ESFS 3.0 - Evropský fond finanční stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

download ESFS 3.0 - Evropský fond finanční stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

of 11

Transcript of ESFS 3.0 - Evropský fond finanční stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    1/11

    Any authors named on this report are research analysts unless otherwise indicated.Please see analyst certifications and important disclosures starting on page 6.

    Europe Special Report

    ECB SMP and EFSF 3.0N O M U R A G L O B A L E C O N O M I C S N O M U R A I N T E R N A T I O N A L P L C

    EFSF 3.0 and the fate of the ECBs SMP

    One key area of market uncertainty is the ECB's stated intention to suspend its SMP

    programme when the EFSF 2.0 is up and running, which could be later this month.

    But the EFSF 2.0 is unable to execute this mandate.

    However, we believe that an awareness of the structural limitations of EFSF 2.0 will

    mean that the ECB will maintain its SMP programme, we assume at a similar scale to

    that seen over the past six months albeit with the purchases remaining conditional on

    fiscal rectitude among recipient countries.

    If we are correct, this would remove one key area of market uncertainty, but many will

    remain since we assume that SMP purchases will remain focused on providing the

    minimum liquidity support necessary to ensure that key non-core countries maintain

    market access.

    We have framed the euro-area crisis in terms of governments and the market searching

    for a steady state solution, defined as a situation where the market no longer fears the

    incremental solvency risk of holding the debt of a euro-area sovereign. In our view, there

    are three, often related, paths towards a steady state solution:

    1. Fiscal union and/or the issuance of Eurobonds with a joint and several

    liability structure. The likelihood of this option has been significantly reduced

    following last month's German Constitutional Court ruling against unbounded

    liabilities accruing to Germany as a result of its involvement in Euro-area

    bailouts.

    2. Monetisation of non-core debt via an aggressive expansion of the ECB's

    balance sheet. This option runs the risk of merely providing a large window of

    market calm after which underlying solvency concerns would remain.

    Nonetheless, it would allow the ECB's unbounded balance sheet to be brought

    to bear on the crisis which could be sufficient to assuage default risks for a long

    period of time. (While the ECB would only buy bonds on the secondary market,

    this should spur demand for primary debt since the bonds could be sold to theECB, limiting their downside). However, our view remains that the ECB is

    reluctant to increase the credit risk on its balance sheet at this time.

    3. Default by selected countries and the potential for some Euro-area

    members to leave the euro. This is naturally a market-unfriendly outcome and

    one that could result in multi-year economic and market disruptions before a

    steady state were reached.

    We recently analysed many of the latest policy proposals for addressing the euro-area

    crisis that work within this framework (EFSF 2.0, 3.0 and beyond, 29 September), most

    notably policies which involve increasing the amount of financial resources brought to

    bear in the crisis by altering the structure of and/or leveraging the EFSF. Now we revisit

    this analysis, and highlight the implications for the ECB's securities markets programme

    (SMP) from some of the proposed changes to the EFSF.

    10 October 2011

    Jens Sondergaard

    +44 (0) 20 710 21969

    [email protected]

    Desmond Supple

    +44 (0) 20 710 22125

    [email protected]

    http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257
  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    2/11

    Nomura Global Economics 2 10 October 2011

    The planned ending of the ECB's SMP a key area of marketrisk

    Since the bond-buying began, its effectiveness has been limited by the markets

    awareness that the ECBs commitment to the SMP has been ambiguous. First, the ECB

    has repeatedly said that the SMP is intended to be temporary. Second, the governing

    council remains heavily divided on the issue and the critical voices are well known (Jens

    Weidmann, Juergen Stark, Yves Mersch, Klaas Knot). A divided governing council

    makes the bond market interventions less effective.

    The ECB is clearly not comfortable with the SMP

    Four main concerns explain the ECBs unease regarding the SMP:

    1. The ECB bond purchases may be violating the Treaty of the European Union,

    Article 21.1 which prohibits the ECB from directly buying bonds from EU

    governments, i.e. the ECB cannot bail out governments in financial distress.

    There may be a legal loophole in that the ECB is buying bonds in the secondary

    markets (i.e. from financial institutions), but the intention of the treaty is clear:

    the central bank should not facilitate the deficit financing of the euro-area

    governments.

    2. Second, the ECB bond-buying has implicitly been conditional on thegovernments adopting the right policy mix of fiscal austerity and structural

    reform. The ECB SMP is a quid pro quo: governments take steps to ensure that

    their public debt is sustainable; the ECB intervenes to correct the mispricing of

    bonds in the markets. If governments do not do their job, the ECB can (and has)

    stepped back from its intervention. This is a dangerous area for a central bank.

    Bond purchases essentially become a stick and carrot tool where the ECB

    takes a direct role in affecting fiscal policy across the euro area. It is hard to see

    how central bank independence is preserved and how the ECB can separate

    fiscal from monetary policy concerns.

    3. We think ECB policymakers are worried about credit risk. A substantial

    commitment to further SMP entails a substantial balance sheet expansion. But

    policymakers worry that such a balance sheet expansion would increase the

    financial risks to their balance sheet. In other words: leveraging up the balance

    sheet exposes the ECB to potential capital losses. Policymakers may worry that

    any significant capital losses would make the ECB technically insolvent. The

    governing council does not have the right to ask for an increase in the ECBs

    capital base. That is the responsibility of the European Council. Of course, there

    is no theoretical problem with a central bank being insolvent if there is sufficient

    confidence that policymakers will not implement an overly loose monetary policy

    as they seek to accumulate profits by printing money (seigniorage) and riding

    the yield curve. In the current context in Europe, we doubt many investors would

    be alarmed if such a scenario emerged. Nonetheless, central banks remain

    strongly opposed to depleting their capital.

    4. The ECB is concerned about the possible inflationary impacts of a large-scale

    SMP intervention. Can the ECB sterilise the inflationary impulse from a large

    balance sheet expansion? If not, then SMP could conflict with the price stability

    mandate, depending on the economic outlook for the euro area.

    The ECBs appetite for its SMP has also related to its own agenda regarding economic

    governance in the euro area. It has explicitly talked about the need for closer economic

    and in particular fiscal integration within the euro area, and is aware that market pressure

    is pushing policymakers down this path. Without this market pressure, the ECB fears that

    the momentum towards the ever closer union will falter. An unconditional commitment

    to SMP removes market pressure and would imply a lost opportunity to substantially

    improve the foundations of European Monetary Union. However, the balancing act for the

    ECB is providing an SMP which is viewed as sufficiently conditional on fiscal

    consolidation in recipient countries and a partial solution to a countys funding pressures,

    The ECBs commitment to

    the SMP has been

    ambiguous

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    3/11

    Nomura Global Economics 3 10 October 2011

    but on the other hand providing sufficient liquidity to ensure that key countries, such as

    Italy or Spain, do not lose market access. If they were to do so, the survival of the euro

    area would become more uncertain. So, the SMP needs to provide a minimum backstop

    until a sustained solution is found.

    ECB is scheduled to pass the SMP baton to the EFSF 2.0,which is unable to grasp it

    Given the ECBs obvious restraint in terms of its SMP intervention, the scheme has had a

    success proportionate to the modest scale of its ambition. It has played an important rolein helping to maintain market access for countries such as Italy and Spain since it has

    limited the rise in yields, but the scheme has clearly not been large enough to transform

    market sentiment towards the semi-core countries since it is not a solution to the debt

    crisis. While maintaining the current SMP is not a substitute for a credible and broad-

    based EU policy response to the crisis, were the ECB to halt its programme the risks of

    Italy and Spain losing market access would increase significantly. In this respect, the

    outlook for the ECBs SMP is a crucial area of market risk.

    Unfortunately, there are question marks about the longevity of the SMP. As we wrote

    recently (Asymmetric market risks in Europe, 6 September 2011), the ECB currently

    plans to halt its SMP and to hand over responsibility for secondary market bond-buying to

    the EFSF once Euro-area parliaments approve planned changes to its structure. This is aconcern because the proposed new structure of the EFSF (EFSF 2.0) is ill-suited to the

    task of taking up the baton of the ECBs bond buying program in our view. At 440bn in

    usable/investible resources, 147bn of which have already been allocated to bailout

    programmes, we think it is too small to comprise a significant buttress against market

    weakness in non-core debt. Moreover, the EFSF lacks the ECBs flexibility since it would

    need to pre-fund its interventions, and there is uncertainty about how the EFSF would

    choose which bonds to buy.

    Does the EFSF 3.0 option change our view of the ECB's SMP?

    When looking at the many and varied options for EFSF 3.0, below we divide them into

    two broad categories: (1) options which by definition address the issue of the SMP by

    making this scheme a central component of the new EFSF; and (2) options such as

    leverage-based options which require a separate view on whether or not we expect the

    SMP to be maintained and in what size.

    Category 1 The ECB indemnity option

    In EFSF 2.0, 3.0 and beyond (29 September 2011), we noted that of the proposed

    changes to the EFSF, one of the most appealing could be to transform the EFSF into a

    mechanism for indemnifying the ECB against losses from its bond holdings. The benefits

    of this approach would be threefold:

    More efficient use of EFSF capital. This scenario would not need the EFSF to

    issue AAA debt for the purpose of its indemnification operations. Hence the full

    value of guarantees726bn could be utilised rather than the 440bn when

    these assets are over-collateralised to form440bn of investible funds.

    SMP uncertainty is removed. Under this scenario, the SMP becomes a central

    element of the EUs EFSF-related plans for addressing the euro-area crisis. This

    option also addresses (depending on the scale of the indemnity provision) the

    ECB's concerns about the credit risk implicit in its SMP.

    Bank recapitalisation. The plan also allows for EFSF funds to be allocated to

    additional uses, such as bank recapitalisation, and hence for the policy

    response to comprise a more comprehensive package of measures.

    We explore this option first as it would allow us to quantify the potential impact on the

    SMP.

    SMP has helped limit the

    rise in yields, but is nosubstitute for a credible

    solution

    EFSF funds can be used

    to indemnify the ECB for

    its bond purchases

    http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=461617http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=461617http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=461617http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=465257http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=461617
  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    4/11

    Nomura Global Economics 4 10 October 2011

    The potential size of the SMP under an ECB indemnity optionscenario

    Under the ECB indemnity option, we can calculate based on some assumptions the

    potential size of the SMP. We assume that from the 726bn in guarantees, we need to

    subtract two amounts. First, we need to remove the 147bn in funds which will be

    committed to the various bailout measures for Greece, Ireland and Portugal. This figure

    includes EFSF commitments to the second Greek aid package included in the 21 July

    private sector Involvement (PSI) deal. While it looks increasingly as if the PSI deal will

    need to be renegotiated, for simplicity we assume that the EFSFs involvement in PSI 2.0will be the same as its role in PSI 1.0. Second, 200bn in funds has been allocated to

    fund a recapitalisation of euro-area banks.

    This leaves a 379bn pool of EFSF funds which would be available to indemnify the

    EFSF against losses on its SMP. Of these funds, we would assume that the ECBs

    existing160.5bn bond purchases would need to be indemnified against losses.

    Full indemnity of the ECBs SMP 218bn. After removing the various items

    above, a full indemnity operation for the ECB would allow for additional bond

    purchases of218bn. This would represent a 76.3% expansion of the SMP, but

    in value terms could be underwhelming since, if the SMP purchases were to

    persist at the pace seen in September, the expansion would provide only

    around seven months additional resources. Of course, EFSF funds can be

    expanded without parliamentary approval, but a full indemnity option would

    require clarity on whether the ECB would continue with its SMP after its full

    indemnity had been fully utilised.

    If the EFSF were to seek to leverage its resources by providing a partial, first loss

    indemnity for the ECBs bond-buying programme, then the SMP could expand further.

    Some indicative numbers are below.

    50% indemnity of the ECBs SMP 598bn. If the EFSF were to provide a

    50% loss guarantee, then it would be able to indemnify the ECB against 758bn

    in bond purchases. After subtracting the existing SMP, this would result in

    additional buying power to the tune of 598bn. This would allow for Septembersrapid pace of bond purchases to be maintained for nearly 19 months, but the

    larger the pool of resources that are committed to the SMP the more credible

    the ECBs actions become and the less potential there is for them actually being

    required.

    25% indemnity of the ECBs SMP 1,356bn. If the EFSF provides a 25%

    first loss guarantee to the SMP then the available pool of resources increases to

    1,516bn which would allow for fresh SMP purchases of 1,355bn. This would

    allow for Septembers pace of bond purchases to be maintained for 43 months,

    and would represent a sizable policy response to the crisis.

    Were the EU to announce that the EFSF were to provide a 25% first loss indemnity to the

    ECB and that200bn of funds would be allocated to fund euro-area bank recapitalisation

    (with larger countries such as Germany and France potentially funding their own

    recapitalisations), then this could significantly alter market sentiment. This package may

    not be sufficient to deliver a steady state solution and at the end of the ECB purchases

    Euro-area countries would need to have addressed their solvency concerns. However,

    the package does provide a significant window of opportunity.

    The key question, is whether the ECB would accept a mere 25% first loss guarantee or

    would it require a larger if not full indemnity? Given that this proposal would increase

    many of the ECBs concerns regarding the SMP noted above (in particular, concerns

    about the capacity to sterilise such a large balance sheet expansion, concerns about

    central bank independence, and the fact that a partial guarantee would still entail a

    potential credit loss), we feel that it is unlikely that the ECB be willing to accept such a

    low first loss provision at this stage of the crisis..

    With EFSF indemnity, the

    ECB could expand the

    SMP up to 1.4trn

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    5/11

    Nomura Global Economics 5 10 October 2011

    However, one practical problem with the proposals above is that parliamentary approval

    is required for the suggested changes to the EFSF. That would likely take at least three

    months, meaning that there may be an interim period when the SMP continues in its

    current form.

    Adverse implications of the indemnity options correlation riskand reconfigured EFSF

    It is important to note two additional implications of the indemnity options. First, by

    utilising the full 726bn in EFSF guarantees, a clear correlation risk would exist sincecountries that would be the target of the SMP would be large contributors to the

    guarantee structure. Italy currently accounts for 19.2% of the EFSFs maximum

    guarantee commitments. Were Italy to step out, unless other countries increased their

    commitments, then the available pool of resources would need to decline. This would not

    be a problem with proposals that utilise the EFSFs 440bn structure, since there rely on

    over-collateralisation of AAA countries and hence do not contain this correction risk.

    Secondly, the indemnity option could require a restructuring of the EFSF structure. Part

    of the EFSFs operations could largely continue unaffected, notably the debt that is

    issued to fund participation in Troika bailout packages and, potentially in the future, bank

    recapitalisations. However, the EFSFs indemnity of the ECB could be structurally

    problematic. The EFSF would issue debt which would be transferred, not lent, to the ECB.This would leave the EFSF with a liability but without an asset with which to service or

    repay its debt. EFSF liabilities would be paid by the guarantors, but this option seems

    inefficient to us. It would be more efficient if governments were to issue debt in their own

    name to finance the ECBs indemnity commitments, and given the statutory requirements

    for the ECB to be recapitalised a similar arrangement already exists. This could entail

    part of the EFSF becoming a mechanism for co-ordinating the transfer of callable

    capital/callable indemnity funds to the ECB.

    These downsides may not necessarily be constraints against the indemnity option, but

    they are important in our view.

    Category 2 - Non indemnity and leverage scenarios

    Options outside of the ECB indemnity proposal require a view on whether the SMP will

    continue and in what size. One can argue that if the EU could implement one of the

    proposals which entail leveraging the EFSF into a 2-3trn pool of usable/investible

    resources, then the scale of the policy response would be so large that the need for SMP

    buying would be removed. This is true, but as we have argued we doubt that there is a

    viable leverage option that could generate such a large pool of investible resources.

    There are three most likely paths to leverage, all of which we think are flawed:

    EFSF turns into a bank and levers its capital base via repos with the ECB .

    The obvious hurdle to this solution is whether the ECB would be willing to allow

    a rapid expansion of its balance sheet and expansion of credit risk on its

    portfolio. This reticence has thus far limited the scale of its SMP programme.

    Indeed, in his final press conference, ECB President Trichet implied that the

    Bank was not supportive of being the mechanism through which the EFSF is

    levered.

    EFSF turns into a bank and undertakes repo financing with the market

    albeit with guarantees from Euro-areagovernments against counterparty

    losses on repo. This option could limit the amount of leverage that the EFSF

    could undertake since increasing the guarantees would incur a contingent

    liability which would raise concerns about the stability of the AAA ratings of

    selected sovereigns in Europe.

    EFSF turns into a bank and utilises repo financing with the market withoutgovernment guarantees. Under this scenario we struggle to see the EFSF

    leveraging itself more than 2x, which would result in a set of usable resources

    that fell considerably short of the recent 2-3trn headlines. The EFSF could

    EFSF 3.0 will require at

    least three months of

    parliamentary approvals

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    6/11

    Nomura Global Economics 6 10 October 2011

    finance non-core debt on relatively generous repo terms (limited collateral

    haircuts) up to the point where its purchases would match its available

    resources. Without additional guarantees, if the EFSF were to lever its balance

    sheet, its perceived credit worthiness would increasingly be defined by the

    quality of its assets (non-core debt) rather than its capital base, meaning

    steadily increasing collateral haircuts would likely be used to address this

    counterpart credit risk. At 2x leverage, repo counterparties would see that a

    50% loss on the EFSFs debt holdings (under an extreme scenario) would

    generate a 25% recovery rate. Beyond this level (and potentially even before

    this point), the cost of repo financing could be prohibitive.

    If we assume that the ECB repo financing is not a viable policy option at this stage, then

    the leverage option would not be large enough to render the SMP redundant. Hence, we

    need to know the likely fate of the SMP when the EFSF 2.0 is up and running, we

    presume, later this month.

    Absent a shock-and-awe solution, the SMP should continue afterEFSF 2.0 is implemented

    As we noted above, there is currently no credible policy backstop to ensure that the

    governments of Spain and Italy continue to have market access. Hopes have been

    raised that a comprehensive framework for addressing the euro-area debt crisis can bedelivered at the G20 meeting in Cannes on 3-4 November as was flagged by this

    weekends Merkel-Sarkozy summit. Encouragingly, Angela Merkel and Nicholas Sarkozy

    appeared to have increased the scope of their ambitions as they implied that a

    comprehensive solution would encompass a bank recapitalisation, a "durable" solution

    for Greece and some form of policy change probably revolving around the EFSF that

    could channel additional fiscal resources to the debt crisis. However, as noted above, we

    doubt any shock-and-awe policy announcement will be delivered given our past research

    which highlights the numerous constraints on aggressively leveraging the EFSF, moving

    towards closer fiscal union and the ECBs reluctance to substantially expand its balance

    sheet via the accumulation of greater credit risk.

    Moreover, without a comprehensive framework for addressing the debt crisis, we see the

    hoped for recapitalisation of the euro-area banking system being only of partial benefit.

    The market would have no certainly that it could crystallise the potential capital deficit in

    the financial system since it would lack confidence about the accuracy of assumptions

    regarding the book value of financial institutions. (In the US in 2009 it was critical that

    TARP was combined with a policy of monetary and fiscal reflation which eased the

    markets fears about the downside risks to bank asset values, and in Europe a credible

    framework for addressing the non-core debt crisis will need to play the role that policy

    reflation did in the US.)

    Without a credible policy package that can arrest market fears regarding euro-area debt,

    we believe the ECB would have no alternative but to maintain its SMP programme.

    Indeed, given that the ECB is likely fully aware that the EFSF 2.0 is unable to take over

    its stated role of buying euro-area debt, we believe that the Bank may not even pause in

    its bond-buying programme once the institution is up and running. Instead, it may carry

    on and wait for the EFSF 2.0 to begin its buying programme, which we doubt it will be

    able to. (The more bearish alternative, is that the ECB does indeed suspend its SMP and

    only resumes buying in the likely, in our view, event of a notable widening in non-core

    spreads to Bunds as the EFSF 2.0 proves unable to stabilise markets.)

    and a continuation of the past six months implies156bn in SMPover the coming year

    It is highly uncertain how many bonds the ECB would need to buy to ensure market

    access. As we said earlier (see Special Topic: Q&A on the ECB and the EFSF, 12

    August 2011), an optimistic view is that the simple threat of ECB intervention would be

    sufficient to keep yields low. And the most pessimistic assumption is that the ECB might

    have to be ready to buy the entire outstanding stock of Italian and Spanish liquid debt

    Without a credible policy

    backstop...

    ...the ECB will probably

    have to maintain its SMP...

    ...possibly buying156bn

    bonds over the coming

    year

    http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=457886http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=457886http://go.nomuranow.com/research/globalresearchportal/getpub.aspx?pid=457886
  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    7/11

    Nomura Global Economics 7 10 October 2011

    (e.g.467bn Bonos for Spain and1.1trn BTB for Italy), but we rule out at this stage any

    major expansion of the ECBs balance sheet.

    We assume that the SMP bond buying will be similar in scale to that which has prevailed

    over the past six months. The scale of buying should be sensitive to prevailing market

    conditions, but the bias which has guided ECB bond-buying over the past six months

    should persist the SMP should provide the minimum level of liquidity support needed to

    ensure that countries which the Bank believes have a liquidity problem will be able to

    access the markets. In terms of size, over the past eight weeks the SMP has resulted in

    average weekly bond purchases of around 11bn, or roughly 44bn a month, however

    over the past six months which encompassed periods of relative market calm

    average weekly purchases have measured 3.3bn or roughly 13bn a month (see

    Figures 1 and 2).

    A sustained continuation of the SMPs pace of the past 8 weeksappears unlikely

    Extrapolating the past eight weeks bond purchases over the coming 12 months results in

    SMP purchases over this period of around 528bn and means a 26.4% increase in the

    size of the ECB's balance sheet. This would represent a notable increase in the pace of

    expansion but we view this as a less likely extreme scenario. If there were such a large

    and persistent need for ECB intervention then we think increased pressure would bebrought to bear on policymakers to accelerate the search for a steady state solution.

    Similarly, since we assume that such a large and sustained increase in SMP would be in

    response to adverse market conditions, almost by definition we assume that such a large

    scale of buying would not be sufficient to transform market sentiment towards Europe.

    Indeed, one danger with a continuation of the SMP is that the market starts to price-in

    such a large expansion of bond purchases, which is one reason why our FX strategy

    team would view the maintenance of an SMP without a pre-defined limit as negative for

    the EUR.

    Alternatively, there could be a continuation of the trend of the past six months. This would

    entail an expansion of the SMP programme over the coming year of 156bn or a mere

    7.8% increase in the ECB's balance sheet. The reality may prove to be somewhere inbetween these scenarios, in which case the SMP may have a less significant impact on

    the size of the ECB's balance sheet than would the provision of the 12-month Long Term

    Refinancing Operations.

    Our view assumes that: (1) SMP is not inflationary,, and (2) Italy and Spain continue to

    deliver on austerity and structural reform programmes. The ECB would likely scale back

    its support (but not stop completely) if Spain and Italy did not deliver the required fiscal

    policy initiatives. The question then would be whether the rise in yields would push

    Spanish and Italian policymakers back towards their programme of fiscal consolidation

    We assume a similar scale

    of SMP bond-buying to

    the past six months

    Figure 1. SMP weekly bond-buying amounts Figure 2. SMP total outstanding amount

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    10-May 02-Aug 25-Oct 17-Jan 11-Apr 04-Jul 26-Sep

    , bn

    Weekly SMP amounts

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    10-May 02-Aug 25-Oct 17-Jan 11-Apr 04-Jul 26-Sep

    , bn

    Total amount purchases

    Source: ECB and Nomura Global Economics Source: ECB and Nomura Global Economics

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    8/11

    Nomura Global Economics 8 10 October 2011

    and thereby allow the ECB to step up its support.

    An ECB pre-commitment to a future SMP appears unlikely

    Indeed, this desire on the part of the ECB to make bond purchases conditional means

    that the likelihood of the Bank announcing and pre-committing to a large bond purchase

    programme is, in our view, very low. The ECB would not want its flexibility curtailed in this

    manner. The new ECB President, Mario Draghi, understands that unconditional help to

    Italy given its politics would be the worst possible outcome in terms of moral hazard,

    and this is a concept which continues to frame ECB thinking about the financial crisis farmore than it has guided the US Feds policy response.

    As for the longevity of the SMP programme, we think this is contingent on external

    factors such as whether the EU can develop a plan that will address the markets

    concerns about debt sustainability in the euro area. Alternatively, in an extreme scenario

    whereby the euro-area crisis results in a deep and lasting recession in Europe and

    generates a significant degree of deflation risk, then the potential for the SMP to expand

    significantly would grow if, as is possible under this scenario, interest rates approach

    their zero bound. But on this score the path to the current SMP might not be so clear

    since in order to engineer inflation in the euro area through QE, one would optimally

    require the ECB to buy government bonds across the euro area, not just periphery bonds.

    So this would involve buying German bunds in very significant amounts.

    Conclusion one market risk removed, many remaining

    In summary, assuming that the EU does not deliver a policy response that directly

    addresses the issue of the SMP by generating a shock-and-awe policy that obviates

    the need for ECB buying, or if it sanctions a policy of indemnifying the ECB against credit

    losses on its bond purchases then we assume that, even after EFSF 2.0 becomes

    effective, the SMP will be maintained.

    While the scale of bond purchases should be sensitive to prevailing market conditions,

    the general goal of the SMP will remain to provide the minimum level of market support

    needed to maintain market access for countries deemed to have a liquidity rather than a

    solvency problem. This outcome would be a positive one for the market in that, if we areright, it would address a key area of market risk, namely the question as to what happens

    to the euro-area debt market once the EFSF 2.0 becomes operational.

    However, as has been seen throughout the life of the SMP, the scale of the programme

    will likely remain insufficient to comprise a solution to the debt crisis and risks continuing

    to be a mechanism that allows the market to scale back its DV01 exposure to non-core

    Europe, without many of these funds being reinvested outside of core bond markets.

    Bond-buying continues to

    be conditional on Italy

    delivering austerity

    ECB bond-buying should

    continue even after EFSF

    2.0 becomes operational

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    9/11

    Nomura Global Economics 9 10 October 2011

    ANALYST CERTIFICATIONS

    We Jens Sondergaard and Desmond Supple, hereby certify (1) that the views expressed in this report accurately reflect our personalviews about any or all of the subject securities or issuers referred to in this report, (2) no part of our compensation was, is or will bedirectly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views expressed in this report and (3) no part of our compensation is tiedto any specific investment banking transactions performed by Nomura Securities International, Inc., Nomura International plc or anyother Nomura Group company.

    Issuer Specific Regulatory Disclosures

    Mentioned companies

    Issuer name Disclosures

    EUROPEAN FINANCIAL STABILITY FACILITY 49

    GOVERNMENT OF PORTUGAL 11

    Disclosures required in the U.S.

    49 Possible IB related compensation in the next 3 monthsNomura Securities International, Inc. and/or its affiliates expects to receive or intends to seek compensation for investment bankingservices from the company in the next three months.

    Disclosures required in the European Union

    11 Liquidity providerNomura International plc and/or its affiliates (collectively "Nomura") is a primary dealer and/or liquidity provider in European, UnitedStates and Japanese government bonds. As such, Nomura will generally always hold positions in these bonds, which from time totime, may be considered a significant financial interest.

    IMPORTANT DISCLOSURES

    Online availability of research and additional conflict-of-interest disclosures

    Nomura Japanese Equity Research is available electronically for clients in the US on NOMURA.COM, REUTERS, BLOOMBERG andTHOMSON ONE ANALYTICS. For clients in Europe, Japan and elsewhere in Asia it is available on NOMURA.COM, REUTERS andBLOOMBERG.Important disclosures may be accessed through the left hand side of the Nomura Disclosure web pagehttp://www.nomura.com/researchor

    requested from Nomura Securities International, Inc., on 1-877-865-5752. If you have any difficulties with the website, please [email protected] technical assistance.The analysts responsible for preparing this report have received compensation based upon various factors including the firm's totalrevenues, a portion of which is generated by Investment Banking activities.Unless otherwise noted, the non-US analysts listed at the front of this report are not registered/qualified as research analysts underFINRA/NYSE rules, may not be associated persons of NSI, and may not be subject to FINRA Rule 2711 and NYSE Rule 472restrictions on communications with covered companies, public appearances, and trading securities held by a research analyst account.

    ADDITIONAL DISCLOSURES REQUIRED IN THE U.S.

    Principal Trading: Nomura Securities International, Inc and its affiliates will usually trade as principal in the fixed income securities (or inrelated derivatives) that are the subject of this research report. Analyst Interactions with other Nomura Securities Internat ional, IncPersonnel: The fixed income research analysts of Nomura Securities International, Inc and its affiliates regularly interact with sales andtrading desk personnel in connection with obtaining liquidity and pricing information for their respective coverage universe.

    Valuation Methodology - Global Strategy

    A Relative Value based recommendation is the principal approach used by Nomuras Fixed Income Strategists / Analysts when they

    make Buy (Long) Hold and Sell (Short) recommendations to clients. These recommendations use a valuation methodology thatidentifies relative value based on:a) Opportunistic spread differences between the appropriate benchmark and the security or the financial instrument,b) Divergence between a countrys underlying macro or micro-economic fundamentals and its currencys value andc) Technical factors such as supply and demand flows in the market that may temporarily distort valuations when compared to anequilibrium priced solely on fundamental factors.In addition, a Buy (Long) or Sell (Short) recommendation on an individual security or financial instrument is intended to conveyNomuras belief that the price/spread on the security in question is expected to outperform (underperform) similarly structured securitiesover a three to twelve-month time period. This outperformance (underperformance) can be the result of several factors, including but notlimited to: credit fundamentals, macro/micro economic factors, unexpected trading activity or an unexpected upgrade (downgrade) by amajor rating agency.

    DISCLAIMERS

    This publication contains material that has been prepared by the Nomura entity identified at the top or bottom of page 1 herein, if any,and/or, with the sole or joint contributions of one or more Nomura entities whose employees and their respective affiliations are specifiedon page 1 herein or elsewhere identified in the publication. Affiliates and subsidiaries of Nomura Holdings, Inc. (collectively, the 'Nomura

    Group'), include: Nomura Securities Co., Ltd. ('NSC') Tokyo, Japan; Nomura International plc ('NIplc'), United Kingdom; NomuraSecurities International, Inc. ('NSI'), New York, NY; Nomura International (Hong Kong) Ltd. (NIHK), Hong Kong; Nomura FinancialInvestment (Korea) Co., Ltd. (NFIK), Korea (Information on Nomura analysts registered with the Korea Financial InvestmentAssociation ('KOFIA') can be found on the KOFIA Intranet at http://dis.kofia.or.kr ); Nomura Singapore Ltd. (NSL), Singapore(Registration number 197201440E, regulated by the Monetary Authority of Singapore); Capital Nomura Securities Public Company

    http://www.nomura.com/researchhttp://www.nomura.com/researchhttp://www.nomura.com/researchmailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://www.nomura.com/research
  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    10/11

    Nomura Global Economics 10 10 October 2011

    Limited (CNS), Thailand; Nomura Australia Ltd. (NAL), Australia (ABN 48 003 032 513), regulated by the Australian Securit ies andInvestment Commission ('ASIC') and holder of an Australian financial services licence number 246412; P.T. Nomura Indonesia (PTNI),Indonesia; Nomura Securities Malaysia Sdn. Bhd. (NSM), Malaysia; Nomura International (Hong Kong) Ltd., Taipei Branch (NITB),Taiwan; Nomura Financial Advisory and Securities (India) Private Limited (NFASL), Mumbai, India (Registered Address: Ceejay House,Level 11, Plot F, Shivsagar Estate, Dr. Annie Besant Road, Worli, Mumbai- 400 018, India; SEBI Registration No: BSE INB011299030,NSE INB231299034, INF231299034, INE 231299034); Banque Nomura France (BNF); NIplc, Dubai Branch (NIplc, Dubai); NIplc,Madrid Branch (NIplc, Madrid) and OOO Nomura, Moscow (OOO Nomura).

    THIS MATERIAL IS: (I) FOR YOUR PRIVATE INFORMATION, AND WE ARE NOT SOLICITING ANY ACTION BASED UPON IT; (II)NOT TO BE CONSTRUED AS AN OFFER TO SELL OR A SOLICITATION OF AN OFFER TO BUY ANY SECURITY IN ANYJURISDICTION WHERE SUCH OFFER OR SOLICITATION WOULD BE ILLEGAL; AND (III) BASED UPON INFORMATION THAT WECONSIDER RELIABLE.

    NOMURA GROUP DOES NOT WARRANT OR REPRESENT THAT THE PUBLICATION IS ACCURATE, COMPLETE, RELIABLE, FITFOR ANY PARTICULAR PURPOSE OR MERCHANTABLE AND DOES NOT ACCEPT LIABILITY FOR ANY ACT (OR DECISION NOTTO ACT) RESULTING FROM USE OF THIS PUBLICATION AND RELATED DATA. TO THE MAXIMUM EXTENT PERMISSIBLE ALLWARRANTIES AND OTHER ASSURANCES BY NOMURA GROUP ARE HEREBY EXCLUDED AND NOMURA GROUP SHALL HAVENO LIABILITY FOR THE USE, MISUSE, OR DISTRIBUTION OF THIS INFORMATION.

    Opinions expressed are current opinions as of the original publication date appearing on this material only and the information, includingthe opinions contained herein, are subject to change without notice. Nomura is under no duty to update this publication. If and asapplicable, NSI's investment banking relationships, investment banking and non-investment banking compensation and securitiesownership (identified in this report as 'Disclosures Required in the United States'), if any, are specified in disclaimers and relateddisclosures in this report. In addition, other members of the Nomura Group may from time to time perform investment banking or otherservices (including acting as advisor, manager or lender) for, or solicit investment banking or other business from, companies mentionedherein. Furthermore, the Nomura Group, and/or its officers, directors and employees, including persons, without limitation, involved inthe preparation or issuance of this material may, to the extent permitted by applicable law and/or regulation, have long or short positionsin, and buy or sell, the securities (including ownership by NSI, referenced above), or derivatives (including options) thereof, ofcompanies mentioned herein, or related securities or derivatives. For financial instruments admitted to trading on an EU regulatedmarket, Nomura Holdings Inc's affiliate or its subsidiary companies may act as market maker or liquidity provider (in accordance with the

    interpretation of these definitions under FSA rules in the UK) in the financial instruments of the issuer. Where the activity of liquidityprovider is carried out in accordance with the definition given to it by specific laws and regulations of other EU jurisdictions, this will beseparately disclosed within this report. Furthermore, the Nomura Group may buy and sell certain of the securities of companiesmentioned herein, as agent for its clients.

    Investors should consider this report as only a single factor in making their investment decision and, as such, the report should not beviewed as identifying or suggesting all risks, direct or indirect, that may be associated with any investment decision. Please see thefurther disclaimers in the disclosure information on companies covered by Nomura analysts available at www.nomura.com/researchunder the 'Disclosure' tab. Nomura Group produces a number of different types of research product including, among others,fundamental analysis, quantitative analysis and short term trading ideas; recommendations contained in one type of research p roductmay differ from recommendations contained in other types of research product, whether as a result of differing time horizons,methodologies or otherwise; it is possible that individual employees of Nomura may have different perspectives to this publication.

    NSC and other non-US members of the Nomura Group (i.e. excluding NSI), their officers, directors and employees may, to the extent itrelates to non-US issuers and is permitted by applicable law, have acted upon or used this material prior to, or immediately following, itspublication.

    Foreign-currency-denominated securities are subject to fluctuations in exchange rates that could have an adverse effect on the value orprice of, or income derived from, the investment. In addition, investors in securities such as ADRs, the values of which are influenced by

    foreign currencies, effectively assume currency risk.

    The securities described herein may not have been registered under the US Securities Act of 1933, and, in such case, may not beoffered or sold in the United States or to US persons unless they have been registered under such Act, or except in compliance with anexemption from the registration requirements of such Act. Unless governing law permits otherwise, you must contact a Nomura entity inyour home jurisdiction if you want to use our services in effecting a transaction in the securities mentioned in this material.

    This publication has been approved for distribution in the United Kingdom and European Union as investment research by NIplc, whichis authorized and regulated by the UK Financial Services Authority ('FSA') and is a member of the London Stock Exchange. It does notconstitute a personal recommendation, as defined by the FSA, or take into account the particular investment objectives, financialsituations, or needs of individual investors. It is intended only for investors who are 'eligible counterparties' or 'professional clients' asdefined by the FSA, and may not, therefore, be redistributed to retail clients as defined by the FSA. This publication may be distributedin Germany via Nomura Bank (Deutschland) GmbH, which is authorized and regulated in Germany by the Federal Financial SupervisoryAuthority ('BaFin'). This publication has been approved by NIHK, which is regulated by the Hong Kong Securities and FuturesCommission, for distribution in Hong Kong by NIHK. This publication has been approved for distribution in Australia by NAL, which isauthorized and regulated in Australia by the ASIC. This publication has also been approved for distribution in Malaysia by NSM. InSingapore, this publication has been distributed by NSL. NSL accepts legal responsibility for the content of this publication, where it

    concerns securities, futures and foreign exchange, issued by their foreign affiliates in respect of recipients who are not accredited,expert or institutional investors as defined by the Securities and Futures Act (Chapter 289). Recipients of this publication should contactNSL in respect of matters arising from, or in connection with, this publication. Unless prohibited by the provisions of Regulation S of theU.S. Securities Act of 1933, this material is distributed in the United States, by NSI, a US-registered broker-dealer, which acceptsresponsibility for its contents in accordance with the provisions of Rule 15a-6, under the US Securities Exchange Act of 1934.

    This publication has not been approved for distribution in the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia or to clients other than 'professional clients' in theUnited Arab Emirates by Nomura Saudi Arabia, NIplc or any other member of the Nomura Group, as the case may be. Neither thispublication nor any copy thereof may be taken or transmitted or distributed, directly or indirectly, by any person other than thoseauthorised to do so into the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia or in the United Arab Emirates or to any person located in the Kingdom of SaudiArabia or to clients other than 'professional clients' in the United Arab Emirates. By accepting to receive this publication, you representthat you are not located in the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia or that you are a 'professional client' in the United Arab Emirates and agree tocomply with these restrictions. Any failure to comply with these restrictions may constitute a violation of the laws of the K ingdom ofSaudi Arabia or the United Arab Emirates.

    No part of this material may be (i) copied, photocopied, or duplicated in any form, by any means; or (ii) redistributed without the priorwritten consent of the Nomura Group member identified in the banner on page 1 of this report. Further information on any of thesecurities mentioned herein may be obtained upon request. If this publication has been distributed by electronic transmission, such as e-

    mail, then such transmission cannot be guaranteed to be secure or error-free as information could be intercepted, corrupted, lost,destroyed, arrive late or incomplete, or contain viruses. The sender therefore does not accept liability for any errors or omissions in thecontents of this publication, which may arise as a result of electronic transmission. If verification is required, please request a hard-copyversion.

  • 8/3/2019 ESFS 3.0 - Evropsk fond finann stability (EFSF, dokument v AJ)

    11/11

    Additional information available upon request.

    NIPlc and other Nomura Group entities manage conflicts identified through the following: their Chinese Wall, confidentiality andindependence policies, maintenance of a Stop List and a Watch List, personal account dealing rules, policies and procedures formanaging conflicts of interest arising from the allocation and pricing of securities and impartial investment research and disclosure toclients via client documentation.

    Disclosure information is available at the Nomura Disclosure web page:

    http://www.nomura.com/research/pages/disclosures/disclosures.aspx

    Nomura International plc Tel: +44 20 7102 1000

    1 Angel Lane, London EC4R 3AB

    Caring for the environment: to receive only the electronic versions of our research, please contact your sales representative.

    http://www.nomura.com/research/pages/disclosures/disclosures.aspxhttp://www.nomura.com/research/pages/disclosures/disclosures.aspxhttp://www.nomura.com/research/pages/disclosures/disclosures.aspx