Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf...

38
No 153 Flying the Nest: How the Home Department Shapes Researchers’ Career Paths Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson July 2014

Transcript of Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf...

Page 1: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

No 153

Flying the Nest: How the Home Department Shapes Researchers’ Career Paths Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson

July 2014

Page 2: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

    IMPRINT  DICE DISCUSSION PAPER  Published by  düsseldorf university press (dup) on behalf of Heinrich‐Heine‐Universität Düsseldorf, Faculty of Economics, Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), Universitätsstraße 1, 40225 Düsseldorf, Germany www.dice.hhu.de 

  Editor:  Prof. Dr. Hans‐Theo Normann Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE) Phone: +49(0) 211‐81‐15125, e‐mail: [email protected]    DICE DISCUSSION PAPER  All rights reserved. Düsseldorf, Germany, 2014  ISSN 2190‐9938 (online) – ISBN 978‐3‐86304‐152‐6   The working papers published in the Series constitute work in progress circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comments. Views expressed represent exclusively the authors’ own opinions and do not necessarily reflect those of the editor.    

Page 3: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

Flying the Nest: How the Home Department Shapes

Researchers’ Career Paths

Hanna Hottenrotta,b and Cornelia Lawsonc,d

aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim, Germany

c Department of Sociology and Social Policy, University of Nottingham, UK d BRICK, Collegio Carlo Alberto, Moncalieri (Turin), Italy

July 2014

Academic researchers face mobility related decisions throughout their careers. We study the

importance of team and organisational characteristics of the home departments for career

choices of departing researchers in the fields of science and engineering at higher education

institutions in Germany. We find that the organisational environments – the nests – shape career

paths. Research funding, research performance in terms of patents and publications as well as

the industry ties of department heads shape job choices. In particular, public research grants

increase the probability that departing researchers take a research job at a university or public

research centre, while grants from industry increase the likelihood that they take a job in

industry. Publication performance of the department head relates to R&D jobs in public, but

not in industry and patents predict the probability that departing researchers will move to small

and medium-sized firms. For these firms seeking technological knowledge from former

university employees may be particularly crucial. Academic start-ups are more likely to be a

job destination for departing researchers from technical universities, from departments with

higher publication output and with a research focus on experimental development.

Keywords: Researcher Mobility, Research Funding, Science-Industry Technology Transfer,

Academic Entrepreneurship, Academic Careers

JEL codes: I23; J24; O3

Acknowledgements

We thank the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) for providing the survey data and Susanne

Thorwarth for help with the collection of publication and patent data. We thank participants at the “The

Organisation, Economics and Policy of Scientific Research” workshop organised by LEI & BRICK, Collegio

Carlo Alberto, Torino (Italy) and the “Beyond spillovers? Channels and effects of knowledge transfer from

universities” workshop at the University of Kassel (Germany) for helpful comments. Cornelia Lawson

acknowledges financial support from the Collegio Carlo Alberto Project ‘Researcher Mobility and Scientific

Performance’.

Hanna Hottenrott (corresponding author), Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), Heinrich

Heine University Düsseldorf, Universitätsstrasse 1, 40225 Düsseldorf, Germany; Phone: +49 211 81-10266, Fax:

+ 49 211 81-15499; Email: [email protected]

Cornelia Lawson, School of Sociology and Social Policy, University of Nottingham, University Park, Nottingham,

NG7 2RD, UK; Email: [email protected]

Page 4: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

1

1. Introduction

Academic researchers face mobility related decision points throughout their careers. The

first important decision point, and the one most often considered in academic literature, is the

completion of doctoral education that leaves researchers to choose their future career paths.

Many young researchers choose to remain in public research but might leave their home

institution and take up jobs at a public research institution or a university elsewhere. Especially

in the US system mobility is encouraged following the PhD and also in Germany, young

academics are usually expected (and have in the past even been required) to leave their home

department following habilitation. For the US it has further been shown that a large share of

young researchers will not remain in academia as more researchers aspire to academia than

positions are available (Fox and Stephan, 2001). Especially in science and engineering, many

PhD holders and post-doctoral researchers leave academia and move to an R&D career in

industry. The same is true for Germany, where the number of faculty positions for full

professors is much lower than that of qualified post-doctoral researchers and lecturers.

Thus, academia is very competitive and researchers may need to withdraw from academic

research and move to a job in industry or public research or a non-research related job. Several

studies on the destination of PhD holders in the US indeed showed that many leave academia

for industry. Of the life science researchers that completed their PhD in 1985 and 1986, only

38% were in tenure stream positions 10 years later, while 24% had taken up a position in

industry (Austin, 2002). This share is even higher for PhD holders in other disciplines. About

34% of physicists and 46% of chemists were employed by industry five to six years after

obtaining their PhD (Stephan, 2012).

Yet, few papers have investigated the factors driving the destination choices of academics.

Studies on the mobility from academia to industry have primarily focussed on academic

entrepreneurship of senior academics (e.g. Audretsch and Stephan, 1999; Stuart and Ding,

2006; Toole and Czarnitzki, 2010), while studies on the mobility between academic institutions

have focussed on international movements (e.g. Franzoni et al., 2012; Stephan, 2012). Recent

interest in career choices of young researchers has resulted in a series of studies on the choice

between a career industry and academia (Roach and Sauermann, 2010; Agarwal and Ohyama,

2013; Balsmeier and Pellens, 2014; Lam and Campos 2014).

None of these studies, however, explicitly considers the organisational environment in

which these career decisions are made. Most research happens in teams, which underlines the

Page 5: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

2

importance of organisational characteristics of the home departments – the nests – for career

choices of departing researchers. Carayol and Matt (2004) have previously shown the

importance of organisational characteristics for knowledge creation. In addition to widening the

understanding of the processes behind knowledge production, research groups also shape the

careers of their members (Walsh and Lee, 2013).

This study adds to previous research by studying the outflow of researchers from 676

science and engineering research units at 46 universities in Germany. Mobility and career

decision points in Germany are very common and can still occur relatively late. The average

age of taking up a position as tenured full professor is 42 years (Schultze et al. 2008). This is

much later than in other academic markets and researchers can be seen to still drop out of

academia or to move abroad at a relatively late age. Also, the average rate of mobility is much

higher in Germany compared to other countries, with more than 50% of PhD holders having

moved at least once over a ten year period (Auriol et al. 2013).

Based on survey data from research units we analyse the factors that drive job destinations

of departing researchers during the years 1997-1999. We differentiate between non-research

and research-related jobs in newly formed firms, small and medium-sized firms (SMEs), large

firms, consulting companies, public research institutes and universities. We link the career

destinations to a broad set of home department characteristics ranging from publications and

patents, research unit composition in terms of employment and research focus, to funding of

researchers. Research funding from public or private sector in the form of research grants that

complement the research unit’s core funding has become increasingly important for German

universities (Hottenrott and Thorwarth 2011) and the sources from which researchers are being

funded may also determine their career paths (Lam and Campos 2014).

In line with earlier research on US researchers we find that by far not all research units

produce researchers solely for academic careers. For our set of research units, we observe that

only 6% saw all their departing employees move to purely academic jobs, while 32% saw all

their departing researchers move to industry. The majority of research units, however, trained

people for academe as well as industry. Results from the estimation of simultaneous equation

models underline the important role of home departments (nests) for the career building of

researchers. We show that the majority of research units see their departing researchers take on

R&D-related jobs in industry. This confirms the important role of former university employees

for industrial R&D. We also find that researchers trained in research units that have more links

Page 6: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

3

to industry and receive more grants from industry are also more likely to move to a job in the

private sector. Conversely, researchers trained in research units that receive more public

funding, have more publications and have a more basic research orientation are more likely to

take up employment in the public sector.

The following section summarizes the literature on career choices of academic researchers

and presents our hypotheses regarding the role of team and research head characteristics that

impact career choices. Section 3 describes the data and section 4 sets out the econometric

framework and presents the results. Section 5 concludes.

2. Mobility and career decisions of academics: background and hypotheses

Movement of scientists and hence scientific knowledge between different academic

institutions, and between university and private institutions is believed to be vital to facilitate

research and innovation in both the private and public sector. It has been stated that researcher

mobility supports knowledge and technology transfer, the creation of networks and productivity

(OECD 2000, 2008). All these assumed positive effects of mobility are related to the embedded

character of researchers’ human and social capital (Granovetter 1985; Griliches 1973) which

can spread and increase through mobility (Schultz 1961; Becker 1962; Nelson & Phelps 1966;

Bourdieu 1986; Coleman 1988; Burt 1997). The movement of scientists aids the diffusion of

ideas across institutions and can result in increased knowledge flows (Azoulay et al., 2011).

Specifically the movement of PhD holders into firms presents an opportunity for knowledge

transfer (Mangematin 2000, Zellner 2003, Enders 2005) and the goal of improving knowledge

and technology transfer with industry has created an increased interest amongst policy makers

in researcher mobility between the public and private sector. At the same time, previous

literature has mourned the potential brain drain from academia to industry that may impede

knowledge production (Aghion et al., 2008; Auriol et al., 2013).

2.1 Individual factors

Industry vs. Academia

These developments in researcher mobility and the choice between careers in academia and

industry have gained increasing scholarly attention in recent years. The decision to remain in

academia or to move to industry in this context has been linked to a scientist’s research ability

and job preferences (David and Dasgupta, 1994; Stern, 2004; Stephan, 2012). Scientists differ

in their ability to produce new knowledge and not all may have the capacity for remaining in

Page 7: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

4

an academic research environment but may instead prefer to move into industry or to a non-

research position. Additionally, scientists assign different levels of importance to monetary and

non-monetary rewards associated to career choices (Levin and Stephan, 1991). The importance

of non-pecuniary factors has been described as ‘taste for science’ that is independent of ability

or salary concerns (Levin and Stephan, 1991; Stephan, 2012). It has been measured as an

intrinsic preference for freedom of research that is accommodated better in an academic than

an industrial work environment (Sauermann and Stephan, 2013). Accordingly, Roach and

Sauermann (2010) and Agarwal and Ohyama (2013) show that young researchers with a higher

‘taste for science’ are more likely to remain in academia. In contrast, researchers that value

pecuniary gains, in terms of salary and access to equipment and funding, and are more interested

in downstream research, are more likely to move to industry (Roach and Sauermann, 2010;

Balsmeier and Pellens, 2014).

Stern (2004) showed that the ‘taste for science’ is strongly correlated to research ability in

terms of publications (see also Sauermann and Roach, 2012). Researchers that value publishing

are more likely to look for a career in academia (Roach and Sauermann, 2010). Similarly, we

could expect that patenting numbers correlate positively with valuing pecuniary benefits

(Owen-Smith and Powell, 2001; Sauermann and Roach, 2012). 1 This ‘taste for

commercialisation’ is associated with favouring a career in industry (Roach and Sauermann,

2010). Balsmeier and Pellens (2014) indeed find for a sample of Flemish researchers that

publication numbers negatively affect the propensity to move to industry, while patent numbers

have a positive effect. Mangematin (2000) confirm that publication numbers increase the

chance of recruitment in academia; and Crespi et al. (2007), who look at the sector mobility of

academic inventors in the European context find that academics with more valuable inventions

are more likely to move to industry. Studies on sector mobility of senior academics instead find

that publication performance has a positive effect on labour mobility to industry (Zucker et al.,

2002; Toole and Czarnitzki, 2010). Thus, publications may not truly represent career

preferences but can indicate career opportunities.

The home department (nest) likely plays a vital role in shaping researchers’ tastes and thus

career preferences. Advisors and supervisors often have a fundamental impact on research focus

and research content. Their skills and experiences may be directly transferred to the young

1

Academic involvement in commercial activities correlates positively with both, pecuniary and non-pecuniary

benefits (Lam, 2011) and several papers have reported a positive link between patents and publications.

Page 8: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

5

scientists with whom they work. Likewise, may a research unit’s professional network shape

career options of departing researchers. This is discussed in detail in section 2.2.

R&D vs. non-R&D jobs

While individual researchers may have a preference for a job in academe or industry, not

all positions in industry are alike. When selecting a job in industry, the departing scientists have

the choice between joining an established firm and starting their own company. Roach and

Sauermann (2010) show that PhD students with an intention to leave academe have a lower

‘taste for science’ and place higher value on pecuniary benefits. In later work Sauermann and

Roach (2012) qualify these findings and show that PhD students who plan to start their own

firm have a taste for both science and commercialisation, while those joining established firms

only value pecuniary benefits. This is also in line with the positive effect of publications and

patents on start-up formation found in the literature on academic entrepreneurship (e.g. Stuart

and Ding, 2006).

Also, differences in workplace characteristics within established firms may attract different

types of scientists. Organisational theory suggests that firms become more bureaucratic as they

grow in size which may result in less autonomy for scientists. They may, however, offer higher

wages and may be better equipped for supporting top research. Sauermann and Stephan (2013)

confirm that scientists at larger firms are less satisfied with their research autonomy but that

they receive higher salaries. Thus, scientists with a higher ‘taste for science’ may be better

advised to join small firms; scientists with a taste for pecuniary returns instead, should join

large firms. Also within academia, job heterogeneity plays a role. Public research institutions

offer research positions without teaching duties that may attract the most able researchers within

the field. They also offer a higher level of autonomy than universities and are more likely to

reward commercial research lines.

2.2 Nest factors

While the individual researcher holds a specific tendency to favour a job in academia or

industry, this is affected by the organisational environment within which he or she works.

Socialisation processes of academia inform scientists’ attitudes towards various pecuniary and

non-pecuniary gains associated with research. Especially the head of the research unit has a

very formative influence on the values and perceived opportunities of his or her research staff.

Page 9: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

6

The research unit also has a strong effect on individual ability. Several papers have shown

that a high quality research environment has a positive effect on individual research

performance (Hall et al. 2007; Waldinger, 2012). Having more full professors, having a larger

percentage of department faculty working on research and having more ‘star professors’ all

contribute to enhanced individual research productivity (Smeby and Try, 2005). Researchers

may moreover gain early citation advantage if co-authored by a scientist with a high reputation

in the scientific community (Petersen et al., 2013).

Researchers trained as PhDs or postdocs in high quality departments will thus have a

publication and reputation advantage and may value academic career paths more than

researchers at other departments. Sauermann and Roach (2014) indeed find that those from

highly ranked PhD programme give higher importance to publishing, which (as seen above)

results in a higher probability to remain in academia.

H1: Research units with higher academic publication performance are more likely to see their

departing researchers take jobs at universities and public research institutions.

Research heads also shape the networks that are crucial for career advancement in academe,

but also beyond. Several papers have considered the prestige of PhD granting and hiring

institutions to study early career advancement. Most of these studies find that the prestige of

the university is more relevant for obtaining an academic position than the level of individual

productivity (Crane, 1965, 1970; Long, 1978; Baldi, 1995). Burris (2004) links this to elite

networks that have developed between top universities. Also in Europe the importance of social

ties for promotion within academia is very high and may impact mobility decisions (Pezzoni et

al., 2012; Zinovyeva and Bagues, 2014). These social ties may be observed through a research

unit’s greater access to prestigious public grants which may be indicative of its research quality

as well as standing within the research community.

H2: Research units with a higher share of public grants are more likely to see their departing

researchers stay in academe.

Also for research careers in industry, social ties are important. Several papers have shown

that academics in departments with links to industry and high levels of commercial activity are

more likely to engage with industry or be entrepreneurial themselves (Bercovitz and Feldman,

2008; Lawson, 2013; Aschhoff and Grimpe, 2014). This is confirmed by Sauermann and Roach

Page 10: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

7

(2012) who find that those with commercially oriented advisors are more likely to value

pecuniary benefits, which in turn affect career choices and opportunities.

H3: Research units with higher patenting activity (also in terms of patents’ relevance for

industrial applications) are more likely to see their departing researchers leave for an R&D

job in industry or start their own business.

Lam (2007) further shows that large firms establish close links with universities, manifested

through hiring of PhDs and postdocs to engage scientists in joint knowledge production. In

doing so, firms establish closer knit networks across institutional boundaries that allow them to

directly tap on knowledge in these departments and influence their teaching and research

agendas. Mangematin (2000) finds for French PhD graduates that the collaboration with a

private-sector partner during the PhD-phase increases the probability of obtaining a position in

the private sector. He also stresses that networks created during the PhD are crucial for finding

a job. These networks are largely influenced by the head of the research unit and industry-ties

may be visible through collaboration with firms (contract research, joint publishing or

patenting). In particular, research funding from industry may constitute a channel through

which ties are maintained.

H4: Research units with stronger industry ties are more likely to see their departing researchers

take R&D jobs in industry, especially in large firms.

Moreover, some research lines may be better suited to meet the need of private firms.

Research units that pursue a higher share of applied research or experimental development may

be more likely to train researchers for industry than departments that focus on basic research

lines.

H5: Research units with focus on applied rather than basic research are more likely to see their

departing researchers start their own business or leave for an R&D job in industry.

3. Data

The empirical analysis is based on a unique dataset that was assembled using different data

sources. The core data were collected through a survey of research units at German higher

education institutions in the fields of science and engineering. The Centre for European

Economic Research (ZEW, Mannheim) conducted the survey of 3,507 research units in 2000

Page 11: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

8

and the sampling method involved stratification by regions. The original sample included public

research institutions as well as universities, technical universities and universities of applied

sciences (Fachhochschulen). For the purpose of this study we exclude respondents from public

research institutions and focus on faculties at institutes of higher education, i.e. institutions that

also offer teaching. The questionnaire was addressed to the head of a research unit, who is

usually a full professor with budget and personnel responsibility. The overall response rate to

the survey was 24.4%. The survey data were complemented with publication and patent

information of the head of the research unit covering the five year period before the survey

(1994-1999). Data on publications were collected manually from the ISI web of science and

patent information from the German Patent Office in 2008. We also collected citations to

publications and patents with a citation window ending in 2008. Publication and patent data

were manually matched to survey respondents based on names and information collected from

university websites and the researchers’ CVs. We also collected information on the year of

doctoral degree for each research unit head to derive a measure for the academic age and

experience of the professor. The German National Library collects information on all doctoral

theses submitted to German universities. For professors with no PhD degree, who can teach at

Universities of Applied Sciences only, or professors that received their degree outside Germany,

we use the year of the first publication to measure the start of their academic career. The final

sample comprises 676 professor-research unit observations from 46 different higher education

institutions of which 56% are Universities (Uni), 23% are Technical Universities (TUs) and

21% are Universities of Applied Sciences (UAS). For each of the 16 German States (Länder),

the sample contains at least one observation. The survey data is further complemented by

university and regional characteristics that are likely to affect the job choice of departing

researchers. These include the number of new firms in the region, the purchasing power of the

regional population as well industry performance in the area. The indicators serve to proxy for

the outside options of the departing researchers.

3.1 Nest characteristics

The unit of analysis is the department, research unit or chair. Teaching and research at German

universities has traditionally been organized around “chairs” with one professor heading a

research group specialized in a certain sub-field. The number of researchers employed at such

chairs may differ substantially. Some may be labelled research unit or department when they

employ several post-doctoral researchers or more than one professor.

Page 12: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

9

Table 1 summarized the main characteristics for the sample of research units that provided full

answers to the survey and for which patent and publication information could be

unambiguously identified.2 The average institution size as measured by the number of students

was about 18 thousand during the year of the survey. Since this distribution is skewed with few

large institutions and many smaller ones, we use the log of the student count in the econometric

analysis. At the level of the research unit, on average, eight researchers (not including the head)

were employed. The mean share of technical staff over all employees was 10 per cent. As could

be expected given that only department or research unit heads were surveyed, these researchers

are very experienced with an average of 22 years since completing their doctoral degree. With

regard to gender, we see that only about three per cent of research unit heads are female.

The surveyed research unit heads were also asked to indicate the importance of several factors

for their unit’s links with industry using a scale from zero to three (0 = not important to 3 =

very important). The first factor related to the head’s former jobs in industry, the second to the

relevance of contract research and the third to joint research with firms. Of these three

categories the first two were of higher importance, on average, than the latter. In terms of

research orientation, the research unit heads indicated the time the unit usually spent on basic

research, applied research and experimental development. In our sample, research units spent

on average about 42 per cent of their time on basic research, about 41 per cent on applied

research and less than 18 per cent on experimental development. By multiplying these time

shares with the number of researchers at the unit we derive indicators for the relative work force

attributed to each type of activity. Research orientation may also be reflected in the publication

and patent record of the unit heads. For the 5-year pre-sample period from 1995 to 1999 we

observe an average count of 11 publications and 1.4 patents. The aggregate number of citations

to journal articles published in that period until 2008 is about 237 at the mean, but the median

is much lower with about 24 citations. Patents got cited during the same period about 20 times

on average (the median is zero and the 75th percentile is just two citations). Thus, as is common

for these types of measures, the distribution of publications and patents is highly skewed.

Therefore, we take logarithms (+1) of these counts in the regression models. We further

2 In few cases for very common names like “Hans Müller” we could not unambiguously identify publications

and patent applications even when addresses, CV information, and research field were taken into account. We

dropped these observations from the sample.

Page 13: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

10

calculate at the professor level the average number of citations per publication and patents and

include these variables as quality-weighted publication and patent indicators.

The survey further provides information on the amount and composition of research grants that

complemented a unit’s institutional core funding. We differentiate between grants from public

sources, e.g. the German Research Foundation (DFG) and the federal state governments, and

income generated from industry sources. 61% of surveyed professors stated that their unit had

received funding from industry and 78% had acquired public research grants in addition to their

core institutional funding. The amount of industry funding and its share over the total budget

differ between institution types and research fields (see Table A.2). On average the share was

8.6% amounting to approximately 98 thousand Euros. The share of research grants received

from public sources is similar for universities and technical universities, but is considerably

lower at universities of applied sciences. On average, research units received 21.7% of their

total budget from public research grants, which corresponds to about 127 thousand Euros.

Table 1: Summary statistics (n = 676)

Variable description Variable name Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Institution and research units

Institution size (total # of students) STUDENTS 17,913.4 11,850.79 1,451 59,599

Number of researchers LABSIZE 7.573 9.537 0 71

Share of technical staff (in % of

total) TECHS 9.943 13.710 0 80

Number of years since PhD EXPERIENCE 21.869 8.720 1 43

University UNI 0.558 0.497 0 1

Technical University TU 0.232 0.423 0 1

University of Applied Sciences UAS 0.210 0.408 0 1

Gender of unit head FEMALE 0.033 0.178 0 1

Head’s former job in industry FORMER_JOB 1.371 1.184 0 3

Contract research for industry CONTRACT_RESEARCH 1.348 1.116 0 3

Joint patenting/publishing with

industry JOINT_RESEARCH 0.851 0.920 0 3

Research orientation/output

Basic research (in %) BASIC 41.707 26.357 0 100

Applied research (in %) APPLIED 40.598 26.357 0 100

Experimental development (in %) DEVELOPEMENT 17.695 21.519 0 100

Number of publications PUBLICATIONS 11.167 20.448 0 243

Page 14: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

11

Number of citations to publications PUB_CITATIONS 236.709 608.970 0 5907

Number of patents PATENTS 1.402 3.463 0 32

Number of citations to patents PAT_CITATIONS 20.054 124.968 0 2634

Research funding

Public grants (in % of total budget) PUBLIC GRANTS 21.779 20.123 0 100

Industry grants (in % of total

budget) INDUSTRY GRANTS 8.580 13.435 0 100

* Seven scientific field dummies not presented. See Table A.2 in the Appendix for details.

3.2 Job choices of departing researchers

The survey asked a series of questions about researchers that had left the unit during the two

years prior to the survey. On average, about six researchers left each research unit (median =

4). We distinguish between short-, medium- and long-term affiliation to the unit and find, in

line with our expectations, that drop-out is highest after four to five years (see Table 2). People

leaving after more than five years occurs much less. This observation points to the conclusion

that the majority of departing researchers leave after completing their doctoral degrees, their

habilitation (postdoc) or quit earlier. We see that this pattern is quite consistent for all institution

types. University of Applied Sciences, however, have fewer departing researchers due to

smaller overall team sizes (see Table A.1 in the Appendix).

Table 2: Departing researchers (n = 676 obs.)

Variable description Median Mean Std.

Dev. Min Max

Number of departing researchers 4 6.30 9.56 0 132

by duration of employment

1-3 years 1 2.63 6.65 0 105

4-5 years 1 2.89 4.68 0 40

> 5 years 0 1.01 3.50 0 60

Table 3 shows the research unit answers regarding the destinations of these departing

researchers. The survey question was formulated such that unit heads were asked to indicate

the type of job (R&D job or other activity) leavers had taken up, the type of firm or institution,

and whether leavers took up the new job in Germany or abroad. Multiple answers were possible

and respondents could also indicate that they did not know. We can broadly classify the job

destinations as jobs in industry and as employment at public institutions, e.g. universities, public

Page 15: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

12

research centres, and other public institutions, which include government. We further

distinguish between different types of “industry jobs”: start-up companies, employment at small

and medium-sized firms (SMEs), employment at large firms, and jobs in consulting firms.3

The descriptive statistic already show that the higher education system provides an important

source for highly qualified employees for both the public and private sectors. Only 6% of

research units trained researchers for public jobs alone, and 31% reported that all their departing

researchers joined industry (numbers not reported in Table 3). The majority of units, however,

indicated destinations in both the public and the private sector. Academic start-ups as post-

employment job choice occurred in about 20% of the units. The foundation of a new firm by

former employees is highest at technical universities as well in the fields of physics and

mechanical engineering (see Table A.2 for a disaggregation by field and institution type). The

difference between SMEs and larger firms is not particularly pronounced, although researchers

that go abroad move to larger firms. A large share of departing researchers tend to stay in R&D-

related jobs as indicated by the generally relative small differences between the categories “any”

job and “R&D” job. When comparing jobs domestically and abroad, we find the overall

distribution pattern to be quite similar although going abroad is relatively less common. Finally,

universities and public research institutions also constitute important destinations for leavers.

We are interested in which department or unit-level factors explain the destination choices of

departing researchers. In the econometric set-up we account for the fact that post-employment

job choices are taken with different options in mind. In addition to the unit level characteristics

presented in Table 1, we control for geographical characteristics as local opportunities may

affect the decision to start a new firm and geographical proximity to large firms or consulting

companies may induce young researchers to move there. We therefore include three measures

for regional economic activity at the district level (Landkreis)4 in values referring to the pre-

survey year. The gross domestic product is included to account for industrial activity in the

region, income per capita to take demand factors into account and we calculate net entry (new

firm registrations minus exists) to control for regional structural change.

Table 3: Job choices of departing researchers by type of destination (n = 676)

Variable description Variable name Mean values

3 A further category was “unemployment“. This category had been selected by 7% of the departments, however,

always in combination with other categories. 4 Germany has 295 of these districts of which our sample covers 38.

Page 16: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

13

ALL DOMESTIC ABROAD

any R&D any R&D any R&D

Industry job INDUSTRY_JOB 0.694 0.580 0.685 0.566 0.158 0.067

Start-up START_UP 0.194 0.090 0.192 0.89 0.033 0.004

SME SME 0.472 0.333 0.462 0.321 0.052 0.021

Large firm LARGE_FIRM 0.546 0.439 0.530 0.425 0.115 0.050

Consulting company CONSULTING 0.197 0.068 0.195 0.058 0.018 0.010

Public job PUBLIC_JOB 0.439 0.339 0.398 0.327 0.159 0.018

(Techn.) University /

UAS UNI_RESEARCH 0.358 0.260 0.300 0.251 0.136 0.010

Public research

institution PUBLIC_RESEARCH 0.204 0.160 0.189 0.155 0.047 0.004

other public institutions OTHER_PUBLIC 0.107 0.027 0.104 0.024 0.006 0.004

* Unemployment and unknown destination / unknown job type not presented.

4. Econometric Analysis

In the following econometric analysis, we aim to identify research unit factors that explain the

job decisions of departing researchers. It is important to note that job choices can be studied at

different levels of aggregation. We start by distinguishing between industry jobs and public

jobs and consider these options to be interdependent. Next, we consider the case that departing

researchers are settled on the decision to take an R&D job. In that case, we would like to know

what determines whether this job is taken in industry or in public research. Third, we consider

the case of a fixed decision to move to industry. In that case, we investigate what determines

the probability that an R&D job is taken up versus a non-research-related job. Finally, we

disaggregate our measures of public and industry jobs and estimate all employment options

(START_UP, SME, LARGE_FIRM, CONSULTING, UNI, PUBLIC_RESEARCH, OTHER_PUBLIC)

simultaneously.

4.1 Identification Strategy

For each of the first three scenarios, we estimate simultaneous (two-equation) discrete choice

models by maximum-likelihood that can be written as

𝑙𝑛𝐿 = ∑ 𝑙𝑛𝛷2(𝑞1,𝑗,𝑥1,𝑗𝛽1, 𝑞2,𝑗,𝑥2,𝑗𝛽2, 𝜌𝑗∗)𝑁

𝑗=1 (1)

where Ф2 is the cumulative bivariate normal distribution function and qi,j = 1 if yi,j ≠ 0 (for I =

1,2). We observe yi,j = 1 if y*i,j > 0 and yi,j = 0 otherwise. If 𝜌 = 0, then the log likelihood for the

Page 17: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

14

bivariate probit model is equal to the sum of the individual log likelihoods of the independent

models.

Next, we disaggregate destinations and estimate the probability of a unit having former

researcher leaving to any of the seven destinations (START_UP, SME, LARGE_FIRM, CONSULTING,

UNI, PUBLIC_RESEARCH, OTHER_PUBLIC) and estimate h-equation multivariate probit models (h

= 7) that can be written as:

𝑦𝑚∗ = 𝑥𝑚𝛽𝑚 + 𝜀𝑚, 𝑚 = 1, … , ℎ (2)

𝑦𝑚 = 𝐷(𝑦𝑚∗ > 0), 𝑚 = 1, … , ℎ (3)

𝜖 = (𝜀1, … 𝜀ℎ)′~𝑁(0, Σ) (4)

with m representing the different destinations and the vector x summarizing unit level,

institutional and regional characteristics. The variance-covariance matrix ∑ has values of 1 on

the diagonal due to normalization and correlations ρjk = ρkj as off-diagonal elements. The log-

likelihood function is then given by:

𝑙𝑛𝐿 = (𝛽1, … 𝛽ℎ), 𝛴; 𝑦|𝑥 = ∑ 𝑙𝑛𝛷ℎ ((𝑞𝑖,1,𝑥𝑖,1𝛽1, … , 𝑞𝑖,ℎ,𝑥𝑖,ℎ𝛽ℎ); 𝛺)𝑁𝑖=1 (5)

The matrix Ω has values of 1 on the diagonal and ωj,k = ωk,j = qi,jqi,kρi,k for j ≠k and

and j,k = (1,..,h) as off-diagonal elements. In the multi-equation case Φℎ denotes the joint

normal distribution of order h.5

4.2 Results

Aggregate destinations

Table 4 presents the results, more precisely marginal effects at the means of all other variables,

from the first set of bivariate estimations on a research unit’s probability to train researchers for

industry and/or public jobs. Both models show that institution type and scientific field are

important factors in shaping the job decision of departing researchers, while regional

characteristics do not have a significant effect. Model 1 includes publication and patent counts,

while we include the citation-weighted publication and patent measures in Model 2. Models 1

and 2 both show that research jointly with industry translates into a higher probability for

5

The expression for the log-likelihood function thus involves an h-dimensional integral that does not have a closed

form. We employ a Maximum Simulated Likelihood Method using the GHK simulator to evaluate the integral

numerically (Geweke 1989, Hajivassiliou and McFadden 1998, and Keane 1994). See Roodman (2009) for details

on the implementation of the simulation method.

Page 18: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

15

researchers to move to industry. Contract research also has a positive, but slightly weaker effect.

A higher publication performance during the five-years prior to the survey is associated with a

higher likelihood of researchers moving to other public institutions. This confirms Hypothesis

1 that research units with higher academic publication performance are more likely to see their

departing researchers take jobs at universities and public research institutions.

Whereas the patent count is not a good predictor for any of the destination options, citation

counts to patents filed in the five-years prior to the survey are positively associated with

industry jobs.

We additionally control for research orientation (basic, applied and experimental) and see that

basic research orientation is equally as important for both destination types. When splitting up

the unit’s grant-based financing into public grants and industry sponsoring, we find that industry

grants predict industry jobs and public grants predict public jobs. Finally, we see that older unit

heads see their former employees more often move to public jobs.

Models 1 and 2 of Table 5a repeat Models 1 and 2 of Table 4 for R&D jobs in industry and/or

public institutions, thus excluding all non-R&D job destinations. Just as previously, we find

that researchers trained in research units with a higher share of industry grants are more likely

to move to industry, while public grants are associated with public sector jobs. Publication

numbers have a positive effect on the propensity of departing researchers to take up jobs in

public institutions, while citations do not. Patent numbers have a positive effect on research

jobs in industry, but the patent citation measure turns insignificant. This partially confirms

Hypothesis 3 that research units with higher patenting activity are more likely to see their

departing researchers leave for an R&D job in industry. We cannot confirm that patent

relevance for industrial applications (as measured through patent citations) matters. The

analysis of the disaggregated destinations provides a more refined view as we describe in the

next section.

Table 4: Simultaneous bivariate probit estimation results on industry versus public sector employment (n = 676)

Model 1 Model 2

INDUSTRY_JOB PUBLIC_JOB INDUSTRY_JOB PUBLIC_JOB

dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e.

Institution and research unit

ln(STUDENTS) -0.037 0.037 0.021 0.049 -0.036 0.037 0.023 0.049

TECHS -0.003 * 0.002 0.001 0.002 -0.003 * 0.002 -0.001 0.002

EXPERIENCE 0.004 0.037 0.009 *** 0.003 0.004 * 0.002 0.009 *** 0.003

Page 19: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

16

FEMALE -0.070 0.104 -0.066 0.117 -0.072 0.101 -0.080 0.116

FORMER_JOB 0.010 0.021 -0.023 0.021 0.008 0.021 -0.030 0.021

CONTRACT_RESEARCH 0.036 * 0.021 0.035 0.025 0.037 * 0.021 0.035 0.025

JOINT_RESEARCH 0.051 ** 0.025 -0.034 0.026 0.051 ** 0.026 -0.033 0.027

Research orientation/output

BASIC 0.016 ** 0.007 0.011 * 0.006 0.016 ** 0.007 0.012 ** 0.006

APPLIED -0.011 * 0.006 -0.001 0.007 -0.011 * 0.006 -0.001 0.007

DEVELOPEMENT 0.004 0.011 -0.001 0.012 0.004 0.011 -0.002 0.025

ln(PUBLICATIONS) 0.019 0.017 0.057 *** 0.021

ln(PATENTS) 0.048 0.030 0.025 0.030

ln(PUB_CITATIONS) 0.016 0.015 0.023 0.019

ln(PAT_CITATIONS) 0.044 ** 0.020 0.039 * 0.020

Research funding

PUBLIC GRANTS 0.002 ** 0.001 0.004 *** 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 0.004 *** 0.001

INDUSTRY GRANTS 0.004 * 0.002 -0.002 0.002 0.003 * 0.002 -0.002 0.002

Log likelihood -685.75 -687.04

rho (s.e.) 0.454 (0.060)*** 0.451 (0.062)***

Joint sign. field dummies 26.50*** 33.13***

Joint sign. of inst. type dummies 36.02*** 36.52***

Joint sign. of regional variables 4.07 4.23

Note: Institution type and field dummies not presented. All models contain a constant. Standard errors clustered by institution

type, field and region (171 clusters). Marginal effects are calculated at means of all other variables. * (**, ***) indicate

significance levels of 1% (5%, 10%).

Finally, Models 3 and 4 of Table 5a compare R&D jobs in industry and other, non-research

jobs in industry. The results for R&D jobs are similar to those reported in Models 1 and 2. But

refining our previous results, we observe that basic research orientation has a positive marginal

effect for R&D jobs in industry but not for other jobs in the private sector.

Page 20: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

17

Table 5a: Simultaneous bivariate probit estimation results on private versus public sector R&D job and type of job in the private sector (n = 676)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

R&D_INDUSTRY R&D_PUBLIC R&D_INDUSTRY R&D_PUBLIC R&D_INDUSTRY OTHER_INDUSTRY R&D_INDUSTRY OTHER_INDUSTRY

dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e.

Institution and research

unit

ln(STUDENTS) -0.061 0.046 -0.014 0.054 -0.059 0.046 -0.013 0.053 -0.061 0.046 0.028 0.042 -0.058 0.046 0.026 0.043

TECHS -0.004 ** 0.002 -0.001 0.002 -0.004 ** 0.003 -0.001 0.002 -0.004 ** 0.002 0.001 0.002 -0.004 ** 0.002 0.001 0.002

EXPERIENCE 0.003 0.003 0.009 *** 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.009 *** 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.002 0.003 0.004 * 0.002

FEMALE -0.065 0.124 -0.028 0.107 -0.069 0.121 -0.041 0.107 -0.060 0.129 0.008 0.110 -0.064 0.127 0.003 0.111

FORMER_JOB 0.007 0.023 -0.016 0.020 0.002 0.024 -0.022 0.021 0.006 0.023 0.006 0.023 0.001 0.024 0.007 0.023

CONTRACT_RESEARCH 0.036 * 0.021 0.034 0.024 0.036 * 0.021 0.034 0.024 0.036 * 0.021 0.001 0.022 0.036 * 0.021 0.001 0.022

JOINT_RESEARCH 0.031 0.025 -0.025 0.023 0.036 0.025 -0.021 0.023 0.033 0.025 0.032 0.023 0.038 0.025 0.029 0.023

Research orientation/output

BASIC 0.018 *** 0.006 0.013 ** 0.005 0.018 *** 0.006 0.015 *** 0.005 0.018 *** 0.006 0.006 0.005 0.019 *** 0.006 0.006 0.005

APPLIED -0.007 0.006 0.002 0.006 -0.007 0.006 0.001 0.006 -0.006 0.006 0.008 0.007 -0.007 0.006 0.008 0.007

DEVELOPEMENT -0.007 0.012 0.001 0.009 -0.006 0.012 0.001 0.009 -0.008 0.013 0.004 0.011 -0.007 0.013 0.003 0.011

ln(PUBLICATIONS) 0.012 0.019 0.043 ** 0.019 0.015 0.019 0.036 * 0.021

ln(PATENTS) 0.055 * 0.033 0.025 0.027 0.051 0.034 -0.033 0.028

ln(PUB_CITATIONS) -0.004 0.017 0.014 0.017 -0.004 0.018 0.034 * 0.019

ln(PAT_CITATIONS) 0.033 0.021 0.024 0.019 0.031 0.021 -0.013 0.019

Research funding

PUBLIC GRANTS 0.002 0.001 0.003 *** 0.001 0.002 * 0.001 0.003 *** 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 0.002 * 0.001 0.002 * 0.001

INDUSTRY GRANTS 0.005 *** 0.002 -0.001 0.002 0.005 *** 0.002 -0.001 0.002 0.004 *** 0.002 -0.001 0.002 0.004 *** 0.002 -0.007 0.002

Log likelihood -710.12 -712.87 -771.31 -772.20

rho (s.e.) 0.352 (0.061)*** 0.356 (0.055)*** 0.195 (0.068)*** 0.196 (0.068)***

Joint sign. field dummies 48.20*** 54.43*** 41.77*** 42.00***

Joint sign. of inst. type

dummies 35.19***

36.52***

41.71***

42.30***

Joint sign. of regional

variables 4.24

4.31

13.77**

13.41**

Note: Institution type and field dummies not presented. All models contain a constant. Standard errors clustered by institution type, field and region (171 clusters). Marginal effects are calculated at means of all other

variables. * (**, ***) indicate significance levels of 1% (5%, 10%).

Page 21: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

18

Table 5b present the results from a set of models distinguishing between the types of jobs taken

in the public sector. The results shows that publication performance matters in terms of quantity

but not necessarily quality (see Model 6) for R&D tasks in the public sector, but not for non-

research related jobs. Similarly basic research orientation and public grants matter only for

R&D jobs. The latter confirms Hypothesis 2 that research units with a higher share of public

grants are more likely to see their departing researchers to stay in academe. Contract research,

on the other hand, appears to predict non-R&D public jobs.

Table 5b: Simultaneous bivariate probit estimation results on type of job in the public sector (n = 676)

Model 5 Model 6

R&D_PUBLIC OTHER_PUBLIC R&D_PUBLIC OTHER_PUBLIC

dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e.

Institution and research unit

ln(STUDENTS) -0.013 0.054 0.037 * 0.014 -0.012 0.053 0.036 ** 0.015

TECHS -0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001 -0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001

EXPERIENCE 0.009 *** 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.008 *** 0.002 0.001 0.001

FEMALE -0.029 0.108 -0.022 0.052 -0.041 0.108 -0.020 0.053

FORMER_JOB -0.015 0.020 0.007 0.009 -0.021 0.020 0.007 0.009

CONTRACT_RESEARCH 0.035 0.024 0.026 *** 0.009 0.035 0.024 0.025 *** 0.009

JOINT_RESEARCH -0.025 0.023 -0.024 * 0.012 -0.021 0.023 -0.025 ** 0.011

Research orientation/output

BASIC 0.013 ** 0.005 0.002 0.002 0.015 *** 0.005 0.002 0.001

APPLIED 0.002 0.006 0.003 0.002 0.001 0.006 0.003 0.002

DEVELOPEMENT -0.001 0.009 0.002 0.004 0.001 0.009 0.002 0.004

ln(PUBLICATIONS) 0.044 ** 0.019 0.007 0.008

ln(PATENTS) 0.028 0.027 -0.006 0.013

ln(PUB_CITATIONS) 0.016 0.017 0.010 0.008

ln(PAT_CITATIONS) 0.024 0.019 0.001 0.008

Research funding

PUBLIC GRANTS 0.003 *** 0.001 -0.001 * 0.000 0.003 *** 0.001 -0.001 * 0.000

INDUSTRY GRANTS -0.001 0.002 -0.001 0.001 -0.001 0.002 -0.001 * 0.000

Log likelihood -512.47 -514.58

rho (s.e.) 0.254 (0.097)** 0.253 (0.097)**

Joint sign. field dummies 32.01*** 41.22***

Joint sign. of inst. type dummies 3.73 4.12

Joint sign. of regional variables 6.86 6.88

Page 22: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

19

Disaggregate destinations

Tables 6a and 6b show the results for all seven disaggregate destinations. Table 6b includes the

quality-weighted publication and patent measures. As in the previously presented models,

research field and institution type matter. For instance, research units at both universities and

technical universities are more likely than research units from universities of applied sciences

to see former employees move to large firms. For SMEs the institution types do not differ. We

find that technical universities are more likely to see employees moving to start-up firms. Again,

research units at universities and technical universities are more likely to produce future

university researchers. In addition, we now find that regional factors are jointly significant.

Previous insights that public grants are a good predictor of public sector R&D employment are

confirmed. The effects from industry grants disappear, however. Interestingly, we find

publication performance to matter also for employment in industry, in particular in start-ups,

large firms and in consulting probably reflecting institutional reputation.

For movements to SMEs contract research and patent numbers are highly significant. When

accounting for industrial relevance of the patents (Table 6b), we find a significant positive

impact of citations-weighted patents for SMEs, large firms and public research institutions, but

the marginal effect is largest for the first destination. Thus, we cannot confirm the part of

Hypothesis 3 that presumed that research units with higher patenting activity (also in terms of

the patent relevance for industrial applications) are more likely to see their departing

researchers start their own business, but rather found academic patenting to be associated with

jobs in established SMEs.

Similarly, we found only partial support for our Hypothesis 4 that research units with stronger

industry ties are more likely to see their departing researchers take R&D jobs in industry,

especially in large firms. While Models 1 and 2 in Table 4 confirmed the first part of the

hypothesis, we second part is less clear. Contract research is associated with SME employment

and the effect of joint research is only significant at a 10% confidence level.

Research units with a research focus on experimental development are more likely to see their

former employees move to start-up firms, while for SMEs and larger firms a focus on basic

research appears to be attractive. Thus, Hypothesis 5 that research units with focus on applied

rather than basic research are more likely to see their departing researchers start their own

business or leave for an R&D job in industry is again only partially confirmed.

Page 23: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

20

Table 6a: Multi-equation simultaneous probit estimation results on separated destinations (n = 676)

Model 1

START_UP SME LARGE FIRM CONSULTING UNI_RESEARCH PUBLIC_RESEARCH OTHER_PUBLIC

dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e.

Institution and research unit

ln(STUDENTS) -0.041 0.029 -0.008 0.05 -0.059 0.045 0.008 0.029 -0.012 0.020 0.030 0.039 0.043 ** 0.017

TECHS 0.002 0.001 -0.001 0.002 -0.001 0.002 -0.001 0.001 -0.002 0.002 -0.001 0.001 0.002 * 0.001

EXPERIENCE 0.005 *** 0.002 0.004 0.003 -0.001 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.008 *** 0.002 0.004 ** 0.002 0.001 0.001

FEMALE 0.156 0.123 -0.012 0.138 -0.199 * 0.112 0.087 0.094 -0.022 0.100 -0.129 *** 0.041 -0.045 0.037

FORMER_JOB 0.002 0.015 -0.030 0.022 0.022 0.026 0.005 0.016 -0.024 0.020 0.007 0.016 -0.003 0.012

CONTRACT_RESEARCH 0.014 0.017 0.065 *** 0.023 0.028 0.023 -0.008 0.015 0.009 0.024 0.028 * 0.017 0.027 *** 0.011

JOINT_RESEARCH -0.006 0.018 0.012 0.027 0.052 * 0.029 0.027 0.017 0.005 0.024 -0.003 0.018 -0.018 0.016

Research orientation/output

BASIC 0.005 * 0.003 0.016 *** 0.005 0.018 *** 0.007 0.006 * 0.003 0.012 ** 0.005 0.008 *** 0.003 0.002 0.002

APPLIED 0.006 0.018 0.005 0.007 -0.007 0.007 0.009 * 0.005 -0.001 0.007 0.002 0.005 0.001 0.003

DEVELOPEMENT 0.017 * 0.009 -0.001 0.016 0.009 0.013 -0.011 0.009 0.001 0.012 -0.002 0.009 0.005 0.005

ln(PUBLICATIONS) 0.031 ** 0.014 0.001 0.019 0.060 *** 0.019 0.029 ** 0.014 0.032 * 0.017 0.018 0.015 0.011 0.010

ln(PATENTS) 0.001 0.020 0.063 ** 0.029 0.036 0.033 -0.023 0.022 0.014 0.030 -0.008 0.019 -0.007 0.015

Research funding

PUBLIC GRANTS 0.001 0.001 0.002 * 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.003 ** 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 -0.001 0.001

INDUSTRY GRANTS 0.002 0.001 -0.001 0.002 0.003 0.002 0.001 0.001 -0.002 0.001 -0001 0.002 -0.001 0.001

Institution type

UNI 0.084 0.060 0.107 0.082 0.533 *** 0.068 0.173 *** 0.066 0.211 ** 0.082 0.086 0.067 0.043 0.041

TU 0.120 * 0.072 0.145 0.090 0.445 *** 0.062 0.195 * 0.107 0.201 ** 0.098 0.091 0.093 0.051 0.052

UAS Reference category

Log likelihood -2051.471

Joint sign. field dummies 152.61***

Joint sign. of inst. type dummies 56.71***

Joint sign. of regional variables 67.80***

Note: Field dummies not presented. All models contain a constant. Standard errors clustered by institution type, field and region (171 clusters). Marginal effects are calculated at means of all other

variables. * (**, ***) indicate significance levels of 1% (5%, 10%). See Table A.3 for correlations between equations.

Page 24: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

21

Table 6b: Multi-equation simultaneous probit estimation results on separated destinations with quality-weighted measures research performance (n = 676)

Model 2

START_UP SME LARGE FIRM CONSULTING UNI_RESEARCH PUBLIC_RESEARCH OTHER_PUBLIC

dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e. dy/dx s.e.

Institution and research unit

ln(STUDENTS) -0.046 0.029 -0.004 0.045 -0.054 0.044 0.003 0.029 -0.017 0.043 0.040 0.038 0.044 ** 0.018

TECHS 0.001 0.001 -0.001 0.002 -0.003 0.002 -0.001 0.001 -0.002 0.002 -0.001 0.001 0.001 * 0.001

EXPERIENCE 0.005 *** 0.002 0.004 0.003 -0.002 ** 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.008 *** 0.002 0.004 ** 0.002 0.001 0.001

FEMALE 0.138 0.120 -0.008 0.136 -0.219 *** 0.111 0.072 0.090 -0.036 0.096 -0.128 *** 0.039 -0.046 0.038

FORMER_JOB 0.001 0.015 -0.029 0.022 0.012 0.026 0.003 0.016 -0.028 0.020 0.007 0.016 -0.002 0.012

CONTRACT_RESEARCH 0.013 0.017 0.065 *** 0.023 0.028 * 0.023 -0.008 0.016 0.008 0.024 0.028 * 0.016 0.027 *** 0.011

JOINT_RESEARCH -0.001 0.017 0.011 0.026 0.054 0.028 0.029 * 0.017 0.014 0.025 -0.009 0.017 -0.021 0.015

Research orientation/output

BASIC 0.006 * 0.003 0.016 *** 0.005 0.019 *** 0.007 0.006 ** 0.003 0.012 ** 0.005 0.008 *** 0.003 0.002 0.002

APPLIED 0.006 0.005 0.005 0.016 -0.008 0.007 0.008 * 0.005 -0.001 0.007 0.003 0.005 0.001 0.003

DEVELOPEMENT 0.018 ** 0.009 -0.002 0.016 0.009 0.014 -0.011 0.009 0.003 0.012 -0.006 0.009 0.003 0.004

ln(PUB_CITATIONS) 0.025 * 0.013 0.019 0.019 0.017 0.017 0.019 * 0.011 0.017 0.017 0.006 0.013 0.010 0.010

ln(PAT_CITATIONS) -0.013 0.013 0.055 ** 0.022 0.038 ** 0.022 -0.022 0.015 -0.010 0.019 0.027 ** 0.013 0.008 0.010

Research funding

PUBLIC GRANTS 0.001 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.003 ** 0.001 0.002 ** 0.001 -0.001 0.001

INDUSTRY GRANTS 0.002 0.001 -0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.001 -0.002 0.001 -0.001 0.002 -0.001 0.001

Institution type

UNI 0.095 0.061 0.085 0.082 0.547 *** 0.065 0.185 *** 0.064 0.231 *** 0.080 0.076 0.066 0.040 0.041

TU 0.130 * 0.075 0.128 0.089 0.447 *** 0.062 0.210 ** 0.107 0.214 ** 0.097 0.074 0.090 0.044 0.052

UAS Reference category

Log likelihood -2051.67

Joint sign. field dummies 163.75***

Joint sign. of inst. type dummies 62.25***

Joint sign. of regional variables 70.26***

Note: Field dummies not presented. All models contain a constant. Standard errors clustered by institution type, field and region (171 clusters). Marginal effects are calculated at means of all other

variables. * (**, ***) indicate significance levels of 1% (5%, 10%). See Table A.3 for correlations between equations.

Page 25: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

22

5 Conclusions

In this paper we studied the importance of team and organisational characteristics of the

home departments for career choices of departing researchers. Young researchers may move

to a different university or move out of academia all together and into industry. Previous

literature has linked these decisions to the young academic’s taste for science and academic

performance (Scott, 2004). Research groups have been argued to affect individual performance

as well as shaping the careers of their members (Walsh and Lee, 2013), by providing young

researchers with a certain skill set and by giving access to professional networks.

Based on survey data from 676 science and engineering research units at 46 universities in

Germany we differentiate between R&D and non-R&D jobs in newly formed firms, SMEs,

large firms, consulting companies, public research institutes and universities. The results from

multiple simultaneous equations models on the likelihood that researchers from a focal

department or research unit take a specific follow-on career decision confirm the important role

of home departments (nests) for career building of researchers.

We find that the performance of the nest in terms of access to research grants and

publication numbers as well as industry ties shape job choices of departing researchers. In

particular, we find that the share of the research unit’s total budget from public grants and its

publication performance increases the probability that departing researchers take a research job

in the public sector. On the other hand, grants from industry increase the likelihood that they

take a job in industry. Patents correlate positively with R&D jobs in SMEs indicating that for

these firms seeking technological knowledge from former university employees may be crucial.

The quality-weighted patent count, however, also matters for employment in larger firms and

public research institutions. In line with these result, we find the department head’s network

with industry partners, especially when established through contract research or joint research

projects, to increase the propensity of her staff to move to industry. Research orientation (basic

versus applied), however, is not a precise predictor of academic or industry job choice. Instead,

researchers from applied units are more likely to go into consulting, while those from units

with a focus on experimental development are more likely to start their own firm.

From a policy perspective these results shed some light on the factors behind the job and

destination choices of academics. Young researchers have been recognised as contributing to

innovation and knowledge production and their mobility as supporting knowledge and

technology transfer. The results show that nest characteristics are important for explaining the

Page 26: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

23

job choices of young researchers and point at the importance of department links and prestige

for job prospects of young researchers. Although the results are based on a single academic

market they can be extended to other countries as temporary positions in academia are

increasing and more academics are trained than positions are available in academe.

We strongly encourage future research on job choices of departing researchers. Little is still

known about which nest designs may contribute to keeping the most able scientific researchers

in academe, while at the same time facilitating knowledge transfer to industry and public

institutions. While our study focussed solely on the home department, future studies may in

addition consider individual characteristics of the researchers. Further, it would be worth

studying more explicitly the mechanisms that shape career decisions and how individual career

preferences change or do not change during initial academic employment. Future studies may

also attempt to measure the selection of certain individuals into particular research

environments and how that affects the nest culture.

Page 27: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

24

References

Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., Stein, J. (2008), Academic Freedom, Private-Sector Focus, and

the Process of Innovation, Rand Journal of Economics 39, 617–635.

Agarwal, R., Ohyama, A. (2013), Industry or Academia, Basic or Applied? Career Choices and

Earnings Trajectories of Scientists, Management Science 59, 950–970.

Aschoff, B., Grimpe, C. (2014), Contemporaneous Peer Effects, Career Age and the Industry

Involvement of Academics in Biotechnology, Research Policy 43, 367-381.

Audretsch, D., Stephan, P. (1999), Knowledge Spillovers in Biotechnology: Sources and

Incentives, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 9, 97-107.

Auriol, L., M. Misu, Freeman, R. (2013), Careers of Doctorate Holders: Analysis of Labour

Market and Mobility Indicators, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers.

2013/04, OECD, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k43nxgs289w-en.

Austin, A.E. (2002), Preparing the Next Generation of Faculty: Graduate School as

Socialization to the Academic Career, Journal of Higher Education 73, 94-122.

Azoulay, P., Zivin J.S.G., Sampat B.N. (2011), The Diffusion of Scientific Knowledge Across

Time and Space: Evidence from Professional Transitions for the Superstars in Medicine,

NBER Working Paper No 16683.

Baldi, S. (1995), Prestige Determinants of First Academic Job for New Sociology PhDs: 1985-

1992, Sociological Quarterly 36, 777–789.

Balsmeier, B., Pellens, M. (2014), Who Makes, who Breaks: Which Scientists Stay in

Academe?, Economics Letters 122, 229-232.

Becker, G.S. (1962), Investment in Human Beings, Journal of Political Economy 70, 9–49.

Bercovitz J., Feldman M. (2008), Academic Entrepreneurs: Organizational Change at the

Individual Level, Organization Science 19, 69-89.

Bourdieu, P. (1986), The Forms of Social Capital, In. Richardson, J.G. ed. Handbook of Theory

and research for the sociology of education, New York, Greenwood.

Burris, V. (2004), The Academic Caste System: Prestige Hierarchies in PhD Exchange

Networks, American Sociological Review 69, 239–264.

Burt, R.S. (1997), A Note on Social Capital and Network Content, Social Networks 19, 355–

373.

Coleman, J.C. (1988) Social Capital in the Creation Human Capital, American Journal of

Sociology 94, 95–120.

Crane, D., (1965), Scientists at Major and Minor Universities, A Study of Productivity and

Recognition, American Sociological Review, 30, 699–714.

Crane, D., (1970), The Academic Marketplace Revisited: a Study of Faculty Mobility Using

the Carter Ratings, The American Journal of Sociology 75, 953–964.

Crespi, A.G., Geuna, A., Nesta, J.J.L. (2007), The Mobility of University Inventors in Europe,

Journal of Technology Transfer 32, 195-215.

Page 28: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

25

Enders, J. (2005), Border Crossings: Research Training, Knowledge Dissemination and the

Transformation of Academic Work, Higher Education 49, 119-133.

Fox, M.F., Stephan, P. (2001), Careers of Young Scientists: Preferences, Prospects and

Realities by Gender and Field, Social Studies of Science 31, 109-22.

Franzoni, C., Stephan, P., Scellato, G. (2012), Foreign Born Scientists: Mobility Patterns for

Sixteen Countries, Nature Biotechnology 30 (12), 1250-1253.

Granovetter, M.S. (1985), Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of

Embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology 91, 481-510.

Griliches, Z. (1973), Research Expenditures and Growth Accounting. In: Williams, B. R. (ed.)

Science and technology in economic growth, London, Macmillan, 59–95.

Hottenrott, H., Thorwarth, S. (2011), Industry Funding of University Research and Scientific

Productivity, Kyklos 64 (4), 534–555.

Lam, A. (2007), Knowledge Networks and Careers: Academic Scientists in Industry-

University Links, Journal of Management Studies 44(6), 993-1016.

Lam, A. (2011), What Motivates Academic Scientists to Engage in Research

Commercialization: ‘Gold’, ‘ribbon’ or ‘puzzle’?, Research Policy 40, 1354-1368.

Lam, A., Campos, A. (2014), Content to be Sad’ or ‘Runaway Apprentice’? The Psychological

Contract and Career Agency of Young Scientists in the Entrepreneurial University, Human

Relations, forthcoming.

Lawson, C. (2013), Academic Patenting: The Importance of Industry Support, Journal of

Technology Transfer 38 (4), 509-535.

Levin, S.G., Stephan, P.E. (1991), Research Productivity Over the Life Cycle: Evidence for

Academic Scientists, American Economic Review 81, 114–132.

Long, J. S. (1978), Productivity and Academic Position in the Scientific Career, American

Sociological Review 43, 889–908.

Mangematin, V. (2000), PhD Job Market: Professional Trajectories and Incentives During the

PhD, Research Policy 29(6), 741-756.

Nelson, R., Phelps, E. (1966), Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion and Economic

Growth, American Economic Review 61, 69-75.

OECD (2000), Mobilising Human Resources for Innovation. Paris: OECD.

OECD (2008), The Global Competition for Talent: Mobility of the Highly Skilled. Directorate

for Science Technology and Industry, Paris: OECD.

Owen-Smith, J., Powell, W.W. (2001), To Patent or Not: Faculty Decisions and Institutional

Success at Technology Transfer, Journal of Technology Transfer 26, 99-114.

Petersen, A., Fortunato, S., Pan, R.K., Kaski, K., Penner, O., Riccaboni, M., Stanley, H.E.,

Pammolli, F. (2013), Reputation and Impact in Academic Careers, arXiv:1303.7274v3

[physics.soc-ph] 23 Jan 2014.

Pezzoni, M., Sterzi, V., Lissoni, F. (2012), Career Progress in Centralized Academic Systems:

an Analysis of French and Italian Physicists, Research Policy 41, 704-719.

Page 29: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

26

Roach, M., Sauermann, H. (2010), A Taste for Science? PhD Scientists’ Academic Orientation

and Self-Selection into Research Careers in Industry, Research Policy 39, 422-434.

Sauermann, H., Roach, M. (2012), Taste for Science, Taste for Commercialization, and Hybrid

Scientists, Paper presented at The Organisation, Economics and Policy of Scientific

Research, Torino, Italy.

Sauermann, H., Roach, M. (2014), Not all Scientists pay to be Scientists: PhDs’ Preferences

for Publishing in Industrial Employment, Research Policy 43, 32-47.

Sauermann H., Stephan, P. (2013), Conflicting Logics? A Multidimensional View of Industrial

and Academic Science, Organization Science 24, 889-909.

Schultz, T. (1961), Investment in Human Capital, The American Economic Review 51(1), 1-17.

Schultze, G.G., Warning, S., Wiermann, C. (2008), What and How Long Does It Take to Get

Tenure? The Case of Economics and Business Administration in Austria, Germany and

Switzerland, German Economic Review 9 (4), 473-505.

Smeby, J. C., Try, S. (2005), Departmental Contexts and Faculty Research Activity in Norway,

Research in Higher Education 46, 593–619.

Stephan, P. (2012), How Economics Shapes Science, Harvard University Press: Cambridge,

MA.

Stern, S. (2004), Do Scientists Pay to be Scientists?, Management Science 50, 835–853.

Stuart, T., W. Ding. (2006), When do Scientists Become Entrepreneurs? The Social Structural

Antecedents of Commercial Activity in Academic Life Sciences, American Journal of

Sociology 112, 97–144.

Toole, A.A., Czarnitzki, D. (2010), Commercializing Science: Is There a University “Brain

Drain” from Academic Entrepreneurship?, Management Science 56, 1599-1614.

Hall, B.H., Mairesse, J., Turner, L., (2007). Identifying Age, Cohort, and Period Effects in

Scientific Research Productivity: Discussion and Illustration Using Simulated and Actual

Data on French Physicists, Economics of Innovation and New Technology 16(2), 159-177.

Waldinger, F. (2012), Peer Effects in Science - Evidence from the Dismissal of Scientists in

Nazi Germany, Review of Economic Studies 79 (2), 838-861.

Walsh, J.P., Lee, Y.-N., (2013), The Bureaucratization of Science, Paper presented at The

Organisation, Economics and Policy of Scientific Research, Torino, Italy.

Zellner, C. (2003), The Economic Effects of Basic Research: Evidence for Embodied

Knowledge Transfer via Scientists’ Migration, Research Policy 32, 1881-1895.

Zinovyeva, N., Bagues, M., (2014), The Role of Connections in Academic Promotion,

American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, forthcoming.

Page 30: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

27

APPENDICES

Table A.1: Departing researchers by institution type (means, n = 676)

Variable description UNI TU UAS

Number of researchers 8.53 10.55 1.74

Number of departing researchers 7.61 7.52 1.46

by duration of employment

1-3 years 3.46 2.25 0.86

in % 34.38 22.61 27.90

4-5 years 3.34 4.21 0.25

in % 42.22 50.14 7.47

> 5 years 1.14 1.36 0.29

in % 10.94 15.78 9.70

Table A.2: Job choices by field and institution type (n = 676)

Field # % INDUSTRY JOBS PUBLIC JOBS

START_UP SME

LARGE_

FIRM

CON-

SULTING

UNI_

RESEARCH

PUBLIC_

RESEARCH

OTHER_

PUBLIC

by field

Physics 106 15.68 0.26 0.55 0.65 0.30 0.58 0.42 0.15

Mathematics /

Computer Science 107 15.83 0.12 0.36 0.46 0.23 0.31 0.12 0.06

Chemistry 95 14.05 0.15 0.62 0.65 0.23 0.52 0.31 0.23

Biology 58 8.58 0.17 0.47 0.26 0.05 0.45 0.19 0.05

Electrical Engineering 101 14.94 0.19 0.45 0.60 0.09 0.20 0.13 0.08

Mechanical Engineering 108 15.98 0.24 0.51 0.58 0.22 0.21 0.08 0.05

Other Engineering 101 14.94 0.21 0.36 0.50 0.18 0.29 0.19 0.12

by institution type

University 377 57.32 0.20 0.52 0.65 0.24 0.47 0.27 0.13

Technical University 157 23.68 0.29 0.54 0.63 0.25 0.35 0.20 0.11

University of Applied

Sciences 142 19.00 0.08 0.27 0.17 0.02 0.08 0.04 0.04

Page 31: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

PREVIOUS DISCUSSION PAPERS

154 Hottenrott, Hanna and Lopes-Bento, Cindy, R&D Partnerships and Innovation Performance: Can There be too Much of a Good Thing?, July 2014.

153 Hottenrott, Hanna and Lawson, Cornelia, Flying the Nest: How the Home Department Shapes Researchers’ Career Paths, July 2014.

152 Hottenrott, Hanna, Lopes-Bento, Cindy and Veugelers, Reinhilde, Direct and Cross-Scheme Effects in a Research and Development Subsidy Program, July 2014.

151 Dewenter, Ralf and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Do Expert Reviews Really Drive Demand? Evidence from a German Car Magazine, July 2014.

150 Bataille, Marc, Steinmetz, Alexander and Thorwarth, Susanne, Screening Instruments for Monitoring Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets – Lessons from Applications in Germany, July 2014.

149 Kholodilin, Konstantin A., Thomas, Tobias and Ulbricht, Dirk, Do Media Data Help to Predict German Industrial Production?, July 2014.

148 Hogrefe, Jan and Wrona, Jens, Trade, Tasks, and Trading: The Effect of Offshoring on Individual Skill Upgrading, June 2014.

147 Gaudin, Germain and White, Alexander, On the Antitrust Economics of the Electronic Books Industry, May 2014.

146 Alipranti, Maria, Milliou, Chrysovalantou and Petrakis, Emmanuel, Price vs. Quantity Competition in a Vertically Related Market, May 2014. Published in: Economics Letters, 124 (1) (2014), pp.122-126.

145 Blanco, Mariana, Engelmann, Dirk, Koch, Alexander K., and Normann, Hans-Theo, Preferences and Beliefs in a Sequential Social Dilemma: A Within-Subjects Analysis, May 2014. Published in: Games and Economic Behavior, 87 (2014), pp.122-135.

144 Jeitschko, Thomas D., Jung, Yeonjei and Kim, Jaesoo, Bundling and Joint Marketing by Rival Firms, May 2014.

143 Benndorf, Volker and Normann, Hans-Theo, The Willingness to Sell Private Data, May 2014.

142 Dauth, Wolfgang and Suedekum, Jens, Globalization and Local Profiles of Economic Growth and Industrial Change, April 2014.

141 Nowak, Verena, Schwarz, Christian and Suedekum, Jens, Asymmetric Spiders: Supplier Heterogeneity and the Organization of Firms, April 2014.

140 Hasnas, Irina, A Note on Consumer Flexibility, Data Quality and Collusion, April 2014.

139 Baye, Irina and Hasnas, Irina, Consumer Flexibility, Data Quality and Location Choice, April 2014.

138 Aghadadashli, Hamid and Wey, Christian, Multi-Union Bargaining: Tariff Plurality and Tariff Competition, April 2014.

Page 32: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

137 Duso, Tomaso, Herr, Annika and Suppliet, Moritz, The Welfare Impact of Parallel Imports: A Structural Approach Applied to the German Market for Oral Anti-diabetics, April 2014. Forthcoming in: Health Economics.

136 Haucap, Justus and Müller, Andrea, Why are Economists so Different? Nature, Nurture and Gender Effects in a Simple Trust Game, March 2014.

135 Normann, Hans-Theo and Rau, Holger A., Simultaneous and Sequential Contributions to Step-Level Public Goods: One vs. Two Provision Levels, March 2014. Forthcoming in: Journal of Conflict Resolution.

134 Bucher, Monika, Hauck, Achim and Neyer, Ulrike, Frictions in the Interbank Market and Uncertain Liquidity Needs: Implications for Monetary Policy Implementation, July 2014 (First Version March 2014).

133 Czarnitzki, Dirk, Hall, Bronwyn, H. and Hottenrott, Hanna, Patents as Quality Signals? The Implications for Financing Constraints on R&D?, February 2014.

132 Dewenter, Ralf and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Media Bias and Advertising: Evidence from a German Car Magazine, February 2014. Forthcoming in: Review of Economics.

131 Baye, Irina and Sapi, Geza, Targeted Pricing, Consumer Myopia and Investment in Customer-Tracking Technology, February 2014.

130 Clemens, Georg and Rau, Holger A., Do Leniency Policies Facilitate Collusion? Experimental Evidence, January 2014.

129 Hottenrott, Hanna and Lawson, Cornelia, Fishing for Complementarities: Competitive Research Funding and Research Productivity, December 2013.

128 Hottenrott, Hanna and Rexhäuser, Sascha, Policy-Induced Environmental Technology and Inventive Efforts: Is There a Crowding Out?, December 2013.

127 Dauth, Wolfgang, Findeisen, Sebastian and Suedekum, Jens, The Rise of the East and the Far East: German Labor Markets and Trade Integration, December 2013. Forthcoming in: Journal of European Economic Association.

126 Wenzel, Tobias, Consumer Myopia, Competition and the Incentives to Unshroud Add-on Information, December 2013. Published in: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 98 (2014), pp. 89-96.

125 Schwarz, Christian and Suedekum, Jens, Global Sourcing of Complex Production Processes, December 2013. Published in: Journal of International Economics, 93 (2014), pp. 123-139.

124 Defever, Fabrice and Suedekum, Jens, Financial Liberalization and the Relationship-Specificity of Exports, December 2013. Published in: Economics Letters, 122 (2014), pp. 375-379.

123 Bauernschuster, Stefan, Falck, Oliver, Heblich, Stephan and Suedekum, Jens, Why Are Educated and Risk-Loving Persons More Mobile Across Regions?, December 2013. Published in: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 98 (2014), pp. 56-69.

122 Hottenrott, Hanna and Lopes-Bento, Cindy, Quantity or Quality? Knowledge Alliances and their Effects on Patenting, December 2013.

Page 33: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

121 Hottenrott, Hanna and Lopes-Bento, Cindy, (International) R&D Collaboration and SMEs: The Effectiveness of Targeted Public R&D Support Schemes, December 2013. Forthcoming in: Research Policy.

120 Giesen, Kristian and Suedekum, Jens, City Age and City Size, November 2013. Forthcoming in: European Economic Review.

119 Trax, Michaela, Brunow, Stephan and Suedekum, Jens, Cultural Diversity and Plant-Level Productivity, November 2013.

118 Manasakis, Constantine and Vlassis, Minas, Downstream Mode of Competition With Upstream Market Power, November 2013. Published in: Research in Economics, 68 (2014), pp. 84-93.

117 Sapi, Geza and Suleymanova, Irina, Consumer Flexibility, Data Quality and Targeted Pricing, November 2013.

116 Hinloopen, Jeroen, Müller, Wieland and Normann, Hans-Theo, Output Commitment Through Product Bundling: Experimental Evidence, November 2013. Published in: European Economic Review 65 (2014), pp. 164-180.

115 Baumann, Florian, Denter, Philipp and Friehe Tim, Hide or Show? Endogenous Observability of Private Precautions Against Crime When Property Value is Private Information, November 2013.

114 Fan, Ying, Kühn, Kai-Uwe and Lafontaine, Francine, Financial Constraints and Moral Hazard: The Case of Franchising, November 2013.

113 Aguzzoni, Luca, Argentesi, Elena, Buccirossi, Paolo, Ciari, Lorenzo, Duso, Tomaso, Tognoni, Massimo and Vitale, Cristiana, They Played the Merger Game: A Retrospective Analysis in the UK Videogames Market, October 2013. Forthcoming in: Journal of Competition and Economics under the title: “A Retrospective Merger Analysis in the UK Videogames Market”.

112 Myrseth, Kristian Ove R., Riener, Gerhard and Wollbrant, Conny, Tangible Temptation in the Social Dilemma: Cash, Cooperation, and Self-Control, October 2013.

111 Hasnas, Irina, Lambertini, Luca and Palestini, Arsen, Open Innovation in a Dynamic Cournot Duopoly, October 2013. Published in: Economic Modelling, 36 (2014), pp. 79-87.

110 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Competitive Pressure and Corporate Crime, September 2013.

109 Böckers, Veit, Haucap, Justus and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Benefits of an Integrated European Electricity Market, September 2013.

108 Normann, Hans-Theo and Tan, Elaine S., Effects of Different Cartel Policies: Evidence from the German Power-Cable Industry, September 2013. Forthcoming in: Industrial and Corporate Change.

107 Haucap, Justus, Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Klein, Gordon J., Rickert, Dennis and Wey, Christian, Bargaining Power in Manufacturer-Retailer Relationships, September 2013.

106 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Design Standards and Technology Adoption: Welfare Effects of Increasing Environmental Fines when the Number of Firms is Endogenous, September 2013.

Page 34: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

105 Jeitschko, Thomas D., NYSE Changing Hands: Antitrust and Attempted Acquisitions of an Erstwhile Monopoly, August 2013. Published in: Journal of Stock and Forex Trading, 2 (2) (2013), pp. 1-6.

104 Böckers, Veit, Giessing, Leonie and Rösch, Jürgen, The Green Game Changer: An Empirical Assessment of the Effects of Wind and Solar Power on the Merit Order, August 2013.

103 Haucap, Justus and Muck, Johannes, What Drives the Relevance and Reputation of Economics Journals? An Update from a Survey among Economists, August 2013.

102 Jovanovic, Dragan and Wey, Christian, Passive Partial Ownership, Sneaky Takeovers, and Merger Control, August 2013. Revised version forthcoming in: Economics Letters.

101 Haucap, Justus, Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Klein, Gordon J., Rickert, Dennis and Wey, Christian, Inter-Format Competition Among Retailers – The Role of Private Label Products in Market Delineation, August 2013.

100 Normann, Hans-Theo, Requate, Till and Waichman, Israel, Do Short-Term Laboratory Experiments Provide Valid Descriptions of Long-Term Economic Interactions? A Study of Cournot Markets, July 2013. Forthcoming in: Experimental Economics.

99 Dertwinkel-Kalt, Markus, Haucap, Justus and Wey, Christian, Input Price Discrimination (Bans), Entry and Welfare, June 2013.

98 Aguzzoni, Luca, Argentesi, Elena, Ciari, Lorenzo, Duso, Tomaso and Tognoni, Massimo, Ex-post Merger Evaluation in the UK Retail Market for Books, June 2013.

97 Caprice, Stéphane and von Schlippenbach, Vanessa, One-Stop Shopping as a Cause of Slotting Fees: A Rent-Shifting Mechanism, May 2012. Published in: Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 22 (2013), pp. 468-487.

96 Wenzel, Tobias, Independent Service Operators in ATM Markets, June 2013. Published in: Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 61 (2014), pp. 26-47.

95 Coublucq, Daniel, Econometric Analysis of Productivity with Measurement Error: Empirical Application to the US Railroad Industry, June 2013.

94 Coublucq, Daniel, Demand Estimation with Selection Bias: A Dynamic Game Approach with an Application to the US Railroad Industry, June 2013.

93 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Status Concerns as a Motive for Crime?, April 2013.

92 Jeitschko, Thomas D. and Zhang, Nanyun, Adverse Effects of Patent Pooling on Product Development and Commercialization, April 2013. Published in: The B. E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 14 (1) (2014), Art. No. 2013-0038.

91 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Private Protection Against Crime when Property Value is Private Information, April 2013. Published in: International Review of Law and Economics, 35 (2013), pp. 73-79.

90 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Cheap Talk About the Detection Probability, April 2013. Published in: International Game Theory Review, 15 (2013), Art. No. 1350003.

89 Pagel, Beatrice and Wey, Christian, How to Counter Union Power? Equilibrium Mergers in International Oligopoly, April 2013.

Page 35: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

88 Jovanovic, Dragan, Mergers, Managerial Incentives, and Efficiencies, April 2014 (First Version April 2013).

87 Heimeshoff, Ulrich and Klein Gordon J., Bargaining Power and Local Heroes, March 2013.

86 Bertschek, Irene, Cerquera, Daniel and Klein, Gordon J., More Bits – More Bucks? Measuring the Impact of Broadband Internet on Firm Performance, February 2013. Published in: Information Economics and Policy, 25 (2013), pp. 190-203.

85 Rasch, Alexander and Wenzel, Tobias, Piracy in a Two-Sided Software Market, February 2013. Published in: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 88 (2013), pp. 78-89.

84 Bataille, Marc and Steinmetz, Alexander, Intermodal Competition on Some Routes in Transportation Networks: The Case of Inter Urban Buses and Railways, January 2013.

83 Haucap, Justus and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Google, Facebook, Amazon, eBay: Is the Internet Driving Competition or Market Monopolization?, January 2013. Published in: International Economics and Economic Policy, 11 (2014), pp. 49-61.

82 Regner, Tobias and Riener, Gerhard, Voluntary Payments, Privacy and Social Pressure on the Internet: A Natural Field Experiment, December 2012.

81 Dertwinkel-Kalt, Markus and Wey, Christian, The Effects of Remedies on Merger Activity in Oligopoly, December 2012.

80 Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, Optimal Damages Multipliers in Oligopolistic Markets, December 2012.

79 Duso, Tomaso, Röller, Lars-Hendrik and Seldeslachts, Jo, Collusion through Joint R&D: An Empirical Assessment, December 2012. Forthcoming in: The Review of Economics and Statistics.

78 Baumann, Florian and Heine, Klaus, Innovation, Tort Law, and Competition, December 2012. Published in: Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 169 (2013), pp. 703-719.

77 Coenen, Michael and Jovanovic, Dragan, Investment Behavior in a Constrained Dictator Game, November 2012.

76 Gu, Yiquan and Wenzel, Tobias, Strategic Obfuscation and Consumer Protection Policy in Financial Markets: Theory and Experimental Evidence, November 2012. Forthcoming in: Journal of Industrial Economics under the title “Strategic Obfuscation and Consumer Protection Policy”.

75 Haucap, Justus, Heimeshoff, Ulrich and Jovanovic, Dragan, Competition in Germany’s Minute Reserve Power Market: An Econometric Analysis, November 2012. Published in: The Energy Journal, 35 (2014), pp. 139-158.

74 Normann, Hans-Theo, Rösch, Jürgen and Schultz, Luis Manuel, Do Buyer Groups Facilitate Collusion?, November 2012.

73 Riener, Gerhard and Wiederhold, Simon, Heterogeneous Treatment Effects in Groups, November 2012. Published in: Economics Letters, 120 (2013), pp 408-412.

Page 36: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

72 Berlemann, Michael and Haucap, Justus, Which Factors Drive the Decision to Boycott and Opt Out of Research Rankings? A Note, November 2012.

71 Muck, Johannes and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, First Mover Advantages in Mobile Telecommunications: Evidence from OECD Countries, October 2012.

70 Karaçuka, Mehmet, Çatik, A. Nazif and Haucap, Justus, Consumer Choice and Local Network Effects in Mobile Telecommunications in Turkey, October 2012. Published in: Telecommunications Policy, 37 (2013), pp. 334-344.

69 Clemens, Georg and Rau, Holger A., Rebels without a Clue? Experimental Evidence on Partial Cartels, April 2013 (First Version October 2012).

68 Regner, Tobias and Riener, Gerhard, Motivational Cherry Picking, September 2012.

67 Fonseca, Miguel A. and Normann, Hans-Theo, Excess Capacity and Pricing in Bertrand-Edgeworth Markets: Experimental Evidence, September 2012. Published in: Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 169 (2013), pp. 199-228.

66 Riener, Gerhard and Wiederhold, Simon, Team Building and Hidden Costs of Control, September 2012.

65 Fonseca, Miguel A. and Normann, Hans-Theo, Explicit vs. Tacit Collusion – The Impact of Communication in Oligopoly Experiments, August 2012. Published in: European Economic Review, 56 (2012), pp. 1759-1772.

64 Jovanovic, Dragan and Wey, Christian, An Equilibrium Analysis of Efficiency Gains from Mergers, July 2012.

63 Dewenter, Ralf, Jaschinski, Thomas and Kuchinke, Björn A., Hospital Market Concentration and Discrimination of Patients, July 2012 . Published in: Schmollers Jahrbuch, 133 (2013), pp. 345-374.

62 Von Schlippenbach, Vanessa and Teichmann, Isabel, The Strategic Use of Private Quality Standards in Food Supply Chains, May 2012. Published in: American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 94 (2012), pp. 1189-1201.

61 Sapi, Geza, Bargaining, Vertical Mergers and Entry, July 2012.

60 Jentzsch, Nicola, Sapi, Geza and Suleymanova, Irina, Targeted Pricing and Customer Data Sharing Among Rivals, July 2012. Published in: International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31 (2013), pp. 131-144.

59 Lambarraa, Fatima and Riener, Gerhard, On the Norms of Charitable Giving in Islam: A Field Experiment, June 2012.

58 Duso, Tomaso, Gugler, Klaus and Szücs, Florian, An Empirical Assessment of the 2004 EU Merger Policy Reform, June 2012. Published in: Economic Journal, 123 (2013), F596-F619.

57 Dewenter, Ralf and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, More Ads, More Revs? Is there a Media Bias in the Likelihood to be Reviewed?, June 2012.

56 Böckers, Veit, Heimeshoff, Ulrich and Müller Andrea, Pull-Forward Effects in the German Car Scrappage Scheme: A Time Series Approach, June 2012.

55 Kellner, Christian and Riener, Gerhard, The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Reward Scheme Choice, June 2012.

Page 37: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

54 De Silva, Dakshina G., Kosmopoulou, Georgia, Pagel, Beatrice and Peeters, Ronald, The Impact of Timing on Bidding Behavior in Procurement Auctions of Contracts with Private Costs, June 2012. Published in: Review of Industrial Organization, 41 (2013), pp.321-343.

53 Benndorf, Volker and Rau, Holger A., Competition in the Workplace: An Experimental Investigation, May 2012.

52 Haucap, Justus and Klein, Gordon J., How Regulation Affects Network and Service Quality in Related Markets, May 2012. Published in: Economics Letters, 117 (2012), pp. 521-524.

51 Dewenter, Ralf and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Less Pain at the Pump? The Effects of Regulatory Interventions in Retail Gasoline Markets, May 2012.

50 Böckers, Veit and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, The Extent of European Power Markets, April 2012.

49 Barth, Anne-Kathrin and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, How Large is the Magnitude of Fixed-Mobile Call Substitution? - Empirical Evidence from 16 European Countries, April 2012. Forthcoming in: Telecommunications Policy.

48 Herr, Annika and Suppliet, Moritz, Pharmaceutical Prices under Regulation: Tiered Co-payments and Reference Pricing in Germany, April 2012.

47 Haucap, Justus and Müller, Hans Christian, The Effects of Gasoline Price Regulations: Experimental Evidence, April 2012.

46 Stühmeier, Torben, Roaming and Investments in the Mobile Internet Market, March 2012. Published in: Telecommunications Policy, 36 (2012), pp. 595-607.

45 Graf, Julia, The Effects of Rebate Contracts on the Health Care System, March 2012, Published in: The European Journal of Health Economics, 15 (2014), pp.477-487.

44 Pagel, Beatrice and Wey, Christian, Unionization Structures in International Oligopoly, February 2012. Published in: Labour: Review of Labour Economics and Industrial Relations, 27 (2013), pp. 1-17.

43 Gu, Yiquan and Wenzel, Tobias, Price-Dependent Demand in Spatial Models, January 2012. Published in: B. E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 12 (2012), Article 6.

42 Barth, Anne-Kathrin and Heimeshoff, Ulrich, Does the Growth of Mobile Markets Cause the Demise of Fixed Networks? – Evidence from the European Union, January 2012. Forthcoming in: Telecommunications Policy.

41 Stühmeier, Torben and Wenzel, Tobias, Regulating Advertising in the Presence of Public Service Broadcasting, January 2012. Published in: Review of Network Economics, 11/2 (2012), Article 1.

Older discussion papers can be found online at: http://ideas.repec.org/s/zbw/dicedp.html

Page 38: Hanna Hottenrott, Cornelia Lawson · Hanna Hottenrotta,b c,dand Cornelia Lawson aDüsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (DICE), University of Düsseldorf, Germany bCentre

ISSN 2190-9938 (online) ISBN 978-3-86304-152-6