Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

85
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Consumer Demand Analysis

description

Finance 30210: Managerial Economics. Consumer Demand Analysis. We can begin our representation of the consumer with a demand function…. Is a function of…. Quantity demanded. Price. Income. Prices of Compliments. Prices of Substitutes. Price. $20. Quantity. 40. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Page 1: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Consumer Demand Analysis

Page 2: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

We can begin our representation of the consumer with a demand function…

csd PPIPDQ ,,,

Quantity demanded

Is a function of…

Price IncomePrices of Substitutes

Prices of Compliments

Quantity

10,40,100 cs PPID

Price

$20

40

10,40,100,2040 D

Page 3: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Given a demand function we can characterize the behavior of demand with elasticity..

Quantity

cs PPID ,,

Price

PQd

p

%

%

$20

$15

40 60

%25% P

%50% dQ

225

50

p

Price elasticity will always be a negative number

Page 4: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

100ID

Price

$20

40 56

41040

I

IQd

I

%

%

Income elasticity will generally be a positive number

Given a demand function we can characterize the behavior of demand with elasticity..

110ID

%40% dQ

%10% I

Page 5: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

40sPD

Price

$20

40 44

5.2010

sP

s

dP P

Qs

%%

Cross price elasticity will be a positive number for substitutes

Given a demand function we can characterize the behavior of demand with elasticity..

48sPD

%10% dQ

%20% sP

Page 6: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

14cPD

Price

$20

32 40

5.4020

I

c

dP P

Qc

%%

Cross price elasticity will be a negative number for compliments

Given a demand function we can characterize the behavior of demand with elasticity..

10sPD

%20% dQ

%40% sP

Page 7: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Note that if the demand relationship is linear, elasticity is not constant

csd ePdPcIbPaQ

QPb

QP

PQ

PQ

p

p

dp

%

%

QIc

QI

IQ

IQ

I

p

dp

%

%

QPd s

Ps

QPe c

Pc

Page 8: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

For example….

IPQd 0025.260

Quantity

000,40ID

Price

$30

100

1100

000,400025.

6.100302

I

p

$80

Page 9: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Let’s try something a little more complicated…a non-linear demand relationship

221

02.2100 IPQd

Quantity

20ID

Price

$400

29.68

400 21

21

21

QP

QPP

QP

PQ

p

$2916

68

24.682004.04.04.

22

Q

IQII

QI

IQ

I

Page 10: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

Quantity

40ID

Price

$12

40

IPd eQ 012.15.150

LN(Quantity)

40ID

Price

$12

3.7

IPd eLNQLN 012.15.150

.15 .012150 P IdLN Q LN LN e

IPQLN d 01215.5

Page 11: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

40ID

Price

$12

40

IPd eQ 012.15.150

8.11215.15.150

150)15(.15.150 012.15.

012.15.012.15.

P

ePe

QPe

QP

PQ

IP

IPIP

p

48.40012.012.150150)012(.012.150 012.15.

012.15.012.15.

I

eIe

QIe

QI

PQ

IP

IPIP

I

Page 12: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

A little math trick…recall the derivative of the natural log

xxx 1ln

xxx

ln

This just says that the difference in logs is a percentage change

Therefore, if we start with elasticity

PPQ

PQ

PQ

p

ln

%ln

%%

Page 13: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

LN(Quantity)

40ID

Price

$12

3.7

IPQLN d 01215.5

8.11215.15.ln%%

PPPQ

PQ

p

48.40012.012.ln%%

IIIQ

IQ

I

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

Page 14: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

Quantity

40ID

Price

$10

3

IQ ePe d 045.65.16

Quantity

40ID

LN(Price)

2.3

3

IQ ePLNeLN d 045.65.16

Id eLNPLNLNQ 045.65.16

IPLNQd 045.65.7.2

Page 15: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

Quantity

40ID

LN(Price)

2.3

3

IPLNQd 045.65.7.2

22.365.165.1

ln%%

QQP

QPQ

p

6.340045.045.

%%

QI

QI

IQ

IQ

I

Page 16: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

Quantity

40ID

Price

$5

8.8

4.12.135. IPQd

LN(Quantity)

40ID

LN(Price)

1.6

2.2

4.12.135. IPLNQLN d

4.12.135. ILNPLNLNQLN d

ILNPLNQLN d 4.12.104.1

Page 17: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Sometimes we use demand functions that are linear in logs…

LN(Quantity)

40ID

LN(Price)

1.6

2.2

ILNPLNQLN d 4.12.104.1

2.1lnln

%%

PQ

PQ

p

4.1lnln

%%

IQ

IQ

I

Log linear demand curves have constant elasticities!

Page 18: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that you setting prices for US Air. You know that you face the following demand curve for the New York/Chicago Shuttle…

Quantity

Price

$200

400

PQ 41200

$80,000 If you wanted to increase revenues, should you increase or decrease your price?D

Page 19: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$199

400

PQ 41200

$80,396

D

PQTR

PPTR 41200

241200 PPTR

PP

TR 81200

40020081200

PTR

If you wanted to increase revenues, should you increase or decrease your price?

You should decrease price. A $1 price decrease will raise revenues by $400

$200

404

Why didn’t revenue go up by $400?

Page 20: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$150

400

PQ 41200

$90,000D

241200 PPTR

081200 P

PTR

150$P

Suppose that you wanted to maximize revenues?

$200

600

Page 21: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Now, let’s go about this a little differently…

Quantity

Price

$200

400

PQ 41200

$80,000

24002004

p

PQTR

QPTR %%%

PPTR p %%%

PTR p %1%

PTR %%

Every 1% drop in price will raise revenues by 1%

D

Page 22: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Using the point elasticity gives you the same answer…

Quantity

Price

$200

400

PQ 41200

$86,400

$180

480

%8100*000,80

000,80400,86

Why didn’t revenues go up by 10%?

5.14801804

p

PTR %5.%

D

Page 23: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

We could also maximize revenues using elasticity…

QuantityD

Price

$150

600

PQ 41200 PTR p %1%

When the elasticity hits -1, revenues stop growing when you lower your price.

14

QP

p

141200

4

PP

PP 412004 150$P

$90,000

Page 24: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

QuantityD

Price

$150

600

PQ 41200

QuantityD

Price

$200

600

$250

$140

$50

$90,000 2.0p

875.p

2p

5p

PDQ

Obviously, the more information you have, the better decisions you will make…

The best pricing decisions would come from a demand curve

However, knowing a few elasticities is quite helpful as well!

Revenue maximizing price Revenue maximizing price

Page 25: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that you setting prices for US Air. You know that you face the following demand curve for the New York/Chicago Shuttle…

IPQ 241000 Suppose that median income is equal to $50,000.

Income in thousands

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

$75,000

Suppose that a recession causes a 20% drop in income. How much would we have to lower our price if we wanted to keep sales constant?

Page 26: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

40241000600 P

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

$72,000

Suppose that a recession causes a 20% drop in income. How much would we have to lower our price if we wanted to keep sales constant?

Now income is $40,000

IPQ 241000

120P

$120

20102 Q

2054 Q

Page 27: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Now, again with elasticity…

Suppose that median income is equal to $50,000.

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

$75,000

83.6001254

p

17.600502

I

Suppose that a recession causes a 20% drop in income. How much would we have to lower our price if we wanted to keep sales constant?

IPQ 241000

Page 28: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

4.32017.% Q

4.31.483.% Q

IPQ Ip %%%

2017.%83.0 P

$123

1.4% P

1.4% P

Suppose that a recession causes a 20% drop in income. How much would we have to lower our price if we wanted to keep sales constant?

83.p

17.I

$73,800

Page 29: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

$75,000

QuantityD

Price

$125

600

$75,000

83.p

17.I

IPQ 241000 IPDQ ,

Again, the more information you have, the better decisions you will make…

The best pricing decisions would come from a demand curve

However, knowing a few elasticities is quite helpful as well!

Page 30: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Now, suppose that you realized that you actually faced two types of customers : Recreational and business travelers. Could you do better?

QuantityD

Price

$150

500Quantity

D

Price

$150

100

PQB 2800

Business

PQR 2400

Recreational

$400

$200

$75,000

$15,000

6.p

3p

Page 31: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Recall the aggregate demand curve we had previously….what we had was actually a piece of what aggregate demand really looked like

QuantityD

Price

$200

600

PQB 2800

$400

$90,000

PQR 2400

At a price above $200, recreational travelers don’t fly. The only demand is coming from business travelers.

At a price below $200, we now have two types of demanders flying.

+

PQ 41200 $150

400

Could we do better?

PQ 2800

Page 32: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that we decided to ignore recreational travelers and cater to business clients…

QuantityD

Price

$200

600

$400

$80,000PQ 41200

400

No…that’s not a good idea!

PQ 2800 22800 PPPQTR 04800

P

PTR

200$P

Page 33: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Why don’t we just charge them different prices?

QuantityD

Price

$200

400Quantity

D

Price

$100

200

200$

4800

2800

28002

P

PP

TRPPTR

PQB

Business Recreational

$400

$200

$80,000

$20,000

100$

4400

2400

24002

P

PP

TRPPTR

PQR

1p1p

Page 34: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$200

$400

The real question is: Is this feasible to do empirically?

This is “the Truth”. Two types of individuals making purchasing decisions. Individual decisions added up across all individuals create an aggregate demand curve.

PQ 2400 PQ 2800

$200 ,41200

200$ ,2800PPPP

Q

Page 35: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$200

$400

If you do a linear estimation, what you end up with something like this…not really what we want

bPaQ

$200 ,41200

200$ ,2800PPPP

Q

bPaQ

Page 36: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

However, if you put a dummy variable in the regression for business/recreational traveler, you could get at the truth…

Quantity

Price

$200

$400

PQ 2400 PQ 2800

cDbPaQ bPaQ

cDbPaQ

Business ,1

Recreation ,0D

YES! We can do this!

Page 37: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Now, lets change it up a little….

QuantityD

Price

$150

450Quantity

D

Price

$150

150

PQB 600

Business

PQR 3600

Recreational

$600

$200

$67,500

$22,500

33.p

3p

Page 38: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Now, if we charge different prices….

QuantityD

Price

$300

300Quantity

D

Price

$100

300

$600

$200

$90,000

$30,000

300$

2600

600

6002

P

PP

TRPPTR

PQB

Business

1p

100$

6600

3600

36002

P

PP

TRPPTR

PQB

Recreational

1p

Page 39: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$200

$600

Again, we have to ask: Is this feasible to do empirically?

This is “the Truth”. Two types of individuals making purchasing decisions. Individual decisions added up across all individuals create an aggregate demand curve.

PQR 3600

PQB 600

PQ 41200

$300

PQB 600PQR 3600 +

Page 40: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$200

$600

PQR 3600

PQB 600

bPaQ

If you do a linear estimation, what you end up with something like this…

bPaQ

Page 41: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

$200

$600

PQR 3600

PQB 600

cDbPaQ

What if we tried the dummy variable trick…

Q a bP cD

Business ,1

Recreation ,0D

bPaQ

We’re Screwed! Time to try something else.

Page 42: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Here’s the process that takes place in the economy…

Individual consumers have preferences over a variety of goods…they have limited incomes and face market prices. Consumers make choices on what to buy

P

QD

P

QD

P

QD

P

QD

Individual decisions can be represented by individual demand curves

P

QD

The market aggregates those decisions into a market demand curve

Page 43: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Here is the problem we face…

P

QD

We can estimate a market demand curve…

P

QD

P

QD

P

QD

P

QD

The problem is that the market demand often tells us very little about what is happening in the background…

Page 44: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

So, here is how we attack the problem…

We see if we can come up with a numerical representation of preferences…

P

QD

P

QD

P

QD

P

D

We then derive the resulting demand curves that come from the consumer choice problem…

P

QD

We then aggregate the individual demand curves to get a market demand. This we can compare to aggregate data to see if we are correct

Page 45: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

How do we get an understanding of consumer preferences? We observe what they do!

Television ACost = $500

Television BCost = $2500

Suppose you walk into the store with a choice between two TVs.

Suppose that you choose Television A

Either you prefer Television A or you can’t afford Television B

Suppose that you choose Television B You must prefer Television B

Page 46: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that you observed the following consumer behavior

P(Bananas) = $4/lb.P(Apples) = $2/Lb.

Q(Bananas) = 10lbsQ(Apples) = 20lbs

P(Bananas) = $3/lb.P(Apples) = $3/Lb.

Q(Bananas) = 15lbsQ(Apples) = 15lbs

What can you say about this consumer?

Is strictly preferred to

Choice A

Choice B

Choice B Choice A

How do we know this?

Page 47: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Consumers reveal their preferences through their observed choices!

P(Bananas) = $4/lb.P(Apples) = $2/Lb.

Q(Bananas) = 10lbsQ(Apples) = 20lbs

P(Bananas) = $3/lb.P(Apples) = $3/Lb.

Q(Bananas) = 15lbsQ(Apples) = 15lbs

Cost = $80 Cost = $90

Cost = $90 Cost = $90

B Was chosen even though A was the same price!

Choice A Choice B

Page 48: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

What about this choice?

P(Bananas) = $2/lb.P(Apples) = $4/Lb.

Q(Bananas) = 25lbsQ(Apples) = 10lbs

Q(Bananas) = 10lbsQ(Apples) = 20lbs

Cost = $90

Q(Bananas) = 15lbsQ(Apples) = 15lbs

Cost = $90

Cost = $100

Is strictly preferred to Choice C Choice B

Choice C

Is choice C preferred to choice A?

Choice B

Choice A

Page 49: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Is strictly preferred to Choice B Choice A

Is strictly preferred to Choice C Choice B

Is strictly preferred to Choice C Choice A

Rational preferences exhibit transitivity

C > B > A

Page 50: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Consumer theory begins with the assumption that every consumer has preferences over various combinations of consumer goods. Its usually convenient to represent these preferences with a utility function

BAU :

A BU

Set of possible consumption choices “Utility Value”

Page 51: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Q(Bananas) = 25lbsQ(Apples) = 10lbs

Q(Bananas) = 10lbsQ(Apples) = 20lbs

Q(Bananas) = 15lbsQ(Apples) = 15lbs

Choice C

Choice A

Choice B

Using the previous example (Recall, C > B > A)

)20,10()15,15()10,25( UUU

Page 52: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

We require that utility functions satisfy a few basic properties

20),( yxUx

y

A

B

C

BUCU

BUAUAUCU

)()(

There is a definite ranking of all choices (i.e. transitivity)

25),( yxU

This tells us that indifference curves can’t cross on another

Page 53: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

20),( yxU

x

y

A

B

C BUCU

BUAUAUCU

)()(

We run into a problem!

25),( yxU

Suppose that indifference curves did cross…

)()( CUAU

Page 54: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

20),( yxUx

y

A

B

C

More is always better!

)()( AUCU

We require that utility functions satisfy a few basic properties

Page 55: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

20),( yxUx

y

A

B

C

People Prefer Moderation!

)()( AUCU

15

5 15

5

10

10

25),( yxU

We require that utility functions satisfy a few basic properties

Note: This is a result of diminishing marginal utility…this guarantees that demand curves slope down!

Page 56: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

20),( yxUx

yA

BC

People prefer extremes!

)()( AUCU

25),( yxU

What if we didn’t have decreasing marginal utility?

Increasing marginal utility produces some weird decisions!!

Page 57: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

x

y

*y

*x

20),( yxU

We can characterize preferences with a few statistics. First, how does a consumer prefer one good relative to another.

x

yMarginal Utility of Y

Marginal Utility of X

),(),(

**

**

yxUyxUMRS

xy

y

x

The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) measures the amount of Y you need to be get in order to give up a little of X

Page 58: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) measures the amount of Y you require to give up a little of X

x

y

*y

*x

20),( yxU

)','(),( ** yxMRSyxMRS

'y

'x

If you have a lot of X relative to Y, then X is much less valuable than Y MRS is low!

Page 59: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

The elasticity of substitution measures the curvature of the indifference curve

x

y'

xy

xy

MRSxy

%

%

Elasticity of substitution measures the degree to which your valuation of X depends on your holdings of X

Page 60: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x

small is

y

x

large is

The elasticity of substitution measures the curvature of the indifference curve

If the elasticity of substitution is small, then small changes in x and y cause large changes in the MRS

If the elasticity of substitution is large, then large changes in x and y cause small changes in the MRS

MRSxy

%

%

Page 61: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

X

Y

X

Y

Elasticity of Substitution measures the degree in which you can alter the mix of goods. Consider a couple extreme cases:

Perfect substitutes can always be can always be traded off in a constant ratio

Perfect compliments have no substitutability and must me used in fixed ratios

Elasticity is 0Elasticity is Infinite

Page 62: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Consumers solve a constrained maximization – maximize utility subject to an income constraint.

),(max,

I ypx ptosubject

yxU

yx

yx

As before, set up the lagrangian…

)(),(),( ypxpIyxUyx yx

Page 63: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

)(),(),( ypxpIyxUyx yx

First Order Necessary Conditions

0),( xx pyxU

ypxpI yx

0),( yy pyxU

y

x

y

x

PP

yxUyxU

),(),(

x

x

y

y

pyxU

pyxU ),(),(

Page 64: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x

),(max0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yxU

yx

yx

xpI

ypI

*y

*x

y

x

y

x

PP

yxUyxU

),(),(

ypxpI yx

Page 65: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x

Individual demand Curves represent a summary of the individual consumer choice problem

x

xp

*x

xp

*x

ypID ,

ypI

xpI

Page 66: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x x

y

x x

small is MRS

large is MRS

xp

xp

Willingness to pay is low

Willingness to pay is high

The marginal rate of substitution controls the height of the demand curve

ypID ,

ypID ,

Page 67: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x*x

The elasticity of substitution will effect the price elasticity of the demand curve

x

xp

'x *x

xp

xp'

D

MRSxy

%

%

xx p

x

%%

ypI

xpI

xpI'

'x

Page 68: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x x

xpsmall is small is x

y

x x

xp

large is large is x

Elasticity of Substitution vs. Price Elasticity

Page 69: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

y

x x

xp0 0x

y

x x

xp

x

Perfect Complements vs. Perfect Substitutes

Page 70: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

An Example: Cobb-Douglas Utility

yxyxU ),(

yxyxU x1),(

1),( yxyxU y

xy

yxyx

yxUyxU

y

x

1

1

),(),(

),(),(

**

**

yxUyxUMRS

y

x Recall, Marginal Rate of Substitution measures the relative value of x. This will determine the intercept of the demand curve

1

Page 71: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

xyMRS

xy

MRSMRS

xy

MRSxy

*%

% 1

xy

xy

xy

MRS

MRSxy

%

%

Recall, elasticity of substitution is measuring the degree of flexibility in the consumption of X and Y and will determine the slope of the demand curve

Page 72: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

max 5.5.

0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yx

yx

yx

)(),( 5.5. ypxpIyxyx yx

y

x

y

x

pp

yxyx

yxUyxU

5.5.

5.5.

5.5.

),(),(

xppy

y

x

An Example: Cobb-Douglas Utility

Marginal Rate of Substitution

Page 73: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

max 5.5.

0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yx

yx

yx

Ixpppxp

y

xyx

Iypxp yx

y

xpIx

2

ypIy

2

An Example: Cobb-Douglas Utility

Page 74: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

x

xp

*x

xp

xp

px

px x

xxx

%%

xpIx

2

, 5.5. yxyxU

22 xx pI

px

1

22 2

x

x

xx

pIp

pI

Constant price elasticity

Page 75: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

max 5.5.

0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yx

yx

yx

xpIx

2 0

%%

xp

px

px y

yyy

Zero cross price elasticity

Page 76: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

max 5.5.

0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yx

yx

yx

xpIx

2

xI

Ix

Ix

I

%%

1

22

1

x

x

pII

p

Constant income elasticity

Page 77: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

max 5.5.

0,0

I ypx ptosubject

yx

yx

yx

xpIx

2

ypIy

2

Ipx x lnln21lnln

Ipy y lnln21lnln

Log-linear demand curves…

Page 78: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Returning to our airline example…suppose we used a customer survey or some other method and came up with preferences of airline travelers

Business Recreational

, 95.05. yAyAU

, 98.02. yAyAU

Airline Travel Everything Else

95.05.

yAMRS

1

98.02.

yAMRS

1

Different intercepts but the same slope…

Page 79: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Returning to our airline example…suppose we used a customer survey or some other method and came up with preferences of airline travelers

Business Recreational

, 95.05. yAyAU

, 98.02. yAyAU

Airline Travel Everything Else

IpA lnln05.lnln

pIA 05.

IpA lnln02.lnln

pIA 02.

Page 80: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

LN(Quantity)

LN(Price)

IpAB lnln05.lnln

IpAR lnln02.lnln +

IpA ln2ln202.ln05.lnln

We end up with something like this…

BARA A

Business

Recreation

Aggregate

We could estimate a log linear demand curve with a dummy variable to check this

dDIcpbaA lnlnln

Page 81: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that we wanted different slopes…

1,1 yxyxU

The Cobb-Douglas utility function is a special case of the CES (Constant elasticity of substitution) utility functions…

1

1

xyMRS

11

The parameter alpha will govern the marginal rate of substitution which influences the intercept of the demand curve

The parameter rho will govern the elasticity of substitution which influences the slope of the demand curve

Page 82: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Suppose that we wanted different slopes…Suppose that we wanted different slopes…

The Cobb-Douglas utility function is a special case of the CES (Constant elasticity of substitution) utility functions…

The resulting demand curve looks like this…

PIpx x lnlnlnlnln

A price index comprised of both good’s prices

1,1 yxyxU

Page 83: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Returning to our airline example…suppose we used a customer survey or some other method and came up with preferences of airline travelers

Business Recreational

95.05.

8.

yAMRS

25.1

98.02.

2.

yAMRS

5

95.05., 2.1

2.2. yxyxU

98.02., 8.1

8.8. yxyxU

Different intercepts and different slopes…

Page 84: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Returning to our airline example…suppose we used a customer survey or some other method and came up with preferences of airline travelers

PIpA lnlnln2.05.ln2.ln

Business Recreational

95.05., 2.1

2.2. yxyxU

98.02., 8.1

8.8. yxyxU

PIpA lnlnln8.02.ln8.ln

Page 85: Finance 30210: Managerial Economics

Quantity

Price

Now, we have something like this…

PIpAB lnlnln2.05.ln2.ln

PIpAR lnlnln8.02.ln8.ln +

PIpA ln2ln2ln02.ln8.05.ln2.ln

Business

Recreation

Aggregate

We could estimate a log linear demand curve to check this

PdIcpbaA lnlnlnln

RABA

A