Fundamental Law of Active Management

download Fundamental Law of Active Management

of 43

Transcript of Fundamental Law of Active Management

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    1/43

    PORTFOLIO CONSTRAINTS AND THE

    FUNDAMENTAL LAW OF ACTIVE MANAGEMENT

    November 2001

    Forthcoming in theFinancial Analysts Journal

    Roger Clarke

    Harindra de Silva

    Steven Thorley

    Roger Clarke, Ph.D., is Chairman of Analytic Investors, Hanrindra de Silva, Ph.D., CFA, isPresident of Analytic Investors, and Steven Thorley, Ph.D., CFA, is Associate Professor ofFinance at the Marriott School, Brigham Young University.

    Please send comments and correspondence to Steven Thorley, 666 Tanner Building, BrighamYoung University, Provo, UT, 84602. Email: [email protected] Phone: 801-378-6065

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    2/43

    Portfolio Constraints and the Fundamental Law of Active Management

    Author Digest

    The expected value added in an actively managed portfolio is dependent on both the

    managers forecasting skill and the ability to take appropriate positions in securities that reflect

    those forecasts. The fundamental law of active management articulated by Grinold gives the

    maximum expected value added for an actively managed portfolio based on the forecasting

    ability of the manager and the breadth of application. However, the fundamental law does not

    address the impact of portfolio constraints on potential value added. Constraints like no short

    sales and security concentration limits impede the transfer of information into optimal portfolio

    positions and decrease the expected value added.

    We generalize the fundamental law of active management to include a transfer coefficient

    as well as an information coefficient. The information coefficient measures the strength of the

    return forecasting process, or signal, while the transfer coefficient measures the degree to which

    the signal is transferred into active portfolio weights. The transfer coefficient turns out to be a

    simple scaling factor in the generalized fundamental law, and is an intuitive way to measure the

    extent to which constraints reduce the expected value of the investors forecasting ability. In the

    absence of any constraints, a well-constructed portfolio has a transfer coefficient of one, and the

    original form of the fundamental law applies. However, in practice, managers often work under

    constraints that produce transfer coefficient values that range from 0.3 to 0.8. The transfer

    coefficient suggests why performance in practice is only a fraction (0.3 to 0.8) of what is

    predicted by the original form of the fundamental law.

    Measuring and illustrating the impact of portfolio constraints on active weights taken

    using the transfer coefficient allows an investment manager to assess strategic tradeoffs in

    constructing portfolios. For example, increasing the tracking error in a long-only portfolio

    typically reduces the transfer coefficient because the long-only constraint becomes binding for

    more securities, and thus impedes the transfer of information into desirable portfolio positions.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    3/43

    3

    Another strategic perspective is that the long-only constraint leads to an unintended small-cap

    bias in actively managed portfolios, motivating market-cap neutrality constraints. However, the

    combination of long-only and market-cap neutrality constraints results in active management that

    is concentrated in the large-cap sector. In addition to the long-only constraint case study, we

    employ the generalized fundamental law and transfer coefficient framework to illustrate the

    impact of turnover constraints, and portfolios under multiple constraints.

    In addition to its ex-ante role, the transfer coefficient is also a critical parameter in

    reconciling realized performance with the realized success of return forecasting. We derive a

    decomposition of ex-postactive management performance, based on the transfer coefficient and

    the realized information coefficient. The ex-post performance decomposition indicates that only

    a fraction (the transfer coefficient squared) of the variation in realized performance, or tracking

    error, is attributable to variation in realized information coefficients. For example, if there are no

    portfolio constraints and the transfer coefficient is 1.0, then variation in realized performance is

    wholly attributable to the success of the return-prediction process. However, if the transfer

    coefficient is 0.3, then only 9 percent of performance variation is attributable to the success of

    the signal, with the remaining 91 percent is attributable to constraint induced noise. Managers

    with low transfer coefficients will experience frequent periods when the signal works but

    performance is poor, and periods when performance is good even though the return forecasting

    process fails.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    4/43

    4

    Portfolio Constraints and the Fundamental Law of Active Management

    Mini-abstract: The fundamental law is generalized to include an information transfer coefficient

    that reflects portfolio constraints.

    Abstract

    Active portfolio management is typically conducted within constraints that do not allow

    managers to fully exploit their ability to forecast returns. Constraints on short positions and

    turnover, for example, are fairly common and materially restrictive. Other constraints, such as

    market-cap and value/growth neutrality with respect to the benchmark, or economic sector

    constraints, can further restrict an active portfolios composition. We derive ex-ante and ex-post

    correlation relationships that facilitate constrained portfolio performance analysis. The ex-ante

    relationship is a generalized version of Grinolds (1989) fundamental law of active management,

    and provides an important strategic perspective on the potential for active management to add

    value. The ex-post correlation relationships represent a practical decomposition of performance

    into the success of the return prediction process and the noise associated with portfolio

    constraints. We verify the accuracy of these relationships with a Monte-Carlo simulation and

    illustrate their application with equity portfolio examples based on the S&P 500 benchmark.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    5/43

    Portfolio Constraints and the Fundamental Law of Active Management

    Most portfolio managers appreciate the fact that value-added is ultimately dependent on

    their ability to correctly forecast security returns. Managers work hard to create valuable

    information about future returns, but may not pay as much attention to limitations in the portfolio

    construction process. Constraints such as no short sales, industry limitations, and restrictions on

    investment style and turnover, all limit a managers ability to transfer valuable information into

    portfolio positions. In this paper, we introduce a conceptual framework and diagnostic tools that

    measure the impact of constraints on value-added. The conceptual framework provides an

    important strategic perspective on where and how managers have the potential to add value. The

    diagnostic tools measure the degree to which realized performance is attributable to return

    forecasts versus the noise induced by portfolio constraints.

    Figure 1 characterizes a triangle of relationships between forecasted and realized residual

    security returns, and active security weights. The realized residual return, ri, refers to the portion

    of the total security return that is uncorrelated to the benchmark portfolio return. We focus on

    residual security returns and risks throughout this paper. Forecasted residual security returns, i,

    are the portfolio managers forecast of rifor each of the i= 1 toNsecurities in the portfolio. The

    active weight, wi, is the difference between the weight of security i in the actively managed

    portfolio and its weight in the benchmark portfolio. Thus, a positive active weight indicates that

    the security is over-weighted in the managed portfolio, and a negative active weight indicates

    that it is under-weighted, compared to the benchmark. Active security weights, wi, which sum

    to zero (rather than one) are a compact way to describe a managed portfolios positions

    compared to the benchmark. Note that in addition to activeweights, the word activeis also used

    to convey the difference between the actively managed and benchmark portfolio returns, as

    explained below.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    6/43

    3

    ForecastedResidual Returns

    i

    ActiveWeights

    wi

    RealizedResidual Returns

    ri

    Signal Quality

    (Information Coefficient)

    Portfolio Construction

    (Transfer Coefficient)

    Value Added

    (Performance Coefficient)

    Figure 1: The Correlation Triangle

    The base of the triangle in Figure 1 represents the value added through active

    management. Value added is measured by the difference between the return on the actively

    managed and benchmark portfolios, adjusting for the managed portfolios beta with respect to

    the benchmark, a difference commonly referred to as the active return, RA. As shown in the

    technical appendix, RAis algebraically equivalent to the sum of the products of active weights,

    wi, and residual returns, ri, for the i = 1 toNstocks in the portfolio;

    ==

    N

    i

    iiA rwR1

    . (1)

    Equation 1 indicates that value is added when positive active-weight securities have positive

    residual returns, and negative active-weight securities have negative residual returns. In other

    words, performance in any given period is related to the cross-sectional correlation between the

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    7/43

    4

    active security weights and realized residual returns - the security data in the bottom two corners

    of the correlation triangle.

    While the direct cross-sectional correlation orPerformance Coefficientat the base of the

    triangle reflects value added, a clearer understanding of the sources and limitations of value-

    added can be obtained by examining the cross-sectional correlations on the two legs. First, there

    is little hope of value added if the managers forecasts of returns do not correspond to actual

    realized returns. Signal quality is measured by the relationship between the forecasted residual

    returns or alphas at the top of the triangle, and the realized residual returns at the right corner.

    This cross-sectional correlation is commonly called the Information Coefficient, or IC.

    Managers with higherIC, or ability to forecast returns, will add more value over time, but only to

    the extent that those forecasts are exploited in the construction of the managed portfolio. The

    second correlation, the relationship between the active weights in the left corner, and forecasted

    residual returns at the top of the triangle, measures the degree to which the managers forecasts

    are translated into active weights. We will refer to this cross-sectional correlation as the Transfer

    Coefficient, or TC.1

    The TC, or correlation between active weights and forecasted residual returns, is equal to

    one in the absence of constraints in portfolio construction. However, investment managers rarely

    enjoy the luxury of a completely unconstrained investment portfolio. Portfolio constraints, like

    no short sales and industry or sector concentrations limit the full transfer of information into

    active weights and lead to TC values much lower than one. As a result, performance is a

    function of both signal quality (the right leg of the triangle) and the constraints imposed in the

    portfolio construction process (the left leg of the triangle).

    The Generalized Fundamental Law

    In this section we formalize the conceptual framework in Figure 1 with a generalized

    version of Grinolds (1989) fundamental law of active management. We first review the original

    form of the fundamental law. Then we generalize the law to account for portfolio constraints.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    8/43

    5

    The fundamental law describes an ex-ante relationship between expected performance

    and the assumed information coefficient in the managers forecasting process. Expected

    performance is measured by the ex-ante information ratio,IR, defined as the portfolios expected

    active return (i.e., return in excess of the benchmark) divided by active risk, IR E(RA)/A.

    Active risk, A, is the standard deviation of active portfolio return, RA, and is also referred to as

    the managed portfolios tracking error. Goodwin (1998) includes a good discussion of

    information ratio calculation procedures. The technical appendix at the end of this paper

    contains a proof of the original form of the fundamental law;

    NICIR= . (2)

    whereIC is the information coefficient andNis the breadth, or number of independent bets in

    the actively managed portfolio.

    As discussed in the technical appendix, Equation 2 is based on the operational

    assumptions that the manager uses mean-variance optimization and an alpha forecasting process

    that incorporates individual security risk estimates and an assumed IC. However, there are two

    additional simplifying assumptions made for mathematical tractability. First, we assume a

    diagonal covariance matrix for residual security returns, or that the benchmark portfolio return is

    the only source of covariance between total security returns. Under this market model

    assumption,Nis simply the number of securities in the portfolio. Second, no budget constraint

    is imposed in the optimization problem, an assumption that allows the active weight for each

    security to be perfectly proportional to its risk-adjusted forecasted return. The second

    assumption does not appear to be a serious limitation for portfolios with a large number of

    securities and typical residual risk-return parameters. In the next section, we test the materiality

    of the two simplifying assumptions with data on the S&P 500. Grinold (1989) readily

    acknowledges the approximate nature of the fundamental law, and presents it as a strategic tool.

    Thomas (2000) provides intuitive support for the strategic perspectives that come from the

    fundamental law. The important lesson of the fundamental law is that breadth of application, as

    well as the quality of the signal, dictates the expected value-added from active management.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    9/43

    6

    A weakness of the traditional form of the fundamental law in Equation 2 is the

    assumption that the portfolio manager can take active weights that fully exploit the return

    forecasting process. This assumption is explicit in Grinolds (1989) original derivation, where

    he states that the law gives us only an upper bound on the value we can add because we

    presume that we can pursue our information without any limitations (pp. 33). Goodwin (1998)

    also emphasizes the fact that the original fundamental law provides an upper bound on potential

    information ratios. Unfortunately, portfolio managers sometimes employ the law without

    acknowledging this fact, and then wonder why realized information ratios are only a fraction of

    their predicted value. Indeed, a common rule of thumb is that the theoretical information ratio

    suggested by the fundamental law should be cut in half in practice. While this is sometimes an

    implicit admission that the true signal quality, or IC, is below the assumed value, much of the

    reduction in performance is simply the result of constraints in the portfolio construction process.

    Below we generalize the fundamental law to incorporate a precise measure of how constraints

    impact value added.

    The technical appendix shows that under the two simplifying assumptions previously

    mentioned, unconstrained mean-variance portfolio optimization leads to active weights for each

    security that are proportional to risk-adjusted forecasted residual returns. Specifically, the

    unconstrained optimal active weight on security iis given by

    2

    12

    *

    i

    i

    iw = (3)

    where i2is the securitys residual return variance, and is a risk-aversion parameter. Because

    the risk-aversion parameter is the same for all securities (is not subscripted), a perfect cross-

    sectional correlation exists between the unconstrained optimal active weights, wi*, and risk-

    weighted forecasted residual returns, i/i2. The full information content of the return forecasts

    is transferred into active weights, with no reduction in the potential for value-added.

    In practice, active managers are often subject to constraints that cause them to deviate

    from the unconstrained optimal weights in Equation 3. Searching algorithms are available that

    can determine optimal weights under constraints, although the results do not generally have a

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    10/43

    7

    closed-form solution. Let wibe a set of active weights based on a formal optimizer, or some

    other portfolio construction process, that is subject to one or more constraints. We define the

    transfer coefficient, TC, as the cross-sectional correlation coefficient between risk-adjusted

    active weights and risk-adjusted forecasted residual returns for the i= 1 to N securities in the

    portfolio. As explained in the technical appendix, when securities have different residual risks,

    the TC and other cross-sectional correlation coefficient calculations generally require risk-

    adjustment in order to correctly tie the fundamental law back to the alpha generation process.

    Based on this definition for the transfer coefficient, the technical appendix presents a proof of the

    generalized fundamental law;

    NICTCIR (4)

    or in terms of the expected active return, AA NICTCRE )( . Like the information

    coefficient,IC, the transfer coefficient, TC, acts as a simple scaling factor in the determination of

    value added. Equation 4 is generalized in the sense that the TCin the original version of the law

    in Equation 2 is assumed to be one. In practice, values for TC rarely approach 1.0, and with

    multiple constraints can be as low as 0.3. The use of the approximate equality notation in

    Equation 4 is motivated by an approximation in the proof, as noted in the technical appendix.

    One can think of TCas an additional adjustment to breadth,N, that reflects the reduction

    in independent bets due to constraints. However, the best conceptualization of TCis motivated

    by its mathematical definition; the transfer coefficient measures the degree to which the

    information in individual security return forecasts is transferred into managed portfolio positions.

    The transfer coefficient is not the only way to access the impact of a particular constraint. Given

    a set of forecasted security returns and an optimization routine, together with an estimated

    covariance matrix, a manager can calculate the expected information ratio, with and without a

    given constraint, and compute the difference.2 We will perform this type of calculation later as a

    numerical check of Equation 4. The value of the generalized fundamental law is that it provides

    a strategic framework in which to view the impact of constraints on potential value-added. In

    addition, the TCplays a critical role in the ex-post decomposition of the realized active return

    developed later.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    11/43

    8

    An alternative formulation of the generalized law in Equation 4 that corresponds to the

    correlation triangle in Figure 1 is also helpful. Expected value-added at the base of the triangle is

    reflected in the ex-ante performance coefficient, orPC. We definePCas the expected value of

    the cross-sectional correlation between risk-adjusted active weights and realized residual returns.

    The technical appendix shows that PCis equal to the ex-ante information ratio, IR,divided by

    the square root ofN. By making this substitution in Equation 4, the generalized fundamental law

    can be expressed in correlation form as

    ICTCPC . (5)

    The formulation of the generalized law in Equation 5 is intuitive; the expected correlation of

    active weights to realized returns (PC) is equal to the correlation of active weights to forecasted

    returns (TC) times the expected correlation of forecasted returns to realized returns (IC).

    However, this simple relationship is only valid ex-ante; the transfer coefficient relates expected

    performance (PC) to expected signal quality (IC). Later, we show that realized or ex-post

    performance is described by a more complicated structure.

    Constraint Case Studies

    In this section, we employ the Barra portfolio optimizer and an S&P 500 benchmark to

    create several case studies in the application of the generalized fundamental law. Barra is a

    leading supplier of security covariance matrix estimates as well as optimization software thatstructures portfolio weights.

    3 We generate a set of forecasted returns for the 500 stocks in the

    index by

    iii SIC = (6)

    whereICis an assumed information coefficient, iis the estimated residual return volatility for

    each stock, and the Si are random numbers drawn from a standard normal distribution. The

    forecasted returns in this illustration are random, but their relative magnitudes and cross-

    sectional variation are consistent with actual security volatilities and the assumed quality of the

    signal.4 We use an assumed ICvalue of 0.067, so that the unconstrained ex-ante information

    ratio, according to the fundamental law, has a value of IR = 0.067 * 500 = 1.50. These

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    12/43

    9

    expected returns are fed into the optimizer with the condition that active portfolio risk (i.e.,

    tracking error) be limited to 5.0 percent.

    As a baseline from which to make comparisons, the first optimization is conducted

    without any constraints placed on the portfolio except the standard full-investment budget

    constraint. The active weights output by the optimizer are shown in Figure 2 with the active

    weights sorted from left to right based on each stocks risk-adjusted forecasted residual return.

    The active weights in Figure 2 range from about +2.0 percent on the left for the stocks with the

    highest forecasted risk-adjusted residual returns, to less than 2.0 percent on the right for stocks

    with the lowest forecasted risk-adjusted residual returns.

    Figure 2

    S&P 500: Unconstrained

    Transfer Coefficient= 0.98

    -4%-3%

    -2%-1%0%1%2%3%4%

    High Risk-adjusted Forecasted Return Low

    ActiveWeight

    The ex-ante active risk, or tracking error of the portfolio, can be calculated and works out

    to be exactly 5.0 percent, as specified to the optimizer. The expected active return, calculated by

    ( ) =

    =N

    i

    iiA wRE1

    (7)

    is 7.9 percent. This gives an ex-ante information ratio of 7.9/5.0 = 1.58, slightly higher than the

    1.50 value suggested by the original fundamental law. The discrepancy is due to the simplifying

    assumptions in the derivation of the law that are not met in the actual optimization. The first and

    most material cause of the discrepancy is the assumption of a diagonal covariance matrix for

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    13/43

    10

    residual security returns. Specifically, the proof of the fundamental law assumes that the only

    source of covariance between total security returns is the benchmark portfolio, an assumption

    that is violated by the actual risk estimates in the Barra-supplied covariance matrix. Second, no

    budget constraint in imposed in the derivation of the theoretical results in Equation 3 while the

    optimizer forces the sum of the active weights to be zero.

    The weights from the unconstrained optimization routine provide an important check on

    the real-world accuracy of the generalized, as well as the original fundamental law. In theory,

    the active weights in Figure 2 should monotonically decline from left to right, in perfect

    correspondence with risk-adjusted expected returns. In fact, small deviations in the pattern occur

    because of residual covariances among the securities. The cross-sectional correlation between

    risk-adjusted weights and expected returns, the transfer coefficient (TC), is 0.98 rather than a

    perfect 1.00. Small deviations from a perfect transfer of information occur because the optimizer

    correctly adjusts for the fact that the residual returns of the securities have some correlation.

    However, the deviations in a real-world setting are small, leading to a transfer coefficient that is

    almost perfect.

    In the sections that follow, we discuss several types of common constraints under

    different levels of active portfolio risk. As a summary of the results, Table 1 presents the TCfor

    each case. For example, the unconstrained case just discussed is shown in the first row. This is

    followed by entries for: 1) the long-only constraint, 2) a long-only and market-cap neutral

    constraint, 3) turnover limits, and 4) a multiple-constraint portfolio similar to what might be

    found in practice. Notice that the transfer coefficient declines when either the active risk is

    increased or when additional constraints are added. In either event, the transfer of information

    into active positions is reduced, thus lowering the transfer coefficient and decreasing the

    information ratio. However, if the decline in the transfer coefficient occurs because of a desired

    increase in active risk for a given constraint, the expected active return does not necessarily

    decline. The investor can be rewarded with an increase in expected active return for the

    additional active risk, even though the information ratio declines. However, such is not the case

    if the decline in the transfer coefficient is caused by adding additional constraints while trying to

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    14/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    15/43

    12

    Case study 1: Long-only constraint

    We discuss the long-only constraint as our first practical example of the generalized

    fundamental law for several reasons. First, the long-only constraint is ubiquitous, so common

    that it is often not properly acknowledged as a constraint. Second, the long-only constraint is

    quite material. We find TC to be lowered more by the long-only constraint than by any other

    single restriction, with the possible exception of tight turnover limits. Third, we can compare our

    findings from the generalized fundamental law to estimated declines in IR documented in the

    recent examination of long-short versus long-only portfolios in Grinold and Kahn (2000). The

    relative advantages of long-short portfolios are also examined by Brush (1997) and Jacobs, Levy

    and Starer (1998, 1999).

    When short sales are prohibited, the manager can only reduce the weight of an

    unattractive security to zero. Thus, the absolute value of the negative active weight is limited by

    the securitys weight in the benchmark. This limit may not be binding for securities with large

    benchmark weights, but is quite restrictive for securities that have smaller benchmark weights.

    In the extreme, securities with little or no weight in the benchmark cannot receive any

    measurable negative active weight, no matter how pessimistic the manager is about future

    returns. When short selling is allowed, securities with large negative forecasted residual returns

    can be shorted, and the short-sale proceeds used to fund long positions in the securities expected

    to have the highest positive residual returns. In other words, the active weights in a long/short

    portfolio are primarily determined by the risk-adjusted return forecasts, and therefore conform

    more closely to the theoretical optimal active weights in Equation 3.

    To analyze the impact of the long-only restriction, the unconstrained portfolio shown in

    Figure 2 is re-optimized with the added constraint that the portfolio weight for each security

    cannot be less than zero. The same set of forecasted returns are used and the tracking error target

    is again set to 5.0 percent. The resulting active weights, sorted by risk-adjusted forecasted

    residual returns, are shown in Figure 3. One notable impact of the long-only constraint is the

    large number of small negative active weights. In fact, only 89 of the 500 stocks are held in the

    managed portfolio, with the remaining 411 receiving negative active weights equal in magnitude

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    16/43

    13

    to their benchmark weight. The positive active weights are concentrated on the relatively few

    stocks with the highest forecasted residual returns at the far left of Figure 3. The correspondence

    between forecasted returns and active weights is much weaker given the long-only constraint.

    The transfer coefficient, calculated by the risk-adjusted cross-sectional correlation between

    active weights and forecasted residual returns, is only 0.58. The TCvalue of 58 percent indicates

    that 42 percent of the unconstrained potential value-added is lost in the portfolio construction

    process, due to the long-only constraint.6

    Figure 3

    S&P 500: Long-Only Constraint

    Transfer Coefficient= 0.58

    -4%-3%-2%-1%0%1%2%3%4%

    High Risk-adjusted Forecasted Return Low

    ActiveWeight

    The accuracy of the generalized fundamental law can be assessed by a direct calculation

    of the expected active return using Equation 7; the sum of the products of active weights taken

    and forecasted residual returns. The directly calculated expected active return on the long-only

    portfolio is 4.2 percent, yielding an IR of 4.2/5.0 = 0.84, or 56 percent of total theoretical

    unconstrained IR of 1.50. Thus, the transfer coefficient of 58 percent, together with the

    information coefficient and the number of securities, provides a fairly accurate perspective on the

    potential value added under constraints. The accuracy of the generalized law will vary

    depending on the degree to which off-diagonal elements in the residual return covariance matrix

    are non-zero, but the law appears to be a reasonably accurate description for a large portfolio of

    securities like the S&P 500.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    17/43

    14

    Case study 2: Factor-Neutrality Constraints

    Portfolios are often constrained to have characteristics that are similar to the benchmark

    along one or more dimensions. For example, the managed portfolio may be constrained to have

    the same style (value/growth) tilt as the benchmark. These constraints can be a material

    restriction in the portfolio construction process, depending on the investing style and data used to

    forecast returns. For example, a growth manager may favor stocks with mid-range P/Es, or

    growth at a reasonable price. If the manager is benchmarked against a growth index, and

    constrained to have the same growth exposure as the index, the positions dictated by the mid-

    range P/E-based return forecasts will be restricted. Another common neutrality constraint

    involves the market-capitalization of the securities in the managed portfolio compared to the

    benchmark. Managers, or their clients, might require that the managed portfolio not be any more

    sensitive on average than the benchmark to market-capitalization exposure.

    Figure 4

    S&P 500: Long-Only Constraint

    (Market Capitalization Sorting)

    -4%-3%-2%-1%0%

    1%2%3%4%

    Large Market Capitalization Small

    ActiveWeight

    We use market-cap neutralization as our example of a factor constraint because a small-

    cap bias happens to be a by-product of the long-only constraint previously discussed. To

    illustrate, Figure 4 displays the active weights in the long-only constrained portfolio in Figure 3,but this time sorted from left to right by market capitalization. With this sorting, the nature of

    the long-only constraint is readily apparent. All the large negative active weights are associated

    with the large-cap stocks on the left side of the chart. The magnitude of the negative active

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    18/43

    15

    weights is very small for the small-cap stocks at the right side of the chart. However, positive

    active weights are as common among the small-cap stocks as the large-cap stocks. The result is

    a significant small-cap bias in the managed portfolio. The bias towards small-cap stocks is an

    unintended but natural consequence of the long-only constraint. Biases in other common risk

    factors, such as a value-growth tilt are often a result of data used in the return forecasting

    process, rather than a by-product of portfolio constraints.

    Figure 5

    S&P 500: Long-Only and Market-Cap-Neutral Constraints

    Transfer Coefficient= 0.47

    -4%-3%

    -2%-1%0%1%2%

    3%4%

    High Risk Adjusted Forecasted Return Low

    ActiveWeigh

    t

    To eliminate the small-cap bias, Figure 5 contains a TCdiagram for an optimization with

    long-only andmarket-cap neutrality constraints.7 The correlation between active weights and

    forecasted residual returns is further reduced to TC = 0.47, or 47 percent. In other words, the

    added constraint leads to an even lower correlation between active weights and forecasted

    residual returns than in Figure 3, with a correspondingly lower potential for value-added. Figure

    6 displays the long-only and market-cap-neutral constrained active weights sorted by market

    capitalization. The small-cap bias induced by the long-only constraint has been corrected; the

    positive active weights have been reduced to match the negative active weights on the small-cap

    end of the graph. However, the result is a portfolio that is constrained away from having

    significant active management in anything but the large-cap arena, as indicated by the amount of

    ink on the left end of the TC chart. In fact, about half of the active management of the

    portfolio, as measured by the absolute value of the active weights, is concentrated in the largest

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    19/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    20/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    21/43

    18

    Figure 7 contains a TC diagram for a portfolio that is unconstrained (i.e., long/short),

    except for a turnover limit of 50 percent. The tracking error is set a 5 percent, as in the previous

    examples.

    Figure 7S&P 500: Turnover Constraint

    Transfer Coefficient= 0.73

    -4%-3%

    -2%-1%0%1%2%3%4%

    High Risk-adjusted Forecasted Return Low

    ActiveWeight

    Active weights, or deviations from the benchmark weight, are zero for many of the stocks in the

    middle section of Figure 7, because turnover cannot be wasted on securities with forecasted

    residual returns that are close to zero. The result is a transfer coefficient of 73 percent. Tighter

    turnover limits naturally result in lower transfer coefficients. For example, when turnover is

    limited to 25 percent, the resulting TCis only 49 percent.

    Case Study 4: Multiple Constraints

    The various types of constraints we have examined have the combined effect of

    significantly altering actual active weights taken from the unconstrained optimal weights in

    Equation 3. As a final example of constrained portfolio construction, Figure 8 contains a TC

    chart for a portfolio with multiple constraints, similar to what might be found in practice. The

    constraints in this optimization are long-only, market-cap and dividend-yield neutrality withrespect to the benchmark, and turnover limited to 50 percent from a prior long-only portfolio

    optimized to an unrelated set of forecasted returns. The benchmark is the S&P 500, and active

    portfolio risk is set at 5 percent, as before. Figure 8 shows only a loose correspondence between

    active weights and forecasted residual returns. There are negative active weights in some of the

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    22/43

    19

    highest forecasted-return stocks, and large positive active weights in some of the lowest

    forecasted-return stocks. The transfer coefficient is 31 percent. More than two thirds, or 69

    percent, of the value-added predicted by the information coefficient alone, is lost in the portfolio

    construction process. TCvalues as low as 30 percent may be common among long-only U.S.

    equity managers. The constraint-sets have an unmeasured and perhaps under-appreciated impact

    on performance.10

    Figure 8

    S&P 500: Multiple Constraints

    Transfer Coefficient= 0.31

    -4%-3%-2%-1%0%1%2%

    3%4%

    High Risk-adjusted Forecasted Return Low

    ActiveWeight

    Ex-post Correlation Diagnostics

    The perspectives discussed to this point relate to the potential value-added through

    portfolio management, as measured by the expected information ratio. Actual performance in

    any given period will vary from its expected value in a range determined by the tracking error

    and the ex post quality of information. We now turn our attention to diagnosing actual

    performance, the ex-post analysis of the realized active returns.

    As explained in the introduction, a key determinant of the sign and the magnitude of the

    realized active portfolio return, RA, is the degree to which the manager has positive activeweights on securities that realize positive residual returns, and negative active weights on

    securities that realize negative residual returns. In other words, actual performance is determined

    by the relationship between active weights and realized residual returns, a cross-sectional

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    23/43

    20

    correlation we refer to as the ex-post or realized performance coefficient. We will use

    subscripted rho notation for realized correlations, to distinguish them from expected

    correlations, denoted by capitalized acronyms. Specifically, the realized performance

    coefficient, w,r, is the cross-sectional correlation between risk-adjusted active weights and

    realized residual returns. On the other hand, the notation for the expected performance

    coefficient is PC, which the generalized fundamental law in Equation 5 states is approximately

    TC times the expected information coefficient, IC. In the technical appendix we derive the

    following important decomposition of the realized performance coefficient

    rcrrw TCTC ,2

    ,, 1 + (8)

    where ,ris the realized information coefficient, and c,ris a realized cross-sectional correlation

    coefficient that measures the noise associated with portfolio constraints. Note that there is no

    realized correlation value associated with the transfer coefficient, TC, because TCmeasures the

    relationship between forecasted risk-adjusted residual returns and active weights, both of which

    are established ex-ante. As in the generalized law, we use the approximate equality notation in

    the ex-ante relationship in Equation (8) because of its dependence on a zero-mean

    approximation, as specified in the technical appendix.

    Equation 8 has important implications. In the ideal world of a completely unconstrained

    portfolio construction process, TChas an approximate value of one. When TCis one in Equation

    8, realized performance, w,r, is determined solely by the actual success of the return forecasting

    process, ,r. In other words, if there is a perfect transfer of forecasted residual returns into

    active weights, then the realized performance coefficient is identical to the realized information

    coefficient. However, Equation 8 indicates that for TC values less than one, realized

    performance is only partly a function of the success of the signal. For lower values of TC,

    realized performance is increasingly dependent on a second realized correlation coefficient, c,r,

    the risk-adjusted cross-sectional correlation between a new variable, ci, and realized returns, ri.

    As explained in the technical appendix, cifor each security is the difference between the actual

    active weight taken and the expected constrained active weight, TCwi*.11

    When the risk-

    adjusted cross-sectional correlation between ciand realized returns, c,r, is positive, performance

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    24/43

    21

    is increased because at the margin the optimization has forced higher weights than expected on

    positively-rewarded securities and lower weights than expected on negatively-rewarded

    securities in order to satisfy the portfolio constraints. Of course the constraint noise coefficient,

    c,r, might just as easily turn out to be negative, decreasing realized performance.

    We can be more specific about the sources of variation in constrained portfolio

    performance. Under the maintained simplifying assumption of a diagonal residual return

    covariance matrix, the variance of each of the three realized correlation coefficients in Equation

    8, w,r, ,r, and c,r, is one overN, the number of observations in the cross-sectional correlation

    calculations. In addition, the two right-hand side correlations, ,r and c,r, are independent. As

    a result, the variance of the realized performance coefficient is decomposed into signal and noise

    variances by

    ( ) )(1)()( ,2

    ,

    2

    , rcrrw VarTCVarTCVar + . (9)

    For example, if TC = 0.80, then 64 percent of the variation in expected performance is

    attributable to the success of the signal, while the remaining 36 percent is attributable to the

    noise induced by portfolio constraints. For a low TC value of 0.30, only 9 percent of the

    variation in performance is attributable to the success of the signal, while the remaining 81

    percent is attributable to constraint-related noise. The practical implication is that heavily-

    constrained portfolios will experience frequent periods when the forecasting process works, as

    indicated by a positive realized information coefficient, but performance is poor. Alternatively,

    the realized active portfolio return may be positive, even though the realized information

    coefficient is negative. Without the perspective of Equations 8 and 9, low TCmanagers might

    wonder why realized performance seems unrelated to their ability to forecast returns.

    Implementation of an Ex-post Diagnostic System

    The ex-post relationship in Equation 8 suggests a diagnostic system for analyzing activemanagement performance under constraints. As explained in the technical appendix, the realized

    active return,RA, is related to the realized performance coefficient, w,r, by

    )/(, iiArwA rStdNR . (10)

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    25/43

    22

    We can think of the term A Nas a measure of portfolio aggressiveness. More active risk, A,

    equates to larger absolute active weights, or a more aggressively managed portfolio. The last

    term in Equation (10), Std (ri/i), is the cross-sectional standard deviation of risk-adjusted

    realized residual returns, or return dispersion. Because the security returns are risk adjusted, theexpected value of the return dispersion term is 1.0. Risk-adjusted statistics are technically more

    precise, although the cross-sectional correlations and standard deviations can also be calculated

    without the risk adjustment.12

    Equation 10 can be read, Active return equals realized performance coefficient times

    portfolio aggressiveness times realized return dispersion. The sign of the realized performance

    coefficient determines the sign of the active return. Portfolio aggressiveness and realized return

    dispersion simply act as scaling factors. The realized performance coefficient is further

    decomposed into the realized information coefficient and the constraint-noise coefficient terms

    according to Equation 8. Combining Equations 8 and 10, we have

    )/(1 ,2

    , iiArcrA rStdNTCTCR + . (11)

    which forms a diagnostic system where the realized active return is the product of the

    decomposed realized performance coefficient (in square brackets) times portfolio aggressiveness

    times realized return dispersion. Because of the simplifying assumptions used to derive the

    generalized fundamental law, actual performance, calculated directly by Equation 1, will vary

    slightly from the explained performance in Equation 11.

    We verify the ex-ante and ex-post mathematical relationships derived in this paper, and

    illustrate the implementation of the diagnostic system, with a Monte-Carlo simulation. In the

    simulation, the forecasted residual returns and active weights from the long-only constrained

    optimization shown in Figure 3 are used. The weights under the long-only constraint have a TC

    of 58 percent (0.578 to be more exact). Ten thousand sets of 500 realized residual returns were

    generated using individual security residual-risk estimates from Barra. The realized return sets

    were generated with anICparameter value of 0.067, the same parameter value used to scale the

    forecasted returns.13

    Summary statistics were then compiled for the ten thousand simulated

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    26/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    27/43

    24

    variation in the realized signal, as suggested by Equation 9. This is very close to the predicted

    value given by TCsquared of 0.5782= 33.4 percent.

    The simulation also provides observations that can be used to illustrate how an ex-post

    correlation diagnostic system operates. Table 2 lists parameter values for five of the ten

    thousand simulated annual periods. The first period shown is noteworthy in that the realized

    information coefficient is a healthy 0.075; slightly above the managers average information

    coefficient of 0.067. Given the success of the forecasting process in this period, the manager

    might expect good realized performance, even acknowledging the decline in expected

    performance due to constraints. Taking the expectation of active return in Equation 11,

    conditional on the realized information coefficient, gives

    NTCRE ArrA ,, )|( = . (12)

    The conditional active return based on Equation 12 is shown in Table 2. The conditional

    expected return in the first period is 4.8%, slightly higher than the average value of 4.2% because

    of the slightly higher than average realized information coefficient. However, the actual active

    return in this period is slightly negative at 0.4% because of an unusually large and negative

    constraint noise coefficient of -0.057. The portfolio constraints precluded the investor from

    taking positions in particular securities that were attractive after the fact. On the other hand, the

    realized information coefficient in the third period is negative, at -0.020. Given the negative

    realized information coefficient, the manager might have expected an active return of -1.3%.

    However, despite the poor success of the return forecasting process in this period, the active

    return is a positive 3.2%. In this case the portfolio constraints precluded the investor from taking

    positions in securities that were particularly unattractive after the fact (indicated by a positive

    constraint noise coefficient of 0.052). The loose correspondence between signal success and

    actual performance in this simulation is indicative of the mid-range TC value of 0.578. The

    disparity between the success of the return forecasting process and actual portfolio performance

    can be even greater and more frequent in lower TCportfolios.

    The active return explained by the diagnostic system is highly correlated with the actual

    active return. However, because of the simplifying assumptions that underlie the mathematics

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    28/43

    25

    the diagnostic system is not exact, as shown in the last two columns of Table 2. The active

    return explained by the diagnostic system is close to but is not an exact match for the actual

    performance of the portfolio. While we are encouraged by the simulation results for the S&P

    500, a commonly used domestic equity benchmark, we are unable to state any general bounds on

    the accuracy of the diagnostic system for other benchmarks. The most critical simplifying

    assumption in the mathematical derivation of the generalized law is the assumption of a diagonal

    residual covariance matrix, which seems to be an acceptable approximation.

    There are a number of ex-post performance diagnostic implementation issues that we do

    not address in this paper. These include non-annual performance periods, the impact of

    estimation error in security risk parameters, and procedures for estimating the inaccuracy of the

    diagnostic system due to simplifying assumptions. However, the simulation illustrates the key

    ex-post concept that the realized information coefficient by itself explains only a portion of the

    actual performance when there are material portfolio constraints. Without an ex-post diagnostic

    system that measures constraint-related correlations, managers may be puzzled by actual

    performance that is only loosely related to their ability to predict returns.

    Conclusion

    We have suggested that the fundamental law of active management, an ex-ante

    relationship, can be generalized to include a transfer coefficient, as well as an information

    coefficient. The information coefficient (IC) measures the strength of the return forecasting

    process, or signal. We introduce the transfer coefficient (TC), which measures the degree to

    which the signal is transferred into active weights. The TCturns out to be a simple scaling factor

    in the generalized fundamental law and is a quick way to measure the extent to which constraints

    reduce the expected value of the investors forecasting ability. In the absence of any constraints,

    the transfer coefficient is approximately one, and the original form of the fundamental law is

    accurate. However, in practice, managers often work under constraints that produce TCvalues

    that range from 0.3 to 0.8. The lower transfer coefficient suggests why average performance in

    practice is only a fraction (0.3 to 0.8) of what is predicted by the original form of the

    fundamental law.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    29/43

    26

    We also derived a decomposition of ex-post performance, based on the transfer

    coefficient and the realized information coefficient. The ex-post performance decomposition

    indicates that only a fraction (TCsquared) of the variation in realized performance, or tracking

    error, is attributable to variation in realized IC. If TC= 1.0, then variation in performance is

    wholly attributable to the success of the return-prediction process. However, if TC = 0.3, then

    only 9 percent of performance variation is attributable to the success of the signal, with the

    remaining 91 percent attributable to constraint induced noise. Low TCmanagers will experience

    frequent periods when the signal works but performance is poor, and periods when performance

    is good even though the return forecasting process fails.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    30/43

    Table 2

    Monte-Carlo Simulation and Ex-Post Correlation Diagnostics Exampl

    S&P 500: Long-Only Constraint

    This table lists five observations out of ten thousand in a Monte-Carlo simulation. The simulation is for the l

    an S&P 500 benchmarked portfolio at the A = 5.0% active risk level (Case Study 1). The information corealized returns isIC= 0.067. The transfer coefficient in this simulation is constant at TC= 0.578. The portf

    at NA = 0.05 * 500 = 1.118. The average and standard deviation summary statistics for realized values, sh

    are for all ten thousand simulated periods.

    Period

    Transfer

    Coefficient

    TC

    Realized

    Information

    Coefficient

    ,r

    Portfolio

    Aggres-

    siveness

    NA

    Conditional

    Active

    Return

    (note a)

    Realized

    Constraint

    Coefficient

    c,r

    Explained

    Performance

    Coefficient

    (note b)

    Realized

    Return

    Dispersio

    Std(ri/

    1 0.578 0.075 1.118 4.8% -0.057 -0.003 1.02 0.578 0.136 1.118 8.8% 0.001 0.079 1.0

    3 0.578 -0.020 1.118 -1.3% 0.052 0.031 0.9

    4 0.578 0.046 1.118 3.0% -0.007 0.021 0.9

    5 0.578 0.010 1.118 0.6% 0.011 0.015 1.0

    Average 0.067 -0.002 1.0

    Std. Dev. 0.044 0.045 0.0

    a) The Conditional Active Return is calculated by Equation 12: ( ) NTCRE ArrA ,,| = .

    b) The Explained Performance Coefficient is calculated by Equation 8: rcrrw TCTC ,2

    ,, 1 + .

    c) The Explained Active Return is calculated by Equation 11: /(1 ,2

    , iArcrA rStdNTCTCR +

    d) The Realized Active Return is calculated by Equation 1: =

    =N

    i

    iiA rwR1

    .

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    31/43

    Technical Appendix

    Framework and Notation

    Given a benchmark portfolio, the total excess return (i.e., return in excess of the risk-free

    rate) on any stock i can be decomposed into a systematic portion that is correlated to the

    benchmark excess return, and a residual return that is not, by

    iBi

    total

    i rRr += (A1)

    whereRBis the benchmark excess return, iis the beta of stock iwith respect to the benchmark,

    and riis the security residual return with mean zero and standard deviation i. The benchmark

    portfolio is defined by the weights, wB,i, assigned to each of the N stocks in the investable

    universe. The benchmark excess return is

    =

    =N

    i

    total

    iiBB rwR1

    , . (A2)

    If a given stock iin the investable universe is not in the benchmark portfolio, then wB,i= 0. Like

    the benchmark, the excess return on an actively managed portfolio, RP, is determined by the

    weights, wP,i,on each stock;

    =

    =N

    i

    total

    iiPP rwR1

    , . (A3)

    Define the active return as the managed portfolio excess return minus the benchmark excess

    return, adjusted for the managed portfolios beta with respect to the benchmark; RARP- PRB.

    The managed portfolios beta, P, is simply the weighted average beta of the stocks in the

    managed portfolio; =

    N

    i

    iiPP w1

    , . With some algebra, and the fact that the beta of the

    benchmark must be exactly one, it can be shown that the active return is

    =

    =N

    i

    iiA rwR

    1

    (A4)

    where the active weight for each stock is defined as the difference between the managed

    portfolio weight and benchmark weight; wi= wP,i wB,i.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    32/43

    29

    The formulation for the active return in Equation A4 (Equation 1 in the paper) is the

    focus of our analysis. Note that the active weights in Equation A4 sum to zero as they are

    differences in two sets of weights that each sum to one. Also, note that the stock returns, ri, in

    Equation A4 are residual, not total, excess returns. Residuals are the relevant component of

    security returns when performance is measured against a benchmark on a beta-adjusted basis.

    Throughout this paper, we take the individual security risk-estimates (i and i) as given,

    although they may in fact be estimated with error.

    We assume that portfolio optimization is based on choosing a set of active weights, wi,

    that maximize the mean-variance utility function

    2)( AAREU = (A5)

    where E(RA) is the expected active return, A2 is the active return variance, and is a risk-

    aversion parameter. Given a set of forecasts for the individual residual stock returns, i, the

    expected active return for the portfolio is

    =

    =N

    i

    iiA wRE1

    )( . (A6)

    Under the important simplifying assumption that the residual stock returns are uncorrelated (i.e.,

    the residual covariance matrix is diagonal), the active return variance is

    = 222 iiA w (A7)

    where i2is the residual return variance for stock i. Substituting Equations A6 and A7 into the

    optimization problem in Equation A5 leads to optimal weights given by the formula

    2

    12

    *

    i

    i

    iw = . (A8)

    The simple closed-form solution to optimal weights in Equation A8 is based on two simplifying

    assumptions. First, we assume a diagonal residual return covariance matrix, or that residual

    returns are perfectly uncorrelated with each other.14

    Second, there is no direct budget constraint

    in the formal optimization problem. Active weights sum to zero, but no such condition is

    imposed in the optimization of Equation A5. The second assumption will generally not be a

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    33/43

    30

    problem for portfolios with many securities and typical risk-return parameters. One security can

    be adjusted to absorb the balancing weight without distorting the analysis to any great extent.

    Despite these two simplifying assumptions, the optimization result in Equation A8 will prove

    useful in understanding the impact of constraints.

    An intuitive property of Equation A8 is that the mean-variance optimal active weight for

    each stock is proportional to the stocks forecasted residual return over residual return variance.

    The constant of proportionality, common to all securities, is related to the inverse of the risk-

    aversion factor, . Lower values of lead to more aggressive portfolios, with proportionally

    larger absolute active weights, higher expected active return, and higher active risk. We can

    insert the optimal weights from Equation A8 into the definition of active return variance in

    Equation A7, and solve for . Using this solution for , the optimal active weights in terms of

    active portfolio risk, A, are

    2

    1

    2

    *

    =

    = i

    iN

    i

    A

    i

    i

    iw

    . (A9)

    We make the operational assumption that the security alphas, i, are generated from

    scores, Si, that have cross-sectional zero mean and unit standard deviation. Specifically, alphas

    are the product of IC, residual security volatility, and score, based on Grinolds (1994)

    prescription;

    iii SIC = . (A10)

    We do not subscript IC, making the implicit assumption that the information coefficient is the

    same for all securities.

    The Fundamental Law

    A proof of Grinolds (1989) fundamental law of active management follows directly from

    the optimization and alpha generation mathematics. Given a cross-sectional set of scores, Si,

    constructed to have zero mean and unit standard deviation, Equation A10 dictates that the ratio

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    34/43

    31

    i/ihas a cross-sectional mean of zero and standard deviation ofIC. Based on the zero-mean

    property, the denominator in the last term in Equation A9 is a standard deviation calculation for

    i/i, but without the requisite N divisor. We employ the term zero-mean property to justify

    variance and covariance calculations that are sums of squares and products.15

    Making this

    substitution, and then multiplying each side by i, gives the risk-adjusted optimal weights16

    =

    NICw A

    i

    i

    ii

    *. (A11)

    Since the last term in Equation A11 is constant across stocks, and the ratio i/ihas a zero mean,

    the set of risk-adjusted optimal active weights, wi*i, also has a zero mean, and cross-sectional

    standard deviation

    NNICStdwStd AA

    i

    iii

    =

    = )( * . (A12)

    The zero-mean property of wi*iand i/iallows the expected active return in Equation

    A6 to be recast in a correlation formulation as follows;

    )/,()()(*

    1

    *

    1

    *

    iiii

    N

    i i

    i

    ii

    N

    i

    iiA wCovNwwRE

    =

    ==

    ==

    ICNStdwStdN Awiiiiw ,*

    , ** )/()( == (A13)

    where w*,is the correlation coefficient between risk-adjusted optimal weights and alphas; the

    correlation between wi*i, and i/i. This correlation coefficient is 1.0 because the two

    variables are proportional, as indicated by Equation A11. Substituting a correlation coefficient

    value of w*, = 1.0, and dividing both ends of Equation A13 by active risk, A, gives the

    original form of the fundamental law

    NICIR= (A14)

    whereIRis the information ratio of expected active return to active risk;IRE(RA)/A.

    In practice, active managers are typically subject to constraints that cause them to deviate

    from the unconstrained optimal active weights. Searching algorithms are available that can

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    35/43

    32

    determine optimal active weights given a set of constraints and security return forecasts,

    although the solutions do not generally have a simple closed-form expression. Let wibe a set

    of active weights that are generated by an optimizer where the active risk is defined by Equation

    A7. The covariance and correlation methodology used in Equation A13 for unconstrained

    optimal active weights can be applied to actual active weights taken as follows;

    )/,()()(11

    iiii

    N

    i i

    i

    ii

    N

    i

    iiA wCovNwwRE

    =

    ==

    ==

    2

    2

    )()/()( iiA

    iiii wMeanN

    ICTCNStdwStdTCN

    == . (A15)

    where Mean(wii) is the cross-sectional mean of wii. The complexity of the final result

    arises from the fact that there is nothing to force the zero-mean property on wii, although the

    mean is likely to be small because the active weights alone, wi, have a zero mean. In addition,

    this term is squared in Equation A15. Using zero as an approximation, and dividing by active

    risk, A, as before, we have the generalized fundamental law;

    NICTCIR (A16)

    or in terms of the expected active return AA NICTCRE )( . TC is the transfer

    coefficient, calculated as the cross-sectional correlation coefficient between risk-adjusted

    forecasted residual returns and active weights; i/iand wii. Note that TCcan be calculatedex-ante (i.e., before returns are realized) based on the set of weights from an optimizer. We will

    continue to employ the approximation Mean(wii) = 0 in the ex-post analysis that follows, and

    use the equality notation wherever the approximation Mean(wii) = 0 impacts the results.

    Ex-post Correlation Coefficient Relationships

    The realized active return in any time period is the sum of the product of weights and

    returns, as defined in Equation A4. The realized active return can be decomposed into cross-

    sectional statistics by

    ( ) )/()/,( ,11

    iiArwii

    N

    i

    ii

    i

    i

    ii

    N

    i

    iiA rStdNrwCovNr

    wrwR

    ==

    =

    == (A17)

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    36/43

    33

    The realized correlation coefficient between risk-adjusted weights and returns, w,r, is an

    important summary measurement of performance that will be referred to as the realized

    performance coefficient. The notation for the expected value of the performance coefficient is

    PCE[w,r]. Note that the cross-sectional standard deviation of realized risk-adjusted returns,

    Std(ri/i), has an expected value of one. Taking expectations on both ends of Equation A17, and

    rearranging, indicates that the expected performance coefficient, PC, is simply the expected

    information ratio, E[RA]/A, over the square root of N . With this substitution, the generalized

    fundamental law in Equation A16 has the form

    ICTCPC . (A18)

    Given a set of actual active weights, wi, from an optimizer, and hypothetical optimal

    active weights, w*i, derived analytically from expected returns, we define a new variable, bi

    wi w*i, which can be thought of as the optimal weight not taken on each stock due to

    constraints. Based on this definition, the cross-sectional variance of biiis

    ),(2)()()( **

    iiiiiiiiii wwCovwVarwVarbVar +=

    ( )TCNNNN

    AA

    ww

    AA 222

    22

    ,

    22

    * =+

    . (A19)

    Note that the substitution of the transfer coefficient, TC, for the correlation w*,w in the final

    result is validated by the proportional relationship between risk-adjusted optimal weights and

    alphas in Equation A11.

    By applying the definitional relationship, wiwi*+ bi, the realized active return can be

    decomposed into two correlation structures by

    ( ) ( ) ( ) = ==

    +

    =+=

    N

    i

    N

    i i

    i

    ii

    i

    i

    ii

    N

    i

    iiiiA

    rb

    rwrbrwR

    1 1

    *

    1

    *

    )/(22,, iiArbr

    rStdNTC +

    (A20)

    where the replacement for Std(bii) is given by Equation A19. Note that the correlation between

    wi*iand ri/iis replaced by the realized information coefficient, ,r, based on the proportional

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    37/43

    34

    relationship in Equation A11. Equating the final expressions in Equations A17 and A20, and

    dividing out common terms, yields the correlation relationship

    rbrrw TC ,,, 22 + . (A21)

    Equation A21 indicates that for unconstrained portfolios with a transfer coefficient close to 1.0,

    the realized performance coefficient, w,r, is largely dependent on the realized information

    coefficient, ,r, or success of the return signaling process. However, for lower TC values,

    realized performance is increasingly dependent on the noise associated with constraints, as

    measured by the correlation coefficient b,r. Note that the expected value of the constraint noise

    coefficient, b,r, is not zero.17

    Also, it will be shown that the constraint noise correlation, b,r,

    and realized information coefficient, ,r, in Equation A21 are not independent.

    Ex-post Performance Decomposition

    An alternative ex-post correlation diagnostic equation can be derived that has more

    favorable statistical properties than Equation A21 using a modified definition of optimal weight

    not taken. In place of bi wi - wi*, we define an alternative variable ci wi - TCwi*.

    Recall that TC is equivalent to the correlation between the hypothetical risk-adjusted optimal

    weights and the actual weights from the optimizer. The multiplier TC in front of wi* is a

    shrinkage factor, or can be thought of as the expected value of wi, given the value of wi*.

    Note that TCand consequently the ci termcan be calculated ex-ante (i.e., after the portfolio is

    optimized but before returns are realized.) The cross-sectional variance of cii parallels that in

    Equation A19;

    ),(2)()()( **2 iiiiiiiiii wwCovTCwVarwVarTCcVar +=

    ( )222

    ,

    22

    2 12 * TCNN

    TCNN

    TC AAww

    AA =+

    . (A22)

    where again the substitution of the transfer coefficient, TCfor the correlation w*,win the final

    result is validated by the proportionality between risk-adjusted optimal weights and alphas.

    Using the result in Equation A22, the realized active return can be decomposed into two

    correlation structures that parallel Equation A20;

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    38/43

    35

    ( ) ( ) ( ) = ==

    +

    =+=

    N

    i

    N

    i i

    i

    ii

    i

    i

    ii

    N

    i

    iiiiA

    rc

    rwTCrcrwTCR

    1 1

    *

    1

    *

    ( )[ ] )/(1 ,2, iiArcr rStdNTCTC + (A23)

    Equating the final expressions in Equations A17 and A23, and dividing out common terms,

    yields the correlation relationship;

    rcrrw TCTC ,2

    ,, 1 + . (A24)

    The correlation diagnostic in Equation A24 differs from Equation A21 in structure and in the

    alternative measure of constraint induced noise, c,r. The expected value of the alternative

    constraint noise coefficient, c,r, is zero. This can be verified by taking expectations of both

    sides of Equation A24, and employing the relationship in Equation A18 and the fact that the

    expected value of the realized information coefficient, ,r, is the assumed information

    coefficient parameter,IC.

    The two ex-ante correlation coefficients on the right-hand side of the alternative

    correlation structure in Equation A24 can be shown to be approximately independent, as follows.

    The realized values of cross-sectional correlation coefficients have a standard deviation of

    N/1 around their means, by definition. Thus, the variance analysis of Equation A24 is

    ( )N

    TCTCCorrelN

    TCN

    TCN

    rcr11),(21111 2,,

    22 + . (A25)

    Rearranging Equation A25 indicates that 0),( ,, rcrCorrel . Similar analysis on the

    correlation structure in the bi-based correlation diagnostic in Equation A21 indicates that it is not

    independent since ),( ,, rbrCorrel 2/)1( TC 0.

    The value of the independence property of the ci-based correlation diagnostic in Equation

    A24 is variance decomposition. Because the two right-hand-side realized correlation coefficients

    are approximately independent, we have

    ( ) )(1)()( ,2

    ,

    2

    , rcrrw VarTCVarTCVar + . (A26)

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    39/43

    36

    Thus, TC2percent of the variation of the performance coefficient, w,r, is due to the success of

    the signal as measured by the realized information coefficient, ,r, while the remaining 1-TC2

    percent is attributable to constraint-induced noise.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    40/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    41/43

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    42/43

    39

    10While it may appear that constraints are always undesirable, some constraints guard against

    the effect of estimation error in the forecasting process, which can then be magnified by the

    optimization process. The manager may be willing to tolerate a lower transfer coefficient to

    protect against sizeable underperformance if the forecasting process fails.11

    An alternative and perhaps more intuitive definition of active weight not taken,

    b w wi i

    = * results in a different ex post correlation structure than Equation (8). However, the

    definition we use in Equation (8) of the difference between actual active weight and expected

    constrained active weight c w TC wi i i

    = * has nicer mathematical properties. The technical

    appendix discusses both results.

    12A simple non-risk-weighted system can be implemented with the cross-sectional correlation

    and standard deviation calculations based on wi, i, and ri, instead of the riskadjusted datawi, i/i, and ri/i. While the characterization of the realized information and transfercoefficients are incorrect when the securities have different estimated residual risks, the ex-postsystem will still add up. However, the components will not correspond exactly to theconceptual decomposition suggested by the generalized fundamental law.

    13 While the realized residual returns are generated to have a 0.067 correlation with their

    respective forecasted residual returns, and have magnitudes consistent with their respective

    residual risks, they are cross-sectionally random within in each set (i.e., the returns simulate a

    perfectly diagonal covariance matrix). Thus, while the simulation is real-world in the

    generation of constrained active weights using an actual non-diagonal covariance matrix, thesimulation controls the generation of the realized residual returns to conform to assumed

    statistical parameters.

    14 The correlation of market model residual returns, as defined in Equation A1, cannot be

    exactly zero, even in a theoretical sense. For example, if the benchmark contains only two

    stocks, then the residual return on the first has to be perfectly negatively correlated to theresidual return on the second. For benchmark portfolios with a large number of stocks (e.g., 500)

    the correlation matrix is populated with off-diagonal elements that are generally small but on

    average tend to be slightly negative.

    15 Specifically, if a variableXhas a mean of zero, then the variance of Xis 2

    1

    1)( i

    N

    i

    XN

    XVar =

    = .

    Similarly, if either X or Y has a mean of zero, then the covariance of X and Y is

    ==N

    i

    ii YXNYXCov 1

    1),( . Also note that the statistical definition of the correlation coefficient

    between two variables, X and Y, is based on Cov(X,Y) x,y Std(X) Std(Y). This definitionaldecomposition of covariances into correlations and standard deviations is used repeatedlythroughout the appendix.

  • 8/10/2019 Fundamental Law of Active Management

    43/43

    16

    Kahn (2000) refers to these risk-adjusted weights as optimal risk allocations.

    17 Taking expectations of both sides of Equation (A21), and employing the expectational

    relationship in Equation A18 and E(,r) =IC, gives E(b,r) 2/)1( TCIC .