Financial Accounting Information, Organizational...

39
Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity and Corporate Governance Systems * Robert Bushman ** Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill Qi Chen Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Ellen Engel Abbie Smith Graduate School of Business, The University of Chicago July 2002 Abstract We investigate whether firms exhibit relatively more costly, delegated monitoring when corporate transparency is relatively low. We study how board structure, directors’ equity incentives, ownership concentration and executive compensation vary with two aspects of corporate transparency: firms’ financial accounting systems and organizational complexity. We proxy for accounting‘s governance usefulness with earnings timeliness, the extent to which current earnings incorporate current value-relevant information, and for organization complexity with industry and geographic diversification. We predict that firms substitute costly governance mechanisms to compensate for low earnings timeliness and high levels of organizational complexity. We document evidence generally consistent with these hypotheses. JEL classification: G30, M41, J33 Keywords: Corporate governance, corporate transparency, earnings timeliness, organizational complexity, diversification * Formerly titled “The Sensitivity of Corporate Governance Systems to The Timeliness of Accounting Earnings.” We have benefited from discussions with and comments from Ray Ball, Sudipta Basu, Bill Beaver, Judy Chevalier, Thomas Hemmer, Bob Kaplan, Randy Kroszner, Darius Palia, Canice Prendergast, Cathy Schrand, Ross Watts, Jerry Zimmerman and accounting workshop participants at CUNY-Baruch, UC-Berkeley, University of Chicago, Harvard Business School, University of Illinois-Chicago, London Business School, University of Minnesota, University of Rochester, University of Texas- Austin, the 1999 Big Ten Faculty Consortium, 1999 Stanford Summer Camp, 1999 Burton Summer Workshop at Columbia, 2000 European Finance Association Annual Meetings and the 2000 AAA Annual Meetings. We are grateful to Hewitt Associates for providing ProxyBase data and to the Graduate School of Business at the University of Chicago for financial support. Finally, we appreciate the research assistance of Xia Chen, Kathleen Fitzgerald, Rebecca Glenn and the data assistance of Darin Clay. ** Corresponding author. Campus Box 3490, McColl Building, Chapel Hill, NC 27599-3490, Phone (919)962- 8301, Email address: [email protected] . 1

Transcript of Financial Accounting Information, Organizational...

Page 1: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity and

Corporate Governance Systems*

Robert Bushman** Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill

Qi Chen

Fuqua School of Business, Duke University

Ellen Engel Abbie Smith

Graduate School of Business, The University of Chicago

July 2002

Abstract We investigate whether firms exhibit relatively more costly, delegated monitoring when

corporate transparency is relatively low. We study how board structure, directors’ equity incentives, ownership concentration and executive compensation vary with two aspects of corporate transparency: firms’ financial accounting systems and organizational complexity. We proxy for accounting‘s governance usefulness with earnings timeliness, the extent to which current earnings incorporate current value-relevant information, and for organization complexity with industry and geographic diversification. We predict that firms substitute costly governance mechanisms to compensate for low earnings timeliness and high levels of organizational complexity. We document evidence generally consistent with these hypotheses.

JEL classification: G30, M41, J33 Keywords: Corporate governance, corporate transparency, earnings timeliness, organizational complexity, diversification

* Formerly titled “The Sensitivity of Corporate Governance Systems to The Timeliness of Accounting Earnings.” We have benefited from discussions with and comments from Ray Ball, Sudipta Basu, Bill Beaver, Judy Chevalier, Thomas Hemmer, Bob Kaplan, Randy Kroszner, Darius Palia, Canice Prendergast, Cathy Schrand, Ross Watts, Jerry Zimmerman and accounting workshop participants at CUNY-Baruch, UC-Berkeley, University of Chicago, Harvard Business School, University of Illinois-Chicago, London Business School, University of Minnesota, University of Rochester, University of Texas- Austin, the 1999 Big Ten Faculty Consortium, 1999 Stanford Summer Camp, 1999 Burton Summer Workshop at Columbia, 2000 European Finance Association Annual Meetings and the 2000 AAA Annual Meetings. We are grateful to Hewitt Associates for providing ProxyBase data and to the Graduate School of Business at the University of Chicago for financial support. Finally, we appreciate the research assistance of Xia Chen, Kathleen Fitzgerald, Rebecca Glenn and the data assistance of Darin Clay. ** Corresponding author. Campus Box 3490, McColl Building, Chapel Hill, NC 27599-3490, Phone (919)962-8301, Email address: [email protected].

1

Page 2: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

1. Introduction

Public companies in the US employ intricate corporate governance systems to limit self-

interested managerial behavior at the expense of outside investors. This paper investigates how board

structure, equity incentives of directors, ownership concentration and executive compensation plans vary

with properties of firms’ information systems and with firms’ organizational complexity. The theory

underlying our study is that firms substitute towards relatively higher use of costly, delegated monitoring

mechanisms when corporate transparency is relatively low. While corporate transparency is a broad

concept, we focus our analysis on firms’ primary financial information system, the financial accounting

system, and two fundamental aspects of organizational complexity, industry and geographic

diversification.1

Our focus on relations between an expanded set of governance mechanisms and both

information systems per se and organizational complexity extends existing research on the benefits of

costly monitoring activities. One influential research strand investigates the premise that the scope for

moral hazard derives from characteristics of a firm’s operating environment and investment opportunity

set. The scope for moral hazard presumably increases as firm performance becomes more sensitive to

managerial behavior or when it becomes more difficult to monitor such behavior. In a seminal paper,

Demsetz and Lehn (1985) conjecture that the scope for moral hazard is greater for managers of firms

with volatile operating environments. They document a significant positive cross-sectional relation

between stock return volatility and ownership concentration suggesting that ownership concentration

increases with the benefits of costly shareholder monitoring. Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia (1999)

extend Demsetz and Lehn (1985) to include additional firm attributes such as R&D, advertising, and

intangible asset intensities. In related research, Smith and Watts (1992) document that firms’ investment

1 Bushman et al. (2002) develop a framework for corporate transparency that classifies information systems contributing to corporate transparency into three categories – corporate reporting, private information acquisition, and information dissemination. Bushman and Smith (2001) posit firm complexity as an important element of transparency.

2

Page 3: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

opportunity sets, as measured by market-to-book ratios, are associated with benefits to imposing risk on

managers via bonus plans and stock option grants.

Following this literature, we also take an equilibrium perspective that observed differences in

corporate governance structures across firms represent optimal contracting arrangements endogenously

determined by firms’ contracting environments. Our analysis flows naturally from Himmelberg et al.

(1999) who document that a significant fraction of the cross-sectional variation in managerial equity

ownership is explained by unobserved firm heterogeneity. We posit monitoring technology and

organizational complexity as two important characteristics that can be extracted from their “unobserved”

firm heterogeneity and studied independently, while controlling for governance determinants considered

in previous research.

First, regarding monitoring technology, we explore the possibility that inherent limitations of

information systems in generating information relevant for monitoring managerial behavior directly

influence governance structure formation. That is, the ability of an information system to measure

managerial behavior is an important governance determinant distinct from others, such as the sensitivity

of firm performance to managerial behavior. It is conceivable that, holding constant investment

opportunities, operating strategies and organizational complexity, inherent differences in the usefulness

of a firm’s information system would impact the cost-benefit trade-off underlying the existing

governance mechanism configuration. Financial accounting systems are a logical starting point for

investigating properties of information systems important for addressing moral hazard problems.

Audited financial statements produced under Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP)

produce extensive, credible, low cost information that forms the foundation of the firm-specific

information set available for addressing agency problems. We theorize that benefits from costly,

delegated monitoring activities increase as the ability of a firm’s current accounting numbers under

GAAP to capture current value relevant information declines.

We predict that where the usefulness of financial accounting information is relatively low, firms

will substitute towards relatively more costly governance mechanisms to at least partially compensate for

3

Page 4: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

poor accounting information. This prediction parallels well known results in the capital markets theory

literature demonstrating that traders increase costly, private information gathering and processing

activities as the precision of accounting disclosures shrinks (e.g., Verrecchia, 1982). It is also consistent

with evidence that managerial incentive plans rely relatively more on non-accounting performance

measures where financial accounting information is more limited (Bushman, et al., 1996, Ittner, et al.,

1997 and Hayes and Schaeffer, 2000), and that ownership concentration across countries is inversely

related to the quality of a country’s accounting disclosures (LaPorta, et al., 1998).

We proxy for the intrinsic governance usefulness of accounting information with earnings

timeliness, which, paralleling Ball, Kothari, and Robin (2000) we define as the extent to which current

GAAP earnings incorporate current economic income or value-relevant information. While firms can

internally choose accounting methods that differ from GAAP, our premise is that our earnings timeliness

metric proxies for inherent limitations of accounting measures to capture value relevant information in a

timely fashion. We develop several metrics for earnings timeliness based on traditional and reverse

regressions of stock prices and changes in earnings. We conjecture that when current accounting

numbers fail to capture current value relevant information they are less effective in satisfying

governance demands of directors and shareholders. We take extensive efforts to address alternative

explanations in an effort to drive the earnings timeliness effect away. In the end, we cannot.

We also investigate the relation between organizational complexity and governance structures.

While the construct “organizational complexity” could encompass a wide range of organizational design

features, we operationalize it along two dimensions with measures of diversification using segment

revenue information to compute Hirfindahl-Hirschman indices measuring with-in firm industry and

geographic concentration. Our premise is that organizations structured to compete in multiple industries

and/or multiple geographic regions are relatively less transparent than focused firms, and face a range of

operational and informational complexities that increase the benefits to costly monitoring activities

relative to firms with tighter industry and geographic focus. We predict that as organizational

4

Page 5: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

complexity increases firms will substitute towards relatively more costly governance mechanism

choices.

We explore cross-sectional relations between corporate governance systems and both earnings

timeliness and organizational complexity of 784 firms in the Fortune 1000. Corporate governance

choices considered are: 1) aspects of board structure expected to facilitate costly oversight activities2; 2)

stockholdings of inside and outside directors; 3) ownership concentration of outside investors; and 4) the

proportions of executives’ contingent pay that are long-term and equity-based.

We find that firms with low earnings timeliness have board structures facilitating costly

monitoring, higher ownership concentration and greater proportions of contingent pay that are long-term

and equity-based, while the equity holdings of directors are not associated with earnings timeliness. Our

results also indicate that the benefits to costly monitoring increase with organizational complexity as

captured by either industry or geographic diversification. In particular, greater industry and geographic

diversification are associated with board structures facilitating costly monitoring and higher ownership

concentration. Also, equity incentives of directors are positively associated with industry diversification,

and the proportions of contingent pay that are long-term and equity increase in geographic

diversification and decrease with industry diversification. These results are conditional on a large set of

control variables capturing investment opportunities, operating cycle length, CEO characteristics and

regulatory considerations.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 further discusses the role of

earnings timeliness and organizational complexity in influencing governance mechanism choices.

Section 3 describes our governance variables and develops hypotheses concerning their sensitivity to the

timeliness of accounting numbers and organizational complexity. Section 4 describes control variables,

sample, and data. Section 5 describes our empirical design and results. Sensitivity analyses are

presented in section 6 and section 7 presents a summary and discussion of implications of the paper.

5

Page 6: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

2. Measuring governance value of accounting numbers and organizational complexity

We attempt to directly measure inter-firm differences in both governance value of accounting

numbers and organizational complexity. The joint hypotheses motivating our empirical design are that

1) the demand for costly information collection and processing by shareholders and directors is an

inverse function of the firms monitoring technology and organizational complexity – key elements of

corporate transparency, 2) our measures of earnings timeliness and industry and geographic

concentration capture key elements of the governance usefulness of accounting systems and

organizational complexity and 3) specified governance structures are a response to the strength of the

demand for costly information collection and processing by shareholders and directors. Section 2.1

discusses the timeliness of earnings as a measure of accounting’s governance value and describes its

construction. Section 2.2 further develops our approach to organizational complexity.

2.1 Earnings timeliness as a measure of the governance usefulness of accounting information

In this subsection we first motivate our use of earnings timeliness and provide theoretical

underpinnings, and then discuss details of the timeliness metric itself. We conjecture that the extent to

which current accounting numbers capture the information set underlying current changes in value (i.e.,

earnings timeliness, as defined in our study) is a fundamental determinant of their governance value to

directors and investors. Directors monitor managerial and firm performance, advise and ratify

managerial decisions, and provide managerial incentives, and so demand information to help them

understand both how and why equity values are changing. Outside investors who monitor firm and

managerial performance also demand such information. Stock prices provide information about overall

changes in equity value. Accounting systems, by collecting and summarizing the financial effects of

2 Characteristics of board structure that we consider include the percentage of directors that are insiders, board size, the percentage of outside directors who have had executive experience in the same Fama and French (1997) industry grouping as the sample firm, and the average number of other boards on which outside directors serve.

6

Page 7: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

firms’ investment, operating, and financing activities, convey information about the underlying sources

of changes in equity value.

Earnings timeliness measures the extent to which current earnings capture the information set

underlying contemporaneous changes in stock price. If stock prices efficiently reflect all information

available to market participants, firms with low earnings timeliness by definition have information

reflected in price that is not reflected in current earnings. This raises important questions that go to the

heart of our hypothesis that earnings timeliness is a determinant of governance choices. If information is

impounded in price beyond earnings by informed arbitrage activities, isn’t this information also available

to the board? And if so, why does the board need costly governance mechanisms to substitute for low

earnings timeliness? Why not just use stock price or simply extract the information included in stock

price? We draw on economic theory to address these questions in support of our hypotheses.

Is the detailed information set reflected in stock price freely available to the board and other

outside investors? Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) demonstrate that fully revealing stock prices are

incompatible with costly information collection activities of investors. In an equilibrium where costly

private information collection and processing activities exist, prices cannot be fully revealing. This

implies that boards and others cannot extract the underlying information from price alone.

However, one could argue that even if prices are not invertible back to the market’s underlying

information set, that the board already has direct access to all this information. In this case, the market is

simply expending energy to collect and trade on information that is already known by the board, and so

earnings timeliness would have no impact on governance as it is irrelevant as a measure of the board’s

information set. Is this likely to be true on average? The extent to which stock price impounds important

information beyond what is known inside the firm is an open question. Research documents a

significant relation between changes in stock price and subsequent investment decisions (e.g., Morck. et

al., 1990 and Baker, et al., 2001). One potential explanation for this is that stock price communicates

new information to a firm’s managers that is then incorporated into investment behavior (see Morck, et

al., 1990) for a discussion of competing hypotheses). A number of recent theory papers formally derive

7

Page 8: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

equilibria supporting a strategy directing role of stock price (see Dow and Gorton, 1997, Subramanyan

and Titman, 1999, and Dye and Sridhar, 2001).

Finally, let’s allow that when earnings have low timeliness, stock price is a more important

element of boards’ information sets. Stock price formation is a complex process that has been the

subject of countless research studies and speculations by investment professionals. Interpreting the

meaning behind stock price movements is not a pedestrian skill. The aggregated nature of information

impounded in price potentially limits its governance usefulness (e.g., Paul, 1992). As a result, utilizing

stock price as a substitute information source for poor accounting numbers is likely to involve substantial

error and to require extensive sophistication and knowledge on the part of board members. Thus,

consistent with our hypotheses, costly governance mechanisms supporting greater sophistication in

understanding stock price changes may be demanded when earnings timeliness is low.

Our timeliness metric is an aggregate of three-firm-specific metrics. The first two metrics are

based on firm-specific reverse regressions between annual earnings and contemporaneous stock returns

over a period of at least eight years ending in 1994 as follows:

EARNt= a0 + a1 NEGt + b1 RETt + b2 NEGt * RETt + et (1)

EARNt is “core” earnings of a given firm in year t, defined as earnings before extraordinary items,

discontinued operations, and special items, deflated by the beginning of year market value of equity.3

RET is the 15-month stock return ending 3 months after the end of fiscal year t. NEG is a dummy

variable equal to 1 if RET is negative, and 0 otherwise.4 This specification allows b1 to capture the speed

with which good news reflected in a firm’s stock returns is reflected in earnings, while b1+b2 captures the

speed with which bad news is reflected in earnings.

3 There are likely relatively high levels of managerial discretion in the timing of recognizing special items relative to the discretion in the timing of core earnings. To the extent that managers’ ability and incentives to manipulate bottom line earnings vary with corporate governance structures, the use of core earnings is less likely to lead to a violation of our assumption that the timeliness of earnings is exogenous under GAAP. Section 6 further discusses and empirically examines the potential impact of earnings management activities on our earnings timeliness measures. 4 Allowing the intercept and slope to vary with the sign of stock returns is patterned after Basu (1997) and Ball, Kothari, and Robin (2000). For sample firms that do not have any negative stock returns during the estimation

8

Page 9: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Our first metric is b1, which reflects the relative speed (across the sample) with which firms’

good news is reflected in firms’ earnings.5 We expect firms with severe timing problems that delay the

recognition within earnings of value-enhancing activities and outcomes to be identified by low values of

b1. Our second metric of the timeliness of earnings is the R2 from equation (1) which, as observed by

Ball, Kothari and Robin (2000), is a decreasing function of the lag with which earnings capture the news

reflected in stock returns.

Our third metric is the R2 from equation (2):

RETt= a0 + b1 EARNt + b2 ∆EARNt + et (2)

where RET and EARN are defined as before, and ∆EARNt is the change in core earnings from year t-1 to

year t, deflated by the market value of equity at the beginning of year t. Equation (2) allows stock prices

to vary with both levels and changes in earnings. We expect this measure of the “market share” of all

value relevant information released during the year that is captured by the level and change in annual

earnings to be a decreasing function of the lag with which earnings captures changes in equity value.

We refer to the R2 from equation (1) as REV_R2 and to the R2 from equation (2) as ERC_ R2.

Equation (1) allows the estimation of a slope that is expected to be an increasing function of the

timeliness of earnings. We refer to this slope (i.e., b1 in equation (1)) as REV_SLOPE.6 We develop a

composite index for these three individual metrics (REV_SLOPE, REV_R2, and ERC_R2) as our primary

metric of the timeliness of earnings. We calculate the percentile rank for each firm in the sample for

each of the three metrics. Thus each firm has three percentile values corresponding to its relative value

period for model (1) (i.e. NEG =0 for all observations), we drop NEG and NEG*RET from the specification of equation (1). 5 Although it also might be interesting to consider b2 as a metric, it is not practical to do so because it is not estimatable for a large number of sample firms that have no negative stock returns during the estimation period. 6 In contrast, we do not use the slope from equation (2) because we expect different timing problems to have opposing effects on the slope from equation (2). For example, we expect the “smoothing” of the recognition of holding gains on assets in place over the lives of the assets to increase the slope in model 2 (analogous to positive effects of the persistence in earnings on ERCs documented in the prior literature). In contrast, we expect distortions in earnings resulting from mismatching of revenues and expenses to decrease the slope in equation (2).

9

Page 10: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

of each of the three metrics. The composite timeliness metric for a given firm, EARN_TIMELY, is

computed for a firm as the average of all three percentile rank values. The use of a composite involving

percentile ranks can mitigate potential measurement error in the timeliness metrics (Greene, 2000).7 We

also conduct sensitivity analyses using the first principal component of the three individual timeliness

metrics as an aggregate measure of earnings timeliness.

We use a summary earnings measure to calculate earnings timeliness as our empirical design

makes it practically difficult to utilize a large vector of disaggregated accounting information in our

estimations. However, accounting information provides boards and other market participants with a

range of disaggregated information with which to monitor the performance of managers. Thus, even if

disaggregated accounting information explained 100 percent of the change in equity value, it would not

be superfluous to governance as a single stock price measure is not a sufficient statistic for the detailed

operational information available from disaggregated accounting information.

Finally, our metric for earnings timeliness may also capture information asymmetries between

managers and investors which in turn should influence costly monitoring choices. Frankel and Li (2001)

measure information asymmetry by the ability of insider trading activity to predict future stock returns,

and find that information asymmetry so defined is negatively related to the R2 from a price on earnings

and book value regression, after controlling for analyst following and the extent of voluntary disclosure.

Managers having private information does not imply that boards have it, allowing for the possibility of a

governance response to low earnings timeliness.

2.2 Measures of organizational complexity

To examine links between organizational complexity and firms’ governance choices, we focus

on two aspects of complexity, industry and geographic diversification. Existing research primarily

studies industry and geographic diversification separately, rarely incorporating them together as part of

7 The use of the ranks of the timeliness metrics will mitigate measurement error in the metrics only if the rank is determined by 'timeliness' rather than the measurement error in metrics.

10

Page 11: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

the same research design (exceptions include Bushman et al. (1995), Bodnar et al. (1998) and Duru and

Reeb, 2002). We reason that while industry and geographic diversification differ substantially along

many dimensions, they share the common characteristic that both organizational features impose

significant operational and informational complexity on firms potentially necessitating a governance

response. In this section, we first describe the nature of the complexities imposed by these organizational

designs, and then discuss existing research that bears on the interpretation of our research design.

Multi-industry firms confront the possibilities that internal capital markets are inefficient, that

managers less effectively manage diverse lines of business, and that unrelated segments can have

conflicting operational styles or corporate cultures. Managers of individual business segments are also

shielded from takeover pressure (Cusatis, et al., 1993) and cannot be given powerful equity incentives

(Schipper and Smith, 1983 and 1986). Finally, combining diverse operations creates severe information

aggregation problems which can result in substantial information asymmetries (e.g., Habib, et al., 1997).

While diversified firms in the U.S. must disclose segment data, this information can suffer from

problems associated with segment identification, cost allocations, and transfer pricing schemes (e.g.,

Givoly, et al., 1999). Combining firms together may also induce information asymmetry by suppressing

the activities of information intermediaries (Gilson, et al., 2001).

Multinational firms face a complex managerial decision-making environment which generates a

range of monitoring difficulties. Such firms face cultural and legal diversity across markets and must

develop, coordinate, and maintain organizations that span international boundaries. Information

complexities arise due to geographic dispersion, cultural differences, multiple currencies, higher auditing

costs, differing legal systems, and language differences (Reeb, et al., 1998 and Duru and Reeb, 2002).

Such complexities can arise as firms act to arbitrage institutional restrictions such as tax codes and

financial restrictions (Bodnar, et al., 1998). For example, firms may employ complex transfer pricing

schemes to shift profits to low tax jurisdictions that can complicate efforts by shareholders and board

members to understand a firm’s foreign operations.

11

Page 12: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

While we hypothesize that diversification causes costly governance responses, diversified firms

may suffer from severe agency problems, implying that perhaps weak governance structures cause

diversification (see Denis, et al., 1997 and Anderson, et al., 1998). A recent series of papers document

that firms diversified across industry segments tend to have lower values than portfolios of similar

focused firms (e.g., Berger and Ofek, 1995, Lamont and Polk, 2002, Lang and Stulz, 1994 and Servaes,

1996).8 A related literature documents increases in performance following restructuring events such as

spinoffs and carve-outs (e.g., Schipper and Smith, 1983 and 1986, Comment and Jarrell, 1995, John and

Ofek, 1995, and Daley, et al., 1997).

However, the jury is still out on whether diversification causes value losses. Rose and Shepard

(1997) document that CEOs of diversified firms are paid more than CEOs of focused firms, and that this

wage premium is more consistent with an ability matching story than an entrenchment story.9 Campa

and Kedia (1999) and Graham et al. (2000) argue that the method used to estimate diversification

discounts may produce spurious discounts, and Denis et al (1997) and Anderson et al. (1998) find no

evidence that existing governance structures are correlated with estimated diversification discounts, and

Anderson et al. (1998) find no evidence that failures of internal governance mechanisms are associated

with the decision to diversify. Ultimately, if agency problems as manifested in weak governance

structures cause diversification, it should work against us finding results consistent with our hypothesis

that more extensive costly monitoring is associated with more diversified firms.

We use the Compustat Business Industry Segment File to compute revenue-based Hirfindahl-

Hirschman indices (HHI) measuring within-firm concentration by industry (IND_CONCENTRATION)

and geographic segment (GEOG_CONCENTRATION), computed as the sum of the square of a firms’

8 In contrast, existing evidence shows that geographic diversification is associated with higher values (Errunza and Senbet, 1984). 9 Contrary to CEO entrenchment explanations for industry diversification, Rose and Shepard (1997) find that the compensation premium for diversification is invariant to CEO tenure and that incumbents who diversify their firms earn less than newly hired CEOs at already diversified firms.

12

Page 13: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

sales in a particular segment as a percentage of total firm sales.10 Higher values of

GEOG_CONCENTRATION and IND_CONCENTRATION indicate more geographic and industry

concentration, respectively. These measures decrease (nonlinearly) with the number of segments,

holding constant variance of segment size, and increase with variance of segment size, holding number

of segments constant. Thus a two segment firm with equal segment sales is less concentrated than a two

segment firm with unequal segment sales. These measures have an upper bound of 1 (a single segment)

and a lower bound of .10 (for a ten segment firm with equal revenue in each segment).

While earnings timeliness and industry and geographic concentration are independently

associated with corporate governance systems, these transparency proxies are also significantly

associated with each other with correlations of 0.15 and 0.11 between earnings timeliness and the

industry and geographic concentration measures, respectively. Boards and other market participants

likely use disaggregated accounting information in the governance process, suggesting that our earnings

timeliness measure may better capture timeliness of the broader accounting information set when firm’s

operations are more homogeneous in product line and location. The positive correlations between

timeliness and concentration are consistent with information loss from aggregation, implying that the

concentration measures may also mitigate measurement error in our earnings timeliness metrics.

3. Predictions and description of governance variables

This section develops hypotheses concerning the sensitivity of governance structures to the

timeliness of earnings and organizational complexity, and describes our governance variables. 11

3.1 Board structure

Fama and Jensen (1983) argue that board effectiveness in monitoring managers depends on the

mix of inside and outside directors. They suggest that an optimal board consists of both inside and

outside directors: insiders for in-depth knowledge of firm specific activities and competitive

10 Prior research uses various metrics to capture diversification including number of reported segments (Denis, et al., 1997), dummy variables for multi-segments (Anderson, et al., 1998), factor analysis of multiple measures (Duru and Reeb, 2002), entropy measures (Bushman, et al., 1995) and variations of HHI (Rose and Shepard, 1997).

13

Page 14: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

environment, and outsiders for independence and monitoring skills. They also suggest that effectiveness

is enhanced by outsiders with labor market incentives to develop reputations as experts in decision

control. Beyond these insights, there exists little formal theory concerning determinants of optimal board

composition (see Hermalin and Weisbach (2002) for a recent review of the literature).

We consider four aspects of board structure associated with costly monitoring: 1) The

percentage of directors who are insiders (%INDIR).12 A higher proportion of insiders, while potentially

undermining board independence, bring insiders’ in-depth knowledge of firm-specific issues. 13 Insiders

also facilitate succession planning by allowing outside directors more opportunity to observe top

managers; 2) Board size measured as the total number of directors on the board (#_DIR). Smaller board

size may make it easier to coordinate efforts and reduce free-riding problems; 3) Outside director

industry expertise computed as the percentage of outsiders with executive experience in the same Fama

and French (1997) industry grouping as the sample firm (%_EXPERT). Such directors bring in-depth

knowledge about growth opportunities, production functions, risk factors etc. faced by firms in the

industry; and 4) Quality of outside directors (i.e. reputation) which, following Shivdisani (1993), we

measure with the average number of other boards on which outside directors serve (#OTH_BOARD).14

We predict that firms with low earnings timeliness will have a higher percentage of insiders on

the board, smaller boards, a higher percentage of outside directors with more expertise and higher quality

outside directors. While we generally believe that the same directional predictions are valid for firms

with higher organizational complexity (i.e., low values for IND_CONCENTRATION and

11 Details concerning data sources and computation of all governance variables are provided in the appendix. 12 Inside directors are officers, retired officers, or relatives of officers of the sample firm. Outside directors are directors who are not officers, retired officers, or relatives of officers of the sample firm. Managers can be required to attend board meetings without being members of the board. To the extent that this occurs, it may weaken the hypothesized relation between the percentage of directors who are insiders and both earnings timeliness and organizational complexity. 13In an attempt to isolate the positive role of insiders’ in-depth knowledge of firm specific activities and competitive environment, we control low independence with the number of years the CEO has been on the board and whether the CEO is a founder of the firm. As documented below, both of these variables are positively and significantly related to the percentage of inside directors on the board. 14 A large number of other boards may also indicate that directors are too busy and perhaps of low quality. We rerun all of our analysis eliminating firms where the average number of other boards is greater than 4 and obtain qualitatively similar results.

14

Page 15: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

GEOG_CONCENTRATION), there is more ambiguity. For example, diversified firms may need bigger

boards due to demand for a wider range of industry and international expertise. Also, because our

measure of director expertise is computed as the percentage of outsiders with executive experience in the

same Fama and French (1997) industry grouping (based on primary SIC code), our measure of board

member expertise may be noisy for multi-industry segment firms.

We compute a composite board structure variable for each firm (BOARD_STRUCTURE) as the

average of the within-sample percentiles of each of the four board characteristics. %INDIR, %_EXPERT,

and #OTH_BOARD are sorted in ascending order, while #_DIR is sorted in descending order before

computing percentiles because we expect board monitoring to decrease with #_DIR and to increase with

the other board characteristics. Hence, we interpret high values of BOARD_STRUCTURE as indicative

of board structures that facilitate costly monitoring.

3.2 Equity-based incentives of inside and outside directors

Holdings of stock directly link directors’ financial incentives with those of outside shareholders.

We predict that the stockholdings of inside directors will be relatively large in firms with limited

accounting information and organizational complexity due to greater benefits of providing inside

directors with equity-based incentives to act in the shareholders’ interests. We also predict that the

stockholdings of outside directors will be large to provide the outside directors with powerful financial

incentives to engage in costly policing and advising activities for the benefit of the shareholders.

To capture directors’ equity-based incentives we include the average value and percentage of

outstanding shares of common stock held by individual inside directors (STKVAL_INDIR and

STK%_INDIR) and by individual outside directors (STKVAL_OUTDIR and STK%_OUTDIR). We

compute composite variables to capture the strength of equity-based incentives of inside

(INDIR_INCENTIVES) and outside directors (OUTDIR_INCENTIVES). Each composite variable

represents the average within-sample percentiles of the percentage and value of shares held by the

15

Page 16: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

corresponding group. In all cases, high values of the composite variables represent relatively large

shareholdings.

3.3 Equity-based monitoring incentives of outside shareholders

In the spirit of Demsetz and Lehn (1985), we predict that the lower the timeliness of earnings

and higher organizational complexity, the higher the concentration of stock ownership by outside

shareholders in response to higher benefits of costly monitoring.

Our measures of ownership concentration are: 1) The average value of stock held by individual

outside investors (STKVAL_SHLDR), computed as total market value of outstanding common stock at

the end of fiscal year 1994 minus the value of shares held by officers and directors as a group, divided by

the number of common shareholders; 2) The average percentage of stock held by individual outside

investors (STK%_SHLDR), computed as the reciprocal of the number of common stockholders as of

fiscal year end 1994; 15 3) The percentage of stock held by institutions (%INST); and 3) The percentage

of stock held by blockholders owning 5% or more of the firms’ shares (%BLOCK).

We compute a composite variable (SHLDR_CONC) representing the average within-sample

percentile of STKVAL_SHLDR, STK%_SHLDR, %INST and %BLOCK. Each of the four individual

metrics is sorted in ascending order before computing the percentile values. Hence, high values of

SHLDR_CONC represent relatively large average shareholdings by individual outside shareholders.

3.4 Executive compensation

We predict that as the timeliness of accounting earnings declines and organizational complexity

increases, executive compensation packages will include both a higher proportion of equity-based

incentives and a higher proportion of long-term incentives relative to total incentives to better align

incentives. A similar prediction is made by Duru and Reeb (2002) relative to industry and geographic

diversification.

15 Ideally we would exclude the number of officers and directors from the denominators of STKVAL_SHLDR and STK%_SHLDR. However, the measurement error from not doing so is likely to be small because the number of officers and directors is small relative to the total number of common stockholders.

16

Page 17: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

To capture the structure of incentive packages of the top five officers we include the percentage

of the value of all their incentive plans represented by equity-based plans (EQINC_TOT ) and by long-

term plans (LTINC_TOT ). We compute the value of all incentive plans during a year as the combined

value of options and restricted stock granted that year as well as long-term performance plan payouts and

annual bonus payments during the year. EQINC_TOT is the percentage of total incentives represented by

grants of stock options and restricted stock, and LTINC_TOT is the percent of managers’ total incentive

plans represented by grants of options and restricted stock plus any payouts from long-term performance

plans (excludes annual bonus payments). For each measure we use the average of the ratio of across the

top five officers of a firm in each year 1994-97, and then average over the four years to minimize

distortions associated with non-annual option grant frequencies. We compute a composite variable

(EXEC_INCENTIVES) as the average of the percentiles of EQINC_TOT and LTINC_TOT. Both

EQINC_TOT and LTINC_TOT are sorted in ascending order before computing percentiles so that high

values of EXEC_INCENTIVES represent relatively high importance of long-term and equity-based

incentive plans and relatively low importance of short-term bonus plans.

4. Control variables, sample, and data

4.1 Control variables

We include a number of variables in our cross-sectional regression models in an effort to control

for alternative explanations for variation in governance structures. As discussed in the introduction, it is

possible that firms’ investment opportunity sets or operating cycle lengths actually cause cross-sectional

differences in governance configurations, and that our measure of accounting quality is simply correlated

with unmeasured aspects of these true causal characteristics. We proxy for investment opportunities and

length of operating cycle with the ratio of the market value of equity to the book value of equity (MTB),

sales growth (GROWTH_SALE) and the number of years a firm has been public (FIRM_AGE). In

sensitivity analysis, we also consider the ratios of R&D to sales, advertising to sales and tangible assets

to total assets as additional proxies for the firms’ investment opportunity set.

17

Page 18: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

We include two variables motivated by Demsetz and Lehn (1985) - the standard deviation of

stock returns (STD_RET) and the market value of equity (MV). Demsetz and Lehn (1985) document a

significant relation between these factors and ownership concentration. We expect a positive association

between our governance structure variables and STD_RET consistent with greater volatility increasing

demand for costly monitoring. We include MV to control for the impact of various unspecified

differences relating to size (e.g., information environment, marginal product of manager effort).

Prior research documents that board composition and managerial ownership depend on past

performance (see Hermalin and Weisbach, 2002, Himmelberg, eta l., 1999 and Kole, 1996). We use

prior period return on equity (ROE) to proxy for performance history. Finally, we consider two variables

relating the influence of the CEO – the number of years the CEO has been a director of the firm

(CEO_TENURE) and an indicator variable for whether the CEO is a founder of the firm (see Finkelstein

and Hambrick, 1989). With the exception of STD_RET, FIRM_AGE and FOUNDER, all of the control

variables are measured as the average over the period of 1989 to 1993. FIRM_AGE is measured by the

number of years a firm has been on CRSP as of year-end 1994 and STD_RET is estimated over the same

period used to estimate models (1) and (2) in section 2.2. FOUNDER is a dummy variable that takes a

value of one if the CEO or Chairman of the Board in place during 1994 is also a founder of the firm and

zero otherwise. Finally, we follow the related governance literature (e.g., Demsetz and Lehn, 1985,

Denis, et al., 1997, Anderson, et al., 1998) and include dummy variable controls for utilities and banks to

consider the role of regulation in the formation of governance systems. Regulation may impact the

governance structure of a firm due to additional third-party monitoring like regulatory bank audits which

may systematically influence optimal governance structures for these firms.

It is possible that a low relative earnings timeliness value could simply capture situations where

alternative sources of public information vary across firms. As a sensitivity check, we thus consider two

variables to capture alternative sources of public information: #ANALF, the number of analyst long-term

earnings growth rate forecasts for the firm from the Zacks database, and #MGTF, the number of

management forecasts for the firm from the First Call database.

18

Page 19: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

4.2 Sample and data

Our sample is selected from the Fortune 1000 firms included on ProxyBase, a database

maintained by Hewitt Associates of compensation and board of directors’ information from annual proxy

statements of firms. We obtain data for fiscal year 1994 from ProxyBase on the number of directors, the

number of inside and outside directors, and directors' stock ownership. We also obtain from ProxyBase

data for 1994 through 1997 on the structure of the compensation packages of the top five officers. We

obtain the percentage of stock held by officers and directors as a group (as reported in proxy statements

for fiscal year 1994) from Compact Disclosure. We collect data from proxy statements for fiscal 1994

concerning the backgrounds of outside directors, including the number of other boards on which they

currently serve, and current and prior employers. We get data from Compustat on 4-digit SIC codes of

sample firms and current / prior employers of outside directors to assess whether outside directors have

industry-specific expertise from serving as an executive of another firm in a given sample firm's

industry. For this analysis, we assign firms to industries on the basis of the classification scheme

reported in Fama and French (1997).16 We require sample firms to have data on annual earnings and the

market value of equity on Compustat and monthly stock return data on the CRSP database for at least

eight years during the period 1985 through 1994 to allow computation of the firm-specific timeliness

variables. All other financial data are from Compustat.

Table 1 describes the industry membership of the 784 sample firms with complete data assigned

on the basis of 4-digit SIC codes and the Fama and French (1997) industry classification scheme. 45

industries are represented by sample firms, with 26 industries represented by at least ten firms. Utilities

(97 firms), banks (81 firms), insurance (45 firms), retail (42 firms), chemicals (33 firms), wholesale (33

firms), computers (31 firms), machinery (30 firms), petroleum and natural gas (29 firms), business

supplies (28 firms), and business services (25 firms) are each represented by at least 25 firms.

16We make one change to the Fama and French (1997) industry classification scheme; we classify SIC code 7372 (Prepackaged Software) as Computers rather than Business Services.

19

Page 20: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 2 includes a summary of the sample distribution of our metrics for the timeliness of

earnings and organizational complexity. The mean and median levels of the ERC_R2 are 0.37 and 0.35,

respectively, while the mean and median levels of REV_R2 are 0.33 and 0.29, respectively.

REV_SLOPE, the slope on positive returns in equation (2), has mean (median) value of 0.04 (0.03).

Mean values of IND_CONCENTRATION and GEOG_CONCENTRATION, are 0.81 and 0.65,

respectively, suggesting greater geographic concentration than industry concentration. Table 2 also

summarizes the sample distribution of other firm characteristics considered in our governance

estimations, including the market value of equity (MV), the standard deviation of 15-month stock returns

(STD_RET), firm age (FIRM_AGE), the market-to-book ratio (MTB), sales growth (GROWTH_SALE),

return on equity of prior years (ROE), CEO tenure and CEO founder information (FOUNDER). Finally,

Table 2 summarizes the sample distribution of all our governance variables. Table 2 reveals that all

model variables display a fair amount of variation across sample firms.

5. Empirical design and results

This section describes the design of our empirical tests and the results. We first examine

correlations between our composite metric of earnings timeliness with its underlying variables to

validate that the composite is capturing the data of interest. We then present our empirical model of the

relation between governance variables and the metrics for the timeliness of earnings and organizational

complexity.

5.1 Correlations of individual and composite timeliness variables

We first examine Pearson and Spearman rank correlations between pairs of individual earnings

timeliness metrics, and between individual metrics and the composite timeliness metric

(EARN_TIMELY) constructed from the sample percentiles of the individual metrics. Correlations

between all three individual timeliness metrics (not tabulated) are positive and highly significant. The

Spearman correlation between the ERC_R2 and REV_R2 is the highest of the three at 0.41, and the

20

Page 21: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

correlation between REV_R2 and REV_SLOPE is the lowest of the three at 0.27.17 The composite metric,

EARN_TIMELY, is highly positively correlated with each of the three individual metrics ranging from

0.72 with REV_SLOPE to 0.80 with ERC_R2. Pearson correlations are generally similar to the Spearman

correlations in both magnitude and significance. Taken together, these correlations suggest that our

individual metrics for the timeliness of the information in the accounting system are linked. Further, the

significant correlations between the composite and individual metrics suggest that our use of sample

percentiles of individual metrics to compute the composite metric appears to be capturing the essence of

the individual metrics.

5.2 Primary model and regression results

We estimate the following cross-sectional regression model:

DEP_VAR =α + β1EARN_TIMELY +β2GEOG_CONCENTRATION+β3IND_CONCENTRATION + δ1 MV + δ2STD_RET + δ3FIRM_AGE +δ4 MTB + δ5GROWTH_SALE + δ6ROE + δ7CEO_TENURE +δ8FOUNDER +δ9UTILITY +δ10FINANCIAL + ε.

(3)

DEP_VAR represents a composite variable for the board structure, equity-based incentives of inside or

outside directors, equity-based incentives of outside shareholders, or the composition of executive

compensation plans. For each DEP_VAR variable whose value is bounded between zero and one, we

apply a logistic transformation before estimating the model.18 The appendix includes detailed

descriptions of all variables.

Our main interest is in the coefficients on the earnings timeliness and organizational complexity

metrics. The composite governance variables are constructed so that high values represent governance

systems that facilitate costly monitoring activities by directors and investors, and that rely more heavily

17 We expect the measures, ERC_R2 and REV_R2, to be correlated since the regressions they relate to involve similar variables. The R2 values are not identical however, since an additional independent variable is include in each equation (i.e., the change in earnings is included in the ERC_R2 model and a dummy variable to distinguish negative returns is included in the REV_R2 model). 18 Specifically, we use the formula

− )_1(

_logVARDEP

VARDEP to transform each composite metric. The transformation is

designed to convert the bounded distribution into an unbounded one. The transformation is similar to that conducted by Demsetz and Lehn (1985) and Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia (1999) in a similar setting. The reported results for the transformed variables are similar to results using the variables before conducting the transformation.

21

Page 22: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

on equity incentives and executive incentive plans other than annual bonus plans. We predict βi<0 (for

i=1 through 3) to reflect the hypothesized negative relation between the composite governance variables

and metrics for the timeliness of earnings and geographic and industry concentration (i.e., the inverse of

organizational complexity).

The results of the estimation of equation 3 are reported in Table 3. We find as predicted, that the

coefficient on EARN_TIMELY is negative and significant for the governance composite metrics for board

structure (BOARD_STRUCTURE), outside shareholder concentration (SHLDR_CONC) and executive

incentive structure (EXEC_INCENTIVES). 19 We find that the coefficient on EARN_TIMELY is not

significantly different from zero for the composites capturing inside and outside director incentives

(INDIR_INCENTIVES and OUTDIR_INCENTIVES). That is, earnings timeliness appears to be unrelated

to the equity incentives of directors, while board structure, ownership concentration and the composition of

executives’ contingent pay are all systematically correlated with earnings timeliness in the predicted

direction.20 In untabulated estimations of equation (3) that exclude the regulated industry controls, we find

that EARN_TIMELY is negative and significant for each of the five composite governance metrics. The

idea is that utilities and banks have high timeliness and low use of alternative costly monitoring

mechanisms. Is the low use of costly monitoring in these businesses because of high timeliness or because

of regulatory monitoring? Our design cannot distinguish these alternative explanations.

Table 3 reports the predicted negative associations the organization complexity and the corporate

governance systems we examine - either or both of the coefficients on IND_CONCENTRATION and

GEOG_CONCENTRATION are negative and significant in the estimations of each composite governance

variable. In particular, the coefficients on both GEOG_CONCENTRATION and IND_CONCENTRATION

19 The estimations are reported after removing significant outliers determined by values of Cook’s distance greater than one and studentized residuals greater than three. The removal of outliers does not impact the significance of the coefficients on EARN_TIMELY and the concentration variables in any of the Table 3 estimations. Further, White’s t-statistics are qualitatively similar to those reported in Table 3. 20 We also estimated equation (3) substituting 1) each of the three individual metrics of earnings timeliness discussed in section 2.1 and 2) the first principal component of the three individual timeliness metrics for EARN_TIMELY. The results (not tabulated) produce qualitatively similar results for the individual timeliness metrics and the principal component of the individual metrics as those in Table 3 with the exception of an insignificant coefficient on REV_SLOPE in the board structure regression.

22

Page 23: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

are significant and negative in the BOARD_STRUCTURE estimation at the 1% and 5% significance levels

(one-sided tests), respectively and in the SHLDR_CONC estimation at the 1% and 5.5% significance

levels, respectively (one-sided tests). IND_CONCENTRATION is similarly significant in the estimations

involving equity incentives of inside and outside directors, but GEOG_CONCENTRATION is not

significant in these models.21 Finally, in the EXEC_INCENTIVES model we find a significant negative

coefficient on GEOG_CONCENTRATION and in contrast to expectation, a significant positive coefficient

on IND_CONCENTRATION.22 While we have no specific hypotheses about the association between the

individual concentration metrics and the various governance composites, the fact that both diversification

measures are not significant in all models is not surprising – the concentration measures are highly

positively correlated (ρ=0.27, p-value = 0.0001).

We also observe from Table 3 that a number of the control variables are significantly associated

with the composite governance structure variables. Interestingly, BOARD_STRUCTURE and

INDIR_INCENTIVES both increase in FOUNDER and CEO_TENURE. In untabulated results we find that

the BOARD_STRUCTURE result is driven primarily by the fact that percentage of inside directors

(%INDIR) is significantly higher when the CEO is a founder (coefficient = .166 and t = 5.6) and the CEO

tenure on the board is longer ((coefficient = .01 and t = 7.2). It is intuitive that INDIR_INCENTIVES

would be higher for a firm founder and a long tenure CEO, as the CEO is likely to have accumulated more

stock holdings in these cases. Other influential control variables are size (MV), return volatility

(STD_RET), FIRM_AGE, and GROWTH_SALE.

We re-estimated equation (3) after including additional control variables capturing other aspects of

the firms’ information environment: the number of analyst long-term earnings growth forecasts for the

21 Denis et al. (1997) find a negative relation between the fractional ownership of officers and directors as a group and an alternative measure of diversification, the number of industry segments. While our multivariate analyses document a negative relation between IND_CONCENTRATION and fractional ownership of officers and directors as a group, we observe a positive, but insignificant univariate correlation (untabulated) between these two measures. 22 In a related study, Duru and Reeb (2002) find that both industry and geographic diversification are correlated with the higher equity incentives for executives. We get similar results before controlling for banks and utilities, but after adding these controls we find that more geographic diversification leads to higher equity incentives while more industry diversification leads to lower equity incentives.

23

Page 24: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

firm, #ANALF, and the number of management forecasts, #MGTF. Univariate correlations (not tabulated)

show that the number of analyst and management forecasts is significantly negatively correlated with

EARN_TIMELY. The results of the estimations with the additional controls (not tabulated) reveal that the

coefficients on EARN_TIMELY, GEOG_CONCENTRATION and IND_CONCENTRATION are similar in

sign and significance in each governance structure regression to those reported in Table 3 except that the

unexpected positive coefficient on IND_CONCENTRATION in the EXEC_INCENTIVES model is no

longer significant.

Taken together, these results provide support for our hypotheses that low earnings timeliness and

high organizational complexity (i.e., low industry and geographic concentration) increase the benefits of

costly monitoring, conditional on the inclusion of several control variables for investment opportunities,

length of operating cycle, stock return volatility, prior performance and CEO characteristics and other

aspects of the firms’ information environment.

Table 4 reports the results of estimating equation (3) for the individual governance variables

underlying the composite governance measures as DEP_VAR. These analyses allow us to determine

which individual governance variables contribute to the significant results using the governance

composites in Table 3. Following our predictions on the composite measures, we expect that all of the

individual governance variables will be negatively related to EARN_TIMELY, IND_CONCENTRATION

and GEOG_CONCENTRATION except for the number of directors (#_DIR) for which we predict a

positive relation with the earnings timeliness and organizational complexity metrics. Although the full set

of control variables is included in the estimation, Table 4 reports only the coefficients on the earnings

timeliness and organization complexity variables for ease of presentation and includes the results with the

composite governance metrics as well to facilitate comparison with the individual governance metrics.

In the board structure category, coefficients on EARN_TIMELY, IND_CONCENTRATION, and

GEOG_CONCENTRATION are negative and significant for two of the four individual metrics for board

structure, #OTH_BOARD and %EXPERT. EARN_TIMELY and IND_CONCENTRATION are negative

and significant in the #OTH_BOARD model. The variable, #OTH_BOARD, captures the reputation of

24

Page 25: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

outside board members with higher values of #OTH_BOARD reflecting a great number of high quality

outside directors. These results suggest that director reputation or quality is the key element in the relation

between BOARD_STRUCTURE and both EARN_TIMELY and IND_CONCENTRATION. The coefficient

on GEOG_CONCENTRATION is significantly negative in the %EXPERT model suggesting that

geographically diversified companies choose outside board members with a high level of expertise in the

firm's main industry. None of our three experimental variables are significant in the regression models for

the percentage of inside directors (%INDIR) or board size (#_DIR).

In the governance categories involving outside shareholder concentration and executive incentives,

we find that the coefficients on EARN_TIMELY and GEOG_CONCENTRATION are negative and

significant in each individual governance metric estimation except for EARN_TIMELY in the model

capturing the average percentage share of the firm held by individual outsiders (STK%_SHLDR). Not

surprisingly, the coefficients on EARN_TIMELY and GEOG_CONCENTRATION in the estimations for

individual governance metrics underlying the equity incentives of inside and outside director composites

are generally not significant, consistent with the insignificant result on the composite measures in these

categories. Consistent with the negative and significant coefficients on IND_CONCENTRATION in the

estimations of INDIR_INCENTIVES and OUTDIR_INCENTIVES, the coefficient on

IND_CONCENTRATION in each estimation involving individual governance metrics in these categories is

significantly negative. Likewise, the coefficients on IND_CONCENTRATION in the models with

individual outside shareholder concentration and executive incentive metrics parallel those of the

composite metrics with an insignificant IND_CONCENTRATION coefficient for the individual outside

shareholder concentration metrics and a positive and significant coefficient on the EQINC_TOT metric.

6. Earnings management and measures of earnings timeliness

While accounting information systems per se may directly influence governance choices, it is

plausible that governance structures also influence the properties of accounting numbers through

earnings management activities. For example, Dechow, Sloan, and Sweeney (1996) document that firms

25

Page 26: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

with alleged GAAP violations are more likely to have boards dominated by insiders.23 One could argue,

however, that even if executives were significantly manipulating earnings, it is not clear how this would

impact timeliness measures estimated using earnings and stock returns. If marginal sophisticated

investors see through earnings management, then earnings management may not impact timeliness. If

they are being fooled, then earnings management could increase earnings timeliness as investors are

fooled into thinking that current earnings are more informative than they really are, or earnings

management could be informative and increase timeliness. In the end, it is not clear how earnings

management impacts earnings/returns relations estimated over long time periods. Regardless, in this

section we address the potential impact of earnings management activities on the properties of

accounting numbers with respect to governance structures.

First, we emphasize that our timeliness metrics are based on “core” earnings, defined as earnings

before special items, extraordinary items and discontinued operations. The focus on core earnings

excludes discretionary accruals within special items, extraordinary items and discontinued operations,

which are likely target areas for earnings management activity. Second, in untabulated results we find

that a key measure associated with voluntary release of information by firms, management forecast

activity (#MGTF), is negatively correlated with earnings timeliness and positively correlated with our

governance structure metrics. This at least raises the question of why firms would choose to make

accounting reports less informative while simultaneously disclosing more voluntarily.

Finally, we conduct a two-stage estimation procedure estimating a system of 5 equations:

T

imeliness model:

EARN_TIMELY = λ + γ1BOARD_STRUCTURE + γ2ALLDIR_INCENTIVES + γ3SHLDR_CONC + γ4EXEC_INCENTIVES + θ1 MV + θ2STD_RET +θ3MTB + θ4GROWTH_SALE + θ5RD_SALE + θ6AD_SALE + θ6PPE_TA + η (4)

G

overnance structure models (4 equations):

DEP_VAR =α + β1EARN_TIMELY +β2GEOG_CONCENTRATION+β3IND_CONCENTRATION 23 Studies addressing governance and earnings management include Healy (1985), Gaver and Gaver (1995) and Holthausen, Larcker and Sloan (1995) which address the impact of executive bonus plan structures on earnings manipulation, and Warfield, Wild and Wild (1995) which examines the impact of ownership structures on discretionary accrual levels and the 'in formativeness' of accounting earnings.

26

Page 27: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

+ δ1 MV + δ2STD_RET + δ3FIRM_AGE +δ4 MTB + δ5GROWTH_SALE + δ6ROE + δ7CEO_TENURE +δ8FOUNDER +δ9UTILITY +δ10FINANCIAL + ε . (5) where DEP_VAR represents one of the four composite governance metrics we examine (i.e.,

BOARD_STRUCTURE, ALLDIR_INCENTIVES (combination of INDIR_INCENTIVES and

OUTDIR_INCENTIVES), SHLDR_CONC and EXEC_INCENTIVES), RD_SALE is the ratio of research

and development expenses to sales, AD_SALE is the ratio of advertising expenses to sales, PPE_TA is the

ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. All other variables are as previously defined.

Table 5 documents that EARN_TIMELY is significant and negative for BOARD_STRUCTURE

(p-value=0.052) and SHLDR_CONC (p-value = 0.026), but is no longer significant for

EXEC_INCENTIVES. As in Table 3, EARN_TIMELY is not significant in the model capturing equity

incentives of directors. Thus, under our two-stage least squares specification the coefficient on

EARN_TIMELY remains significantly associated with two of the three composite corporate governance

structure metrics that displayed significant association in our primary results. We acknowledge that

inferences from our two-stage estimation results are dependent on the success with which we found

appropriate instruments for the analysis. While this section presents arguments mitigating the potential

impact of earnings management on our earnings timeliness metrics and an alternative specification with

results generally supportive of our primary analyses, we cannot definitively eliminate the possibility of

earnings management activity impacting our metrics through the structure of governance systems.

7. Summary and implications

We investigate whether firms exhibit relatively more costly, delegated monitoring when

corporate transparency is relatively low. We study how board structure, directors’ equity incentives,

ownership concentration and executive compensation vary with two aspects of corporate transparency:

firms’ financial accounting systems and organizational complexity. We proxy for accounting‘s

governance usefulness with earnings timeliness, the extent to which current earnings incorporate current

value-relevant information, and for organization complexity with industry and geographic

diversification. We predict that firms substitute costly governance mechanisms to compensate for low

27

Page 28: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

earnings timeliness and high levels of organizational complexity. We document evidence generally

consistent with these hypotheses. Our focus on relations between an expanded set of governance

mechanisms and both financial information systems and organizational complexity extends existing

research on the benefits of costly monitoring activities.

Although our results are consistent with the predicted effects of earnings timeliness and

organizational complexity on governance systems, we acknowledge that caution should be exercised in

inferring causality. While we take extensive efforts to address alternative explanations, it is possible that

our timeliness and complexity metrics are picking up the effects of omitted correlated variables or that

the direction of causality should be reversed.

This paper also extends the capital market and stewardship literatures in accounting. Most

existing research into the stewardship relevance and research into the value relevance of accounting have

proceeded independently. We explore whether the relative importance of accounting numbers in equity

valuation appears to “matter” in the determination of corporate governance systems of large public

companies in the U. S. Although causal inferences are problematic, associations between measures of

the usefulness of accounting numbers in valuation and governance structures are a necessary (although

not sufficient) condition for concluding that governance structures are influenced by the limitations of

accounting numbers for valuation purposes.

Finally, our evidence supports the notion that the firm-specific timeliness metrics capture

meaningful differences across large public U.S. companies in the information properties of accounting

numbers. This provides a basis for using such firm-specific metrics to investigate other economic

consequences of the information properties of accounting, such as voluntary disclosures, corporate

signaling, analyst activity, corporate investment decisions, financing choices, and the cost of debt and

equity capital.

28

Page 29: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Appendix: Model Variable Measurement

Dependent variables: (All the dependent variables are calculated at their 1994 values except for

LTINC_TOT and EQINC_TOT which are averaged over 1994-97). Board Structure: %INDIR: (number of inside directors) / #_DIR; #_DIR: total number of directors; %_EXPERT: (number of expert outside directors)/(number of outside directors), where a director is

coded as expert if he has had experience as an executive in the same industry); #OTH_BOARD: (total number of other boards outside directors serve on) / (number of outside

directors); BOARD_STRUCTURE: average of percentile ranks of #_DIR (descending), %INDIR (ascending), %_EXPERT

(ascending) and #OTH_BOARD (ascending); Board and Officer Incentives: STKVAL_INDIR : (average number of common shares owned by each inside director) * (stock price at

1994 fiscal year end); STK%_INDIR: (average number of shares owned by each inside director) / (total number of common

shares outstanding at 1994 fiscal year end); INDIR_INCENTIVES: average of percentile ranks of STKVAL_INDIR (ascending) and STK%_INDIR

(ascending); STKVAL_OUTDIR: (average number of common shares owned by each outside director) * (stock price at

1994 fiscal year end); STK%_OUTDIR: (average number of shares owned by each outside director) / (total number of

common shares outstanding at 1994 fiscal year end); OUTDIR_INCENTIVES: average of percentile ranks of STKVAL_OUTDIR and STK%_OUTDIR (ascending);

ALLDIR_INCENTIVES: average of percentile ranks of STKVAL_INDIR, STKVAL_OUTDIR, STK%_INDIR and STK%_OUTDIR (ascending);

Outside Shareholder Concentration: STKVAL_SHLDR: (market value of common stock - value of stock held by officers and directors) /

(number of common shareholders at 1994 fiscal year end). STK%_SHLDR: 1/(number of common shareholders at 1994 fiscal year end); %INSTN: (number of shares held by institutions)/(total number of common shares outstanding at

1994 fiscal year end); %BLOCK percentage of the firms’ shares held by over 5% blockholder;

SHLDR_CONC: average of percentile ranks of STKVAL_SHLDR, STK%_SHLDR, %INSTN, and %BLOCK (ascending);

Executive Incentives: LTINC_TOT: (value of grants of long-term incentives) / (value of grants of long-term incentives

plus annual bonuses); EQINC_TOT: (value of grants of equity-based incentives)/(value of grants of long-term incentives

plus annual bonuses); EXEC_INCENTIVES: average of percentile ranks of LTINC_TOT (ascending) and EQINC_TOT;

(ascending);

NOTE: Rank values of governance metrics are used in the estimations involving individual governance measures (table 4) for comparability with governance composite measures.

29

Page 30: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Appendix: Model Variable Measurement (continued): Measures of earnings timeliness: ERC_R2: R2 of the firm-specific regression of 15-month (ending three months after fiscal year end) stock

return on the level of and change in annual core earnings, both deflated by market value of equity at the beginning of the period. Each regression starts from 1985 and has at least 8 years of observations. Fisher transformation of the R2 is used in the regression estimations. The percentile ranking, Rank_ERC_R2, (ascending) of the Fisher transformed ERC_R2 is included in EARN_TIMELY (composite);

REV_R2: R2 of the firm-specific regression of annual earnings deflated by price at the beginning of the period on 1) 15-month (ending three months after fiscal year end) stock return and 2) an interactive variable of the 15-month stock return times a dummy variable = 1 if the 15-month stock return is negative. Each regression starts from 1985 and has at least 8 years of observations. Fisher transformation of the R2 is used in the regression estimations. The percentile ranking, Rank_REV_R2, (ascending) of the Fisher transformed REV_R2 is included in EARN_TIMELY (composite);

REV_SLOPE: The estimated coefficient on the 15-month positive stock return from the model described in REV_R2 above. The percentile ranking, Rank_REV_SLOPE, (ascending) is included in EARN_TIMELY (composite);

EARN_TIMELY : average of Rank_ERC_R2, Rank_REV_R2 and Rank_REV_SLOPE; Measures of organizational complexity: GEOG_ CONCENTRATION: the sum of the squares of (firm sales in each geographic segment/ total firm sales).

Segment data obtained from Compustat Business Industry Segment file. IND_ CONCENTRATION: the sum of the square of (firm sales in each industry segment/total firm sales). Segment

data obtained from Compustat Business Industry Segment file). Note: All of the following variables are the average values of the variable over 1989 to 1993. Other Firm Characteristics (Table 3) MV: market value of equity (stock price #199* number of common shares outstanding #25); STD_RET: standard deviation of the dependent variable in the ERC regression; FIRM_AGE: number of years a firm has been included in the CRSP database as of the end of 1994; MTB: ratio of market value of equity to book value of common equity; GROWTH_SALE: growth rate of net sales computed as (change in net sales)/(prior year net sales); ROE: net income before extraordinary items (#18) / total shareholders' equity (#216) CEO_TENURE: number of years the CEO has been a director of the firm; FOUNDER: dummy variable equal to 1 if CEO or Chairman of the Board is a founder of the firm; zero

otherwise; UTILITY: Dummy variable = 1 if the firm is a utility firm as defined in Table 1; zero otherwise; FINANCIAL: Dummy variable = 1 if the firm is in the banking business as defined in Table 1; zero otherwise; Characteristics of firm information environment (sensitivity analyses) #ANALF: the number of analyst long-term earnings growth rate forecasts for the firm from the Zacks

database; #MGTF: sum of the number of management forecasts of accounting numbers made by the firm over the

period 1994 through 1996 from the First Call database. Additional instruments for earnings timeliness in simultaneous equations analyses (Table 5) RD_SALE: research and development expenses (#46) / net sales (#12); AD_SALE: advertising expenses (#45) / net sales (#12); PPE_TA: plant, property and equipment (#8) / total asset (#6);

30

Page 31: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 1 Industry Membership of Sample Firms 1

INDUSTRY No. Firms INDUSTRY No. Firms Agriculture 1 Measuring and Control

Equipment 10

Aircraft 5 Medical Equipment 16 Alcoholic Beverages 3 Nonmetallic Mining 4 Apparel 8 Personal Services 1 Automobiles and Trucks 20 Petroleum and Natural Gas 29 Banking 81 Pharmaceutical Products 14 Business Services 25 Precious Metals 2 Business Supplies 28 Printing and Publishing 14 Candy and Soda 3 Recreational Products 6 Chemicals 33 Restaurants, Hotel, Motel 9 Computers 31 Retail 42 Construction Material 19 Rubber and Plastic Products 5 Construction 13 Shipbuilding, Railroad

Equipment 6

Consumer Goods 22 Shipping Containers 4 Defense 2 Steel Works, etc. 14 Electrical Equipment 11 Telecommunications 16 Electronic Equipment 22 Textiles 10 Entertainment 2 Tobacco Products 2 Fabricated Products 1 Trading 5 Food Products 17 Transportation 21 Healthcare 2 Utilities 97 Insurance 45 Wholesale 33 Machinery 30 Total 784

1 Industries are defined on the basis of 4-digit SIC codes using the industry groupings identified in Fama and French (1997). The only departure from the Fama and French industry groupings is our classification of SIC code 7372 as Computers rather than Business Services.

31

Page 32: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 2 Sample Distribution of Model Variables1

VARIABLE NOBS MEAN STD. DEV Q1 MEDIAN Q3 Earnings timeliness metrics: EARN_TIMELY 784 0.50 0.22 0.33 0.50 0.67

ERC_R2 784 0.37 0.23 0.17 0.35 0.55 REV_R2 745 0.33 0.21 0.16 0.29 0.47 REV_SLOPE 745 0.04 0.15 -0.01 0.03 0.09

Organizational complexity: GEOG_CONCENTRATION 784 0.81 0.27 0.61 1.00 1.00

IND_CONCENTRATION 784 0.65 0.28 0.40 0.63 0.99

Other firm characteristics: MV ($ millions) 784 3347.85 7048.44 480.38 1083.08 2978.03 STD_RET 784 0.41 0.24 0.25 0.35 0.47 FIRM_AGE 783 30.07 17.98 22.00 24.00 39.00 MTB 784 2.53 5.69 2.62 1.76 1.37 GROWTH_SALE 784 0.09 0.13 0.03 0.06 0.12 ROE 784 0.10 1.18 0.07 0.11 0.15 CEO_TENURE 778 12.14 9.20 5.0 10.0 17.0 FOUNDER 784 0.14 0.35 0 0 0Information environment variables: #ANALF 784 13.87 8.72 18.80 12.20 7.00

#MGTF 784 0.84 1.48 0 0 1.00

Governance Structure Metrics: Board Structure

%INDIR 784 0.22 0.12 0.13 0.20 0.28 #_DIR 784 11.22 3.30 9.00 11.00 13.00 %_EXPERT 756 0.08 0.14 0.00 0.00 0.13 #OTH_BOARD 757 2.08 1.16 1.17 2.00 2.83

Board Stock-based Incentives STKVAL_INDIR (in $ millions) 780 37.90 235.17 3.04 9.06 21.91 STK%_INDIR 780 0.02 0.04 0.00 0.01 0.02

STKVAL_OUTDIR (in $ millions) 783 10.85 80.09 0.18 0.72 3.36 STK%_OUTDIR 783 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00

Outside Shareholder Incentives STKVAL_SHLDR (in $thousands) 776 268.11 445.35 62.80 151.31 308.34 STK%_SHLDR 753 0.19 0.22 0.03 0.10 0.26 %INSTN 782 0.53 0.20 0.38 0.56 0.68 %BLOCK 782 0.22 0.22 0.06 0.16 0.32

Executives Stock-Based Incentives LTINC_TOT 779 0.57 0.22 0.43 0.60 0.72 EQINC_TOT 779 0.49 0.24 0.32 0.51 0.67

1 For variable definitions, please refer to Appendix.

32

Page 33: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 3 Summary statistics from regressions of composite governance variables

on earnings timeliness, organizational complexity measures and various control variables

DEP_VAR = α + β1EARN_TIMELY +β2GEOG_CONCENTRATION+β3IND_CONCENTRATION+ δ1 MV

+ δ2STD_RET + δ3FIRM_AGE +δ4 MTB + δ5GROWTH_SALE + δ6ROE + δ7CEO_TENURE

+δ8FOUNDER +δ9UTILITY +δ10FINANCIAL + ε . (3)

BOARD_ STRUCTURE

INDIR_ INCENTIVES

OUTDIR_ INCENTIVES

SHLDR_ CONC

EXEC_ INCENTIVES

EARN_TIMELY -0.15 (-1.79)*

-0.18 (-0.92)

-0.10 (-0.46)

-0.44 (-3.77)**

-0.56 (-2.37)**

GEOG_ CONCENTRATION

-0.18 (-2.45)**

0.09 (0.53)

0.20 (1.01)

-0.45 (-4.44)**

-0.42 (-2.00)*

IND_ CONCENTRATION

-0.12 (-1.68)*

-0.52 (-3.16)**

-0.39 (-2.05)*

-0.16 (-1.60)

0.37 (1.84)*

MV -0.03 (-2.21)*

0.01 (0.26)

-0.15 (-3.82)**

-0.12 (-5.82)**

0.23 (5.65)**

STD_RET 0.32 (3.88)**

0.60 (3.13)**

-0.29 (-1.29)

0.15 (1.32)

0.72 (3.07)**

FIRM_AGE -0.00 (-0.81)

-0.01 (-3.36)**

-0.02 (-4.49)**

-0.01 (-3.68)**

-0.00 (-0.39)

MTB 0.02 (1.63)

0.01 (0.74)

0.03 (1.24)

0.01 (0.98)

0.00 (0.13)

GROWTH_SALE -0.09 (-0.54)

0.51 (1.44)

1.55 (3.67)**

0.88 (4.05)**

0.35 (0.79)

ROE -0.01 (-0.04)

-0.02 (-0.55)

0.30 (0.75)

0.01 (0.35)

-0.19 (-1.00)

CEO_TENURE 0.01 (2.32)*

0.04 (9.26)**

-0.00 (-0.61)

0.00 (0.28)

-0.02 (-2.70)**

FOUNDER 0.18 (3.18)**

0.58 (4.53)**

0.30 (2.00)*

-0.06 (-0.81)

-0.16 (-1.01)

UTILITY -0.13 (-2.01)*

-1.72 (-11.88)**

-1.19 (-6.97)**

-1.16 (-13.27)**

-1.03 (-5.71)**

FINANCIAL -0.37 (-6.64)**

0.19 (1.50)

0.43 (2.88)**

-0.03 (-0.42)

-0.16 (-1.02)

Adjusted R2 0.19 0.44 0.22 0.41 0.15 No. of obs. 773 771 771 773 765

1Summary statistics include coefficient estimates with t-statistics in parenthesis. DEP_VAR = variables reflecting composite corporate governance used as dependent variables in the above regression analyses. See

Appendix for descriptions and measurement information for specific DEP_VAR composites and all other model variables. ** (*) significant at the 1% (5%) level - one-tailed test for EARN_TIMELY, GEOG_CONCENTRATION and

IND_CONCENTRATION, two-tailed test for remaining variables.

33

Page 34: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 4

Summary statistics from regressions of individual and composite governance variables on earnings timeliness, organizational complexity measures and various control variables 1

DEP_VAR = α + β1EARN_TIMELY +β2GEOG_CONCENTRATION+β3IND_CONCENTRATION+ δ1 MV

+ δ2STD_RET + δ3FIRM_AGE +δ4 MTB + δ5GROWTH_SALE + δ6ROE + δ7CEO_TENURE

+δ8FOUNDER +δ9UTILITY +δ10FINANCIAL + ε . (3)

DEP_VAR Pred. Sign

EARN_ TIMELY

GEOG_ CONCENTRATION

IND_ CONCENTRATION

AdjustedR2

Board Structure BOARD_STRUCTURE (-) -0.15 (-1.79)* -0.18 (-2.45)** -0.12 (-1.68)* 0.19

%INDIR (-) -0.03 (-0.70) -0.05 (-1.19) -0.05 (-1.32) 0.18 #_DIR (+) -0.02 (-0.44) -0.05 (-1.32) 0.02 (0.55) 0.32 %_EXPERT (-) 0.00 (0.05) -0.05 (-2.95)** 0.03 (1.55) 0.13 #OTH_BOARD (-) -0.08 (-1.99)* -0.03 (-0.68) -0.10 (-2.83)** 0.29

Board and Officer Incentives INDIR_ INCENTIVES (-) -0.18 (-0.92) 0.09 (0.53) -0.52 (-3.16)** 0.44

STKVAL_INDIR (-) -0.03 (-0.92) 0.01 (0.32) -0.10 (-3.25)** 0.43 STK%_INDIR (-) -0.07 (-2.12)* 0.03 (0.98) -0.08 (2.77)** 0.57

OUTDIR_ INCENTIVES (-) -0.10 (-0.46) 0.20 (1.01) -0.39 (-2.05)* 0.22 STKVAL_OUTDIR (-) -0.02 (-0.55) 0.03 (0.82) -0.08 (-2.19)* 0.22 STK%_OUTDIR (-) -0.03 (-0.83) 0.05 (1.36) -0.06 (-1.85)* 0.38

Outside Shareholder Concentration SHLDR_CONC (-) -0.44 (-3.77)** -0.45 (-4.44)** -0.16 (-1.60) 0.41

STKVAL_SHLDR (-) -0.11 (-2.83)** -0.15 (-4.31)** -0.05 (-1.54) 0.35 STK%_SHLDR (-) -0.04 (-1.23) -0.08 (-3.17)** -0.03 (-1.37) 0.68

%INSTN (-) -0.16 (-3.60)** -0.10 (-2.55)** -0.04 (-1.05) 0.19 %BLOCK (-) -0.07 (-1.67)* -0.05 (-1.52) -0.01 (-0.31) 0.27 Executive Incentives EXEC_INCENTIVES (-) -0.56 (-2.37)** -0.42 (-2.00)* 0.37 (1.84)* 0.15

LTINC_TOT (-) -0.08 (-1.75)* -0.09 (-2.11)* 0.06 (1.43) 0.14 EQINC_TOT (-) -0.09 (-1.94)* -0.07 (-1.75)* 0.10 (2.59)** 0.13

1Summary statistics include coefficient estimates with t-statistics in parenthesis. Coefficients and t-statistics for variables other than EARN_TIMELY, GEOG_CONCENTRATION and IND_CONCENTRATION are not tabulated for ease of presentation.

DEP_VAR = variables reflecting composite and individual corporate governance used as dependent variables in the above regression analyses. Ranks of individual corporate governance metrics are used for comparability with composite governance metrics. See Appendix for descriptions and measurement information for specific DEP_VAR metrics and all other model variables.

** (*) significant at the 1% (5%) level - one-tailed test for EARN_TIMELY, GEOG_CONCENTRATION and IND_CONCENTRATION.

.

34

Page 35: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Table 5 Summary of simultaneous estimation of composite governance variables and earnings timeliness 1

System of equations: Equation 1: EARN_TIMELY = λ + γ1BOARD_STRUCTURE + γ2ALLDIR_INCENTIVES + 3SHLDR_CONC +

γ4EXEC_INCENTIVES + θ1 MV + θ2STD_RET +θ3MTB + θ4GROWTH_SALE + θ5RD_SALE + θ6AD_SALE + θ6PPE_TA + η (not tabulated) (4)

Equations 2 through 5: DEP_VAR = α + β1EARN_TIMELY +β2GEOG_CONCENTRATION

+β3IND_CONCENTRATION + δ1 MV + δ2STD_RET + δ3FIRM_AGE +δ4 MTB + δ5GROWTH_SALE + δ6ROE + δ7CEO_TENURE +δ8FOUNDER +δ9UTILITY +δ10FINANCIAL + ε (3)

BOARD_ STRUCTURE

ALLDIR_ INCENTIVES

SHLDR_ CONC

EXEC_ INCENTIVES

EARN_TIMELY -2.11 (-1.63)

1.03 (0.58)

-3.95 (-1.95)*

3.36 (1.01)

GEOG_ CONCENTRATION

-0.19 (-1.95)*

0.18 (1.30)

-0.39 (-2.52)**

-0.43 (-1.68)*

IND_ CONCENTRATION

-0.13 (-1.42)

-0.44 (-3.40)**

-0.20 (-1.37)

0.32 (1.32)

MV -0.09 (-2.40)**

-0.07 (-1.42)

-0.22 (-3.71)**

0.32 (3.31)**

STD_RET 0.50 (3.34)**

0.07 (0.35)

0.43 (1.83)

0.53 (1.36)

FIRM_AGE -0.00 (-0.54)

-0.01 (-4.84)**

-0.01 (-2.38)**

0.00 (0.14)

MTB 0.02 (0.99)

0.05 (1.83)

0.00 (0.07)

0.01 (0.23)

GROWTH_SALE -0.25 (-1.07)

0.84 (2.63)**

0.63 (1.72)

0.58 (0.98)

ROE 0.54 (1.83)

0.40 (0.98)

1.21 (2.64)**

-1.41 (-1.88)

CEO_TENURE 0.00 (0.26)

0.02 (3.74)**

-0.01 (-0.95)

-0.01 (-0.96)

FOUNDER 0.09 (0.93)

0.47 (3.34)**

-0.26 (-1.66)

0.14 (0.54)

UTILITY 0.24 (0.96)

-1.55 (-4.40)**

-0.51 (-1.28)

-1.71 (-2.61)**

FINANCIAL -0.22 (-1.89)

0.21 (1.34)

0.24 (1.35)

-0.38 (-1.29)

Adjusted R2 0.12 0.41 0.24 0.09

1Summary statistics include coefficient estimates with t-statistics in parenthesis. DEP_VAR = variables reflecting composite corporate governance See Appendix for descriptions for

specific DEP_VAR composites and all other model variables. ** (*) significant at the 1% (5%) level - one-tailed test for EARN_TIMELY, GEOG_CONCENTRATION and

IND_CONCENTRATION, two-tailed test for remaining variables.

35

Page 36: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

References

Anderson, R., T. Bates, J. Bizjak and M. Lemmon, 1998. Corporate Governance and Firm Diversification. Working paper Washington and Lee University. Baker, M., J. Stein and J. Wurgler, 2001. When does the market matter? Stock prices and the investment of equity-dependent firms. NBER Working Paper 8750. Ball, R., S. P. Kothari, and A. Robin, 2000. The Effect of International Institutional Factors on Properties of Accounting Earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economic 29, 1-51. Basu, S., 1997. The Conservatism Principle and the Asymmetric Timeliness of Earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, 3-37. Berger, P. and E. Ofek, 1995. Diversification’s Effect on Firm Value. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 39-65. Bodnar, G., C. Tang, and J. Weintrop. 1998. Both Sides of Corporate Diversification: The Value Impacts of Geographic and Industrial Diversification. Working Paper, Wharton School. Bushman, R., and A. Smith, 2001. Financial Accounting Information and Corporate Governance. Journal of Accounting and Economics 32, 237-333. Bushman, R., R. Indjejikian and A. Smith, 1995. Aggregate Performance Measures in Business Unit Manager Compensation: The Role of Intrafirm Interdependencies. Journal of Accounting Research, 33 Supplement, 101-128. Bushman, R., R. Indjejikian and A. Smith, 1996. CEO Compensation: The Role of Individual Performance Evaluation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 21, 161-193. Bushman, R., J. Piotroski, and A. Smith, 2002. What Determines Corporate Transparency? Working Paper, The University of North Carolina. Campa, J. and S. Kedia, 1999. Explaining The Diversification Discount. Working paper, New York University. Comment, R., and Jarrell, G., 1995. Corporate Focus And Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 67–87. Cusatis, P., J. Miles and R. Woolridge, 1993. Restructuring Through Spin-Offs: The Stock Market Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 33, 293-311. Daley, L., V. Mehrotra and R. Sivakumar, 1997. Corporate Focus And Value Creation – Evidence From Spinoffs. Journal of Financial Economics 45, 257–281. Dechow, P., R. Sloan and A. Sweeney, 1996. Causes and Consequences of Earnings Manipulations: An Analysis of Firms Subject to Enforcement Actions by the SEC. Contemporary Accounting Research 13, 1-36.

36

Page 37: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Demsetz, H. and K. Lehn, 1985. The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155-77. Denis, D. J., D. K. Denis, and A. Sarin. 1997. Agency Problems, Equity Ownership, and Corporate Diversification. Journal of Finance 52, 135-160. Dow, J., and G. Gorton, 1997. Stock Market Efficiency And Economic Efficiency: Is There A Connection? Journal of Finance 52, 1087-1129. Duru, A., and D. Reeb, 2002. Geographic and Industrial Corporate Diversification: The Level and Structure of Executive Compensation. Forthcoming, Journal of Accounting Auditing and Finance. Dye, R., and S. Sridhar, 2001. Strategy-Directing Disclosures. Working paper, Northwestern University. Errunza, V., and L. Senbet. 1984. International Corporate Diversification, Market Valuation and Size Adjusted Evidence. Journal of Finance 34, 727-745. Fama, E. and K. French, 1997. Industry Costs of Equity. Journal of Financial Economics 43, 153-93. Fama, E. and M. Jensen, 1983. Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301-25. Finkelstein, S., and D. Hambrick. 1989. Chief Executive Compensation: A Study of the Intersection of Markets and Political Processes. Strategic Management Journal 10, 121-134. Frankel, R. and X. Li, 2001. The Characteristics Of A Firm’s Information Environment And The Predictive Ability Of Insider Trades. Working paper 4218-01, MIT Sloan Scholl of Management. Gaver, J. and K. Gaver, 1995. Compensation Policy and the Investment Opportunity Set. Financial Management 24, 19-32. Gilson, S., Healy, P., Noe, C. and K. Palepu, 2001. Analyst Specialization and Conglomerate Breakups. Journal of Accounting Research 39, 565-582. Givoly, D., C. Hayn and J. D'Souza, 1999. Measurement Errors and Information Content of Segment Reporting. Review of Accounting Studies 4, Issue 1. Graham, J., M. Lemmon, and J. Wolf, 2000. Does Corporate Diversification Destroy Value? Working paper, Duke University. Greene, W., 2000. Econometric Analysis. MacMillan, New York, NY. Grossman, S.J. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1980. The Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets. American Economic Review, 70, 393-408. Habib, M., D. B. Johnsen and N. Naik, 1997. Spinoffs and Information. Journal of Financial Intermediation 6, No. 2.

37

Page 38: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

Hayes, R. and S. Schaefer, 2000. Implicit Contracts and the Explanatory Power of Top Executive Compensation for Future Performance. RAND Journal of Economics, 31, 273-293. Healy, P., 1985. The Effect of Bonus Schemes on Accounting Decisions. Journal of Accounting & Economics 7, 85-113. Hermalin, B. and M. Weisbach, 2002. Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Determined Institution: A Survey of the Economic Literature. Forthcoming, Economic Policy Review Himmelberg, C., R. Hubbard, and D. Palia, 1999. Understanding the Determinants of Managerial Ownership and the Link between Ownership and Performance. Journal of Financial Economics 53, 353-384. Holthausen, R., D. Larcker, and R. Sloan, 1995. Annual Bonus Schemes and the Manipulation of Earnings. Journal of Accounting & Economics 19, 29-74. Ittner, C., D. Larcker and M. Rajan, 1997. The Choice of Performance Measures in Annual Bonus Contracts. The Accounting Review 72, 231-255. John, K. and E. Ofek, 1995. Asset Sales and Increase in Focus. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 105-126. Kole, S., 1996. Managerial Ownership and Firm Performance: Incentives or Rewards? Advances in Financial Economics 2, 119-149, Lamont, O., and C. Polk , 2002. Does Diversification Destroy Value? Evidence From The Industry Shocks. Journal of Financial Economics 63, 51–77. Lang, L. and R. Stulz, 1994. Tobin’s Q, Corporate Diversification, And Firm Performance. Journal of Political Economy 102, 1248–1280. La Porta, R. F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1998. Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155. Morck, R., R. Vishny, and A. Shleifer, 1990. The Stock Market And Investment: Is The Market A Sideshow? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 157-215. Paul, J., 1992. On the Efficiency of Stock-Based Compensation. Review of Financial Studies 5, 471-502. Reeb, D., C.Y. Kwok, and Y. Baek. 1998. Systematic Risk of the Multinational Corporation. Journal of International Business Studies 29 (Second Quarter), 263-279. Rose, N., and A. Shepard, 1997. Firm Diversification And CEO Compensation: Managerial Ability Or Executive Entrenchment. Rand Journal of Economics 28, 489-514. Servaes, H., 1996. The Value Of Diversification During The Conglomerate Merger Wave. Journal of Finance 51, 1201–1225.

38

Page 39: Financial Accounting Information, Organizational ...faculty.chicagobooth.edu/ellen.engel/research/governance-jae... · Financial Accounting Information, Organizational Complexity

39

Schipper, K. and A. Smith, 1983, Effects of Recontracting on Shareholder Wealth: The Case for Voluntary Spin-offs. Journal of Financial Economics 12, 437-467. Schipper, K. and A. Smith, 1986, A Comparison of Equity Carve-Outs and Seasoned Equity Offerings: Share Price Effects and Corporate Restructuring. Journal of Financial Economics 15, 153-186. Shivdisani, A., 1993. Board Composition, Ownership Structure, and Hostile Takeovers. Journal of Accounting and Economics 16, 167-98. Smith, C. and R. Watts, 1992. The Investment Opportunity Set and Corporate Financing, Dividend, and Compensation Policies. Journal of Financial Economics 32, 263-92. Subrahmanyam, A. and S. Titman, 1999. The Going-Public Decision and the Development of Financial Markets. Journal of Finance 54, 1045-1082. Verrecchia, R., 1982. The Use of Mathematical Models in Financial Accounting. Journal of Accounting Research, 20, 1-55. Warfield, T., J. Wild and K. Wild, 1995. Managerial Ownership, Accounting Choices, and Informativeness of Earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 20, 55-100.