Finance and Economic Development

download Finance and Economic Development

of 136

Transcript of Finance and Economic Development

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    1/136

    THREE ESSAYS ON FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND

    ECONOMIC GROWTH

    DISSERTATION

    Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for

    the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the

    Graduate School of The Ohio State University

    By

    Pilhyun Kim, M.A.

    * * * * *

    The Ohio State University

    2006

    Dissertation Committee:

    Dr. Paul Evans, Adviser

    Dr. Masao Ogaki

    Dr. Pok-sang Lam

    Approved by

    Adviser

    Graduate Program inEconomics

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    2/136

    ABSTRACT

    The primary part of my dissertation investigates the potential effects offinancial

    sector development on economic growth. In order to reveal the nature of these effects,

    I focus on the potential channels of influence from the financial to the real sector.

    I investigate the link between thefi

    nancial sector and economic growth focusing on

    the role of the financial sector in funding innovative activities. To this aim, I construct

    a model where the economy is driven by innovative activities that require both human

    capital and external funding. My analysis shows that when certain conditions are

    satisfied, there exists a unique equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy

    is jointly determined by the levels of human capital and financial development. An

    implication of this is that financial liberalization policies that do not adequately

    address the fundamentals of the economy can cause bank failures and possibly a

    financial crisis. Furthermore, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter

    values of the economy, there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small

    number of bankers and the other with a large number of bankers.

    Also, I examine empirically whether financial development has any effect on the

    rate of technological innovation using patent applications as a proxy for innovative

    output. For a sample of twenty eight countries from 1970 to 2000, my analysis shows

    that financial development is indeed significant in raising the growth rate of innovative

    output.

    ii

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    3/136

    In addition, I investigate whether financial development enhances investment ef-

    ficiency. The efficiency channel hypothesis states that financial development may

    increase the efficiency of investment by directing the funds to the most productive

    uses. I examine if there is any evidence of financial development positively affect-

    ing the efficiency of aggregate investment using developing countries as a sample.

    Compared to the volume channel, the efficiency channel has received relatively little

    attention until recently. I address the issue of the efficiency channel using two alterna-

    tive measures of aggregate investment efficiency. I find that, for developing countries,

    financial development significantly and positively affects productivity of investment.

    iii

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    4/136

    To my parents and my family

    iv

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    5/136

    ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

    I am indebted to Dr. Paul Evans, my advisor, for his valuable and expert guidance,

    insightful comments and encouragement during the course of this study. Without his

    patient guidance my dissertation would have been impossible.

    Special gratitude is extended to Dr. Masao Ogaki and Dr. Pok-sang Lam for their

    comments and valuable help to improve my study.

    Financial support from the PEGS Research Grant is greatly acknowledged as well

    as the Graduate Teaching Assistantship the Department of Economics have offered

    me throughout my residence at the Ohio State University.

    In addition, my special thanks go to my wife Jihee and my family who have been

    always supporting and praying for me.

    Most of all, I would like to express my deepest appreciation to my father and

    mother for their belief in my abilities and undying support throughout my life.

    v

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    6/136

    VITA

    January 9, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Born - Gwanju, Korea

    1991 ........................................B.A. Economics, University of Wiscon-sin, Madison

    1998 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . .. . . . . . .M.A. Economics, The Ohio State Uni-

    versity2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . .. . . . . . .Ph.D Candidate, The Ohio State Uni-

    versity

    1998 - 2004 .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . .Graduate Teaching Associate, TheOhio State University

    2004 - 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . .Lecturer, The Western WashingtonUniversity

    FIELDS OF STUDY

    Major Field: Economics

    Studies in:

    Money MacroeconomicsApplied EconometricsEconomic Growth

    vi

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    7/136

    TABLE OF CONTENTS

    Page

    Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii

    Dedication . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iv

    Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v

    Vita . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi

    List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . x

    List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi

    Chapters:

    1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

    2. Literature Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

    2.1 Models of the finance-led growth theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

    2.2 Empirics of the finance-led growth theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

    3. A Finance-led Growth Hypothesis: Revisited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

    3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

    3.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163.2.1 Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

    3.2.2 A formal model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

    3.3 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

    3.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

    vii

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    8/136

    4. How Does Financial Development Promote Growth? . . . . . . . . . . . 35

    4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

    4.2 Related Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

    4.2.1 Theories of the finance-led growth hypothesis . . . . . . . . 374.2.2 Empirical studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

    4.3 Theoretical background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

    4.3.1 Final goods sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

    4.3.2 Intermediate goods sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

    4.3.3 The research sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

    4.3.4 The growth of the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

    4.4 Empirical analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

    4.4.1 Patents as a proxy for technological innovation . . . . . . . 47

    4.4.2 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

    4.4.3 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 544.4.4 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

    4.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

    5. Investment Efficiency and Financial Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

    5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

    5.2 Investment, output growth, and financial development . . . . . . . 74

    5.2.1 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77

    5.2.2 Estimation strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79

    5.2.3 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

    5.3 Investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 845.3.1 Measures of investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84

    5.3.2 Investment efficiency estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87

    5.3.3 Determinants of investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

    5.3.4 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92

    5.3.5 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93

    5.3.6 The effects of political stability and legal environment . . . 94

    5.3.7 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95

    5.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

    6. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

    Appendices:

    viii

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    9/136

    A. Data Sources for Chapter 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

    B. Countries Used in Chapter 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

    Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

    ix

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    10/136

    LIST OF TABLES

    Table Page

    4.1 Sample Countries Used for Patent Regression . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67

    4.2 Fixed Effects Estimation I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

    4.3 Fixed Effects Estimation II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

    4.4 Fixed Effects Estimation with Selected Independent Variables . . . . 70

    5.1 Investment Regression I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100

    5.2 Investment Regression II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101

    5.3 Investment Regression III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102

    5.4 Investment Efficiency Estimates using GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103

    5.5 Investment Efficiency Estimates Using IVA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105

    5.6 Investment Efficiency Regression I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107

    5.7 Investment Efficiency Regression II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

    5.8 Investment Efficiency Regression III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

    5.9 Investment Efficiency Regression IV . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110

    x

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    11/136

    LIST OF FIGURES

    Figure Page

    3.1 Screening Costs of Competing Bankers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

    3.2 Equilibrium When + < 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

    3.3 Effects of Deterioration in Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

    4.1 Long Run GDP Growth vs. Long Run Patent Growth . . . . . . . . . 65

    4.2 Movements of Financial Development Indicators for Selected Countries 66

    5.1 Output Growth and Investment in Cambodia . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

    5.2 The Share of Industry Value Added in GDP in Developing Countries 99

    xi

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    12/136

    CHAPTER 1

    Introduction

    The primary part of my dissertation investigates the potential effects offinancial

    sector development on economic growth. In order to reveal the nature of these effects,

    I focus on the potential channels of influence from the financial to the real sector.

    The nature of the interaction between the real and the financial sectors has been

    hotly debated among researchers. Those who favor the finance-led growth hypothesis

    argue that the existence of a vibrant financial sector has growth-enhancing effects. In

    this literature, an economy can grow faster due to an efficient allocation of resources

    by the financial sector, mainly banks. A number of channels of influence have been

    proposed in the literature, which include increased savings, increased investment, in-

    creased efficiency thereof, increased human capital accumulation, and positive effects

    of the financial sector on innovation processes. Investigations of the validity of these

    channels as true agents of long-run growth, so far, have yielded mixed empirical re-

    sults. In chapter 2, I review the vast literatue on this subject to examine how the

    literature has evolved over time.

    In chapter 3, I investigate the link between the financial sector and economic

    growth focusing on the role of the financial sector in funding innovative activities. My

    1

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    13/136

    motivation is based on the research by Easterly and Levine (2001) in that it is the

    residual that accounts for most of the income and growth differences across nations.

    Broadly speaking, innovative activities require both human and financial capital.

    They act as complements in the production function of ideas. However, the interaction

    between the two has been largely ignored in the literature. In order to improve our

    understanding of how the financial sector interacts with the real sector, the nature

    of interactions between two major components of innovative activities needs to be

    examined more closely. In this chapter, I pursue this goal by constructing a model

    where the economy is driven by innovative activities that require both human capital

    and external funding from the financial sector. Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is

    assumed that the role of the financial sector in this model is to screen the innovators for

    their probabilities of success. In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional

    literature in four important ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when

    it is realized but when it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by

    observations that not all innovations are implemented in the production processes.

    Secondly, I assume that the magnitude of technological change an innovator comes

    up with is a function of that innovators human capital. Thirdly, it is assumed in

    this model that external finance is needed not for R&D activities but for utilization

    of innovations. Finally, it is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs.

    My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

    equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

    of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

    financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

    economy can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore,

    2

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    14/136

    in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

    costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

    there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

    the other with a large number of bankers.

    In chapter 4, I examine empirically whether financial development has any effect

    on the rate of technological innovation. A flood of empirical studies began to appear

    in the 1990s to test the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis. A typical

    test strategy involves regressing some indicator of financial development on some

    aggregate growth measures such as investment growth, GDP growth or total factorproductivity growth. By and large, the current empirical literature lacks one crucial

    element in that it does not consider the channels of influence suggested by theoretical

    models and fails to show how financial development affects economic growth. In

    order to examine the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis, I depart from the

    conventional literature. Instead of estimating a relationship between aggregate growth

    measures and financial development indicators, I test the validity of the finance-led

    growth hypothesis by focusing on the innovation channel of influence, using patent

    applications as a proxy for innovative output. Under the framework of ideas-driven

    growth, the hypothesis I test is that financial development enhances innovation, which

    is the main engine of economic growth. If the finance-led growth hypothesis is right,

    as the financial sector develops over time in a certain country, the growth rate of

    innovation should be higher, which would, then, lead to faster economic growth due

    to a rising level of productivity. Using panel data on twenty eight countries from 1970

    to 2000, my analysis shows that financial development is indeed significant in raising

    the growth rate of innovative output.

    3

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    15/136

    According to the finance-led growth hypothesis, financial development affects in-

    vestment in two ways. Firstly, a better developed financial sector may raise the

    investment rate by pooling and risk sharing. This is the so-called volume channel.

    Secondly, the efficiency channel hypothesis states that financial development may in-

    crease the efficiency of investment by directing the funds to the most productive uses.

    In chapter 5, I examine if there is any evidence of financial development positively af-

    fecting the efficiency of aggregate investment using developing countries as a sample.

    Compared to the volume channel, the efficiency channel has received relatively little

    attention until recently. In this chapter, I address the issue of the efficiency channel

    using two alternative measures of aggregate investment efficiency. I find that, for

    developing countries, financial development significantly and positively affects pro-

    ductivity of investment. Further, I depart from the existing studies by focusing on

    the banking sector to measure the degree of financial development. In chapter 6, I

    conclude.

    4

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    16/136

    CHAPTER 2

    Literature Review

    The literature on the finance-led growth hypothesis is vast. Accordingly, a few

    survey papers have been written on this subject. See, for example, Levine (1997) and

    Tsuru (2000). The focus of this review is, therefore, not to present an exhaustive

    review of the literature as it would be rather redundant, but to assess critically how

    the literature has evolved over time and to identify the remaining issues that need to

    be resolved.

    Theoretical models of the finance-led growth hypothesis are, in general, modified

    versions of endogenous growth theories with risky investment opportunities. Due

    to uncertainty about the outcome of investment, the allocation of resources is sub-

    optimal. The financial sector enters this world to reduce welfare loss resulting from

    this uncertainty by providing information, risk-pooling, and liquidity. As the financial

    sector develops, possibly as a result of feedback from economic growth, the provision

    of these services becomes more efficient so that a faster rate of economic growth is

    realized.

    The overriding research theme that came out of the theoretical models and that has

    occupied the attention of the empirical researchers for the past decade is a question of

    5

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    17/136

    whether growth rate of an economy is positively correlated with the level offinancial

    development. A typical method employed to test this theory has been to regress

    some aggregate growth variables on financial development indicators that are based

    on some ratio of monetary aggregates to GDP. Simple as it may be in its approach,

    this line of research has produced an impressive amount of evidence for the finance-led

    growth theory. In what follows, I examine more closely how the literature has evolved

    over time both theoretically and empirically.

    2.1 Models of the finance-led growth theory

    An initial theoretical interest lay in the effects of financial development on the

    efficiency of capital accumulation. Greenwood and Jovanovich (1990) is among the

    frontiers of this approach. They assume an economy where growth is driven by capi-

    tal accumulation, and the risky nature of investment prevents agents from allocating

    resources in an efficient manner, resulting in welfare loss in the absence of the finan-

    cial sector. However, as the economy grows, it becomes able to pay the setup costs

    to establish the financial sector of which the role is to collect and process information

    and to pool risks across investors/savers. Once the financial sector is established, it

    allows a higher rate of return to be earned on capital, promoting economic growth.

    Bencivenga and Smith (1991) pursue a similar vein and present a model where ran-

    dom liqudity shocks raise the fraction of savings invested in liquid but unproductive

    assets. The financial sector enters this world exogenously, contrary to Greenwood

    and Jovanovich, to provide liquidity to economic agents and makes it possible for

    them to invest a larger portion of their savings in productive and illiquid assets. Al-

    though the specific types of risk assumed in these models are different, the nature of

    6

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    18/136

    the fundamental role the financial sector plays is essentially the same. By processing

    information and reducing risks, the financial sector reduces uncertainty associated

    with investment and directs funds to their most productive uses, and consequently,

    enhances the rate of economic growth.

    As doubts about the effectiveness of capital accumulation in promoting long-term

    growth arose, researchers shifted their focus to potential positive effects financial

    development may have on productivity growth. The main sources of productivity

    growth considered in this literature are purposeful innovative activities and market

    specialization that are risky. Uncertain nature of the outcomes of innovative activi-ties (Fuente and Marin, 1996) and market specialization characterized by increasing

    number of firms (Galetovic, 1996; Greenwood and Smith, 1997) make monitoring

    necessary. Since monitoring is assumed to be costly, there is an incentive for the

    financial sector to endogenously emerge to economize on the monitoring costs as in

    Diamond (1983). The provision of monitoring services by the financial sector then

    leads to increased levels of innovative activities and market specialization, which re-

    sult in enhanced economic growth. The main weakness of this type of model is that

    there seems to be no empirical evidence of the financial sector conducting active

    monitoring (Allen and Gale, 2001). Furthermore, the proposition that the financial

    sector actively monitors the outcome of investment may have a weaker ground in

    those countries where the banking sector provides a large share of external finance

    with debt contracts.. Since debt contracts require the investor/borrower to repay a

    fixed amount after a certain period independent of the outcome of investment, the

    banking sector does not have an incentive to actively monitor the activities of the

    investor/borrower except ascertaining the state of the outcome of such activities at

    7

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    19/136

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    20/136

    development rises, possibly suggesting diminishing marginal returns. This evidence

    directly contradicts the existing theories where economic growth is a (monotonically)

    increasing function of the level of financial development. Finally, the models where

    the financial sector actively monitors do not seem to accurately reflect the experiences

    of many countries.

    2.2 Empirics of the finance-led growth theory

    First systematic investigation of the relationship between finance and growth was

    conducted by King and Levine (1993). In their study, it was found that the level of

    financial development was positively correlated with growth variables such as GDP

    per capita growth, investment rate, and total factor productivity growth. Notwith-

    standing the rigorous statistical analysis they conducted to reveal the relationship,

    their study was more significant in that it brought the issue of simultaneity up to the

    center stage. It was pointed out that the use of lagged values offinancial development

    indicators, as King and Levine did in their study, does not resolve the simultaneity

    bias if the agents behaved in forward-looking manner, which would make their results

    hard to interpret. By contrast, De Gregorio and Guidotti (1995) argued that the

    use of lagged levels of financial development indicators is justified in cross-sectional

    studies by noting that "the theories suggest that economic growth induces growth in

    the financial system but this has no implications regarding the size of the financial

    system with respect to GDP." Further, their Barro-type cross-sectional estimation

    found that the positive effects of financial development on growth vary over time

    periods, regions, and income levels, which suggested that the relationship might be

    nonlinear.

    9

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    21/136

    As the issues of simultaneity and nonlinearity persisted, it was suggested that a

    time-series study focusing on a small group of countries would prove to be beneficial.

    The results from the early attempts in this direction cast doubt on the validity of

    the finance-led growth hypothesis. For example, Demetriades and Hussein (1996),

    who were among the first researchers to employ time-series approach, found, using

    cointegration tests, that the relationship between finance and growth is bidirectional

    and that this relationship is country-specific. Similar results were obtained by Arestis

    and Demetriades (1997), Luintel and Khan (1999), and Shan et al (2001) using VAR

    estimation. However, more recent studies have reestablished finance as an important

    source of economic growth. To cite a few, Xu (2000) found evidence for the finance-led

    growth hypothesis using multivariate VAR, directly contradicting the findings of the

    previous time-series studies. Calderon and Lie (2003) agree with Xu, after conducting

    Geweke decomposition test on pooled data of 109 countries, and conclude that finance

    generally leads growth albeit some evidence of bidirectional Granger-causality. More

    recently, Christopoulos and Tsionas (2004) applied panel unit root and cointegration

    tests, threshold cointegration test, and panel VECM to find support for unidirectional

    causality from finance to growth.

    Another strand of research that has been pursued is the use of panel studies.

    Compared to the approaches mentioned above, panel study was generally regarded as

    more advantageous (Temple, 1999). Using dynamic GMM to control for simultaneity

    and unobserved country-specific effects, Beck et al (2000) found that financial devel-

    opment promotes growth by improving productivity. Rioja and Valev (2004) adapt

    a similar method to investigate whether financial development affects growth differ-

    ently according to the income levels. While they concede that developed countries

    10

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    22/136

    growth is enhanced by finance-stimulated productivity growth as in Beck et al, they

    argue that the effects offinancial development on growth of developing countries are

    via capital accumulation.

    Overall, the current trend in this area can be summarized as the following. First,

    the consensus on the bidirectional causality seems to be gaining an increasing support.

    This may be a natural course of work since the financial sector is, after all, a part of

    an economic system. Second, there is an increasing emphasis on the need to employ a

    time-series approach when considering the relationship between financial development

    and growth. Third, along with the second trend, researchers are increasingly puttingan effort to incorporate infrastructural environments into the analysis. Fourth, the

    importance of incorporating microeconomic mechanism in modelling the behavior of

    the financial markets is gaining acceptance among researchers in this area. Given

    that there has been an increased emphasis on the microeconomic environment in

    macroeconomic topics, this seems rather late. At least, the research in this area

    seems to be going in the right direction. Finally, since 1996, there has been more

    attention on the channels of influence from financial development to economic growth

    11

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    23/136

    CHAPTER 3

    A Finance-led Growth Hypothesis: Revisited

    3.1 Introduction

    Ever since Schumpeter highlighted a potentially growth-enhancing role of banks as

    efficient allocators of funds in 1911, the relationship between financial sector and real

    sector has been a subject of heated debates. In his argument, banks help an economy

    achieve first-best outcome by providing efficient markets for funds. In contrast to

    this argument, there are also a group of economists who view the financial sector as

    something that merely mirrors the real sector. Most notably, Robinson (1952) argued

    that "...finance does not lead growth. Growth leads finance..." The main argument

    of those who oppose finance-led growth theories is that, simply put, financial markets

    evolve in response to increased demands for better services from a growing economy.

    Therefore, the development offinancial markets only mirrors that of real sectors. This

    led Lucas to state that economists badly over-stress the role offinancial sectors. These

    two polar positions on the role of financial sectors have led economists to consider

    the issue of causality extensively.

    The approach I take to investigate the link between the financial sector and eco-

    nomic growth focuses on the role of the financial sector in financing innovative activ-

    ities. Our motivation is based on the research by Easterly and Levine (2001) in that

    12

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    24/136

    it is the residual that accounts for most of the income and growth differences across

    nations. Further, the idea that innovative activities need financial assistance is quite

    intuitive. We can easily imagine what might have happened to IT companies if there

    had been no venture capital. It clearly illustrates the possibility of positive effects

    the financial sector may have on the real sector activities.

    Broadly speaking, innovative activities require both human and financial capital.

    They act as complements in the production function of ideas. However, the interaction

    between the two has been largely ignored in the literature. An exception is the study

    by Outreville (1999) where he shows empirically that there is a positive relationshipbetween human capital and financial development, although no formal theory was

    offered to explain the finding. In order to improve our understanding of how the

    financial sector interacts with the real sector, the nature of interactions between two

    major components of innovative activities needs to be examined more closely. In this

    chapter, I pursue this goal by constructing a model where the economy is driven by

    innovative activities that require both human capital and external funding from the

    financial sector. Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is assumed that the role of

    the financial sector in this model is to screen the innovators for their probabilities

    of success. However, unlike King and Levines version of the financial sector that

    plays an active screening role of weeding out bad entrepreneurs, the financial sector I

    consider is a more passive one. Specifically, it is assumed that the role of the financial

    sector is to assess and convey the probability of success to the innovators so that the

    latter can make optimal borrowing decisions. It is passive in a sense that it does not

    refuse to lend to those innovators with low probability of success. Rather, it penalizes

    them by imposing higher repayment requirements. Therefore, contrary to King and

    13

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    25/136

    Levine, the financial sector does not improve the aggregate probability of success by

    screening.

    In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional literature in four impor-

    tant ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when it is realized but when

    it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by observations that not

    all innovations are implemented in the production processes. For example, we know

    from history that the steam engine was invented in Ancient Greece two-thousand

    years ago. However, it obviously did not ignite the industrial revolution at that time

    as it did in England millenniums later. A similar example can be found in the UnitedStates at the turn of the 20th century. Around the time when mass production of

    automobiles was about to be started, an automobile that could run on electricity was

    invented. It drove quietly, emitted less pollution and was technologically superior

    to gasoline-driven automobiles. However, we all know how the electric-automobile

    industry fared in the end. Although it was technologically superior to other competi-

    tors, it did not survive the forces of the market because it lacked commercial appeals.

    Gasoline-driven cars were simply much faster and more powerful than electric ones,

    and hence were more attractive to automobile buyers. In a sense that the aim of

    innovation is to improve the welfare, in terms of higher incomes or more convenience,

    of economic agents, a steam engine in Ancient Greece or electric cars in the early 20th

    century can hardly be regarded as a success. This is especially true if one regards the

    purpose of innovation to be improvements of production technology. To put it rather

    bluntly, a technology that is not used commercially is the same as a technology that

    is not invented as far as its effects on output production is concerned. Accordingly,

    in the model considered here, it is assumed that innovators invent new technologies

    14

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    26/136

    with certainty. What is uncertain is whether the new technology would be successful

    commercially. Then, the job of assessing the probability of commercial success is

    left to the financial sector. Secondly, I assume that the magnitude of technological

    change an innovator comes up with is a function of that innovators human capital.

    The idea is simply that the smarter the innovator is, the bigger the improvements

    over the existing technology will be. It should be noted in advance that although

    the magnitude of technological change is endogenized, the resulting implication in

    terms of economic growth remains similar to the existing literature. Thirdly, it is

    assumed in this model that external finance is needed not for R&D activities but for

    utilization of innovations. Venture capital markets justify this assumption. Finally,

    it is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs. The assumption offixed

    setup costs has been used in the literature to explain poverty traps and bidirectional

    causality between finance and growth. However, historical experiences of developed

    countries do not support this assumption (Galetovic, 1996). My analysis shows that

    one does not need the assumption of setup costs to establish bi-causality or to explain

    poverty traps.

    My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

    equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

    of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

    financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

    economy can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore,

    in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

    costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

    15

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    27/136

    there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

    the other with a large number of bankers.

    The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. In section 2, a formal model

    preceded by a sketch is presented. In section 3, the models implications are discussed.

    In section 4, I conclude.

    3.2 Model

    3.2.1 Environment

    Imagine a small island populated by groups of workers and bankers who are risk-

    neutral. While bankers move freely to and from other islands, workers are assumed

    not to be mobile. People on this island live infinitely, but their planning horizon

    is on a daily basis. In particular, there are L number of identical workers with a

    zero population growth rate. The workers daily routine consists of three events in

    the morning, afternoon, and evening. At every morning, he is endowed with one

    unit of manna for the day. Notice that the manna depreciates completely in one

    day so that there is no saving for tomorrow. The worker can use the manna for two

    things. He can use some fraction of it to accumulate human capital which will enable

    him to become an innovator in the afternoon. With what remains, he produces the

    consumption good using the old technology. After obtaining education, the worker

    innovates over the existing technology. At this time, the worker/innovator does not

    know the likelihood of commercial success of his invention. Once he comes up with

    an idea as to how to improve the old technology, he goes to the banker to finance

    his production of consumption goods. Notice that the magnitude of improvement

    depends on the fraction of the manna he spent to receive education. That is to say,

    16

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    28/136

    the smarter the worker/innovator is, the bigger the improvement will be. When he

    meets with the banker, the probability of commercial success is revealed through

    the screening of the banker. Then the worker/innovator borrows from the banker to

    finance his production activity. In return he promises to pay a certain fraction of

    the consumption goods he expects to produce in the afternoon as a repayment to the

    banker. In the afternoon, the state of his innovations commercial success is revealed.

    If it is a success, the worker uses the new technology to produce consumption goods

    of which some fraction is paid back to the banker as a repayment. If it is a failure,

    the worker returns what was borrowed, instead of the agreed amount of repayment,

    to the banker. In the evening, the innovator/worker consumes what is left, and goes

    to sleep to start a new day tomorrow.

    There is an arbitrarily large number of identical bankers on this island. Since

    they can move freely across different islands unlike the workers, exactly how many

    bankers are on the island at any particular time is not relevant. What is relevant in

    this economy is how many bankers decide to finance the innovators. In the morning,

    the banker is endowed with the capital good. He is also endowed with a technology

    that can transform his endowment to the consumption good at the rate of r, and

    this process is assumed to take a day. With the endowment, the banker must figure

    out whether he should open a bank or use the endowed technology to transform it

    to consumption goods for his own use in the evening. Once he decides to open a

    bank, he does so without paying setup costs. Then, he waits for the innovators to

    come and ask for loans. When the innovator comes in for a loan to implement his

    innovation, the banker screens him to gauge the likelihood of the commercial success

    of the innovators idea. Based upon the probability of commercial success, which is

    17

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    29/136

    different across the innovators, the banker decides on the amount of repayment, in

    terms of the consumption goods that he must receive for lending a given amount of

    capital to the innovator. In the afternoon, he receives the proceeds from investing in

    the worker/innovator. In the evening, he consumes what he received in the afternoon.

    In the next morning, the whole cycle starts anew. With this description in mind, we

    move to formalize the model in the next section.

    3.2.2 A formal model

    Workers

    Initially, the island is endowed with a certain level of technology denoted by A0

    at time 0. In each day t, there exists L number of workers who live infinitely. It

    is assumed that there is no population growth and that L is some arbitrarily large

    number less than infinity. As mentioned above, the worker is daily routine consists

    of three events. In the morning, he is endowed with one unit of manna. He can use

    the manna for two activities: innovation and/or production with an old technology.

    His problem is to figure out how to allocate the manna between these two activities.

    If he decides to innovate, he spends a fraction vi of the manna to receive education

    that will enable him to become an innovator in the afternoon. The interpretation of

    vi is that it measures the amount of sacrifice the worker needs to make to make an

    innovation as it could have been used to produce the consumption goods with the

    old technology. Notice that the education process is assumed to be instantaneous for

    simplicity.

    18

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    30/136

    The worker i improves upon the old technology that is available for everyone based

    upon the following:

    Ait = itAt1. (3.1)

    where it = (vit). The parameter stands for the effectiveness of education process

    and is greater than zero. is an idea production parameter between 0 and 1. This

    specification of implies that the magnitude of the technological change is an increas-

    ing function of human capital acquired through education. In essence, it is similar to

    Aghion and Howitts model (1999) where the economy is driven by innovation and

    creative destruction. In their model, the magnitude of technological change is a func-

    tion of some exogenous parameter (their ) and the number of people working in the

    research sector. The difference is that I model to be solely a function of human cap-

    ital and leave out the exogenous component. In terms of model implications, nothing

    is lost by the explicit modelling of in this fashion. An attractive feature, on the

    other hand, of specifying this way is that it allows for the possibility of diminishing

    marginal returns. R&D literature shows that as research efforts increase, captured

    implicitly by v here, the number of innovations that results grows at a decreasing

    rate. Aghion and Howitts specification does not coincide with this empirical finding.

    Admittedly, the specification of in my model is based on observations only and

    rather ad-hoc. However, I argue that specifying explicitly rather than taking it

    as exogenous is a step in the right direction toward understanding the impacts that

    innovations have on the economy.

    Recall that the fact the worker comes up with a new technology does not mean

    that the innovation is successful commercially. As discussed in the previous section,

    19

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    31/136

    whether the innovation is a success is judged by its commercial usefulness. After com-

    ing up with a new technology, the worker/innovator is randomly and uniformly put

    into a location around the circumference of the island. The circumference of the island

    is assumed to be equal to 1. In this model, I posit that the probability of commercial

    success, p, is a function of the distance between the worker/innovator and the banker

    who finances him, and that this distance is not known to the worker/innovator until

    he is screened by the banker. This idea is motivated by observations from the venture

    capital market. In the case of venture capital, it is accepted that the likelihood of

    success for a new idea, business plan, and/or product is critically dependent upon

    how close relationship the innovator has with those who provide funds. In this model,

    the nature of the relationship between the borrower and the lender is captured by

    the distance between the two. An exact specification of the probability of commercial

    success will be given in the next section.

    Afterwards, the worker/innovator goes to the banker to borrow capital to finance

    his production activity using the new technology, after which the probability of com-

    mercial success is revealed through the screening of the banker. Given the now-

    revealed probability of the commercial success for his innovation, the worker/innovator

    decides the optimal amount of capital, xit, to borrow and promises to repay Iit to the

    banker if the innovation is commercially successful. Note that the capital is borrowed

    after the innovation occurred as described in the previous section.

    In the afternoon, the probability of the innovations commercial success is realized

    to everyone. If the innovation is commercially successful, the worker uses the new

    20

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    32/136

    technology, Ait, and the capital, xit, borrowed from the banker to produce consump-

    tion goods according to a production function:

    yHit = Aitxit = (vit)

    At1xit (3.2)

    where is between 0 and 1. H stands for the production sector that employs a

    new technology. Note that after one day, the new technology becomes available

    to everyone. If the innovation is unsuccessful, then the worker/innovator returns the

    borrowed capital/consumption good, x, instead ofI, to the banker. At the same time,

    he spends 1 vit to produce consumption goods with the old technology according

    to the production function:

    yLit = At1(1 vit) (3.3)

    where L designates the production sector with the old technology. In the evening,

    the day is complete with the worker consuming what is left.

    Bankers

    In this model, the bankers are assumed to be symmetrical and to maximize prof-

    its. Similar to the workers, each bankers daily routine consists of three events. In

    the morning, the representative banker is endowed with arbitrarily large units of cap-

    ital/consumption goods less than infinity.1 It should be pointed out that the exact

    amounts of endowments do not need to be specified for the same reason that the

    number of the bankers present on the island need not be specified. It is implicitly

    assumed in this model that the bankers can potentially finance as many workers as

    possible as long as it is profitable. Considering that in the real world, the amount

    1 This endowment will be designated as a capital good from now on for the sake of convenience.

    21

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    33/136

    of funds that can be potentially available to the innovator is significantly large espe-

    cially when there is a relatively free flow of funds across countries, I believe that this

    assumption is reasonable. In addition, making this assumption allows us to abstain

    from having to deal with the effects of inter-island transfer of capital/consumption

    goods.

    In the morning, he has to decide what to do with the endowment. He can use it

    to invest in the worker/innovator or have it transformed at a rate of r. To use an

    analogy, his decision can be described as having to choose between risk-free bonds

    that pay an interest of r and risky bonds with a higher rate of return than r. Notice

    that opening up a bank does not cost the banker anything. Once he opens the bank,

    he meets and screens the worker/innovator to assess the probability of commercial

    success of the innovation which is defined as:

    p(zit) = ezit, 0 < zit < dt (3.4)

    where zit is the distance between the banker and the worker/innovator i at time t.dt

    is the maximum distance the worker/innovator can be located from the banker.

    The screening is assumed to be costly. Intuitively, the further away the worker/innovator

    is from the banker, the more costly it would be for the banker to assess the probability

    of commercial success. Hence, the screening costs would be a function of z. Another

    way to think about it is to imagine that, in practice, it would cost more for the banker

    to find out the likelihood of success if the borrower is of a somewhat dubious nature,

    which z represents. To capture this, I define the screening cost to be:

    SC(zit) = ezit , 0 < zit < dt (3.5)

    22

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    34/136

    where is a exogenous policy variable that measures the stringency of the government

    policies regarding the screening processes. A higher level of implies that more

    strict policies are in place, and hence the banker incurs higher costs for screening.

    Figure (3.1) illustrates the relationship between two neighboring banks in terms of

    the screening costs. It can be seen that for those innovators whose distances z are

    between dt and dt, the banker A has a monopoly power over them since it has a cost

    advantage over all other banks and in particular over its adjacent bankers B and B.

    It can be seen that since the circumference of the island is equal to 1, and the bankers

    will open their banks along the circumference, 12dt

    = Nt, where Nt is the number of

    bankers open for business at time t.

    Once the screening is done, the banker informs the worker/innovator of the prob-

    ability of commercial success so that the latter can make a optimal decision on how

    much to borrow. Then the banker meets the worker/innovators demand by supplying

    him with xit. In return, it is promised to the banker that he would receive I from the

    worker/innovator if the innovation is commercially successful, and xit if it is not.

    In the afternoon, the probability of success is realized and the banker receives

    either I or xit depending on the state of the worker/innovator. In the evening, he

    consumes what he has received from the worker/innovator along with the rest of the

    endowments.

    Equilibrium

    In order to solve the model, we start with the worker. Given the setup above, the

    problem the worker i faces at time t is to choose vit to maximize his consumption in

    23

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    35/136

    the evening. Formally, in the morning, he maximizes

    pit(Aitxit Iit) (1pit)xit + At1(1 vit)

    by choosing v. Since zit is not yet known at the time of decision, the problem above

    becomes in effect

    E{pit(Aitxit Iit) (1pit)xit} + At1(1 vit). (3.6)

    Before solving the workers problem, it will be convenient to specify I at this

    point. When lending xit, the banker charges Iit to hedge against the potential loss in

    case the innovation is a failure so that

    (1 + r)xit = pitIit + (1pit)xit, (3.7)

    where r is the world interest rate and exogenous.

    Solving Eq. (3.7) gives Iit as:

    Iit =

    1 +

    r

    pit

    xit. (3.8)

    One can see from Eq. (3.8) that the banker needs to be compensated for the

    risk he takes by financing the worker/innovator. As long as pit is less than one, the

    return he gets from investing in the worker/innovator is greater than what he would

    get from the endowed technology. If pit is equal to 1, then there is no uncertainty in

    this world, and therefore the banker does not need to be compensated for investing

    in the worker/innovator, which is as safe as the endowed transformation technology.

    Also, note that those innovators with low probabilities of success are imposed higher

    repayment requirements. In this world, the bankers do not weed out the bad innova-

    tors as in King and Levine (1993). Instead, they impose higher penalties and let the

    borrowers make the optimal decision.

    24

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    36/136

    Going back to the workers problem, When z is revealed in the afternoon, the

    probability of success is now known to the worker/innovator. Then, the workers

    problem after z is revealed is

    pit(Aitxit Iit) (1pit)xit. (3.9)

    Differentiating Eq. (3.9) with respect to xit gives:

    xit =

    Aitpit1 + r

    . (3.10)

    Using Eq. (3.10) and Eq. (3.6), the workers problem before z is revealed can be

    described as:

    maxv

    CEn

    (Aitpit)1

    1

    o(3.11)

    where CR

    11

    1

    . Since the innovators are randomly and uniformly located

    around the circumference of the island,

    E(p1

    1

    it ) =1

    dt

    Zdt0

    ezit1 dzit. (3.12)

    Noting that Ait = (vit)At1, Eq. (3.11) becomes:

    maxv

    (vit)

    1 A1

    1

    t1

    1

    dt

    (1 e

    dt1 )C, (3.13)

    where C is as defined above. Differentiating Eq. (3.13) with respect to v gives:

    vit = D

    1 e

    dt1

    dt

    ! 1+1

    (3.14)

    where D

    At1(1 )11R(1)

    1+1 . Eq. (3.14) shows that the opti-

    mal fraction of manna to be spent on receiving education depends on d. Note that by

    symmetry, vit = v

    jt for i 6= j.

    25

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    37/136

    Next, we examine the behavior of the banker. Given the setup from the previous

    section, the banker will decide to enter and finance the worker/innovator only if the

    expected average profit from financing is greater than expected average screening

    costs. Hence, the entry condition for the representative banker is

    E{pitIit + (1pit)xit} = E(ez). (3.15)

    It follows then that the decision rule for the banker is given by:

    vit =

    1

    1

    R

    A

    1

    (edt 1

    1 edt1

    )1

    (3.16)

    where R = 1 + r.

    On this island, the equilibrium values of vit and Nt(=12dt

    ) are jointly determined

    by the decisions of the worker/innovator and the banker, represented by Eq. (3.14)

    and Eq. (3.16) respectively. Differentiating Eq. (3.14) with respect to d, we find

    that how v responds to changes in d depends on the values of two parameters, and

    . Specifi

    cally, if + 6 1, the optimal level of education, v, rises as more bankers

    enter since v/d 6 0. In other words, the workers would devote a larger fraction of

    the manna to obtain education if there is a larger number of bankers in the economy.

    If + > 1, the opposite situation occurs. By contrast, Eq. (3.16) shows that

    the bankers optimal level of d rises as the workers increase their efforts to receive

    education.

    In the steady state, vit = v and dt = d

    (or Nt = N) by symmetry. These

    relations imply that pit = pi and xit = xi because zit = zi. Then, since the average

    output per worker thats produced using a new technology is AtE(pixi ), the total

    26

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    38/136

    output produced by using new technologies is given by:

    yHt = L(v)At1E(pix

    i ). (3.17)

    Total output produced using old technologies is given by:

    yLt = LAt1(1 v). (3.18)

    Then the total aggregate output in equilibrium at time t is given by

    yt = At1L

    (v)E(pixi ) + (1 v

    )

    . (3.19)

    Finally, the growth rate of the economy at the steady state is:

    log

    yt+1

    yt

    = log

    At

    At1

    = log(v) (3.20)

    Hence, the growth of the economy is driven by the level of efforts the workers exert

    to receive education (v), which is jointly determined by the bankers and the workers,

    the idea production parameter, , and effectiveness of the educational system, .

    3.3 Discussion

    As noted above, the behavior of the economy in equilibrium is dependent upon

    the summed values of two parameters, and . Evidence from economic growth

    literature tells us that the value of is typically estimated to be roughly between

    0.3 and 0.4. As for the value of , there is no practical way to measure as its

    estimation essentially requires, among other things, separating out and measuring

    the technological changes that results from human capital accumulation. However,

    it is reasonable to argue that since there is no reason to believe that the value of ,a

    27

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    39/136

    parameter that governs the degree of diminishing marginal returns to human capital,

    would be much different from that of , the sum of and is likely to be less than

    1. Accordingly, the model has an implication that for a given value of v, there exists

    a unique value of d that is optimal, and vice versa for reasonable parameter values

    (Figure 3.2).

    The model presented in this chapter has some interesting policy implications.

    Firstly, the tougher the government toward the financial sector, the better it is for

    the economy. A rise in the stringency of policy rules, , shifts graph B in Figure

    (3.2) to the left, inducing a higher level of human capital accumulation and a fasterrate of economic growth. Another implication is that the economy of this island

    will not benefit from those financial policies that aim to raise the number of banks

    without paying attention to the fundamentals of the economy. When d is artificially

    lowered, say, by the government, the value of v that is optimal to the workers becomes

    greater than that of v optimal to the bankers. Hence, over time, the bankers will

    begin to suffer losses, and, as a consequence, some bankers have to exit in order

    for the economy to restore its equilibrium. This is in line with experiences of Latin

    American and Asian countries. Beginning around the mid-1980s, these countries have

    implemented financial policies that aimed to encourage competition by inducing more

    entry, but often failed to address the issue of whether and how the fundamentals of

    their economies would adapt to such policy changes. One of the results of these

    policies was, as we know, rather catastrophic. In some instances, the failure of the

    banking sector was so severe as to cause an economy-wide financial crisis. This

    model provides an explanation for how financial liberalization policies that ignore the

    fundamentals of the economy can lead to bank failures, and ultimately financial crisis.

    28

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    40/136

    Secondly, the model is able to explain the existence of poverty trap without in-

    troducing setup costs. Furthermore, it suggests that two kinds of poverty traps may

    exist. Firstly, deterioration in the effectiveness of the education system induces the

    workers to receive less education, pushing graph W to the left, while shifting graph

    B in the same direction. On net, the deterioration of the education system leads to a

    lower equilibrium level of d. On the other hand, its effect on v is uncertain. However,

    if the workers are more susceptible to deterioration of the education system than the

    bankers are, the economy would be stuck in the poverty trap despite the presence

    of a large number of banks (Figure 3.3). Therefore, it is possible that a large finan-

    cial sector coexists with slow growth of the economy. Secondly, in contrast to the

    preceding case, there can be a poverty trap with only a small number of bankers in

    the economy as well. This happens when the financial regulations become lax. For

    instance, if the regulations regarding the screening processes become relaxed, perhaps

    as part of ill-designed liberalization policies, it causes a drop in the equilibrium values

    of the number of bankers present in the economy and human capital accumulated,

    leading to a slower growth.

    Another possibility that has been ignored so far is the case of + > 1. If this were

    the case, then the bankers and the workers on this island live in a strange world. Since

    it is not possible to analytically examine this case because of the number of parameters

    involved, only a qualitative discussion is provided. First of all, depending on the

    parameter values, indeterminacy could arise. Secondly, if the parameter values are

    such that the bankers are more inelastic than the workers, a rise in actually reduces

    the human capital accumulation and, thus, hinders economic growth. However, it

    should be reminded again that this scenario is an unlikely depiction of the real world

    29

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    41/136

    given the commonly accepted idea of what the values of these two parameters , and

    , should be.

    3.4 Conclusion

    The exact nature of the relationship between finance and growth has been the

    subject of heated debates for many years. Consequently, many models have been

    proposed to shed light on this issue. One strand of this literature investigates the role

    of the financial sector in promoting innovative activities. This chapter is part that

    literature.

    The approach I take to investigate the link between the financial sector and eco-

    nomic growth focuses on the role of the financial sector in financing innovative activi-

    ties. It is motivated by increasing empirical evidence that technological advancement

    is a key to economic growth. To study this link, I start with the proposition that

    human and financial capital act as complements in the production function of ideas.

    Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is assumed that the role of the financial sector

    in this model is to screen the innovators for their probabilities of success. However,

    unlike King and Levines version of the financial sector that plays an active screening

    role of weeding out bad entrepreneurs, the financial sector I consider plays a passive

    role of assessing and conveying the probability of success to the innovators so that

    the latter can make optimal borrowing decisions.

    In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional literature in four impor-

    tant ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when it is realized but when

    it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by observations that not

    all innovations are implemented in the production processes. Secondly, I assume that

    30

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    42/136

    the magnitude of technological change an innovator comes up with is a function of

    that innovators human capital. Thirdly, it is assumed in this model that external

    finance is needed not for R&D activities but for utilization of innovations. Finally, it

    is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs.

    My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

    equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

    of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

    financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

    economy can bring about bank failures and possibly afi

    nancial crisis. Furthermore,in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

    costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

    there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

    the other with a large number of bankers.

    31

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    43/136

    32

    Screening costs for Screening costs for

    Banker B Banker B

    A B B A

    Screening costs forBanker A

    -2dt -dt 0 dt 2dt

    Note) The vertical axis measures the costs of screening. The horizontal axis measures the

    distance between adjoining bankers.

    Figure 3.1: Screening costs of competing bankers

    Banker B Banker BBanker A

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    44/136

    33

    Note) The figure above describes the equilibrium of the economy when 1 + < . (W)

    represents the decision rule of the worker/innovator given by Eq. (3.14). (B) represents

    that of the banker given by Eq. (3.16).

    Figure 3.2: Equilibrium when 1 + <

    v

    d

    (W)

    (B)

    v*

    d*

    (B)

    d

    v'

    Rise in

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    45/136

    34

    Note) The figure above describes how the economy responds to deterioration of the

    education system when 1 + < . (W) represents the decision rule of the

    worker/innovator given by Eq. (3.14). (B) represents that of the banker given by Eq.

    (3.16).

    Figure 3.3: Effects of deterioration in education

    v

    d

    (W)

    (B)

    v*

    d*

    (B)

    d

    v'

    (W)

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    46/136

    CHAPTER 4

    How Does Financial Development Promote Growth?

    4.1 Introduction

    What makes an economy grow? Much research has been done to identify the

    determinants of economic growth. Among suggested factors, researchers found that

    generally investment is one of the most important determinants of economic growth.

    This is not surprising. As a child needs a constant supply of nourishment to develop

    properly, so does an economy to realize sustained development and growth. Only

    that for the economy, nourishment would be in the form of investment in factors of

    production such as physical and human capitals and technologies. I start from this

    basic proposition that investment in factors of production is one of the fundamental

    forces that drive economic growth.

    Investment in factors of production generally necessitates the use of funds. The

    problem is that the amount of funds is often limited compared to the number of

    investment opportunities available and therefore should be allocated to more produc-

    tive investment opportunities. Then, who is responsible for allocating these funds

    among various investment opportunities? Any undergraduate student who took a

    money-and-banking class will tell you with certainty that the answer to the question

    35

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    47/136

    is the financial sector.2 Indeed, that is what conventional textbooks teach us: one

    of the basic roles of the financial sector is to allocate funds efficiently. However, the

    existence of the financial sector by itself does not guarantee that the allocation will

    be efficient. Financial sectors exist in various forms and differ in their level of so-

    phistication across countries. Then, in the presence of asymmetric information, those

    financial sectors that are relatively more developed will be more able to efficiently

    screen out bad investment opportunities. Then, to the extent that investment is an

    important determinant of economic growth, it follows that the degree of development

    of the financial sector should matter for economic growth. However, albeit much re-

    search, there is much controversy among professional economists regarding the role of

    the financial sector in promoting economic growth. And, those studies that do show a

    positive relationship between GDP per capita growth and a financial development in-

    dicator have been criticized for not accounting for a possible endogenous relationship

    in their estimations. Furthermore, it was argued that the existing empirical studies

    in general do not show how the financial sector does affect growth.

    The goal of this paper is to tackle these two main issues. The strategy I take is to

    focus on a potential channel of influence from the financial sector to the real sector.

    By doing so, I am able to ameliorate the problem of endogeneity as well as to shed

    some light on the largely ignored question of how the financial sector affects economic

    growth.

    2 In this paper, terms such as financial intermediation, financial sector, and banking sector will

    be used interchangeably when there is no confusion.

    36

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    48/136

    4.2 Related Literature

    4.2.1 Theories of the finance-led growth hypothesis

    The origin of the finance-led growth hypothesis can be traced back to Bagehot

    (1873). Early studies by Goldsmith (1969), McKinnon (1973), and Shaw (1973)

    constitute a first systematic investigation into the link between the financial sector

    and the real sector. Although they found a positive relationship between these two

    sectors, the finance-led growth hypothesis did not receive much attention at the time

    due to the lack of a formal theoretical foundation to back the empirical findings.

    Under the exogenous growth regime, the only way thefi

    nancial sector could aff

    ect thegrowth rate of an economy was via technological innovation, which was not modeled

    adequately by then-existing growth theories. With the arrival of endogenous growth

    theories, the finance-led growth hypothesis received renewed attention. In a world

    governed by endogenous growth theories, the growth rate of an economy can be

    enhanced not only by an increase in productivity growth but also by either an increase

    in the effi

    ciency of capital accumulation or an increase in the savings rate.

    Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and Bencievenga and Smith (1991) observe that

    the primary role the banking sector plays is the provision of liquidity and argue

    that, by providing liquidity, the banking sector enables more investments in illiq-

    uid/productive assets and thereby enhances the efficiency of capital accumulation

    and economic growth. Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1995) study an alternative way

    the banking sector can enhance the efficiency of capital accumulation where a re-

    duction of agency costs due to financial development allows a larger share of savings

    to be channeled into investments. However, whether or not financial development

    positively affects savings rate is not a clear-cut issue. For example, Devereux and

    37

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    49/136

    Smith (1994) show that a reduction in idiosyncratic risk and the rate of return risk

    may either reduce or increase savings rates depending on the degree of risk aversion

    of economic agents. Furthermore, Japelli and Pagano (1994) show that reducing liq-

    uidity constraints reduces savings since the younger generation in their model borrow

    much more in the absence of liquidity constraints. Saint-Paul (1992) builds a model

    where the financial sector allows more specialization in productive and risky tech-

    nology by reducing idiosyncratic risks. More to the spirit of ideas-driven economic

    growth, but not quite, Galetovic (1996) studies the interaction between the financial

    sector and the research sector. In his model, the financial sector plays the indirect

    role of economizing the costs of monitoring research firms for investors. Contrary to

    these models where the financial sector promotes the process of learning by doing,

    King and Levine (1993) consider the financial intermediaries as actively involved in

    the production of ideas itself by screening and monitoring innovative projects.

    It is rather odd to note that the theory of the finance-led growth was revived

    by the birth of endogenous growth theories, and yet the researchers have paid only

    scant attention, with an exception of King and Levine (1993), on the effects offinan-

    cial development on innovative activities in examining the validity of the finance-led

    growth hypothesis. In the context of both exogenous and endogenous growth theo-

    ries, the ultimate engine of economic growth is a rise in the productivity level as an

    outcome of either learning by doing or intentional effort to come up with a better

    technology. Also, Easterly and Levine (2001) show that the residual rather than

    factor accumulation accounts for most of the income and growth differences across

    countries. Further, the importance of purposive technological innovation in enhanc-

    ing productivity is well illustrated by the amount of effort a large number of countries

    38

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    50/136

    put into establishing a robust R&D sector. Based on these observations and the fact

    that investment in R&D requires funds, at least partly, from the financial sector, I

    argue that if the finance-led growth hypothesis is correct, then we should be able to

    detect evidence of positive effects offinancial development on innovation. Therefore,

    my aim in this paper is to examine this particular channel of influence. In doing so,

    I hope to shed further light on the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis.

    4.2.2 Empirical studies

    A flood of empirical studies began to appear in the 1990s to test the validity of

    the finance-led growth hypothesis. Unfortunately, theoretical models of finance-led

    growth do not provide empirical researchers with structural guidelines on which they

    can base their estimation. As a result, one is forced to use reduced-form estimation

    and test the general conclusion of these models. Since the implication of all the

    theoretical models in this area is basically that a better-developed financial sector

    enhances economic growth, regardless of the channel of influence, a typical test strat-

    egy involves regressing some indicator of financial development on some aggregate

    growth measures such as investment growth, GDP growth or total factor productiv-

    ity growth. A first attempt in this direction was made by employing cross-sectional

    estimation (King and Levine, 1993, and De Gregorio and Guidotti, 1995). Using a

    cross-sectional framework, they find a positive relationship between financial develop-

    ment and economic growth. However, a potentially endogenous relationship between

    financial development and economic growth made interpretation of these results diffi-

    cult. Demetriades and Hussein (1996) and Odedokun (1996) take a Granger causality

    39

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    51/136

    approach to avoid these problems and present mixed results. They find that the ef-

    fects offinancial development on growth are country-specific. Based on their findings,

    they argue that a robust test of the finance-led growth hypothesis should incorporate

    the time dimension of the data under consideration. Benhabib and Spiegel (2000)

    employ a panel GMM method to reach a similar conclusion.

    By and large, the current empirical literature lacks one crucial element in that

    they do not consider the channels of influence suggested by theoretical models and

    fail to show how financial development affects economic growth. Furthermore, time-

    series approach, while potentially resolving endogeneity issue, does not tell us exactly

    what the relationship between these two is. In addition, their results are as hard

    to interpret as cross-sectional estimation because Granger causality does not really

    provide an answer for the causal relationship between financial development and eco-

    nomic growth. Researchers who conduct causality tests in this area argue that, for

    some countries, economic growth causes financial development, when what they re-

    ally need to say is that economic growth Granger-causes financial development. This

    does not really address the question of what causes what, especially when one con-

    siders that, statistically, Christmas card sales Granger-cause Christmas. In sum, the

    current empirical literature suffers from two problems. First, as long as one regresses

    GDP growth on a measure of financial development, the issue of endogeneity is not

    satisfactorily resolved. Second, the channel of influence has not been specified so far,

    thus, limiting our understanding of how the financial sector affects growth.

    In order to examine the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis, I depart

    from the conventional literature. Instead of estimating a relationship between ag-

    gregate growth measures and financial development indicators as is commonly done

    40

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    52/136

    in the current literature, I test the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis by

    focusing on the innovation channel of influence, using patent applications as a proxy

    for innovative output. Under the framework of ideas-driven growth, the hypothesis

    I test is that financial development enhances innovation, which is the main engine

    of economic growth. If the finance-led growth hypothesis is right, as the financial

    sector develops over time in a certain country, the growth rate of innovation should

    be higher, which would, then, lead to faster economic growth due to a rising level

    of productivity. Using panel data on twenty eight countries from 1970 to 2000, my

    analysis shows that financial development is indeed significant in raising the growth

    rate of innovative output.

    In section 2, I provide a theoretical motivation for the empirical analysis by ex-

    tending a standard Romer-type growth model to include agency costs and draw a

    testable implication. In section 3, I discuss the estimation strategy employed and the

    issues that need to be addressed. In section 4, I conclude.

    4.3 Theoretical background

    One of the common assumptions made in finance-led growth theories is that the

    financial sector (mainly the banking sector) actively monitors borrowers of funds.

    Allen and Gale (2001) show that evidence is to the contrary. They show that in most

    cases, the banking sector does not serve as an active monitor. The rationale for this is

    that often times the banking sector makes a debt contract with the borrowers in which

    profits of a lending bank are not dependent upon the borrowers degree of success.

    Rather, they simply depend on whether the borrower succeeds or not.3 Therefore,

    3 Of course, this is not the case for equity contracts. However, in most cases, equity markets arerelatively small in terms of intermediating funds and are ignored in this paper.

    41

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    53/136

    the welfare of the lending bank will depend more on how well it screens out the bad

    borrowers and less on its effectiveness as a monitor. Based on this observation, I

    extend a standard Romer-type endogenous growth model and include the financial

    sector as a provider of funds for researchers with agency costs to illustrate how the

    degree offinancial development affects the rate of technological innovation. Note that

    agency costs in this model represent the costs of screening for the financial sector.

    The goal of the model is, thus, to show that high agency costs discourage innovation

    and growth of the economy.

    4.3.1 Final goods sector

    A perfectly competitive final goods sector produces a single homogenous consump-

    tion good by combining labor and intermediate goods. The production function for

    the final goods sector is given by

    Y =

    AZ0

    xj dj, (4.1)

    where A is the number of intermediate goods used and x is the amount of inter-

    mediate good j used and is between 0 and 1. Given this production function, and

    normalizing the price offinal goods to one, a firm in the final goods sector maximizes

    its profit;R

    xj dj RA0

    pjxjdj, where pj is the price of an intermediate good j. Profit

    maximization gives the price of an intermediate good j as

    pj = x1j . (4.2)

    4.3.2 Intermediate goods sector

    The intermediate goods sector consists of monopolistic firms that buy designs from

    the research sector to be used in production of intermediate goods. These firms are

    42

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    54/136

    monopolistic since the designs they buy are protected by patents that exclude others

    from using the same designs. Therefore, each monopolist produces only one type of

    intermediate good. With the design in hand, the monopolist produces intermediate

    goods using a one-to-one production function. In other words, the monopolist requires

    one unit of capital to produce one unit of intermediate good.

    Formally, the monopolist maximizes the profit function given by:

    pj(xj)xj rxj, (4.3)

    where r is the interest rate for borrowing capital. The firms supply ofxj derived from

    the profit maximization, together with the demand schedule in Eq.(4.2), determines

    the price of xj to be equal to r/, which implies that xj = x and, consequently, that

    Y = Ax.

    Using Eq.(4.2) and pj = r/, we get x = 2Y/Ar. Then, the profit for each

    monopolist can be specified as;

    I = (p

    r)x

    = (1 )Y

    A. (4.4)

    Further, since the total amount of the intermediate goods used in the final goods

    sectorRA0

    xidi = Ax, should be equal to the total amount of capital spent in the

    intermediate goods sector, (1aK)K, x is equal to (1 aK)K/A. Note that (1 aK)

    is the portion of capital stock used in the intermediate goods sector, and K is the

    total stock of capital in the economy. Finally, the production function turns out to

    be

    Y = A1[(1 aK)K]. (4.5)

    43

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    55/136

    4.3.3 The research sector

    Recall that my primary goal in this section is to provide a theoretical sketch of

    how financial development affects innovation. I aim to show here that the share of

    capital spent in research sector is increasing in the degree offinancial development as

    proxied by lower agency costs.

    In this model, each researcher faces a similar problem as the monopolist in the

    intermediate goods sector. In other words, each researcher borrows capital from the

    financial sector to finance her innovation. What is different from the monopolists

    case is that the researchers cost of borrowing capital is not r but r + c where c

    is the exogenous agency costs. The researcher pays an additional cost of c because

    the financial sector has to screen the researchers when they borrow funds. With

    this environment, the researcher tries to maximize her profit based on her production

    function. I make a standard assumption that when the researcher innovates, she takes

    the actions of other researchers and the knowledge stock as given so that she faces

    the arrival rate of defined as:

    = A1[aKK]1, (4.6)

    where stands for the arrival rate of new technology per unit of capital spent on

    innovation at the individual researchers level.

    When a new technology is developed, assuming that the design lasts forever, the

    researcher receives a price, pA which is equal to the monopolists profit discounted by

    r, (1 )x/. Since x = 2Y/Ar,

    pA =(1 )Y

    rA. (4.7)

    44

  • 8/6/2019 Finance and Economic Development

    56/136

    Given the price pA and the arrival rate , the marginal product of capital spent in

    the research sector equals simply pA. Equating this to the marginal cost of capital,

    r + c, and noting that r = 2Y

    (1aK)K, I get the share of capital used in the research

    sector as:

    1

    (1 aK)

    K

    A

    = a1K

    "2

    A

    K

    11

    1 aK

    1+ c

    #. (4.8)

    Although the Eq. (4.8) cannot be solved explicitly for aK, it can be seen that

    there exists a