Global Macro Commentary March 8 - The H Curve

2
Global Macro Commentary The HCurve Tuesday, March 08, 2016 Guy Haselmann (212) 225-6686 Director, Capital Markets Strategy John Zawada Director, US Rate Sales The HCurve Let’s picture a graph where the x variable is a central bank’s official interest rate and the y variable is the resulting economic benefit. Economic benefits of central bank accommodation are nonlinear. Nonlinear functions have slopes that change. In fact, the ‘economic benefits’ slope will differ at every point along the curve. This is somewhat obvious as a slope measures the rate of change and central bankers admit that their effectiveness weakens over time and with each successive ease. This point is true, yet incomplete. It suggests that marginally declining utility will eventually cause the slope to drop zero; i.e., at some point further accommodation will simply provide no economic benefit. However, the truth is that central bank stimulus is a parabolic function, whereby the slope goes negative at a certain point. The peak point at which the slope begins to change direction is the parabola’s vertex, or the point at which the level of central bank accommodation is optimal. Central banks seem to be operating by a different function. Their rhetoric and ideology suggests belief in a perpetually positively sloped line, whose worst case slope is simply one that is less positive over time. In other words, the second derivative or rate of change in the slope is the only thing that falls; that is, until a zero slope is reached. In truth, too much accommodation can cause longrun damage and risks to financial stability. There are indeed many moving parts that impact and change the vertex level. Different paradigms result in different optimal vertex levels. However, the exercise is still worthwhile. After all, how many times in an economics class does a professor utter the words “all else being equal?” Certainly, a regime with tight regulatory and fiscal policies would move the vertex (the optimal level) to a more accommodative stance (lower official interest rates). The point is to find the true interest rate floor (a level that likely not 0%) A good analogy for the Hcurve might be the Laffer Curve. This curve represents the relationship between rates of taxation and the resulting level of government revenue. The curve shows how taxable income changes in response to changes in the rate of taxation (i.e., income inelasticity). It theorizes that no income would be raised at the extreme rates of 0% and 100%. At the extremes, the yaxis of the Laffer Curve stops at zero (no revenue). However, on the Hcurve, the yaxis outputs can fall well below zero (negative economic benefits) with the wrong amount of central bank stimulus. Moreover, the Hcurve will be more timevarying and act different during policy reversals (exit strategies). I’ve argued for many years that central bank interest rates set below a certain level were counterproductive. Savers, pension funds, and insurance companies are certainly punished. It seems that zero and negative interest rates cause damage to consumer sentiment and elsewhere. (See March 4 th note: “Toppling Scales of Balance”) Interest rates below a certain level hurt lending, because low margins disincentivize lenders who might feel margins do not adequately compensate them for the risks. In a fractional reserve banking system, bank lending is oil for the economic engine. Velocity of money has collapsed for a reason, probably other than regulation. Central bank policy is supposed to work on an 1824 month lag, yet markets have come to expect action at every meeting in which growth and inflationary goals have not been met. Central banks need to change these expectations and stop promising more than they can deliver. After all, the Hcurve suggests a negative impact. Ineffectiveness can damage central bank credibility. Can central banks really achieve their goals of the perfect amount (2%) of ‘goldilocks’ inflation? They can achieve hyperinflation like Zimbabwe or Venezuela, but can they orchestrate the finetuned micromanaged amount of 2%; particularly in a complex globalized world? I am working to develop the Hcurve more thoroughly. I thought the name was catchy and easier to say than the HaselmannCurve. The graph is easy to envision. The actual equation might take some more time to develop. The key to the equation will be to determine the level at which the slope turns negative. The Hcurve numerator formula may have to include a datamining function that searches for use of military, or weapon, references by central bank officials. The tipping point might occur when the use of the following terms reach a certain level: bazooka; fire power; shock and awe; whatever it takes; arsenal, ammunition, war chest, arrows, preemptive strike, and bullets. The Fed is at war against economic and financial market weakness. In the movie “War Games”, the military supercomputer was programed to predict possible outcomes of nuclear war by playing tictactoe against itself. In the end, it learned that not only are there no winners, but “the only winning move is not to play”. Zero and negative rates could be their nuclear war. “Laissez faire et laissez passer, le monde va de lui même” – Jacques Claude Marie Vincent Gournay

description

Global Macro Commentary March 8 - The H Curve

Transcript of Global Macro Commentary March 8 - The H Curve

Page 1: Global Macro Commentary March 8 - The H Curve

Global Macro Commentary The H‐Curve Tuesday, March 08, 2016

Guy Haselmann (212) 225-6686 Director, Capital Markets Strategy John Zawada Director, US Rate Sales

    

The H‐Curve  Let’s picture a graph where the x variable is a central bank’s official interest rate and the y variable is the 

resulting economic benefit.   

Economic benefits of central bank accommodation are non‐linear. Non‐linear functions have slopes that change. In fact, the ‘economic benefits’ slope will differ at every point along the curve. This is somewhat obvious as a slope measures the rate of change and central bankers admit that their effectiveness weakens over time and with each successive ease. 

This point is true, yet incomplete.  It suggests that marginally declining utility will eventually cause the slope to drop zero; i.e., at some point further accommodation will simply provide no economic benefit. However, the truth is that central bank stimulus is a parabolic function, whereby the slope goes negative at a certain point. The peak point at which the slope begins to change direction is the parabola’s vertex, or the point at which the level of central bank accommodation is optimal. 

Central banks seem to be operating by a different function. Their rhetoric and ideology suggests belief in a perpetually positively sloped line, whose worst case slope is simply one that is less positive over time. In other words, the second derivative or rate of change in the slope is the only thing that falls; that is, until a zero slope is reached.  In truth, too much accommodation can cause long‐run damage and risks to financial stability. 

There are indeed many moving parts that impact and change the vertex level.  Different paradigms result in different optimal vertex levels. However, the exercise is still worthwhile.  After all, how many times in an economics class does a professor utter the words “all else being equal?”  Certainly, a regime with tight regulatory and fiscal policies would move the vertex (the optimal level) to a more accommodative stance (lower official interest rates).  The point is to find the true interest rate floor (a level that likely not 0%) 

A good analogy for the H‐curve might be the Laffer Curve.  This curve represents the relationship between rates of taxation and the resulting level of government revenue. The curve shows how taxable income changes in response to changes in the rate of taxation (i.e., income inelasticity). It theorizes that no income would be raised at the extreme rates of 0% and 100%.   

At the extremes, the y‐axis of the Laffer Curve stops at zero (no revenue).  However, on the H‐curve, the y‐axis outputs can fall well below zero (negative economic benefits) with the wrong amount of central bank stimulus.  

Moreover, the H‐curve will be more time‐varying and act different during policy reversals (exit strategies). 

I’ve argued for many years that central bank interest rates set below a certain level were counter‐productive. Savers, pension funds, and insurance companies are certainly punished. It seems that zero and negative interest rates cause damage to consumer sentiment and elsewhere. (See March 4th note: “Toppling Scales of Balance”)  

Interest rates below a certain level hurt lending, because low margins disincentivize lenders who might feel margins do not adequately compensate them for the risks.  In a fractional reserve banking system, bank lending is oil for the economic engine. Velocity of money has collapsed for a reason, probably other than regulation. 

Central bank policy is supposed to work on an 18‐24 month lag, yet markets have come to expect action at every meeting in which growth and inflationary goals have not been met. Central banks need to change these expectations and stop promising more than they can deliver. After all, the H‐curve suggests a negative impact. 

Ineffectiveness can damage central bank credibility. Can central banks really achieve their goals of the perfect amount (2%) of ‘goldilocks’ inflation? They can achieve hyper‐inflation like Zimbabwe or Venezuela, but can they orchestrate the fine‐tuned micro‐managed amount of 2%; particularly in a complex globalized world?  

I am working to develop the H‐curve more thoroughly. I thought the name was catchy and easier to say than the Haselmann‐Curve. The graph is easy to envision. The actual equation might take some more time to develop. 

The key to the equation will be to determine the level at which the slope turns negative. The H‐curve numerator formula may have to include a data‐mining function that searches for use of military, or weapon, references by central bank officials. The tipping point might occur when the use of the following terms reach a certain level: bazooka; fire power; shock and awe; whatever it takes; arsenal, ammunition, war chest, arrows, preemptive strike, and bullets. The Fed is at war against economic and financial market weakness. 

In the movie “War Games”, the military super‐computer was programed to predict possible outcomes of nuclear war by playing tic‐tac‐toe against itself.  In the end, it learned that not only are there no winners, but “the only winning move is not to play”.  Zero and negative rates could be their nuclear war. 

“Laissez faire et laissez passer, le monde va de lui même” – Jacques Claude Marie Vincent Gournay 

Page 2: Global Macro Commentary March 8 - The H Curve

www.gbm.scotiabank.com

TM Trademark of The Bank of Nova Scotia. Used under license, where applicable. Scotiabank, together with "Global Banking and Markets", is a marketing name for the global corporate and investment banking and capital markets businesses of The Bank of Nova Scotia and certain of its affiliates in the countries where they operate, including Scotia Capital Inc. Disclaimer This publication has been prepared for Major U.S. Institutional Investors by Fixed Income Strategists of the Bank of Nova Scotia, New York Agency. (“BNS/NYA”). BNS/NYA Fixed Income Strategists are employees of Scotiabank’s Fixed Income Credit Sales & Trading Desk and support the trading desk through the preparation of market commentary, including specific trading ideas, and other materials, both written and verbal, which may or may not be made publicly available, and which may or may not be made publicly available at the same time it is made available to the Fixed Income Credit Sales & Trading Desk. Fixed Income Strategists are not research analysts, and this report was not reviewed by the Research Departments of Scotiabank. Fixed Income Strategist publications are not research reports and the views expressed by Fixed Income Strategists in this and other reports may differ from the views expressed by other departments, including the Research Department, of Scotiabank. The securities laws and regulations, and the policies of Scotiabank that are applicable to Research Analysts may not be applicable to Fixed Income Strategists.

This publication is provided to you for informational purposes only. Prices shown in this publication are indicative and Scotiabank is not offering to buy or sell, or soliciting offers to buy or sell any financial instrument. Scotiabank may engage in transactions in a manner inconsistent with the views discussed herein. Scotiabank may have positions, or be in the process of acquiring or disposing of positions, referred to in this publication. Other than the disclosures related to Scotiabank, the information contained in this publication has been obtained from sources that Scotiabank knows to be reliable, however we do not represent or warrant that such information is accurate and complete. The views expressed herein are the views of the Fixed Income Strategists of Scotiabank and are subject to change, and Scotiabank has no obligation to update its opinions or information in this publication. Scotiabank and any of its officers, directors and employees, including any persons involved in the preparation or issuance of this document, may from time to time act as managers, co-managers or underwriters of a public offering or act as principals or agents, deal in, own or act as market-makers or advisors, brokers or commercial and/or investment bankers in relation to the securities or related derivatives which are the subject of this publication.

Neither Scotiabank nor any of its officers, directors, partners, or employees accepts any liability for any direct or consequential loss arising from this publication or its contents. The securities discussed in this publication may not be suitable for all investors. Scotiabank recommends that investors independently evaluate each issuer and security discussed in this publication, and consult with any advisors they deem necessary prior to making any investment.