Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The...

9

Transcript of Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The...

Page 1: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:
Page 2: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

3 The Mathematics of Sharing

3.1 Fair-Division Games

3.2 Two Players: The Divider-Chooser

Method

3.3 The Lone-Divider Method

3.4 The Lone-Chooser Method

3.5 The Last-Diminsher Method

3.6 The Method of Sealed Bids

3.7 The Method of Markers

Page 3: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 3Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

The divider-chooser method is undoubtedly the best known of all continuous fair-division methods. This method can be used anytime the fair-division game involves two players and a continuous set S (a cake, a pizza, a plot of land, etc.). Most of us have unwittingly used it at some time or another, and informally it is best known as the you cut–I choose method. As this name suggests, one player, called the divider, divides S into two shares, and the second player, called the chooser, picks the share he or she wants, leaving the other share to the divider.

Divider-Chooser Method

Page 4: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 4Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

Under the rationality and privacy assumptions we introduced in the previous section, this method guarantees that both divider and chooser will get a fair share (with two players, this means a share worth 50% or more of the total value of S). Not knowing the chooser’s likes and dislikes (privacy assumption), the divider can only guarantee himself a 50% share by dividing S into two halves of equal value (rationality assumption); the chooser is guaranteed a 50% or better share by choosing the piece he or she likes best.

Divider-Chooser Method

Page 5: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 5Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

On their first date, Damian and Cleo go to the county fair. They buy jointly a raffle ticket, and as luck would have it, they win a half chocolate–half strawberry cheesecake. Damian likes chocolate and strawberry equally well, so in his eyes the chocolate and strawberry

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

halves are equal in value.

Page 6: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 6Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

On the other hand, Cleo hates chocolate–she is allergic to it and gets sick if she eats any– so in her eyes the value of the cake is 0% for the chocolate

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

half, 100% for the strawberry part.

Once again, to ensure a fair division, we will assume that neither of them knows anything about the other’s likes and dislikes.

Page 7: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 7Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

Damian volunteers to go first (the divider). He cuts the cake in a perfectly rational division of the cake based on his value system–each piece is half of the cake and to him worth one-half of the total value of the cake. It is now Cleo’s turn to choose, and her choice is

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

obvious she will pick the piece having the larger strawberry part.

Page 8: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 8Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

The final outcome of this division is that Damian gets a piece that in his own eyes is worth exactly half of the cake, but Cleo ends up with a much sweeter deal–a piece that in her own eyes is worth about two-thirds of the cake. This is, nonetheless, a fair division of the cake–both players get pieces worth 50% or more.

Example 3.1 Damian and Cleo Divide a Cheesecake

Page 9: Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 2Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: 3.2 - 9Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc.

Example 3.1 illustrates why, given a choice, it is always better to be the chooser than the divider–the divider is guaranteed a share worth exactly 50% of the total value of S, but with just a little luck the chooser can end up with a share worth more than 50%. Since a fair-division method should treat all players equally, both players should have an equal chance of being the chooser. This is best done by means of a coin toss, with the winner of the coin toss getting the privilege of making the choice.

Better to be the Chooser