, the actual loss in consumer

    surplus is slightly smaller than $12.96. However, the deviation is expected to be

    little.

    FIGURE 2.2 PERFECTLY INELASTIC DEMAND (ADDICTED SMOKER)

  • 6

    Consumer surplus could be defined as the satisfaction or utility consumers

    receive for which they dont have to pay for. Therefore, the reduction in consumer

    surplus suggests a corresponding decrease in the satisfaction or utility level of

    addicted smokers.

    2.3.2 LOSS OF ENJOYMENT

    Smoking is an enjoyable activity to most smokers, addicted or non-addicted. It

    can help one relax and relieve from tension. However, smoking has negative and

    widely recognized impacts on health.

    It is assumed that an individual smoker, as a rational consumer, weighs both the

    individual cost and benefit before buying a pack of cigarettes. As illustrated in the

    equation below, the value of this enjoyment is indicated by the willingness to pay

    for such a habit, which equals to the sum of the price of cigarette and the health-

    related risk one is willing to take when smoking. For social smokers who do not to

    smoke daily, they probably aware of the risk of prolonged smoking, so their

    willingness to undertake health risk is small. As a result, the cost for them to forgo

    this enjoyment of smoking is small.

    Total value of smoking = Willingness to pay for smoking

    = Price of cigarettes

    + Health risks

    2.3.3 LOSS OF SOCIAL OPPORTUNITIES

    Another reasons that people start smoking is that they can integrate better into a

    social circle, or they use it as an opportunity to carry out social interaction. In some

    circumstances, smoking is a stepping-stone for one to join a particular social circle.

  • 7

    Not smoking might seem as an unfriendly gesture to the smoking peers, alienating

    oneself from them, and thus hindering integration. The value of this cost is hard to

    determine and it varies on an individual basis. Some will find this cost substantial in

    a business social context and some are just going to lose some smoking friends.

    2.3 BENEFITS

    2.3.1 PERSONAL SAVINGS

    Smoking is an expensive activity as it can cost hundreds of dollars monthly if

    addicted. A regular smoker consumes approximately 18 packs of cigarettes a month

    with the current price ranging at $9.00 to $12.00 per pack. The expense is between

    $162 and $216 per month. For social/potential smokers, the consumption is lower

    but the rate of consumption can increase exponentially when the addiction is built.

    In the long run, not smoking is able to save quite a significant amount of money.

    We estimate the expenditure on cigarettes in a 10-year horizon. Assume ceteris

    paribus and take average annual inflation rate over the past 10 years (approximately

    2%):

    Annual expenditure of cigarette would be $ !"#!!"#! 12 = 2,268 = $",!"#!.!"! =!!!! $20,780

    2.3.2 REDUCED HEALTH RISK

    Long-term smoking is a major cause for health problems such as cancer, heart

    disease, stroke and Chronic Obstructive Pulmonary Disease (COPD). According to

  • 8

    Singapore Chinese Health Study, smokers generally have greater Hazard Ratio (HR)

    in these diseases. Besides, the report has also proven that the prevalence of stroke

    and cancer is higher among smokers (Sin How, Bee Choo et al. 2013). Most notable

    disease among smokers is lung cancer. Study shows that probability of getting lung

    cancer with smoking is 3.4% which is much higher than non-smokers 0.35%

    (Wong, Seow et al. 2010).

    TABLE 2.1. ADMISSIONS FOR LUNG CANCER (EXCL. SURGERIES)

    Ward Type Hospital Volume Average Length of Stay (days)

    50th percentile Bill ($)

    90th percentile Bill ($)

    A SGH 52 3.3 4498 10093

    Private (2 Bedded)

    MEH 40 1.4 5587 20494

    Private (4 Bedded)

    MEH 40 1.7 4268 12099

    B2 NUH 64 6.8 2074 3993

    SGH 217 3.8 1201 2697

    TTSH 114 2.6 621 2808

    C NUH 76 6.3 1268 2930

    SGH 122 4.8 898 2058

    TTSH 72 8.1 1209 2675

    Day Surgery (Private)

    MEH 50 1 3945 5030

    Source: Ministry of Health

    Total costs of treatments such as radiotherapy, chemotherapy, drugs and etc. is

    difficult to gauge, as it depends on the combinations of treatments that each patient

    requires. Plus, advancement in medical technologies further complicates the true

    estimation for the treatment cost. In general, treatment cost can be amount up to tens

    of thousands depending on individual condition in a month. In United States, the

    average monthly total cost of lung cancer for patient of a standardized age of 72

  • 9

    (with treatment) is about USD 16,000 in the year of 2000 (Cipriano, Romanus et al.

    2011). According to this information, we roughly estimate that average monthly

    total cost for lung cancer in Singapore in 2014: US$ 16,000 * (1.02)13 = US$

    20,678, with an error term subjected to country differences and medical

    advancement. Not smoking is able to reduce the risk of getting these diseases and

    hence avoiding the hefty medical bill.

  • 10

    SECTION 3:

    LIQUOR INDIVIDUAL COSTS AND BENEFITS

    3.1 COSTS

    3.1.1 LOSS OF CONSUMER SATISFACTION

    Alcohol is widely known for its muscle relaxing and anxiety reducing effects.

    This is due to the depression of the central nervous system resulting in slower

    communication to the brain. Also, drinking alcohol releases feel-good chemicals into

    the area of the human brain otherwise known as the pleasure center. This rush of

    chemicals leads to great surges of satisfaction and happiness (The Indian Express,

    2012). With the tax hike, this avenue of stress reduction and happiness will result in

    a likely loss in consumer satisfaction. Also, this tax hike is implemented at the

    expense of leisure attained from alcohol consumption.

    Furthermore, a survey carried out in a Northeastern liberal arts college in the US

    concluded that students who were engaged in binge drinking were reportedly happier

    than their non-binge drinking counterparts. This form of happiness derived from

    binge drinking was also associated with an elevated perception of social status

    amongst peers (Szalavitz, 2012).

    At the individual level, this loss in consumer satisfaction can be directly

    assumed to be the price increase in alcohol. For instance, before the tax hike, an

    individual is willing to pay $10 for a round of drinks at a bar. After the tax hike, the

    individual has to pay $10 (1 + Y) for the same round of drinks, where Y is the

    increase in alcohol costs due to tax hike. Assuming this individual decides to cap his

    expenditure at $10, he would be lowering his consumer satisfaction by Y%. Hence,

  • 11

    the value of consumer satisfaction lost can be assumed to be the elevation in alcohol

    costs due to the tax hike, because the minimum amount of money this individual

    requires is $10Y to bring him up to at least the original level of satisfaction.

    A United Nations Socioeconomic survey was conducted from 1990 to 2006.

    From the data, the latest observation on local alcohol consumption in 2006 was 2.6

    liters of pure alcohol per capita.

    Excise tax as a per cent of total retail price for 1 liter of pure alcohol = 2.1%

    Total value of excise tax = $70.00 per liter of pure alcohol

    Total retail price for 1 liter of pure alcohol: (70/2.1) X 100 = $3,333

    Based on the above illustration and the latest observation of local alcohol

    consumption of 2.6 liters of pure alcohol in 2006, as well as the retail price for 1 liter

    of pure alcohol, the value of consumer satisfaction lost on average per capita is (0.25

    * 2.6 * 3,333) = $2,166. Present Value equals to 2166 * (1.032)6 = $2,700

    The following table shows the increase in price of alcohol due to the tax hike.

    Source: Ministry of Finance, ST Graphics

  • 12

    3.1.2 PARTIAL LOSS OF HEALTH BENEFITS

    A reduction in alcohol consumption may also lead to a fall in health benefits.

    Moderate amounts of alcohol raise levels of high-density lipoprotein (HDL, or

    good cholesterol), and higher HDL levels are associated with greater protection

    against heart disease. Moderate alcohol consumption has also been linked with

    beneficial changes ranging from better sensitivity to insulin to improvements in

    factors that influence blood clotting. Such changes would tend to prevent the

    formation of small blood clots that can block arteries in the heart, neck, and brain,

    the ultimate cause of many heart attacks and the most common kind of stroke

    (Harvard School of Public Health, 2014).

    Based on a health study compiled by Professor David J. Hanson from 1997 to

    2013, moderate drinking is categorized by an average of 3.55 liters of pure alcohol in

    a year. Studies have shown that moderate drinking leads to 29% reduction in

    cardiovascular diseases and 37% reduction in coronary heart diseases. It contributes

    to 33% to 56% lower incidence of risk of diabetes and also 34% to 55% lowered

    incidence of diabetic-related coronary heart diseases. This reduction in risks for the

    several diseases is expected to result in approximately 2 years of additional life

    expectancy.

    As mentioned earlier, the average consumption of pure alcohol per capita is

    around 2.6 liters, lower than the level of moderate drinking recommended. Thus, the

    tax levied leads to an even lower consumption of alcohol among those who dont

    drink excessively. For every person that used to drink occasionally but discouraged

    by the tax increase, his statistical life expectancy is shortened by 2 years. With the

    statistical value of a human life being $1.45 million and Singapores average life

  • 13

    expectancy being 82 years, it is calculated that the cost of health benefit per capita is

    1.45 million * 2 years / 82 years = $35365.85 (Quah, Wai-Mun, & Ying, 2009).

    3.2 BENEFITS

    3.2.1 INCREASE PRODUCTIVITY

    It has also been estimated that productivity loss is the main social cost of

    harmful drinking (Collins & Lapsley, 2008; Rehm et al., 2006; Saar, 2009), costing

    the U.S. $134 billion in 2008 (Harwood, 2010). Absenteeism and poor job

    performance often led to accidents and injuries. The following calculation illustrates

    the saving in productivity loss, resulted from a decrease in alcohol consumption

    among binge drinkers in Singapore.

    Average Price Elasticity of demand for alcohol in developed countries: -0.38

    Percentage of binge drinkers in US: 20% of total population = 62.78 million

    Percentage of binge drinkers in Singapore before tax hike: 12.6% of total population

    = 0.68 million

    Tax hike of 25% ! Increase in retail price of alcohol beverages by approximately 24%

    Increase retail price by 24% ! demand falls by (24 * 0.38) = 9.12%

    Estimated decrease of binge drinkers in Singapore due to tax hike: 0.062 million

    Estimated savings in productivity loss in Singapore: (0.062m/62.78m) * 134billion X

    1.26 SGD/USD = $0.166 billion

    Estimated savings in productivity loss in Singapore per capita: 0.174b/5.3m = $31.47

    Present Value: 31.47 * (1.032)4 = $35.70

  • 14

    Former binge drinkers in Singapore are expected to be more productive at work and

    contribute an additional value of approximately $31.47 to the firms output.

    3.2.2 PERSONAL SAVING

    A United Nations Socioeconomic survey conducted from 1990 to 2006. From

    the data, the latest observation on alcohol consumption in 2006 was 2.6 liters of pure

    alcohol per capita.

    Since the estimated price elasticity of demand is -0.38, a tax hike of 25% will

    lead to a decrease in consumption of alcohol by 9.5%. This will lead to an estimated

    0.247-liter reduction in pure alcohol consumption.

    Excise tax as a per cent of total retail price for 1 liter of pure alcohol = 2.1%

    Total value of excise tax = $70.00 per liter of pure alcohol

    Total retail price for 1 liter of pure alcohol: (70/2.1) * 100 = $3,333

    Total estimated economic savings per capita: 3,333 * 0.247 = $823.33

    Present Value: 823.33 * (1.032)6 = $994.61

    3.2.3 HEALTH BENEFITS

    When sin taxes are high, it deters the consumption of alcohol among those who

    drink excessively. It would indirectly lead to more health benefits as well

    (Chaloupka, Grossman, & Saffer, 2002).

    Some examples of health benefits include less mortality from liver cirrhosis,

    cardiovascular diseases, sexually transmitted diseases and even depression. In fact, in

    a study conducted, using data from 1961 to 1984, Grossman estimated that a 10 per

    cent increase in tax rates would reduce cirrhosis mortality by 8.3 to 12.8 per cent in

  • 15

    the long run (Grossman, 1998). In 2013, OECD also released a new Health Working

    Paper, which concludes that using taxes on alcohol to attain public health objectives

    are effective (OECD, 2013).

    Thus, in this case, we can establish that having a higher alcohol would raise

    health benefits for those with excessive drinking habits in Singapore. We calculate

    this increase in health benefit by Grossmans estimate. Using the average values, we

    find that a 25 per cent increase in Singapores alcohol tax would lead to an estimated

    26.38 per cent decrease in cirrhosis mortality.

  • 16

    SECTION 4:

    SOCIAL COSTS

    4.1 MARKET INEFFICIENCY

    Rising rents, together with foreign labor restrictions, have already pushed up

    operating costs of businesses, especially Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs)

    across Singapore. The tax hike is likely to deliver a further and direct blow to bars,

    clubs and coffee shops, where the sales of cigarettes and liquor products constitute a

    substantial proportion of the revenue. Inevitably, profit margins will be slashed in

    accordance with the increase in vice taxes, as costs have increased but sales are

    forecasted to plummet.

    Endowed with greater bargaining power and economies of scale, large firms are

    more likely to cope better with the increased tax burden. In theory, those with greater

    flexibility in their cost structures could absorb higher proportion of the tax compared

    to their competitors. This could effectively provide these companies with the option

    to undercut their competitors for the purpose of boosting sales and increasing market

    share. Such an option could serve as a temporary competitive advantage to phase out

    the weaker and usually smaller firms. In other words, Small and Medium Enterprises

    (SMEs) are likely to be the losers in this situation, which can be detrimental to

    Singapores economy because we have a significant bulk of SMEs here. This will

    undermine all the efforts that the government is putting in to help these SMEs all

    these years.

    Whoever the losers is, the tax is expected to lead to some degrees of market

    inefficiency due to the reduced competition, since neither tobacco nor liquor industry

    is a natural monopoly or oligopoly.

  • 17

    4.2 REDUCTION IN TOTAL SURPLUS

    Smaller firms, with little bargaining power with their suppliers, are expected to

    pass on the tax burden partially, if not entirely, to consumers. And thus, this results

    in reduced total surplus, as well as dead weight loss. In fact, most coffee shops in

    Singapore have already started charging higher beer prices since the announcement

    of the tax (Chow, 2014), undoubtedly causing customer disutility (Aripin, 2014).

    4.3 THE CIGARETTE BLACK MARKET

    With higher taxes, smokers seeking alternatives will turn to the black market for

    more affordable options. In fact, higher sin taxes are often associated with a booming

    cigarettes black market (Hartnett, 2014). In 2013, Singapore Customs seized 2.9

    million packets of cigarettes; almost double that in 2012 and 1 million more in the

    previous year (Yeo, 2014). In light of rising cigarette prices triggered by sin taxes,

    more smokers would be driven to the black market; therefore cigarette smuggling is

    expected to increase.

    TABLE 4.1: ESTIMATION OF CIGARETTE CONFISCATION

    Year 2011 2012 2013 2014*

    Number of cigarettes seized (in millions) 1.9 1.4 2.9 2.0

    *Figures for 2014 are estimated.

    We use a conservative estimate in predicting cigarette smuggling for 2014. By

    using the average of the previous years, we estimate Singapore Customs can seize

    2.0 million packets in 2014, as shown in Table 4.1. Implications on society include

    tax revenue that went unpaid and manpower resources to clamp down on such

  • 18

    smuggling. The estimated evaded tax in 2014 will be valued using figures from the

    latest cigarette hauls from 2013.

    In late 2013, the authority conducted the second largest contraband cigarettes

    haul and confiscated a total of 17600 cartons and 8 packets, with a total value of

    $1.6million and total duty and tax evasion of over $1.3million (Sim, 2013). These

    figures are used as a proxy for potential tax duties evaded in 2014 based on the

    estimated 2 million packets Singapore Customs can expect to seize.

    TABLE 4.2: TAX RELATED TO CIGARETTE SMUGGLING

    2nd largest haul in 2013 2014*

    Number of cigarettes seized (in packets)

    (17,600 x 10) + 8 = 176,008

    2,000,000 x 1% = 20,000**

    Total Tax evaded $1,300,000 $7.38 x 20,000 = $147,600

    Tax/Packet $1,300,000 / 176,008 = $7.38

    $7.38

    *Figures for 2014 are estimated. ** Assuming 10% increase in tax causes 1% increase in black market trading volume.

    Table 4.2 summarized the estimated tax revenue forgone as a result of increased

    cigarette smuggling. We assume that the 10% increase in tobacco tax leads to 1% in

    crease in the illegal trading. The rise in the black market trading volume is likely to

    cost $147,600 a year in tax revenue that could have gone towards nation-building

    instead. Other than the forgone revenue, increased cigarette smuggling will require

    higher enforcement costs to clamp down on smugglers and more importantly, the rise

    of organized crime in Singapore.

  • 19

    4.4 INCOME DISPARITY

    Assuming smoking and excessive drinking activities are the only differences

    that separate these consumers from the rest of the consumers, heavy smokers and

    drinkers are significantly penalized through these increases in vice taxes which will

    in turn use up an even bigger portion of their income in order to sustain this habit.

    This may result in an income disparity between consumers that smoke or/and drink,

    and consumers that do not.

    According to the Adam Smith Institute, the average smoker spends 1,660 a

    year on cigarettes, which is 20% of the income of the bottom 10%. The effects of

    rising cigarette prices usually do spill over to the smokers families, especially low-

    income earners, thereby putting unnecessary financial stress and burden on them

    (Venkatesh, 2013). While the figures may not be that of Singapores, it is intuitive

    that such habits actually take up a significant portion of income of the lower-income

    group in the country, and sometimes even the working class. With the increase in

    excise duties, the income gap will thus continue to widen.

  • 20

    SECTION 5:

    SOCIAL BENEFIT

    This section covers the social benefits generated by the tax hike on both goods.

    5.1 ADDITIONAL TAX REVENUE

    The biggest benefit of an increase in tax is the additional tax revenue generated.

    The rise in liquor duties is expected to yield another S$120 million a year, while the

    tax increase in tobacco is to result in an estimated S$70 million. Therefore, the tax

    hike is expected to lead to additional revenue, totaling approximately S$200 million,

    for the government.

    As mentioned earlier and shown in the Table 5.1 below, the incremental in

    alcohol price due to the tax hike depends on both the volume and alcohol percentage

    of each beverage. This means that a small can of Anchor beer is able to cause an

    increase in price by $0.19. This demonstrates the severity of this tax; making its

    point that tax revenue is bound to increase tremendously.

    TABLE 5.1: IMPACT OF ALCOHOL TAX ON PRICES

    Source: Ministry of Finance, ST Graphics

  • 21

    5.2 DETERRENCE OF NEW ENTRANTS

    We acknowledged that there are different demand functions for goods such as

    alcohol and cigarettes, due to different levels of addiction.

    For heavy smokers and drinkers, the demand for alcohol and cigarettes is

    inelastic (Collis, Czubek, & Johal, 2010). This is due largely to the addictive nature

    of both consumer goods. In this case, when the demand for a good is inelastic, tax

    on these goods would mean that the costs are highly likely to be passed on to

    consumers, as sellers know that an increase in price does not stop most of the

    buyers. This leads to a successful transfer of burden from producers to consumers.

    Consumers, thus, are the ones who face rising prices.

    When prices are increased, demand for the good, theoretically, falls. However,

    due to the price inelastic nature of the good, an increase in tax may not force

    consumers to quit. This is especially true for heavy users, who are addicted to either

    cigarettes or alcohol. It is difficult to reduce the overall number of drinkers and

    smokers.

    Instead, a high sin tax is more likely to deter new entrants. This means that

    ideally, a sin tax will reduce the growth rate of new smokers and drinkers. It may

    even force moderate and mild users out of the market. This is depicted in a study

    conducted by Grossman, 1989, where it is proven that the use of alcohol by youths

    is inversely related to the prices of alcoholic beverages (Michael & Grossman,

    1989).

  • 22

    5.3 SAVING ON PRODUCTIVITY LOSS

    In 2013, the first comprehensive report was done to investigate costs of

    smoking at the workplace in the United States (Berman, Crane, Seiber, & Munur,

    2013)

    TABLE 5.2: COST OF SMOKING INCURRED BY EMPLOYERS

    United States (USD)* Singapore (SGD)**

    Smoking Breaks $3,077 $3,077 x 1.25 = $3,846.25

    Health Insurance $2,055 -nil-

    Absenteeism $517 $517 x 1.25 = $646.25

    Total estimated costs ~$5,816 ~$ 4,492.50

    * Figures for United States are referenced from the report Tobacco Control. ** Figures for Singapore are estimated costs based on current exchange rate USD1=SGD1.25

    Table 5.2 shows that it is more expensive to hire smokers since they incur costs

    in the form of smoke breaks, health insurance and absenteeism. There is no

    comprehensive study that calculates the cost of smoking to employers in Singapore.

    However, one can use the associated figures from Tobacco Control as a proxy to the

    Singapore context.

    Healthcare insurance is usually not directly provided by companies in

    Singapore. Instead, companies can opt to contribute to their employees Medisave

    accounts, at a pre-determined rate, for both smoking and no-smoking employees.

    Therefore there are no healthcare insurance costs in Singapore context. Assuming

    smokers from both countries take similar smoking breaks and absenteeism from

    work, each Singaporean smoker will cost their bosses an estimated $4,492 more

    than their non-smoking coworkers.

  • 23

    With the tax hike, smoking at the workplace will be reduced. We assume equal

    proportions of both types of smokers since there are no official statistics available.

    As per earlier analysis, the social smokers will cut out smoking completely due to

    higher prices but the regular smoker will not. The benefit of the tax is thus savings

    of $4,492 / 2 = $2,256 per smoking employee to the average firm.

    5.4 FEWER EXTERNALITIES

    Tobacco products and alcoholic beverages are deemed as demerit goods,

    because of the negative externalities generated. Negative externalities occur when

    third parties, who are not involved in the production and consumption of the good,

    incur external costs and are not compensated.

    With fewer drinkers and smokers, it would lead to a fall in negative externalities

    on the whole. These could include lower crime rate, fewer road accidents, lesser

    vandalism and even an overall drop in disruptions in society.

    5.4.1 FEWER TRAFFIC ACCIDENTS

    Research has indicated that higher alcohol taxes affect not only alcohol

    consumption but also various alcohol-related problems as well. One example would

    be traffic fatalities.

    There have been numerous studies investigating the relationship of alcohol

    taxes and traffic fatalities. With U.S. data from 1982 to 1988, a study has confirmed

    findings that a higher alcohol tax is associated with lower rates of traffic fatalities.

    (Ruhm, 1996) This means that higher alcohol taxes are indirectly linked to lower

  • 24

    traffic fatality rates. They found that for every 1% increase in the price of beer, the

    traffic fatality rates fell by the same proportion.

    TABLE 5.3 ROAD ACCIDENT CASUALTIES AND CASUALTY RATES

    Source: Singapore Police Force, 2012

    The table above shows that Singapores road accident rates for a 10-year period

    have been steadily decreasing. For a conservative estimate, we take the average of

    the 10-year period and arrive at 2.33 casualties per 10,000 vehicles. After taking into

    account the 25 % increase in alcohol tax, the eventual retail price for beer increased

    by 24%. When coupled with results that a 1% increase in price of beer causes a

    corresponding fall in traffic fatalities, then the traffic fatality rate is calculated to fall

    to 1.77/10,000 vehicles. Thus the benefit of this tax is the additional 0.55 lives

    gained from lesser traffic fatalities. We use the same measure for the value of one

    life ($1.45million), arriving at the equivalent of $0.79 million.

  • 25

    5.4.2 LESSER AIR POLLUTION

    Air pollution that caused by smoking is known as Environmental Tobacco

    Smoke (ETS), which is actually the smoke from other people's cigarettes.

    Secondhand smoke is the combination of smoke from the burning end of a cigarette

    and the smoke breathed out by smokers. Secondhand smoke contains more than

    7,000 chemicals. Hundreds are toxic and about 70 can cause cancer.

    According to Pope (2002), an elevation of 10 mg/m3 of long-term exposure to

    fine particle air pollution (particulate matter (PM2.5)), including that from tobacco

    smoke, is associated with 6%, 9% and 14% increased risk for all cause,

    cardiopulmonary and lung cancer mortality respectively.

    With lesser smoking, emission of PM2.5 into the air will be lesser.

    5.5 REDUCTION OF EMOTION DISTRESS

    When a family member falls sick, it is human nature that the whole family gets

    emotionally affected. Such a spillover phenomenon becomes a social cost when the

    family members of those who are suffering the consequences of smoking and

    excessive drinking become upset, depressed or absent-minded. The health condition

    of one person in a family could have a multiplier effect that decreases other

    members productivity and physical wellbeing, of which the extent and value is

    beyond the scope of this paper.

  • 26

    6. CONCLUSION

    As is with the case of other government policies, the increase in excise duties

    on tobacco and alcoholic products introduced in Budget 2014 has various costs and

    benefits incurred by targeted individuals and the society as a whole.

    For individual smokers, the 10% tax increase will raise the cost of lighting up

    each cigarette, especially among addicted smokers whose demand curves are

    inelastic; therefore resulting in loss of consumer surplus and disutility. Non-addicted

    smokers are predicted to consume fewer tobacco products at the cost of foregone

    enjoyment. As the non-addicted adjust their consumption pattern, it is possible that

    they bear the cost of fewer smoking-related social opportunities. On the other hand,

    both types of smokers enjoy the personal savings on cigarette consumption and

    ensuing reduction in health risks in the long term, where demand curves are

    relatively elastic.

    For individual drinkers, they can obtain less consumer satisfaction since less

    liquor can be bought given the same budget. With its most pronounced effect on

    excessive drinking, the liquor tax forces binge drinkers to give up some, however

    minor, personal satisfaction associated with the social perception of being able to

    drink. In terms of cost, first and foremost, it should not be neglected that the tax

    could discourage normal and healthy consumption of alcohol, resulting in foregone

    health benefits, such as lower risk of cardiovascular diseases. Besides, for those

    drinkers on track to developing alcohol use disorder, the tax increase deters the

    development of an addiction and brings them many benefits, including reduced

    health risks, saving on consumption, and preservation of working ability. Moreover,

  • 27

    for who have yet developed a habit out of drinking but are indeed consuming

    alcohol excessively, the benefit is mainly realized in health benefits.

    From a social perspective, the increase in sin tax could substantially reduce

    the profit margin of small and medium enterprises that rely on the sales of cigarettes

    and alcohol, as the enterprises are unable to shift the major part of the tax burden to

    consumers. Therefore, companies that are more flexible in absorbing the tax could

    tap on this opportunity to drive out their competitors, resulting in market

    inefficiency. Besides, both tax increases, to some extent, cause decrease in supplier

    surplus and give rise to deadweight losses. Moreover, the tax on tobacco, to be

    specific, is expected to add to the prevalence of black market trading, therefore

    leading to tax evasion. There is also law enforcement cost incurred by the

    government to regulate against tobacco smuggling. Furthermore, the increases in

    excise duties drive a wedge between the already wide income gap between those

    who consume cigarettes and alcohol and those who dont.

    In terms of social benefits, the tax change is expected to add an additional 200

    million to the governments budget, which would be presumably well spent to

    improve the society. Secondly, the rising costs reduce the prevalence of smoking

    and drinking. Since many new entrants are likely to place substantial value on the

    social benefits of these demerit goods, fewer smoking buddies and drinking

    buddies are expected to deter new entrants through negative multiplier effect.

    Thirdly, for companies who hire smokers that cut down smoking due to the sin tax

    policy, the time wasted and productivity lost is saved. Last but no least, fewer

    externalities, including road accidents, air pollution, and emotional distress, will be

    curbed to a certain extent thanks to the policy.

  • 28

    Despite the indicative calculations and estimations in this paper, it is

    recommended one that aims to evaluate the costs and benefits of such tax increases

    should conduct more robust data collection and quantitative analyses. Nonetheless,

    this paper has dedicated its effort in providing a preliminary and comprehensive

    cost-benefit analysis of the issue at hand.

  • 29

    APPENDIX:

    INDIVIDUAL CONTRIBUTIONS

    ** Due to final restructuring of contents and editing, the individual sections of

    the report no longer exactly coordinates with what is initially stated below in this

    appendix.

    Liang Tian:

    Explored the costs and benefits to individual smokers. Identified the different

    types of smokers and drafted the demand curves that they face, and thus the slightly

    differentiating costs that they face, from their respective perspective. And then

    discussed the benefits to be enjoyed by smokers as a result of this tax hike.

    Jensen:

    Researched and examined the individual perspectives of a drinker, and

    categorizing them clearly for better understanding. Analyzing the costs and benefits

    faced by them as a result of the tax rise, which stretches beyond what conventional

    economic theories can predict.

    Soo Yue:

    Reviewed different articles to gain a comprehensive scope of the impacts of a

    vice tax increase on society, and applying it into Singapores context. She discussed

    mainly on the social costs incurred from the tax increase of tobacco and liquor. And

    used economic theories to explain certain inclinations of the economy.

  • 30

    Jamie:

    Her focus area is on the social benefits of this recent sin tax hike. With several

    references to different sources, examples were given to back up discussions. Taking

    on the macroeconomic perspective, she listed the improvements to be enjoyed in

    Singapore if the sin tax rise is to be effective.

    Li Ting:

    She compiled and edited the works of the above four members to ensure the

    coherence within and across the different sections, to avoid any contradictions or

    overlaps. Makes sure that each part is communicated effectively, which adds to the

    overall soundness of the analysis of this paper.

    Alan Dai Sheng

    He edited the paper for the final round; verified key arguments and reasoning

    presented; and made necessary changes, such as adding in novel content,

    restructuring contents, and substantiating argument. He also wrote the Introduction

    and Conclusion to give readers a clear direction and summary of the paper. On top

    of that, he works on the cover, content and bibliography pages, and produce the final

    presentation of our term paper.

  • 31

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    Collis, J., Czubek, M., & Johal, S. (2010). Estimating Price Elasticities of Demand for

    Alcohol and Tobacco in the UK.

    Ruhm, C. (1996). Are Recessions Good for Your Health?

    Chaloupka, F., Grossman, M., & Saffer, H. (2002). The Effects of Price on Alcohol

    Consumption and Alcohol-related Problems.

    Gallet, C. (2007). The Demand for Alcohol: A Meta-analysis of Elasticities.

    Michael, & Grossman. (1989). Health Benefits of Increase in Alcohol and Cigarette Tax.

    Ministry of Finance. (2014, 03 14). Budget Measures. Retrieved 04 10, 2014, from Budget

    2014 Singapore:

    http://www.singaporebudget.gov.sg/budget_2014/BudgetMeasures.aspx

    Berman, M., Crane, R., Seiber, E., & Munur, M. (2013). Estimating the cost of a smoking

    employee. Tobacco Control .

    Chow, J. (2014, 03 01). Beer prices rise by $1.30 at Kopitiam outlets. Retrieved 04 16, 2014,

    from The Straits Times: http://www.straitstimes.com/breaking-

    news/singapore/story/beer-prices-rise-130-kopitiam-outlets-20140301

    Aripin, N. A. (2014, 03 14). Singapore drinkers complain about jacked-up beer prices.

    Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from Yahoo News Singapore:

    https://sg.news.yahoo.com/singapore-drinkers-complain-about-jacked-up-beer-

    prices-172509722.html

    Grossman, M. C. (1998). An empirical analysis of alcohol addiction: results from

    monitoring the future panels. Economic Inquiry , 36 (1), 39.

    Sim, W. (2013, 12 6). More than 17,600 cartons of contraband cigarettes seized in year's

    second-largest haul. Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from The Straits Times:

    http://www.straitstimes.com/breaking-news/singapore/story/more-17600-cartons-

    contraband-cigarettes-seized-years-second-largest-h

    Venkatesh, N. (2013). Impact of smoking: Influence on the society and global business.

    International Journal of Business and Management Invention , 2 (3), 46-53.

  • 32

    Hartnett, K. (2014, 2 2). Bostons black-market cigarette problem. Retrieved 4 16, 2014,

    from The Boston Globe: http://www.bostonglobe.com/ideas/2014/02/02/boston-

    black-market-cigarette-problem/mJpfuuFZXXYxrBiEgTcyJM/story.html

    Yeo, J. S. (2014, 01 23). 2.9 million packets of contraband cigarettes seized by Singapore

    Customs last year - See more at: http://www.straitstimes.com/breaking-

    news/singapore/story/29-million-packets-contraband-cigarettes-seized-singapore-

    customs-last#sthash.E3rxNxg2.dpuf. Retrieved 4 16, 2014, from The Straits Times:

    http://www.straitstimes.com/breaking-news/singapore/story/29-million-packets-

    contraband-cigarettes-seized-singapore-customs-last

    Chang, R. (2014, 02 21). Singapore Budget 2014: Duties on alcohol, tobacco and gambling

    to rise. Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from The Straits Times:

    http://www.straitstimes.com/breaking-news/money/story/budget-2014-duties-

    alcohol-tobacco-and-gambling-rise-20140221

    Channel News Asia. (2014, 02 21). Budget 2014: Taxation on liquor, tobacco products,

    betting to increase. Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from Channel News Asia:

    http://www.channelnewsasia.com/news/singapore/budget-2014-taxation-

    on/1007940.html

    Ministry of Finance. (2014, 02 21). Budget Speech . Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from Budget

    2014 Singapore: http://www.singaporebudget.gov.sg/budget_2014/pe.aspx

    Department of Statistics, Singapore. (2013). Yearbook of Statistics Singapore, 2013.

    Singapore: Department of Statistics.

    World Health Organisation. (2011). Singapore: Socioeconomic Context. Retrieved 04 16,

    2014, from World Health Organisation:

    http://www.who.int/substance_abuse/publications/global_alcohol_report/profiles/sg

    p.pdf

    Abraham, T. (2012, 11 24). Smoking: Tougher measures needed. Retrieved 04 16, 2014,

    from The Straits Times: http://www.straitstimes.com/premium/forum-

    letters/story/smoking-tougher-measures-needed-20121124

    Ministry of Health. (2012). Singapore Mental Health Survey. Singapore: Ministry of Health.

    OECD. (2013). OECD Health Working Paper. Paris: Organisation of Economic Co-

    operation and Development.

  • 33

    Quah, E., Wai-Mun, C., & Ying, S. H. (2009). What is human life worth? In C. Wai-Mun,

    & S. H. Ying, Singapore and Asia: Impact of Global Financial Tsunami and other

    Economics Issues (pp. 173-184). Singapore: World Science Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd.

    Harvard School of Public Health. (2014). Alcohol: Balancing risks and benefits. Retrieved

    04 16, 2014, from Harvard School of Public Health:

    http://www.hsph.harvard.edu/nutritionsource/alcohol-full-

    story/#possible_health_benefits

    The Indian Express. (2012, 01 12). Why drinking makes you feel so good? Retrieved 04 16,

    2012, from The Indian Express: http://archive.indianexpress.com/news/why-

    drinking-makes-you-feel-so-good/898943/1

    Szalavitz, M. (2012, 08 20). Why College Binge Drinkers Are Happier, Have High Status.

    Retrieved 04 16, 2014, from Time Magazine:

    http://healthland.time.com/2012/08/20/why-college-binge-drinkers-are-happier-

    have-high-status/