Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

download Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

of 25

Transcript of Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    1/25

    Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the LowerPartial Moment

    Mattias Persson

    Department of Economics

    Lund University

    P.O. Box 7082

    220 07 LundSweden

    Email: [email protected]

    June 8, 2000

    Abstract

    Portfolio selection models generally assume that the investor knows the param-

    eters of the probability distribution of security returns. In practise the investor

    must, however, employ estimates of the necessary parameters. In this paper we

    investigate the effect of estimation risk on the efficient frontier in the lower partial

    moment framework. The results of the average difference between the actual and

    estimated portfolios show that the estimated portfolios are biased predictors of the

    actual portfolios. However, the estimates of the optimal portfolios can be improved.

    If our concern is the uncertainty in the optimal portfolio weights, then a bootstrap

    approach should be used to improve the optimizations. On the other hand, if our

    concern is related to the risk and portfolio mean returns of the optimized portfolios,

    then a James-Stein approach should be used .

    I thank seminar participants at Lund University, at the Nordic Econometric meeting , Uppsala, 1999,

    and at the 28th Annual Conference of Economists, Melbourne, 1999, for valuable comments.

    1

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    2/25

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    3/25

    the MLPM efficient portfolios, although the poor performance of mean-variance optimized

    portfolios that use sample estimates as inputs has often been noted. For example, Best

    and Grauer (1992) analyzed the effects of changes in assets means, and found that such

    changes had large effects on the composition of the mean-variance efficient set. Chopraand Ziemba (1993), studied the relative importance of errors in mean returns, variances,

    and covariances. Jobson (1991), investigated the effect of errors in the input parame-

    ters, and Broadie (1993), showed in a simulation study, that the estimation errors in the

    mean-variance efficient frontier can be surprisingly large, and that estimates of portfolio

    performance are optimistically biased predictors of actual portfolio performance. Michaud

    (1989), discussed the implications of estimation error for portfolio managers, and Jobson

    (1991) investigated the effect of input parameters, but without restriction on short-selling.

    Simaan (1997), compared the estimation risk in the mean-absolute deviation model andthe mean-variance model, and showed that ignoring the covariance matrix resulted in

    greater estimation risk.

    The purpose of this paper is to investigate the effect of estimation errors in the MLPM-

    model. We particularly address the following question; How far away is the optimized

    portfolio, based on sample data, from the true efficient portfolio? The issue is analyzed

    using a simulation approach similar to the one employed by Broadie (1993) and Jobson

    and Korkie (1980).1 A simulation approach is employed because it can directly show the

    effect of estimation error on the results of the efficient portfolios in the MLPM-model. Inorder to analyze how large the estimation errors are in the MLPM-model, we compare

    the results to the estimation errors in the mean-variance model. Finally, three different

    approaches to improve the portfolio optimization are employed. Two of the methods have

    previously been used in the mean-variance model and belong to the class of shrinkage

    estimators which improve the asset means. The third approach used to improve the

    performance is a bootstrap approach, which in contrast to the other two methods are

    employed to improve not only the assets mean returns but also the estimates of the risk

    measure and the optimized portfolio weights.

    The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows: section 2 gives a brief review

    of portfolio selection in the lower partial moment, in section 3 the methodology of the

    simulation study is presented, the results are presented in section 4 and the summary and

    1 This approach is also proposed by Michaud (1998) as a method to improve the estimates of mean-

    variance efficient portfolios.

    3

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    4/25

    concluding remarks are provided in section 5.

    2 Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    Bawa (1975, 1978), Bawa and Lindenberg (1977) and Fishburn (1977) have shown that the

    lower partial moment provides a more general alternative to the traditional mean-variance

    model. Consider an investor who is averse to downside risk with target rate of return, .

    Let X denote the investors portfolio allocation across k assets with X0 = (X1, X2,...,Xk)

    and let R represent the vector of security returns R0 = (R1, R2,...,Rk) . Let F and FX

    denote the joint distribution of security returns and the probability distribution of returns

    of the portfolio respectively. The nth order lower partial moment of the distribution of

    returns under the allocation X about , LPMn(; X) is then

    LP Mn(; X) =

    Z

    (RX)ndFX(RX) =Z

    (X0R)ndF(R). (1)

    The investors optimization problem is then to minimize (1) subject to

    k

    Xi=1

    XiE(Ri) = (2)

    kXi=1

    Xi = 1 orkXi=1

    Xi = 1, Xi > 0

    Bawa (1976) has shown that the LPMn(; X) is a convex function ofX. Furthermore,

    the optimal value of LPMn(; X), as a function of , is increasing and convex for all

    greater than the mean of the portfolio that yields the minimum lower partial moment over

    the feasible set. This is the same property exhibited by the admissible boundary in the

    mean-variance model. The target rate of return, , can be fixed, variable but deterministic

    and stochastic. For example, when the downside risk is measured against some benchmark

    portfolio we have a stochastic target rate of return.2 The MLPM-model was proposed as

    2 In terms of equilibrium valuation, a target rate of return equal to the riskless rate of return and

    normality is both required for the MLPM-CAPM to be reduced to the standard CAPM, see Bawa and

    Lindenberg (1977).

    4

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    5/25

    an approximation for arbitrary distributions by Bawa (1975) and Bawa and Lindenberg

    (1977), and is a way of reducing the dimensionality of stochastic dominance to a two-

    parameter framework. In fact, the admissible set obtained in the MLPM-model for a

    fixed is a subset of the admissible set under second order stochastic dominance whenn is equal to zeros or one, and third order stochastic dominance when n is equal to two.

    The analysis in the MLPM-model holds exactly if the distribution of stock returns belong

    to the two-parameter location scale family, which includes normal distributions, Student

    t-distributions with the same degree of freedom, and stable distributions with the same

    characteristic exponent (between one and two) and skewness parameter (not necessarily

    zero).

    The MLPM-model is justified for a general set of utility functions. The order, n, of the

    LPMn measure, determines the type of utility functions consistent with that risk measure.LPM

    0

    3 is consistent with all utility functions that prefer more to less (u0 > 0), and LPM1

    with all risk averse utility functions (u0 > 0 and u00 < 0), while LPM2

    is valid for all

    risk averse functions displaying skewness preference (u0 > 0, u00 < 0 and u000 > 0). That

    is, LPM1

    is consistent with the familiar HARA class of utility functions, while LPM2

    is

    consistent with the DARA class of utility functions.

    Many popular notations of risk are special cases of the MLPM-model. For example,

    with n = 0 and the target rate of return equal to zero, LPM0

    is the probability of a loss.4

    For n = 2 and a target rate of return equal to the mean of the distribution, LPM 2 becomesthe traditional semivariance measure. Moreover, under the normal distribution LPM

    2is

    proportional to variance, and would result in the same ordering of the risky assets as the

    mean-variance model.

    Therefore, the power and flexibility of the downside-risk framework stem from the

    joint set of assumptions regarding investors preferences and asset return distributions.

    Unlike other frameworks, which place restrictions on preferences or on distributions, the

    lower partial moment approach uses a combined set of reasonable and less restrictive

    assumptions. The downside risk approach in the lower partial moment is not only more

    attractive in terms of its consistency with the way investors actually perceive risk5, but

    3 The LPM0

    efficient set is not convex, and can therefore not be used for the general purpose of portfolio

    selection.

    4 The probability of loss, has, among others, been studied by Kataoka (1963) as a measure of risk.

    5 See for example Fishburn (1977) and Mao (1970).

    5

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    6/25

    it is also valid under a broader range of conditions.

    3 Methodology

    A simulation approach is employed for the analysis of estimation risk in the MLPM-

    model because it can directly show the effect and magnitude of the estimation error on

    the portfolios. In addition, a simulation approach allows us to concentrate on the effect of

    estimation risk on the outcome of the MLPM analysis. An analytical approach would be

    difficult since the lower partial moments for a given portfolio depend on the actual location

    of the discrete observations, and the discrete observations directly affect the estimated

    portfolios which in turn implies that a closed form solution does not exist. Furthermore,

    investors are probably not directly interested in the magnitude of the estimation errors inthe parameters, but rather in their effect on the outcome of the portfolios. Since the sim-

    ulations and optimizations are computer intensive we restrict our analysis to incorporate

    only LPM of the second order, which is also the most commonly used measure.

    3.1 Population parameters

    We simulate returns from a multivariate normal distribution, and this is done for two

    reasons. First, under multivariate normality both the mean-variance and MLPM-modelproduce identical orderings of the portfolios, and thus the population MLPM e fficient

    frontier can be calculated. Second, the results from the MLPM-model can, under mul-

    tivariate normality, be compared to the results from the mean-variance model in order

    to analyze whether estimation errors are larger in the MLPM-model than in the mean-

    variance model.

    To asses realistic population parameters for the assets we draw N, N = 5 and 25,

    assets from the monthly return series from the Center for Research in Security Prices

    (CRSP) database on the New York Stock Exchange between January1

    989 to December1995 without replacement. The returns on the N assets are then used to compute a

    population mean vector, N, and a covariance matrix,P

    N . The target rate of return

    used is, = M, where M is the estimated mean return on the value weighted index in

    the CRSP database during the same period as above. M is fixed, and was estimated to

    6

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    7/25

    1.02 percent on a monthly basis.6 For each N we end up with a N,and aP

    N, and the

    population portfolio weights XM.

    The next step is to calculate the population efficient set in the MLPM-model, and to

    obtain the population portfolio weights, mean returns and lower partial moments. Thepopulation weights were obtained through optimization of equation (1), where equation

    (1) was solved for a portfolio with normally distributed returns. Next, the optimal weights

    obtained through optimization of equation (1) were controlled against the weights from

    the mean-variance model since the MLPM model should at least produce a subset of

    the mean-variance efficient set. It is true that the mean-variance model and MLPM-

    model produce identical rankings of the portfolios, but the efficient sets do not have to

    be identical. The population efficient sets are obviously identical when the target rate of

    return is set equal to the mean return of the assets, since the LPM2 is equal to one-halfof the variance. Remember that the efficient set in the MLPM-model for a fixed and

    when n = 2 is a subset of third order stochastic dominance, and it is well known that

    the portfolio that yields the minimum variance (MVP) on the mean-variance efficient set

    belongs to second order stochastic dominance when returns are normally distributed. This

    implies that the portfolio that yields the minimum lower partial moment on the e fficient

    set must be equal to the MVP or be a mean-variance efficient portfolio with higher mean

    return than MVP. However, the portfolio that yields the minimum lower partial moment

    must still be a mean-variance efficient portfolio, to be more specific, all efficient portfoliosin the MLPM-model belong to the MV efficient set under normally distributed returns.

    3.2 Details of the simulation and optimization procedure

    The simulation and optimizations are carried out in two steps. First, we simulate T

    returns, R, from the multivariate normal distribution N(N,P

    N). This simulation is

    carried out through a linear transformation and the problem of simulating multivariate

    normally distributed returns is reduced to a simulation of independent and identicallydistributed standard normal random variables.7 Second, the T observations on the N

    6 The analysis has also been conducted with a target rate of return equal to zero, but the results are

    similar to the results under = M. The results are available upon request.

    7 The Randn function in Matlab was used to simulate standard normal random variables, and the seed

    of the random generator was set equal to the sum of the current time.

    7

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    8/25

    assets are used in the following optimization to obtain the estimated MLPM efficient

    portfolios:

    Min{x}

    1T

    TXi=1

    min(RX0 , 0)2 bX0 (3)subject to X0I = 1 (4)

    and X 0. (5)

    Where R is the return matrix, b is the estimated mean return vector of the assets, andI is a vector of ones. is a trade-off parameter between risk and return, and the target

    rate of return, , is set equal to M. The critical-line algorithm of Markowitz (1992) and

    Markowitz et al. (1993) was used to solve the optimization problem. This algorithmsolves the optimization problem efficiently and yields a set of corner portfolios that can

    be used to compute the efficient portfolio for a specific . Since the portfolio weights

    for a portfolio between two corner portfolios are linear combinations of the two corner

    portfolios, the algorithm traces out the whole efficient set. The critical-line algorithm also

    has the advantage that we know that we will always end up with the sample efficient set, in

    contrast to the optimization setup where a restriction is put on the expected return on the

    portfolio. Hence, for simulation purposes of efficient portfolios this is the best optimization

    setup.8

    Furthermore, let cXl denote the vector of portfolio weights that solves (3) for aspecific , = l, and let b() and dLP M2() denote the estimated, mean return and lowerpartial moment respectively for the efficient portfolio at = l. The two steps, described

    above, are repeated 10 000 times for the target rate of return, and for T equal to 36, 60,

    120 and 240 observations. In order to analyze how severe the estimation errors are we

    also estimate mean-variance efficient portfolios which will be used for comparisons. In

    this case we have the following optimization problem:

    Min{x}

    XbCX0 bX0 (6)subject to X0I = 1 (7)

    and X 0. (8)

    8 If a restriction is put on the expected return on the portfolio and a simulation or resampling approach

    is used, we cannot be sure that the resulting portfolio belongs to the e fficient set.

    8

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    9/25

    Where bC is the estimated variance-covariance matrix and as above, the critical-linealgorithm of Markowitz (1987) is used to solve the optimization problem.

    3.3 Portfolio optimization with improved estimates

    The estimation risk literature suggest, that we should be able to improve the portfolio

    optimization by using improved estimates of the assets mean returns at least in the

    mean-variance model. In the mean-variance framework several studies have found that

    the portfolio optimization is extremely sensitive to the estimates of the mean returns, and

    that small changes in the mean returns can have large effects on the optimized portfolios,

    e.g. Chopra and Ziemba (1993), Best and Grauer (1992), and Michaud (1989). The

    present study compares the portfolio optimization and the estimation errors for three

    different approaches, two shrinkage estimators of the means and a bootstrap approach.

    Shrinkage estimators have been studied by Jorion (1985, 1991), Dumas and Jacquillat,

    Grauer and Hakansson (1998), and Michaud (1998).

    Steins (1955) suggestion that the efficiency, in a mean squared error sense, of the

    estimate should be improved by pooling the information across series leads to a number

    of so-called shrinkage estimators that shrink the historical means to some grand mean.

    The first estimator used to improve the means is the classical James-Stein (JS) estimator,

    which takes the form9

    bJS = (1 w)b + wrGI (9)where I is a vector of ones and as above b is the sample estimate, rG = 1NPbi is thegrand mean,

    wt = min h1, (n 2)/(T(b rGI)0

    bC1(b rGI))i

    is the shrinking factor, and bC is the sample variance-covariance matrix calculated with Tobservations. In this case the simple sample means are shrunk toward the arithmetic

    average of the sample means. As noted by Jorion (1985), this shrinking is difficult to

    9 For a discussion of James-Stein estimators, see Efron and Morris (1973, 1977).

    9

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    10/25

    reconcile with the generally accepted trade-off between risk and expected return, unless,

    of course, all assets fall within the same risk class.

    The second estimator used to improve the assets means is the Bayes-Stein (BS) esti-

    mator of Jorion (1985, 1991). This estimator takes the form

    bBS = (1w)b + wrGBSI (10)where

    rGBS = I0bC1b/(I0bC1I),

    w = /( + T)

    and the shrinking factor is

    = (N + 2)/h

    (b rGBSI)0bC1(b rGBSI)i .In this case, the grand mean is the mean of the MVP portfolio in the sample. It should be

    noted, that the shrinkage estimators are biased and nonlinear, since the shrinkage factor

    is itself a function of the data.

    The third method used to improve the portfolio optimizations is a bootstrap approach.The bootstrap method, introduced by Efron (1979), is a computer-intensive method for

    estimating the distribution of an estimator or statistic by resampling the data at hand. A

    bootstrap approach to portfolio selection in the mean-variance framework has previously

    been used by Liang et al. (1996) and Hansson and Persson (2000). Let Rp be the simulated

    return matrix for the N assets of length T from simulation trail p. We resample the Rp

    matrix T times with replacement so that we end up with a bootstrapped return matrix,

    R, of length T. In the resampling, we resample cross-sectionally so that the correlation

    structure among the assets is not destroyed. From each resampled R we optimize the

    portfolios according to (3) and the estimated efficient portfolios for R are obtained.

    Then the portfolios of interest are obtained from the corner portfolios that solve (3). This

    procedure is repeated B times for each R, and in the end we have a set of bootstrapped

    observations for each estimated efficient portfolio. The average portfolio weights, portfolio

    returns and LP M2 s of the B resampled estimated efficient portfolios corresponding to

    10

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    11/25

    the portfolio at are then taken as the solution to the portfolio optimization for the

    return matrix Rp. That is, the solution for the portfolio corresponding to a specific for

    the return matrix Rp in simulation trail p is given by

    bxRp() = 1BBXb=1

    bxb(), bRp() = 1BBXb=1

    bb() and dLP MRp() = 1BBXb=1

    dLP Mb()In order to investigate how the efficiency of the bootstrap approach depend on B,

    B was set in the interval 50 to 300. The simulations are only repeated with improved

    estimates for N = 5 but for all values of T, i.e. T = 36, 60, 120 and 240. When JS and

    BS are used to improve the estimates, the number of simulations, P, is 10 000, while the

    number of simulations is reduced to1

    000 in the bootstrap approach.

    3.4 Quantitative measures of estimation errors

    The effect of using estimated parameters instead of the true parameters when computing

    the MLPM efficient set can be studied through the true-, actual- and estimated-efficient

    set. This approach was proposed by Broadie (1993).10 The true efficient set is the

    population efficient set which is unknown to the investors. The estimated efficient frontier

    is the efficient frontier based on the estimated parameters and is the sample efficient

    frontier. The actual efficient set is defined as follows: Each point on the estimated efficient

    frontier corresponds to a portfolio of the N assets, using the portfolio weights from the

    estimated parameters, i.e. the sample efficient portfolio, and then applying them to the

    true parameters. That is, the expected returns and variance-covariance matrix in (1)

    yields the actual efficient frontier. The characteristics of the actual portfolio are what

    the investor with the estimated portfolio weights actually holds. In short, the estimated

    frontier is what appears to be the case based on the data and the estimated parameters,

    but the actual frontier is what really occurs based on the true parameters.

    The estimation errors that we focus on are the errors between the actual efficient

    frontier and the true efficient frontier. The estimation errors are measured through the

    following root-mean-squared errors (RMSE) measures:

    10 Other measures used are the cash equivalent loss in Chopra and Ziemba (1993) and the utility loss

    used in Jorion (1985) and Simaan (1997).

    11

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    12/25

    f() =

    vuut

    1

    P

    PXp=1

    ()

    ep()

    2

    (11)

    fLPM() =

    vuut 1P

    PXp=1

    LP M()

    1

    2 gLP Mp()122 . (12)Where, p() and LP M() denote the target point on the true efficient set for the portfolio

    at . ep() and gLP Mp() 12 represent the mean return and LPM of the actual portfoliocorresponding to that specific for simulation trail p. P is equal to the number of

    simulations, 10 000.

    Investors observe the estimated frontier but portfolio performance is given by the

    actual frontier. In order to answer the question How far is the estimated portfolio from

    the actual portfolio?, a second measure of estimation errors is used. Let bp() anddLP Mp()12 denote the estimated parameters corresponding to the portfolio on theestimated efficient frontier for simulation trail p. Then the average difference of the mean

    returns of the portfolios between the actual and estimated portfolios is given by g(),

    and the average difference between the standardized LPM1

    2

    2is given by gLPM().

    g() =1P

    PXp=1

    bp() ep() (13)gLPM() =

    1

    P

    PXp=1

    dLP Mp() 12 gLP Mp() 12 (14)

    4 Results

    The effect of using estimated parameters instead of true parameters on the MLPM efficient

    frontier is graphed in Figure 1. The estimated efficient frontier is located to the left of boththe true and actual efficient frontiers, which implies that the estimated efficient frontier

    underestimates the risk of the portfolios. Recall that the actual efficient portfolio frontier

    is how the estimated portfolios really look like and it is also these portfolios that the

    estimated portfolios are evaluated against. It can, however, be seen in Figure 1 that we

    generally end up with inefficient portfolios. What seems most striking about Figure 1, is

    12

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    13/25

    the large difference between the estimated frontier and the actual frontier, the estimated

    frontier overestimates the expected return for the portfolios and underestimates the risk

    of the portfolios. This seems to indicate that the estimated portfolios are optimistically

    biased predictors of portfolio performance. However, the difference between the true andactual portfolios are not constant over the frontiers but rather the di fference seems to

    increase with the portfolio mean return.

    2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    1.1

    1.2

    1.3

    1.4

    1.5

    Standardized LPM

    M

    ean

    Portfolio

    Return True Efficient Frontier

    Estimated Frontier

    Actual Frontier

    Figure 1: Mean-Lower Partial Moment frontiers using 36 observations.

    In Table 1, the estimation errors between the actual and the true portfolios are pre-

    sented. In Panel A it can be seen that the RMSE are surprisingly large when there are five

    assets in the frontiers. The RMSE for both LPM and the mean returns on the portfolios

    fall with and the number of observations used to estimated the frontier. Our estimate

    of the portfolio that yields the minimum lower partial moment is much better than for

    portfolios with a higher mean portfolio return. The relative efficiency between portfolios

    at = 2000 and = 0 is as high as 43 when 36 observations are used to estimate the risk

    of the portfolios, and the relative efficiency is almost 74 when 240 observations are used.11

    11 The relative efficiency is the ratio between the two mean-squared errors. The higher the ratio, the

    higher is the relative efficiency.

    13

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    14/25

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    15/25

    The results for the MV-model are presented in Table 2. The RMSE decrease, as in the

    MLPM-model, with the number of observations and with . Furthermore, the errors for

    high return portfolios in the 25 asset case have, just as in the MLPM-model, decreased. If

    the sizes offLPM and f are compared to the corresponding f and f in the MV-model, weobserve that the errors in the MLPM-model are larger than in the MV-model, especially

    for low portfolios. This is especially true for the difference in efficiency between fLPM

    and f

    . In fact, the difference in efficiency between the two models increases with the

    number of observations used in the optimization.

    Table 2.

    Root Mean-Squared Errors between Actual and True Portfolios

    in the Mean-Variance Model

    Panel A: N = 5T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    f

    f f f f f f f2000 6.94 0.40 6.89 0.38 6.72 0.35 6.49 0.31100 4.90 0.25 4.50 0.23 3.85 0.19 2.99 0.1550 3.67 0.21 3.04 0.19 2.16 0.15 1.45 0.1110 1.02 0.10 0.71 0.08 0.41 0.06 0.23 0.045 0.55 0.07 0.35 0.05 0.19 0.04 0.10 0.031 0.25 0.05 0.15 0.04 0.08 0.03 0.04 0.02

    0.1 0.23 0.04 0.14 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.04 0.020 0.23 0.04 0.14 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.04 0.02

    Panel B: N = 25T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    f

    f f f f f f f2000 6.50 1.00 6.12 0.90 5.47 0.74 4.37 0.58100 3.89 0.81 2.94 0.67 1.83 0.49 1.23 0.3450 3.00 0.64 2.26 0.52 1.58 0.36 1.18 0.2410 1.64 0.31 1.24 0.25 0.82 0.19 0.56 0.155 1.39 0.21 0.97 0.18 0.55 0.14 0.30 0.101 0.53 0.12 0.31 0.09 0.15 0.06 0.08 0.05

    0.1 0.39 0.09 0.23 0.07 0.12 0.05 0.06 0.040 0.38 0.09 0.23 0.07 0.11 0.05 0.06 0.04

    All values in percent, except

    The difference in efficiency between the two models continuous to hold independently

    of the number of assets used. If we look at an increase in RMSE when we go from five

    assets to 25, the relative increase in fLPM is actually smaller than the increase in f, while

    the increase is higher in f for the MLPM-model.

    The fact that the errors are larger for high return portfolios in both models is a dark

    side of portfolio optimization that cannot be ignored. In its search for assets with high

    15

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    16/25

    mean returns the portfolio optimization favors assets with overestimated mean returns

    and underestimated risk. This error-maximization property of the portfolio optimization

    also pertains to errors in our risk estimates (Michaud (1989)). However, the results in

    Table 1 and 2, actually indicate that the severity of the error-maximization problemdiminishes as the number of assets in the asset universe is increased.

    The result that the errors are larger in the MLPM-model than in the MV-model should

    not come as a surprise since the LPM risk measure is a partial domain risk and hence only

    uses a truncated part of the available data. This in turn translates into larger estimation

    errors in the MLPM-model.

    In Table 3, the results from the optimizations with James-Stein improved estimates

    of the mean returns are presented. It can clearly be seen that the JS improved estimates

    make the errors between the actual and true portfolios even larger as compared to thesituation in Table 1 in which the sample estimates were used. In addition, the errors

    between the portfolios increase with the number of observations used in the portfolio

    optimization. For example, the errors are higher for the minimum lower partial moment

    portfolio, i.e. = 0, when 240 observations are used. The relative efficiency between the

    simple sample estimates is almost 20 for fLPM and 4 for f. The JS approach is in the

    MLPM-model outperformed by the classical approach of using simple sample estimates,

    and this approach has been shown to improve the performance of the MV-model, e.g.

    Jorion (1985) and Dumas and Jacquillat (1990).

    16

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    17/25

    Table 3.

    Root Mean-Squared Errors between Actual and True Portfolios

    in the MLPM-model with James-Stein Estimator

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f2000 5.59 0.41 5.55 0.39 5.32 0.36 4.90 0.31100 3.18 0.24 3.10 0.23 3.16 0.20 3.23 0.1850 2.96 0.21 2.77 0.20 2.73 0.18 2.75 0.1610 1.79 0.14 1.60 0.13 1.91 0.13 2.30 0.135 1.39 0.12 1.36 0.11 1.84 0.12 2.28 0.131 1.07 0.10 1.23 0.10 1.81 0.12 2.28 0.14

    0.1 1.02 0.10 1.21 0.10 1.80 0.12 2.28 0.140 1.02 0.10 1.21 0.10 1.80 0.12 2.28 0.14

    All values in percent, except and N=5

    Turning to Table 4, the results of the Bayes-Stein improved portfolios are presented.

    When the BS estimator is used to improve the assets mean returns, there is some im-

    provement in the RMSE for both fLPM and f. The improvement is particularly eminent

    for the portfolios in the interval between 100 and 5, where the efficiency has increased for

    fLPM. For the low -portfolios the fLPM is somewhat larger with the BS improved mean

    returns when compared to the simple sample estimates in Table 1. In fact, it is somewhat

    surprising that the BS approach does not improve the estimates of the actual portfolios

    more, since the simulation is based on normally distributed returns and we know that the

    minimum variance portfolio is close to the MLPM efficient set.

    Table 4.

    Root Mean-Squared Errors Between Actual and True Portfolios

    with Bayes-Stein Estimator

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f2000 4.77 0.40 4.76 0.38 4.69 0.34 4.55 0.31

    100 3.27 0.25 3.01 0.23 2.68 0.19 2.34 0.1650 2.86 0.21 2.48 0.19 1.97 0.16 1.51 0.1210 1.52 0.14 1.14 0.12 0.79 0.09 0.63 0.075 1.15 0.12 0.87 0.10 0.65 0.08 0.56 0.071 0.85 0.10 0.67 0.08 0.58 0.08 0.54 0.07

    0.1 0.80 0.09 0.66 0.08 0.57 0.08 0.53 0.080 0.78 0.09 0.65 0.08 0.57 0.08 0.53 0.08

    All values in percent, except , and N=5.

    17

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    18/25

    The results from the bootstrap approach are presented in Table 5. 300 bootstrap

    resamples were used to compute the portfolio characteristics. With this approach all

    estimates, except for the portfolio when = 2000, were improved as compared to the

    results in Table 1, where the sample estimates were used in the optimization. The RMSEfor both fLPM and f have decreased, which implies that the bootstrap approach is the

    most efficient method for improving the estimates as compared to the classical, JS and BS

    methods. Furthermore, the relative efficiency between the simple sample estimates and

    the bootstrap approach increases with the number of observations used in the portfolio

    optimization. The RMSE are larger than those in Table 5 when less than 300 bootstrap

    samples were used to estimate the portfolios, but the RMSE were still smaller than the

    RMSE when the simple sample estimates were used. Since 300 bootstrap samples are

    the maximum of resamples used in the present study it is possible that the RMSE coulddecrease further if the number of bootstrap resamples are increased beyond 300.12

    Table 5.

    Root Mean-Squared Errors Between Actual and True Portfolios

    with a Bootstrap Approach

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f fLPM f

    2000 5.50 0.34 5.52 0.33 5.20 0.30 5.04 0.27100 2.73 0.18 2.55 0.17 2.82 0.16 2.68 0.1450 2.80 0.17 2.52 0.16 2.64 0.15 2.28 0.1310 2.04 0.13 1.51 0.11 1.17 0.10 0.78 0.085 1.52 0.11 1.03 0.10 0.74 0.08 0.53 0.071 0.79 0.08 0.54 0.07 0.41 0.06 0.35 0.06

    0.1 0.56 0.07 0.42 0.06 0.35 0.06 0.32 0.050 0.52 0.07 0.41 0.06 0.34 0.06 0.31 0.05

    All values in percent, except . N=5 and 300 bootstrap samples usedto compute the bootstrap estimates.

    Lets turn to the second question raised above: How far is the estimated portfoliofrom the actual portfolio? In Table 6, the results for the portfolio optimizations based

    on the simple sample estimates are presented. Again the results illustrate the error-

    maximization properties of portfolio optimization, i.e. the actual portfolios mean returns

    12 The results for the bootstrap approach when 50, 100 and 200 bootstrap resamples were used are

    available upon request.

    18

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    19/25

    are overestimated and the risk underestimated. The bias is surprisingly large in both

    parameters, and the number of observations used in the portfolio optimization have a

    large impact on the bias. For example, when 36 observations are used g is three times

    as large as the corresponding g when 240 observations are used to estimate the portfoliolocated at = 2000. The results in Table 6 are important because they indicate the large

    degree to which estimated frontiers are optimistically biased predictors of actual portfolio

    performance.

    The James-Stein estimator actually performs better for estimating the characteristics

    of the actual portfolios than for estimating the characteristics of the true portfolios. The

    results for when the JS-estimator is employed to improve the asset mean returns are

    presented in Table 7. The bias in the portfolios mean returns has decreased, but the bias

    in the risk measure is more or less unaffected by the JS-estimator.

    Table 6.

    Average Difference Between Estimated and Actual Portfolios

    in the MLPM-model

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g2000 -1.01 1.54 -0.73 1.17 -0.48 0.80 -0.32 0.54100 -1.04 1.54 -0.75 1.18 -0.49 0.80 -0.33 0.5450 -1.04 1.51 -0.75 1.14 -0.49 0.75 -0.31 0.48

    10 -0.93 1.19 -0.62 0.82 -0.35 0.48 -0.20 0.275 -0.84 0.99 -0.54 0.66 -0.30 0.37 -0.16 0.201 -0.68 0.64 -0.42 0.41 -0.22 0.22 -0.12 0.13

    0.1 -0.60 0.49 -0.37 0.32 -0.20 0.18 -0.11 0.110 -0.59 0.47 -0.36 0.31 -0.20 0.18 -0.11 0.11

    Table 7.

    Average Difference Between Estimated and Actual Portfolios

    with James-Stein Estimator

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g2000 -0.93 0.65 -0.66 0.45 -0.43 0.27 -0.29 0.16

    100 -0.93 0.64 -0.65 0.46 -0.41 0.29 -0.27 0.1650 -0.91 0.63 -0.62 0.44 -0.38 0.26 -0.23 0.1510 -0.78 0.49 -0.49 0.31 -0.26 0.15 -0.15 0.075 -0.71 0.41 -0.44 0.25 -0.22 0.11 -0.13 0.041 -0.60 0.28 -0.36 0.16 -0.18 0.07 -0.10 0.017

    0.1 -0.56 0.23 -0.33 0.13 -0.17 0.05 -0.10 0.010 -0.56 0.22 -0.33 0.12 -0.17 0.05 -0.10 0.01

    19

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    20/25

    In Table 8, the results for when the Bayes-Stein estimator was used to improve

    the mean returns of the assets are presented. The results are comparable, in size, with

    the results when the JS-estimator was used to improve the asset means. However, the

    bias in the mean returns of the portfolios has decreased although the bias in the risk ofthe portfolios has not improved.

    The results for the bootstrap approach are presented in Table 9, and they are somewhat

    mixed. The bootstrap approach results in a lower bias for the risk measure for high

    portfolios when 36 or 60 observations are used in the optimization, but in all other cases

    the bias is larger than when the sample estimates are used.

    Table 8.

    Average Difference Between Estimated and Actual Portfolios

    with Bayes-Stein Estimator

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g2000 -1.01 0.57 -0.74 0.40 -0.50 0.23 -0.33 0.12100 -1.03 0.58 -0.73 0.42 -0.47 0.25 -0.30 0.1550 -1.00 0.56 -0.69 0.39 -0.42 0.23 -0.25 0.1310 -0.83 0.42 -0.53 0.26 -0.29 0.13 -0.16 0.065 -0.76 0.36 -0.47 0.21 -0.25 0.10 -0.14 0.041 -0.66 0.26 -0.40 0.15 -0.21 0.07 -0.12 0.03

    0.1 -0.62 0.23 -0.37 0.13 -0.20 0.06 -0.11 0.02

    0-0.61 0.22 -0.37 0.13 -0.20 0.06 -0.11 0.02

    Table 9.

    Average Difference Between Estimated and Actual Portfolios

    with a Bootstrap Approach

    = M T = 36 T = 60 T = 120 T = 240

    gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g gLPM g2000 0,082 2,23 0,49 1,68 0,61 1,22 0,82 0,82100 -0,13 2,24 0,24 1,68 0,35 1,22 0,49 0,8350 -0,29 2,22 0,04 1,66 0,13 1,19 0,22 0,7910 -0,86 1,95 -0,60 1,37 -0,46 0,88 -0,39 0,53

    5 -1,03 1,72 -0,78 1,17 -0,58 0,72 -0,47 0,431 -1,09 1,22 -0,85 0,80 -0,61 0,48 -0,47 0,31

    0.1 -1,01 0,94 -0,80 0,63 -0,57 0,41 -0,45 0,270 -0,98 0,90 -0,79 0,61 -0,56 0,40 -0,45 0,27

    20

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    21/25

    5 Summary and Concluding Remarks

    The present study has analyzed the effect of estimation risk on the portfolio selection

    problem in the lower partial moment framework. A simulation study was used to capture

    the effects of estimation errors and the important distinction between the true, estimated

    and actual efficient set was made. In short, the estimated frontier is what appears to be

    the case based on the data and the estimated parameters, but the actual frontier is what

    really occurs based on the true parameters. The true efficient set is based on the unknown

    parameters and is, as the actual frontier, unknown to the investor. In addition, three

    different methods for improving the portfolio optimizations have been employed in this

    chapter and they were compared to the classical approach in which the sample estimates

    are used as inputs into the portfolio optimizations. The three different methods were two

    different shrinkage estimators; James-Stein and Bayes-Stein, and the third method was a

    bootstrap approach.

    The results showed that the errors in the optimized portfolios, that is the di fference

    between the actual and true portfolios, can be surprisingly large in the mean-lower partial

    moment framework. This is especially true for portfolios at low levels of risk tolerance and

    for portfolios with high portfolio mean returns. That is, the portfolio optimizations suf-

    fered from error-maximization which implies that the optimization setup favors assets with

    overestimated mean returns and underestimated risks. Thus, the results in the presentstudy are well in line with the well known result from the mean-variance model, that our

    estimates of portfolios close to the minimum risk portfolio are better than portfolios with

    higher portfolio mean returns.

    The bootstrap approach performed best of the three methods used to improve the

    portfolio optimizations, and the James-Stein approach actually performed worse than the

    classical approach of using sample estimates as inputs into the portfolio optimizations.

    The results of the average difference between the actual and estimated portfolios show

    that the estimated portfolios are biased predictors of the actual portfolios in that theyunderestimate the risk in the portfolios and overestimate the portfolio mean returns. In

    this case the James-Stein approach produced the smallest bias, and the performance of

    the bootstrap approach was comparable with the results from using sample estimates.

    Hence, the estimated optimal portfolios in the lower partial moment suffer to a larger

    extent from estimation errors, but the estimates can be improved. If our concern is the

    21

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    22/25

    uncertainty in the optimal portfolio weights, then a bootstrap approach should be used

    since this approach produce the lowest root-mean squared errors between the actual and

    true efficient portfolio. On the other hand, if our concern is related to the risk and portfolio

    mean returns of the optimized portfolios a James-Stein approach should be used.

    22

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    23/25

    6 References

    Barry, C. B. 1974. Effects of Uncertain Means, Variances and Covariances, Journal of

    Finance, Vol 29, 515-524

    Bawa, V. S. 1975. Optimal Rules for Ordering Uncertain Prospects, Journal of Finan-

    cial Economics, 2, 95-121.

    Bawa, V. S. 1976. Admissible Portfolios for All Individuals, Journal of Finance, 31 (4),

    1169-1183.

    Bawa, V. S. and R. W. Klein. 1979. The Effect of Estimation Risk on Optimal Portfolio

    Choice, Estimation Risk and Optimal Portfolio Choice, Amsterdam, North-Holland.

    Bawa, V. S. and E. B. Lindenberg. 1977Capital Market Equilibrium in a Mean-Lower

    Partial Moment Framework, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 189-200.

    Best, M. J. and R. P. Grauer. 1992. The Analytics of Sensitivity Analysis for Mean-

    Variance Portfolio Problems, International Review of Financial Analysis, 1(1), 17-

    37.

    Broadie, M. 1993. Computing Efficient Frontiers Using Estimated Frontiers, Annals of

    Operations Research: Financial Engineering, 45 (Special Issue), 21

    -58.

    Chopra, V. K. and W. T. Ziemba. 1993. The Effects of Errors in the Means, Variances

    and Covariances, Journal of Portfolio Management, 4, 6-11.

    Efron, B. 1979. Bootstrap Methods: Another Look at the Jackknife, Annals of Statis-

    tics, 7: 1-26.

    Eftekhari, B. 1998. Lower Partial Moment Hedge Ratios, Applied Financial Economics,

    8, 645-652.

    Fishburn, C. P. 1977. Mean-Risk Analysis with Risk Associated with Below-Target

    Returns, American, Economic Review, 67(5), 116-126.

    Grauer, R. and N. Hakansson. 1998. Applying the Grinblatt-Titman and the Condi-

    tional (Ferson-Schadt) Performance Measures: The Case of Industry Rotation Via

    the Dynamic Investment Model Manuscript.

    23

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    24/25

    Grootveld, H. and W. Hallerbach. 1999. Variance vs Downside Risk: Is there really

    that much difference?, European Journal of Operational Research, 114: 304-319.

    Hansson, B. and M. Persson. 2000. Time Diversification and Estimation RiskFinancial

    Analysts Journal, (May/June).

    Harlow, V. W. 1991. Asset Allocation in a Downside-Risk Framework, Financial Ana-

    lysts Journal, Sept/Oct: 28-40.

    Harlow, W.V. and Rao. R.K. 1989. Asset Pricing in a Generalized Mean-Lower Partial

    Moment Framework: Theory and Evidence, Journal of Financial and Quantitative

    Analysis, 24: 285-311.

    Jobson, J.D. 1991. Confidence Regions for the Mean-Variance Efficient Set: An alterna-tive Approach to Estimation Risk, Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting,

    1: 235-256.

    Jobson, J. D. and B. Korkie. 1980. Estimation for Markowitz Efficient Portfolios,

    Journal of American Statistical Association, 75: 544-554.

    Jorion, P. 1985. International Portfolio Diversification with Estimation Risk, Journal

    of Business, 58: 259-278.

    Jorion, P. 1991. Bayesian and CAPM Estimators of the Means: Implications for Port-

    folio Selection, Journal of Banking and Finance, 15: 717-727.

    Kataoka, S. 1963. A Stochastic Programming Model, Econometrica, 31: 181-196.

    Liang, Y., F.C.N. Myer, and J.R. Webb. 1996. The Bootstrap Efficient Frontier for

    Mixed-Asset Portfolios Real Estate Economics, 24, no. 2 (Summer):247-256.

    Lien, D. and Y. K. Tse. 2000. Hedging Downside Risk with Futures Contracts, Applied

    Financial Economics, 10: 163-170.

    Lewellen, J. and J. Shanken. 1998. Market Efficiency, Rational Expectations, and

    Estimation Risk. paper presented at the annual meeting of American Finance As-

    sociation, New York (1999).

    24

  • 8/14/2019 Estimation Risk and Portfolio Selection in the Lower Partial Moment

    25/25

    Markowitz, H. 1987. Mean-Variance Analysis in Portfolio Choice and Capital Markets.

    Oxford, Basil Blackwell.

    Markowitz, H. 1992. Portfolio Selection - Efficient Diversification of Investments. Ox-

    ford, Basil Blackwell (First published 1959)

    Markowitz, H., P. Todd, G. Xu and Y. Yamane. 1993. Computing the Mean-Semivariance

    Efficient Set by the Critical Line Algorithm Annals of Operations Research: Finan-

    cial Engineering, 45 (Special Issue), 307-317.

    Michaud, R. O. 1989. The Markowitz Optimization Enigma: Is Optimized Optimal?

    Financial Analysts Journal, (January/February): 31-42.

    Michaud, R.O. 1998. Efficient Asset Management - A Practical Guide to Stock PortfolioOptimization and Asset Allocation. Boston, Harvard Business School Press.

    Roy, A. 1952. Safety-First and the Holding of Assets Econometrica, 20, 431-449.

    Rudolf, M., H. Wolter. and H. Zimmerman. 1999. A Linear Model for Tracking Error

    Minimization, Journal of Banking & Finance, 23, 85-103.

    Sortino, F. and R. van der Meer. 1991. Downside Risk, Journal of Portfolio Manage-

    ment, 2, 27-31

    .

    25