entry choices hight-tech.pdf

download entry choices hight-tech.pdf

of 31

Transcript of entry choices hight-tech.pdf

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    1/31

    The International Market Entry Choices

    of Start Up Companies in High

    Technology Industries

    For a young, resource-co nstrained, technology-based start-up

    emba rking on intemational sales, the choice of entry mode is a

    strategic decision of major importance . Yet within the emerging

    research stream of intemational entrepreneurship, curiously lit-

    tle attention has been devoted to the empirical analysis of for-

    eign marke t entry forms. The authors address this important

    issue by analyzing the determinants of 398 export decisions

    taken from a

    U K

    survey of 246 technology-based start-ups with

    intemational activities. The findings show that the entry m ode

    decision is necessarily a trade-off hetween the resources avail-

    able and the support requirem ents of the customer. Issues of the

    innovativeness of the technology and the historic channel expe-

    rience of the firm in its domestic market

    are

    particularly strong

    determinants of mode choice. The authors suggest that an

    orga-

    nizational capability perspective on these firms behavior offers

    a better explanation of their entry decisions than either transac-

    tion cost

    or stage

    theory.

    During the past decade, the phenomen on of globalization bas

    received considerable attention and bas shaped botb tbe dis-

    course and tbe actions of managers, policymakers, and acad-

    emics. Researcb on the topic is rooted p rimarily in sociology,

    cultural studies, political science, and economics. A com-

    mon denominator is the definition of globalization as a

    process in w hich the constraints of geography on social, cul-

    tural, political, and economic arrangements recede (Waters

    1995). One manifestation of a globalizing world is the emer-

    gence of entrepreneurial start-ups that have an international

    outlook from inception. Some of these firms even carry out

    different activities along their value chains in different coun-

    tries and thereby blur tbe national identity of the firm. The

    international activities of these exceptional young firms

    labeled infant mu ltinationa ls (Lindqvist 1991), born glob-

    als (Knigbt and Cavusgil

    1996;

    McKinsey Company 1993),

    and international new ventu res (Oviatt and McDougall

    1994)have received an increasing amount of attention from

    researchers over the past couple of years. Yet relatively little

    attention has been devoted to tbe empirical analysis of for-

    eign entry modes. Most studies provide descriptive informa-

    tion on the chosen entry modes, but witb tbe exception of

    Lindqvist (1991), Bell (1995), and Shrader, Oviatt, and Mc-

    Dougall (1997), few researchers have attempted to explain

    A B S T R A C T

    Oliver Burgel and

    Gordon C. Murray

    Submitted December 1998

    Revised June 1999

    Jouma l of ntemational Marketing

    Vol 8, No. 2, 2000, pp. 33-62

    ISSN10B9 031X

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    2/31

    PREVIOUS RESEARCH

    IN INTERNATIONAL

    ENTREPRENEURSHIP

    the choice of entry modes. This omission is even more sur-

    prising given that it is vy^idely acknow^ledged that the initial

    foreign entry behavior of

    a

    young firm can he of major impor-

    tance in its future economic success.

    Empirical studies in international entrepreneurship have

    heen hoth exploratory and , less frequently, explanatory in na-

    ture. Whereas some have had an explicit focus on interna-

    tional husiness theories, others have focused more on general

    performance issues. Qualitative stud ies have described prod-

    uct characteristics (Jolly, Alahuhta, and Jeannet 1992; Miuray

    1996; Roberts and Senturia 1996), market entry forms (Jolly,

    Alahuhta, and Jeannet 1992; McDougall, Shane, and Oviatt

    1994;

    Roberts and Senturia 1996), and characteristics of

    founders and key employees (Boter and Holmquist 1996; Mc-

    Dougall, Shane, and Oviatt 1994; Mvirray 1996; Roherts and

    Senturia 1996). Quantitative studies we siuveyed have ana-

    lyzed structural characteristics of the firms, including age,

    size, and technology intensity (Lindell and Karagozoglou

    1997; Lindqvist 1991), market entry forms (Bell 1995;

    Lindqvist 1991; Shrader, Oviatt, and McDougall 1997), geo-

    graphic spread of foreign sales (Bell 1995; Shrader, Oviatt,

    and McDougall 1997), the relation between strategic orienta-

    tion and growth/profitahility (Bloodgood, Sapienza, and

    Almeida 1996; McDougall and Oviatt 1996; Shrader, Oviatt,

    and McDougall 1997), characteristics of founders and key

    employees (Bloodgood, Sapienza, and Almeida 1996), and

    the role of risk in internationalization decisions (Shrader,

    Oviatt, and McDougall 1997).

    Three empirical studies that investigate entry modes in more

    detail stand out. Lindqvist (1991) reports that the preferred

    entry modes of the Swedish firms in her sample were direct

    exporting and foreign sales through intermediaries such as

    agents and distrihutors. However, she does not investigate the

    determinants that influence the choice of entry modes. In-

    stead, she explores the propensity to use sales subsidiaries.

    Here, she finds no or weak relationships between entry mode

    choices and product characteristics, research and develop-

    ment(R D)intensity, or market size. Lindqvist's findings sug-

    gest that internationalization could be understood as

    jumping a threshold ; that is, when the firms have decided

    to operate internationally, their choice of entry modes is not

    influenced by structural characteristics, such as size andR D

    intensity. In Bell's (1995) study of the in ternational operations

    of Irish, Finnish, and Norwegian software firms, 70% of all

    sales transactions were carried out through either direct ex-

    ports or agents and distributors. Few firms engaged in foreign

    direct investment, and when this did occur, they were preoc-

    cupied with setting up marketing and sales suhsidiaries.

    Firms that commercialized highly customized products al-

    most exclusively relied on direct exporting, whereas firms

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    3/31

    that sold standard, off-the-shelf products were more likely to

    use sales intermediaries. Shrader, Oviatt, and McDougall

    (1997) argue that different entry modes represent different de-

    grees of resource commitment and therefore risk for the firm.

    They argue that firms actively manage their risk in interna-

    tional operations by balancing entry m ode risk, country risk,

    and risk from overdependence of foreign markets. Their em-

    pirical findings on

    U.S.

    irms

    hat high-risk countries were en-

    tered using low-risk/low-commitment market entry modes

    and vice versa support their theoretical argument.

    Two theoretical articles analyze the structural aspects of in-

    ternational activities in more detail. Oviatt and McDougall

    (1994) examine internationa l new ventures (INVs), a type of

    firm that from inception, seeks to derive significant compet-

    itive advantage from the use of resources and the sale of out-

    puts in mu ltiple coun tries (Oviatt and McDougall 1994, p.

    49).They argue that sustainable INVs must have an innova-

    tive organizational structurefor example, assuming a con-

    trolling position in a network or using hybrid arrangements

    involving subcontractors and intermediate sellers. More di-

    rectly related to the choice of entry mode, Zacharakis's (1997)

    contribution explicitly deals with the choice of export agents

    and distributors to enter international markets. Zacharakis

    only considers the use of intermediaries, because he claims

    that direct exporting is not an appropriate choice for

    start-ups. Civen the wealth of studies on exporting (for a

    recent review, see Leonidou and Katsikeas 1996) and interna-

    tionalization processes (Johanson and Vahlne 1990) that ind i-

    cate that direct exporting is actually a widespread entry

    mode of small firms, we believe that Zacharakis's perspective

    is too constrained to capture the full scope of decisions that

    managers of a new venture will face.

    These contributions represent important first steps in ex-

    plaining the entry decisions of internationally operating

    start-ups. These studies have several common elements.

    The firms investigated predom inantly operate in high-tech-

    nology industries. In addition, the majority of the studies

    have an explicit focus on young firms. Findings from quan-

    titative surveys agree that the preferred entry modes of tech-

    nology-based start-ups are characterized by relatively low

    resource commitment and are directed toward commercial-

    ization rather than foreign production. However, they also

    report that technology-based start-ups have a tendency to

    enter several foreign markets within a short time span. Most

    articles based on a case study methodology include firms

    that made bold commitments to international operations

    during their early years. Rapid and sometimes resource-

    intensive market entries into different countries were de-

    scribed. Some extreme cases were international from incep-

    tion and performed different activities along their value

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    4/31

    cbains in different countries McDougall, Sbane, and Oviatt

    1994). Together, these findings contrast previous research

    that examines the international activities of more tradi-

    tional small and medium-sized enterprises Bamberger and

    Evers 1994; Leonidou and Katsikeas 1996). However, they

    also leave questions about the determinants of the choice of

    a particular entry mode largely unaddressed. Acknowledg-

    ing the dearth of empirical studies in this area, Oviatt and

    McDougall 1997) conc lude that there is a need for further

    work to analyze the prevalence and determinants of interna-

    tional entrepreneurship.

    pjjg purpose of this study was to use a large data set to deter-

    RESE RC H OBJECTIVE ND

    mine wh at mo des of foreign market entry our resp ond ent

    H Y PO T H E SE S firms chose and wh at were the primary reasons for their

    elected choices. The modeled entry decision was simplified

    to the choice of selling abroad either by direct exporting or

    through the use of distributors. Our reasons for this choice

    are both pragm atic and the oretically justified. First, we re-

    ceive empirical support from previous studies, which report

    that exporting and the use of intermediaries are in reality the

    two predominant alternatives employed by entrepreneurial

    bigb-tecbnology firms Bell 1995; Lindqvist 1991). In sbort,

    our model mirrors wbat small firms actually do.

    Second, the choice between direct exporting and tbe use of

    distributors is of utmost managerial relevance for technology

    entrepreneurs. W ith the singular exception of the U.S. econ-

    omy, the finite market opportunities in many countries may

    not justify the development expenditures for certain highly

    specialized niche technologies unless international expan-

    sion is considered from inception . Technology-based start-

    ups therefore face a dangerous dilemma. On the one hand,

    they may be forced to venture abroad to belp amortize their

    initial development exp enditures and generate sufficient rev-

    enues to finance ongoing development activities. On the

    other hand, because many technology-based start-ups experi-

    ence negative cash fiows during their early years, they may

    lack the necessary human and financial resources required

    for the effective commercialization of their products on their

    own. Given these resource constraints, identifying end cus-

    tomers and providing pre- and after-sales support services

    may be handled better by a local partner. Tbe downside of

    this arrangement is that revenues must

    e

    shared between the

    start-up and the distributor. Additional costs can be incurred

    by the start-up because of tbe need to provide tecbnical train-

    ing and the creation of incentives and monitoring mecha-

    nism s. Early on, technology entrepreneurs therefore must

    make complex and highly strategic trade-offs, because the

    choice of the foreign sales mode may have profound implica-

    tions for botb costs and revenue generation.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    5/31

    Third, the main theoretical frameworks in the field of inter-

    national business that analyze entry modes come to different

    conclusions when they are applied to firms that at the same

    time are young (or inexperienced) and operate in high-tech-

    nology sectors. Process models (Johanson and Vahlne 1977,

    1990) consider commitment to internationalization a func-

    tion of experiential knowledge of foreign markets. Accord-

    ingly, a start-up company would be expected to gain initial

    experience through reactive exporting before proactively

    venturing into foreign markets. The choice between direct

    exporting and the use of more complex and proactive entry

    modes thus depends on firm experience and foreign market

    knowledge. Despite having received empirical support,

    process models and the subsequently developed stage

    mo dels of internatio naliz atio n (e.g., Cavusgil 1980) are

    frequently criticized for being too deterministic and for fail-

    ing to take firm-specific factors other than experience into

    account (Andersen 1993).

    A rival approach, the transaction cost economics (TCE) ap-

    proach, has been influential, as it provides a decision rule

    with regard to individual entry decisions. Firms are ex-

    pected to choose the governance or entry mode that mini-

    mizes the costs of carrying out particular transactions. In its

    application, TCE is concerned with comparing different in-

    stitutional arrangements for carrying out economic activity

    (Williamson 1985). As the choice between direct exporting

    and involving foreign distributors is essentially a choice be-

    tween an internal arrangement and an arrangement involv-

    ing an external third party, the tools of TCE are applicable

    to mod el the decision. Yet the TCE approach assumes a ca-

    pacity for discretionary resource deployment. For example,

    the com mercialization of a produc t incorporating advanced

    technology may require a high degree of asset specificity. If

    this asset specificity leads to high costs of involving a dis-

    tributor, a firm is expected to switch from direct exporting

    to a sales subsidiary when its foreign sales to a particular

    country exceed a certain level. However, this option may

    not reflect the reality of resource constraint start-ups. They

    may rather be inclined, or obliged, to establish collaborative

    relationships with intermediaries to get access to assets, re-

    sources, and capabilities they do not own. Cooperation may

    not be a choice but an imperative for the young firm. The

    widespread use of collaborative strategies in technology-

    intensive industries has triggered the development of the

    organizational capability (OC) perspective. Its proponents

    argue that OC, compared with TCE, represents a superior

    approach for the analysis of collaborative governance

    arrangements (Madhok 1997). To date, we do not know of

    any study that has applied the OC perspective to the inter-

    nationalization of smaller, entrepreneurial firms.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    6/31

    The key elements of these three competing internationaliza-

    tion theories (stage, TCE, and OC) can be isolated as separate

    and independent sets of variables in our decision model. Ac-

    cordingly, they are incorporated in our hypothesis construc-

    tion. The employment of an integrated multivariate approach

    should provide further evidence whether or not these sets of

    variables explain the choice of entry modes made by high-

    tech start-ups. Following established research practice, we

    have chosen the entry decision and not the firm as the unit of

    analysis. Similar to many other researchers, we argue that en-

    try decisions are a function of firm-specific factors, product-

    specific factors, and target country-specific factors (Cavusgil,

    Zou, and Naidu 1993; Erramilli and Rao 1993). Essentially,

    the choice between direct exporting and sales through

    distributors is a choice between an internalized transaction or

    an externalized transaction involving intermediaries. We find

    ourselves within the established tradition of researchers that

    have conceptualized entry modes choices as binary (see, e.g.,

    Barkema and Vermeulen 1998; Davidson and McFetridge

    98 ;Erramilli and Rao 1993; Kogut and Singh 1988). Ac-

    cordingly, we develop a set of hypotheses to test which vari-

    ables account for the choice between direct exporting and

    exporting through distributors as the two predominant modes

    of foreign market entry for technology-based start-ups.

    ^^ ^^^^^^^^^

    This discussion of our research objective leads to the genera-

    ypoth s s tion of seven related or closely associated hypotheses per-

    taining to those factors that most instrumentally influence

    the choice of channel mode used in entering first foreign

    markets. As has already been stressed, the choice for the

    young firm of either going alone (direct exporting) or allying

    with a partner (using a distributor) is of pivotal strategic im-

    portance given the risk/reward implications of this decision.

    Direct exporting gives the firm autonomy and control but de-

    nies it the assets (including networks) and experience of the

    distributor. Alternatively, to contract with a distributor raises

    the sensitive issues of sharing profit margins. The latter is

    likely to be influenced by the distribution of bargaining

    power within the manufacturer-distributor relationship

    (Zacharakis 1997). From the local distributor s perspective,

    the smaller the foreign manufacturer and the lower the po-

    tential sales volume, the less profitable the medium-term re-

    lationship is. Below a certain projected sales volume, the

    decision to provide the service will not be bilateral but will,

    in practice, be solely that of the distributor. Aligning the ob-

    jectives of the two parties has been studied widely in a do-

    mestic context (e.g., Anderson and Narus 1990; Heide and

    John 1994). Yet in a foreign country, the task of monitoring a

    distributor is likely to be even more difficult for a small en-

    trepreneurial firm. Therefore, selling through an established

    distributor relationship is likely to require higher up-front in-

    vestment than exporting. In the particular case of technology-

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    7/31

    based start-ups, tbe availability of resources is probably an

    even more crucial predictor of subsequent firm actions

    (Oakey, Rotbwell, and Cooper 1988). Accordingly, we argue

    that this route to foreign markets will be employed by start-

    ups commanding greater resources.

    Hi:

    Firms that sell into foreign markets through inter-

    mediaries are larger than firms that export directly

    to end customers.

    related hypothesis pertains to the international experience

    of the firm. The internationalization process perspective ar-

    gues that firms increase their commitment to international

    sales over time as their experiential knowledge of foreign

    markets increases (Johanson and Vahlne 1977, 1990). Ac-

    cording to this logic, firms that are more experienced in in-

    ternational sales are expected to use more resource-intensive

    entry modes. This view also posits that, over time , firms that

    start international sales with low-commitment entry modes

    switch to entry modes that require a higher degree of com-

    mitment as a result of better knowledge of foreign markets.

    Formalizing a distribution agreement frequently involves le-

    gal and other ad min istrative costs. The distributo r s staff

    must be trained in selling tbe product, installing it, and pro-

    viding subsequent maintenance or upgrades. Tberefore, we

    believe that the use of distributors represents a more commit-

    ted entry m ode that is used by more experienced firms.

    H2:

    Firms that sell into foreign markets through inter-

    mediaries are more experienced in international

    operations than firms that export directly to end

    customers.

    It is, however, not necessary that experience in international

    operations has to be gained by the firm as organizational en-

    tity. A young firm initiating its first market en tries cannot be

    expected to bave direct experiential knowledge of interna-

    tional operations embodied in its processes and routines.^ In

    tbe case of start-ups, the founders interna tional experience

    can be a substitute for organizational experience. If key man-

    agers in tbe young firm have previous experience in foreign

    markets, it may initiate cross-border activities using more

    complex entry modes. Accordingly, the international experi-

    ence of senior managers has in the past been used to predict

    the scale and scope of international activities of start-up

    firms (Bloodgood, Sapienza, and A lmeida 1996; Reuber and

    Fiscber 1997).

    H3: Managers of firms tbat sell into foreign markets

    tbrougb intermediaries will be more likely to have

    international experience than managers of firms

    that export directly.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    8/31

    The experienceof tbefirm isalsoa keyvariableinresearcb

    contributions tbat apply

    the

    OC perspective

    to the

    choice

    of

    entry modes (Anlakh

    and

    Kotabe 1997; Madbok 1997). Theo-

    ristsofOC argue that present outcomes arestrongly influ-

    enced

    by

    past experiences

    and

    routines that bave become

    embedded

    in the

    organization (Madhok 1997).

    Ifa

    firm uses

    a

    particular sales channel

    in its

    domestic market,

    it may be ex-

    pected

    to

    replicate tbis familiar practice (i.e., negotiating

    contracts, incentivizing,

    and

    motivating intermediaries)

    in

    foreign markets. Thus,

    tbe

    higher costs

    or

    risks

    of

    arranging

    more complex foreign sales modes

    can

    arguably

    be

    reduced

    through leveraging experiences gained earlierin adomestic

    market.^

    H4:Firms will sell into foreign markets tbrougb inter-

    mediaries rather than export directly

    if

    they already

    use distributors

    for

    tbeir domestic sales.

    The OC perspective argues that

    a

    firm's value-creating activi-

    tiesare afunction ofits resourceandcapability base (Madhok

    1997;Teece, Pisano,andShuen 1997). Madhok distinguishes

    between activities

    in

    which

    tbe

    focus

    is

    capability develop-

    ment

    and

    activities

    in

    wbich

    the

    focus

    is tbe

    exploitation

    ofanexisting advantage.In tbecaseofstart-upsgivenour

    focusonsales modeswe argue thattheobjectiveoftbeirin-

    ternational sales

    is to

    exploit fully

    the

    commercial value

    of

    tbeir technological competency to ensure tbeir survival.

    Mad-

    bok also introduces the notionsof ownership effect and lo-

    cational effect.

    Tbe

    former

    is

    represented

    by tbe

    ratio

    of

    embedded-to-generic firm-specific know-how, whereas

    tbe

    latter

    is

    defined

    as tbe

    ratio

    of

    embedded-to-generic market-

    specific knowledge (Madbok 1997). AccordingtoMadhok,a

    firm will carry

    out a

    transaction itself (internalization)

    if

    tbere

    is

    a

    high potential

    for tbe

    erosion

    in the

    value

    of tbe

    firm's

    know-how stemming from

    the

    ownership effect.

    In

    contrast,

    a

    firm will haveapreference forcollaborationifthereis abigb

    potential

    for the

    erosion

    in the

    value

    of

    the firm's know-how

    from

    the

    locational effect.

    In

    summary, collaborative arrange-

    ments will

    be

    preferred

    in

    countries where

    the

    idiosyncratic

    waysofdoing business erodethevalueoffirm-specific know-

    bow. Conversely,

    a

    firm

    is

    less likely to involve tbird parties

    if

    firm-specific know-bow

    is

    inimitable

    or

    immobile, whicb

    thereby makes

    the

    sharing of routines witb intermediaries

    dif-

    ficult (Hill, Hwang,and Kim1990; Madhok 1997). Tbissug-

    gests tbat

    a

    firm will have

    a

    higher propensity to avoid the

    use

    of intermediaries

    if

    its technology

    is

    advanced

    or if

    the firm

    is

    unfamiliar with potential users

    in its

    target market. Civen

    the

    importance oftacit knowledge for such products, market-

    based support infrastructures may

    not

    be effective

    or

    available

    (Meldrum 1995). Therefore, effective commercialization

    may

    only

    be

    possible

    by

    internalization

    of

    the sales process. Idio-

    syncratic ways

    of

    doing business abroad

    may

    therefore repre-

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    9/31

    sent a lesser barrier than in tbe case of more established tech-

    nologies, especially if tbe product is sold to industrialized

    countries. Collaborations are expected to occur more fre-

    quently when tbe technology is more mature and established,

    a proposition that has received some validity in p rior researcb

    on international technology transfers (Davidson and

    McFetridge 1985).

    H5:

    Tbe products of firms that sell into foreign markets

    through intermediaries are technologically more

    matvu:e tban those of firm s tbat export directly.

    Previous research on internationalization bas found that

    product characteristics affect the way firms manage their in-

    ternational activities (Cavusgil and Zou 1994; Cavusgil, Zou,

    and Naidu 1993). Product characteristics have also been

    found to influence tbe chosen entry modes in the case of

    young technology-based firms (Lindqvist 1991). Tbe impor-

    tance of client-specific customization as a barrier to interna-

    tionalization has been reported in studies that examine

    produc t characteristics of international start-ups (Lindell and

    Karagozoglou 1997; Murray 1996; Roberts and Senturia

    1996). Tbe transformation from offering customized technol-

    ogy solutions to offering standardized or shrink -wra pped

    products in whicb the technology is embedded is associated

    witb an increasing market orientation of the firm (Roberts

    1991). Companies whose pro ducts are tailor m ade for partic-

    ular customers bave been found to be more likely to sell

    directly witho ut involving interm ediaries (Bell 1995). Fur-

    thermore, it is more probable that the technological skills

    required to tailor a particular product to the needs of a cus-

    tomer reside within tbe company that developed the product

    rather than w ith the distributor in a target country.

    Hg: The products of firms that sell into foreign markets

    through intermediaries require less client-specific

    customization tban those of firms that export

    directly.

    The tools of TCE have also been widely used to analyze tbe

    determinan ts of entry mode choices. In essence, TCE is con-

    cerned with finding tbe most efficient institutional or con-

    tractual arrangement for economic transactions (Hennart

    1989). Instead of following tbe m ethods used by researchers

    who measure transaction costs indirectly by defining situa-

    tions in wbich asset specificity and uncertainty are suppos-

    edly high (see, e.g., Anderson and Catignon 1986; Hennart

    1990), we follow the approach of Klein, Frazier, and Rotb

    (1990) and attempt to measure tbe costs involved in tbe sell-

    ing process of high-tecbnology goods directly. During tbe

    sales process for high-tecbnology goods, the vendor may be

    required to spend considerable time advising and educating

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    10/31

    the potential customer on the key features and relative merits

    of the product. After the sale, more complex products may

    require installation by trainedstaff, regular after-sales ser-

    vice,

    and periodic upgrades (Cavusgil and Zou 1994; Hutt

    and Speh 1992). To carry out these tasks, the sales and tech-

    nical staff of the vendor will require particular skills. In the

    case of exporting, these skills are normally resident within

    the manufacturer. Selling a product through an intermediary,

    however, requires those skills also to be already present

    within, or transferable to, the distributor. The producer may

    therefore need to provide regular training to tbe staff of tbe

    intermediary to transfer the necessary skills and routines and

    effectively support the product. High up-front investments

    into these specific assets reduce tbe subsequent bargaining

    power and margins of the party that incurs these costs.

    Zacharakis (1997) argues that a small entrepreneurial firm is

    more likely to be obliged to reduce the distributor's set-up

    costs through the provision of training or other transfers than

    a large established multinational. Furthermore, a distributor

    may not be motivated to push a complex product that re-

    quires substantial presale consulting and installation efforts.

    Therefore, products and services that incur substantial costs

    during the sales process should make it more difficult to

    align the interests of the start-up and a potential distributor.

    However, selling a technologically advanced product is

    likely to require an effective support infrastructure (Meldrum

    1995).

    Using distributors tbat can exploit economies of scale

    and scope not available to tbe young firm may be the only

    way to provide tbe necessary infrastructure to service foreign

    customers. Furthermore, the costs of learning how to perform

    the relatively standardized tasks of installation, end-user

    training, and maintenance are likely to be relatively low

    when the distributor already has a portfolio of related prod-

    ucts in place. Therefore, we hypothesize that in international

    markets, distributors represent the preferred vehicle for start-

    ups to ensure effective customer support for products whose

    commercialization is resource intensive.

    H7:The pre- and after-sales transaction costs of prod-

    ucts sold into foreign markets through intermedi-

    aries are higher tban the costs of products of firms

    that export directly.

    j ~

    TTj

    ^ 6 include R D intensity as a control variable. It has in the

    ontrol Variables past been used as a proxy variable in studies that have ap-

    plied the framework of transaction costs to international mar-

    ket entry choices (Davidson and McFetridge 1985) to

    operationalize asset specificity and information asjnnmetries

    in exchange relations. We argue that there are two problems

    with this measure. First, it constitutes an input variable and

    may not necessarily have an impact on the asset specificity

    required to commercialize the output of the firm. Higb R D

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    11/31

    expenditures may not give rise to asset specificity or infor-

    mation asymmetries per se. Indeed, higherR Dinvestment

    may even allow a reduction in transaction costs by designing

    out complexity for the customer. Second, it is usually mea-

    sured at firm level, not at prod uct level, because it is difficult

    to obtain

    R D

    intensity (R D expen diture divided by sales)

    on a product group basis. Althougb highR Dexpenditures

    and the need to amortize them quickly probably have an im-

    pact on the decision to internationalize, we do not believe

    that tbis variable bas an impact on the entry modes chosen.

    Therefore, we argue that the dimensions are better repre-

    sented by measuring transaction costs directly and by mea-

    suring the maturity of the technology. Because of its

    widespread use in empirical studies, however, we include

    R D

    intensity as a control variable to detect any firm-level ef-

    fects it might have on the choice of entry mode. We do not

    present any hypotheses regarding the target country, but in-

    clude it as a control variable as well. We follow the ap-

    proaches of Erramilli and Rao (1993), Shrader, Oviatt, and

    McDougall (1997), and Barkema and Vermeulen (1998) and

    include the additional variables country risk, absolute size of

    the target country, and gross domestic product (GDP) per

    capita. We also include further dummy variables to control

    for any industry-specific effects tbat may affect the chosen

    sales mode.

    To summarize, similar to otber researchers before us (e.g.,

    Cavusgil, Zou, and N aidu 1993), we attempt to explain the

    international entry modes using firm-specific variables,

    product-specific variables, and variables specific to the

    environment in which the firms operate. Firm size and

    experience in international activities can be seen as opera-

    tionalizations of the internationalization process model.

    Experience with tbe domestic sales mode and tbe innovative-

    ness of the technology can be seen as operationalizations of

    the OC perspectives, whereas product characteristics are

    proxies for the transaction cost perspective.

    For the pvu:pose of this study, we define a high-tech start-up

    as a legally independent company that is not older than ten

    METHO

    years and that operates in one or more high-technology sec-

    tors.

    An operationalizable definition of high-technology sec-

    tors in tbe United Kingdom bas been established by Butchart

    (1987),

    who provides a definition of bigh-tech industries

    based on the two ratios of

    R D

    expenses to sales and em-

    ployees working in R D to total employees. Employing this

    definition, we identified 33 high-technology industries as

    having above average expenditu res for R D (for a list of in-

    cluded indus tries, see Appendix A). Using a database ob-

    tained from Dun and Brad street, we identified firms

    operating in tbose industries that had at least three employ-

    ees in 1997 and had been founded between 1987 and 1996.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    12/31

    We acknowledge that this method cannot consider high-tech

    firms in industries that are not included by Butchart's defini-

    tion. Yet as opposed to targeting low-technology sectors in

    the search for high-technology start-ups, we expected the

    proposed approach to result in an increased likelihood of ob-

    taining responses from firms that fulfil the specified eligibil-

    ity criteria. In total, we identified a gross sample of 7788 U.K.

    firms. We subsequently screened all identified company

    records to exclude those firms whose business activities sug-

    gested they were not carrying out any

    R&D

    activities (e.g., re

    tailers, wholesalers, assemblers). As a result, we retained

    3590 firms as eligible for inclusion in the research sample.^

    We then chose 2000 firms using a random sampling process

    stratified by size class and service/manufacturing.

    On the basis of a review of the specialized literature, we de-

    veloped a foiu:-page questionnaire. We carried out four pilot

    case studies to test whether the questions in the survey in-

    strument appeared relevant, easy to understand, and unam-

    biguous to the target respondents. As a result, we modified

    the questionnaire to take into account the expressed con-

    cerns. We posted an introductory letter and questionnaire fol-

    lowed by three reminders, if appropriate, to the managing

    directors of these 2000 firms. Managing directors have been

    used in past studies to collect data on the overall performance

    of entrepreneurial firms and have been identified as reliable

    sources of information (Brush and Vanderwerf 1992). A total

    of 134 envelopes came back unopened from companies that

    could no longer be located at their addresses in the database.

    Nine companies wrote back saying they were in the process of

    receivership. Sixty-one firms contacted us, indicating that

    they did not wish to participate in the survey. Altogether, 466

    firms returned the completed questionnaires, which resulted

    in a response rate of24 .After consistency checks to confirm

    that each firm fulfilled all the criteria for eligibility (i.e., firms

    needed to be less than ten years old and independently

    owned firms), 362 (19 ) firms could be retained in the data

    set. We performed t-tests using the original Dun and Brad-

    street data to check for nonresponse bias. We did not detect

    any statistically significant differences using information on

    sales, sales change (in relation to the previous financial year),

    number of employees, and credit rating. The latter measure

    reflects the credit worthiness of the firm as attributed by

    credit rating analysts and is therefore of particular interest

    when judging the firm's overall performance status. The ab-

    sence of significant differences suggests that the firms in oin:

    sample do not differ from the nonrespondents.

    In specifying the entry modes, we followed the definitions of

    perationahzation Root (1994), Klein, Frazier, and Roth (1990), and Aulakh and

    of Variables Kotabe (1997). Accordingly, we asked respondents to specify

    whether the chosen mode of their international activities was

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    13/31

    direct exporting, the use of an agent or sales representative

    selling on a commission basis, the use of a distributor, a sales

    joint venture, a wbolly owned sales subsidiary, or licensing.

    We asked firms to make similar statements regarding their do-

    mestic sales mode. We measured size using two variables:

    sales during tbe last financial year and number of employees.

    Because of the b igh correla tion of these two variables (r = .74,

    p

    .0001), we constructed a single measiu-e out of tbe stan-

    dardized scores. We decided against using the share of nondo -

    mestic revenues as a measure of experience (Aulakh and

    Kotabe 1997). In principle, we accept tbe reasoning behind

    tbat cboice; that is, firms that score high on that measure have

    an understanding of foreign operations. However, we argue

    tbat in th e case of a sample com posed of start-ups, it is impos-

    sible to distinguish between cause and effect; that is, tbe sbare

    of nondomestic revenues co uld at the same time be a function

    of the entry modes used. Therefore, we m easure international

    experience as tbe number of years tbe firm bas already been

    engaged in international operations before entering a particu-

    lar market. To operationalize the international experience of

    the firms' senior managers, we include dummy variables for

    whether the foimders had lived abroad or had worked for in-

    ternationally operating companies before starting their present

    business (Bloodgood, Sapienza, and Almeida 1996). The inno-

    vativeness of the technology employed was measured using a

    four-item scale (see Ap pen dix B). Resp onde nts were asked

    whether their products are best classified as incorporating

    tested combinations of existing technology, new combinations

    of existing technology, novel technolog y dev eloped externally,

    or novel technology developed specifically for tbis product by

    the company. We measured tbe extent to which a product re-

    quires client-specific customization and the transaction costs

    incurred during the sales process using five-point Likert scales

    (see Appendix B). Tbe foiu- items measvu-ing transaction costs

    were tben combined into a single scale (alpha .73). Dummy

    variables were included to specify wbetber or not the firm be-

    longed to a particular industry. We divided the firms into tbe

    five indu stry categories: software, inform ation technology (IT)

    and conununications hardware, engineering, biomedical tech-

    nology, and electronics (see Appendix A). We obtained coun-

    try risk ratings from tbe publication Institutional Investor (see

    also Shrader, Oviatt, and McDougall 1997). Because of the

    bigh correlation between co untry risk data and GDP per capita

    data (r =

    .93,

    p > .0001), we only included risk in our analysis.

    Appendix shows a correlation table of our variables.

    Of the 362 firms that partic ipated in the survey, we subse- ~

    quently only retaine d firms wit h interna tional activities. Al- RESULTS

    together, 246 (68%) firms were engaged in international

    sales. Table 1 describes these respondent firms. On average,

    they were six years old, started with 5 employees, and had

    grown to 22 employees by the time of tbe survey. Eight per-

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    14/31

    Table 1.

    Descriptive Statistics

    Variable

    Age

    Sales, first year*

    Sales, last year*

    Employees,

    first year

    Employees,

    last year

    R&D intens ity

    ( of sales )

    R&D intens ity

    ( of employees)

    ean

    5.8

    274

    1215

    4.4

    20.0

    16.7

    30.7

    Standard

    eviation

    2. 6

    508

    1722

    6. 5

    24.2

    22.0

    23.0

    inimum

    0

    0

    50

    1

    1

    0

    0

    aximum

    10

    6900

    16100

    50

    180

    150

    1.00

    edian

    6

    124

    6 50

    3

    12

    8

    25

    Table 2.

    International Activities

    of Sample Firms

    Sales in thousands of English pounds.

    cent of tbe firms indicated tbat tbey did not carry out any

    R&D activities. The indicators for botb R&D sbare and per-

    centage of employees working on product development sug-

    gest that tbe rema ining 92 of sampled firms operate in

    technology-intensive and/or knowledge-intensive areas and

    spen d, on average, the equiva lent of 15 of their ann ual

    sales revenue on R&D.

    Table gives an overview of the interna tional activities of the

    start-ups in our total sample. On average, these firms gener-

    ated38 of their total turnover from international sales (me-

    dian 30 ) through operations in ten countries (median 6). A

    third of these firms (34 ) generated more than 50 of their

    revenues from nondomestic sales. A total of28 of all born

    international firms generated international revenues witbin

    tbeir first year of formation. Tbis latter group now generates,

    on average, 46 of its revenues from foreign sales. Rougbly

    half the sample firms (46 ) had ente red their first foreign

    market by tbe end of tbeir second year. However, foreign di-

    rect investment in internationally dispersed assets played a

    minor role among the firms in our sample. Only 11 compa-

    nies had established either a joint venture or a wholly owned

    subsidiary to manufacture their products abroad.

    Variable

    Intemational sales

    { of tota l firm s)

    Share of nondomestic

    revenue ( )

    Number of

    countries entered

    Years before first

    intemational sales

    ean

    67.9

    38.4

    10.0

    2.2

    Standard

    eviation

    46.7

    31.7

    11.9

    2.1

    inimum

    1

    1

    0

    aximum

    100

    90

    10

    edian

    30

    6

    2

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    15/31

    Because our chosen u nit of analysis is the market entry deci-

    sion, we asked respondents to provide us with information

    on their three most important foreign markets, defined hy

    their contrihution to the total sales of the firm's hest-selling

    produ ct. This resulted in a data set of 547 market entry deci-

    sions (see Table 3). Ten cases were excluded from the analy-

    sis,because respondents either could not provide country

    level sales or indicated that they operated using entry modes

    that were difficult to classify.*

    Of the 547 market entry decisions in our sample, the pre-

    ferred current entry mode used hy the firms was distributors

    (42 ) followed by direct exporting (36 ) and use of sales

    agents

    (11 ).

    Market entry m odes that required some form of

    direct investment were not extensively used by the firms in

    our sam ple. A total of 7entries (5 ) were carried out using

    the joint ventu re form, and 15 entries (3 ) were throug h

    wholly owned subsidiaries. The generation of international

    sales revenues through licensing equally had a marginal role

    (9, 2 ). In comparison with the first entry mod es used by

    these firms, it appears that aggregate changes of entry modes

    over time reflect a tendency to use arrangements that repre-

    sent a higher commitment to international sales. Of the 121

    observed changes, 95 (79 ) represented a move toward in-

    creasing commitment to foreign sales. These descriptive

    findings provide further evidence for the validity of our

    choice to compare direct exporting and exporting through

    distrihutors as the main strategic options for the majority of

    high-tech start-ups.

    Table 4 gives an overview of the geographic spread of the in-

    ternational firms in our sample. The most important markets

    for British high-tech start-ups are found in Western European

    countries, followed by North American and East Asian coun-

    tries. When individual countries are examined, however, the

    most frequently entered export market is the United States,

    with 96 entries, followed by France (68) and Germany (64).

    Entry Modes

    Geographic Spread of Entries

    Entry Mode

    Exporting

    Agents

    Distributors

    Sales joint venture

    WboUy owned sales subsidiary

    Licensing

    Missing/otber

    Total

    First Entry

    24 1

    68

    198

    12

    7

    1 1

    10

    547

    44

    12

    36

    2

    1

    2

    2

    100

    urrent Entry

    19 9

    60

    227

    27

    15

    9

    10

    547

    36

    11

    4 2

    5

    3

    2

    2

    100

    Notes: The table shows the first and current entry mod es used iu the most imp ortant foreign

    markets for the company's best-selling product.

    Table 3.

    First and Current Entry Modes

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    16/31

    Table 4.

    Geographic Focus of

    International Activities

    Unit of Analysis

    Entry M ode

    European Union/European

    Free Trade Association

    United States and Canada

    East Asia (Japan, Hong Kong,

    Singapore, Korea, Taiwan)

    Australia and New Zealand

    Emerging markets, Europe

    South Am erica

    Middle East

    Emerging markets, Asia

    Other

    Total

    Entries

    Current

    Entries

    307

    106

    37

    25

    12

    3

    22

    13

    2 1

    54 7

    56

    19

    7

    5

    1

    4

    2

    4

    100

    Firms

    First Country

    Entered

    138

    56

    14

    6

    3

    11

    4

    10

    244

    57

    22

    6

    1

    1

    5

    2

    4

    100

    For the first market enteredwhich may not be the firms'

    largest marketa similar pictiu-e emerges. Although the ma-

    jority of firms (138, 57 ) had their first international sales in

    Western Europe, the most popular country of first entry was

    the United States (52, 21 ). It is noteworthy that43 of first

    entries were made to countries that do not belong to the Eu-

    ropean Union/European Free Trade Association. When the

    second, third, fourth, and fifth market entries are examined, a

    similar pattern is evident (not shown here). These results

    lend broad support to the findings of Lindqvist (1991) and

    Bell (1995). Although a narrow majority of firms chose geo-

    graphically close countries for their first international sales,

    an important minority of firms entered spatially distant mar-

    kets first.

    The descriptive results suggest that there is some support

    for the theoretical claims of process models when the aggre-

    gate sample is considered; that is, firms' entry modes

    changed over time to reflect an increase of commitment to

    foreign markets, and most firms first sell into relatively close

    markets. However, several indiv idual firm s deviate from this

    pattern. That the single most important target country, both

    for first entry and for absolute numbers of market entries, is

    the United States suggests that entry mode choices are also

    driven by more compelling strategic reasons than psychic

    distance alone. The economic size of the target market or the

    recognition of significant, country-specific opportunities

    may be more persuasive factors. We next present the results

    of the regressions and investigate to what extent the chosen

    firm-specific, product-specific, and country-specific factors

    influenced the foreign entry decision.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    17/31

    To test the hypotheses stated previously, we estimated three

    probit models with the entry m ode 1= distributor, 0 = direct

    Regression nalysis

    export) as the dependent variable. These two entry modes

    capture 78 of the observed entry mod es in our sample.

    Still, we excluded 28 cases because of missing information

    on one or more independent variables. We report the mar-

    ginal parameter coefficients of the model to compare the

    magnitude of the effects of the different variables. We esti-

    mated our principal model including all cases available for

    analysis (Model

    1).

    Webase our discussion of the hypotheses

    primarily on the results of this first model.

    The overall solution is statistically significant at p >

    .0001.

    Among the 398 entry mode choices for which all variables

    were complete, 213 (55 ) firms chose distributors and 174

    (45 ) firms chose to export directly. The classification ratio of

    more than 70 therefore suggests that the predictive ability of

    the estimated model represents a substantial improvement

    over the 55 maximum chance criterion (equivalent to as-

    suming that all firms are distributors). In all three models, the

    measure of size is positively related to the use of distributors,

    and the effects are highly significant in a statistical sense.

    However, when the marginal effects are examined, the real im-

    pact of size on entry mode is very small. Nonetheless, Hj can

    be accepted. The international experience of the firm at the

    time of the market entry is not significantly related to the

    choice of a particular sales mode in any of the three m odels.

    H2

    therefore cannot

    be

    accepted.

    H3

    also must be rejected. Liv-

    ing experience abroad and previous work for an internation-

    ally operating company are both negatively related to the use

    of intermediaries. However, only living experience abroad is

    statistically significant.H4was supported. Firms that used dis-

    tributors domestically also had a higher propensity to use in-

    termediaries for their international sales. A comparison of the

    marginal effects also shows that this variable has the strongest

    effect of all the variables included in the model.

    H5,

    following

    the organizational capability perspective, states that the prod-

    ucts of irmshat export directly incorporated newer technolo-

    gies than the products of firms that entered foreign markets

    through intermediaries. This hypothesis must be rejected.

    Compared with the base case ofaproduct incorporating tested

    combinations of existing technology, more advanced technol-

    ogy tends to be sold through intermediaries. However, the co-

    efficients indicate that this is a curvilinear re lationsh ip, as the

    probability to sell through an intermediary is highest for prod-

    ucts that had the second highest score of technological nov-

    elty.

    HQ

    is supported by the model. Products that require

    extensive customization are more likelyto besold internation-

    ally without the use of intermediaries.H7cannot be accepted.

    The measures used to operationalize the costs of commercial-

    ization turned out to have a statistically insignificant impact

    on the decision to involve intermediaries in the sales process.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    18/31

    Among the control variables, only one industry effect turned

    out to be significant. All other things being equal, firms in

    biotechnology and medical tecbnology rely much more on

    intermediaries to sell their products abroad compared with

    the base case of the electronics industry. Effects for software,

    engineering, and IT hardware were not significantly different

    from the base case. Research and development intensity was

    used as a control variable and resulted in a significant, albeit

    weak, effect. Accordingly, firms that have higher R&D expen-

    ditures have a lower propensity to sell through distributors.

    However, as the size of the marginal effect in Table 5 indi-

    cates, firm differences of at least one order of magnitude must

    be present to bave a substantial impact. Finally, among tbe

    country variables, only the absolute market size appears to

    bave a significant impact on tbe entry mode decision. Tbe

    size of a national market tbus seems to be positively related

    to tbe propensity to use distributors. The estimates for coun-

    try risk did not have a statistically significant effect within

    the model.

    To examine the validity of our findings, we tested two addi-

    tional models. Over time, some sample firms had changed

    the modes of market entry employed. Thus, the current entry

    mode could be a result of dynamic learning effects ratber

    than of actual differences in firm or product characteristics.

    Model 2 therefore only includes those entry modes that have

    not been subject to cbanges over time. We make a further

    modification in Model 3, in which only those entry modes

    that represent at least 10 of the total turnover of the firm

    were included. Our results could be biased by the presence of

    reactive, unsolicited foreign sales that are not a result of firm-

    specific factors or managerial action. Choosing a relatively

    high threshold of 10 should lead to the exclusion of the

    majority of these cases. The estimation of both Model 2 and

    Model 3 confirmed tbe results of our main model. Models 2

    and 3 equally represent statistically significant solutions,

    and their respective classification ratios of 70.60 and 71.04

    compare favorably with chance criteria of50 (Model 2) and

    5 (Model 3). Furthermore, as Table 5 shows, the effects of

    our explanatory variables in the three models are strikingly

    consistent. The only differences were marginal changes

    of statistical significance for management's foreign living

    experience in Model 3 and the insignificance of one of the

    technology dummy variables in Models 2 and 3. The latter,

    however, does not contradict the results of Model 1, because

    newer tecbnologies remain more likely to be sold through in-

    termediaries compared with the base case.

    From tbe previous analysis, a couple of results merit furtber

    IS USSION consideration. First, we were surprised by the very incidence

    of international activities among the firms in our sample. A

    majority of start-ups (68 ) engaged in international sales. On

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    19/31

    average, these technology-based young firms sold 38 of

    their tvirnover in foreign countries, and33 of the firm s gen-

    erated more turnover from international than domestic sales.

    Respondents typically sold into ten countries at the time of

    the survey and had initiated international activities two

    Variable

    Firm size

    Managementliving experience abroad

    Managementprevious work experience

    in internationally operating firm

    Firm experience in intemational sales

    before market entry (in years)

    Domestic sales mode

    Products based on new combinations

    of tested technology

    Products based on novel tecbnology

    developed outside

    Products based on novel technology

    developed in-house

    Degree of custom ization

    Cost of sales

    Industry: software

    Industry: IT hardware

    Industry: engineering

    Industry: biotechnology/medical

    technology

    R&D ex penditu res

    Target country: absolute market size

    Target country: country risk

    Number of observations

    Log-likelihood

    t (d.f.)

    Prob

    > x

    Pseudo R2

    Classification ratio

    *10

    significance level.

    **5 significance level.

    1 significance level.

    Model 1

    .095

    (.008)***

    -.106

    (.081)*

    -.020

    .734

    - .004

    .780

    .368

    (.000)***

    .162

    (.069)*

    .319

    (.001)***

    .204

    (.021)**

    -.068

    (.001)**

    .001

    .976

    - .084

    .424

    .070

    .435

    .122

    .179

    .429

    (.000)***

    -.003

    (.030)**

    -.005

    (.006)***

    .001

    .643

    398

    -219.26

    109.98

    .0000

    .2 0

    70.60

    Model 2

    .119

    (.002)***

    -.129

    (.058)*

    -.017

    .801

    .006

    .680

    .457

    (.000)***

    .128

    .188

    .346

    (.002)***

    .179

    (.062)*

    -.053

    (.017)**

    -.009

    (.800

    - .061

    .591

    .060

    .553

    .141

    .173

    .460

    (.000)***

    -.002

    .142

    - .033

    (.078)*

    .001

    .538

    339

    -185.52

    98.90

    .0000

    .2 1

    73.16

    Model 3

    .0 8

    (.037)**

    -.105

    .140

    - .091

    .199

    - .224

    .231

    .343

    (.000)***

    .118

    .272

    .258

    (.043)**

    .188

    (.073)*

    -.057

    (.016)**

    .041

    .307

    .010

    .929

    .112

    .284

    .157

    .145

    .469

    (.000)***

    -.003

    (.080)*

    -.005

    (.010)***

    .001

    .730

    297

    -167.71

    76.22

    .0000

    .1 9

    71.04

    Notes: base case = an electronics com pany selling prod ucts that inco rporate tested technology.

    Table 5.

    Estimation Results of the

    Probit Models

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    20/31

    years after formation. Second, given the importance of inter-

    national activities, we looked at the target countries and en-

    try modes used. The majority of firms chose countries in

    Western Europe for their first market entry. However, the

    most freque ntly targeted country is the United States (19 of

    all entries). A sizeable prop ortion of firms (42 ) entered

    more distant non-European m arkets first. Strategic considera-

    tions and the exploitation of new opportunities rather than

    psychic/economic distance are more likely to account for

    these entry decisions.

    According to the sample average, these young firms elected

    to choose entry modes that were not resource intensive. But

    among these low-resource entry m odes, the use of intermedi-

    aries was currently more prevalent than direct exporting.

    Arguably, selling through distributors represents a more com-

    plex and advanced managerial arrangement because of the

    requirement to attract, train, incentivize, and monitor

    a third-party agent. We therefore expected, all other things

    being equal, the use of foreign intermediaries to be more

    prevalent among more experienced and larger firms. As hy-

    pothesized, we found a positive effect of firm size on the

    propensity to sell through intermediaries. However, an

    analysis of the marginal effect reveals thatsimilar to the sta-

    tistically significant but weak effect of

    R D

    intensity the

    real impact of that variable is quite small. Firm differences of

    at least one order of magnitude m ust be present to have a sub-

    stantial impact on the choice of entry mode. The influence of

    experience on mode choice turned out to be contrary to our

    hypotheses. Direct firm experience did not have a significant

    impact on the commitment of the chosen entry mode. How-

    ever, as intensive experience with foreign operations cannot

    realistically be expected among young firms initiating their

    first foreign sales, we also tested for management's interna-

    tional experience, a substitute for direct company experi-

    ence.

    This variable had a significant impact on the choice of

    entry mode, albeit not in the hypothesized direction. This re-

    sult suggests that managers who have lived abroad are more

    likely to sell internationally without the assistance of inter-

    mediaries. A possible interpretation of this finding is that in-

    ternationally experienced managers do not need to rely on

    the superior market knowledge or commercial network of a

    local distributor to commercialize their products abroad.

    Their teniue abroad means that they already have their own

    personal networks and can evaluate them in comparison

    with the services offered by a distributor. We conclude from

    these findings that experiential knowledge, the key variable

    in the internationalization process theory (Andersen 1997),

    is of limited value to explain the entry mode choices of the

    high-tech start-ups in our sample. This echoes the findings of

    other researchers (see, e.g.. Bell 1995). In addition, our find-

    ings could provide further evidence for those researchers that

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    21/31

    argued that different entry modes do not so much represent

    distinct levels of commitment determined by past experience

    but rather represent distinct managerial choices determined

    by product- and firm-specific considerations (Andersen

    1993;Leonidou and Katsikeas 1996).

    In the case of start-ups, the choice of foreign entry modes

    may therefore represent a compromise between the limited

    resources of the start-up and the support requirements de-

    manded by the customers of its products. As hypothesized,

    our results indicate that a high degree of required customiza-

    tion leads to the exclusion of intermediaries during the sales

    process. Products that require a high level of client-specific

    adaptation are more likely to be sold directly by the manu-

    facturer. We argue that this is the case because the expertise

    and tacit knowledge required to configure a product accord-

    ing to customers detailed specifications are more likely to re-

    side with the m anufacturer than w ith the intermediary. We

    further hypothesized that start-ups whose products require

    extensive pre- and after-sales support will be more likely to

    sell through distributors. However, this hypothesis could not

    be supported, because the level of required support did not

    affect the choice of entry mode significantly.

    We suggest the following interpretation of this result. The ef-

    fects of the customization (Hg) and after-sales support (H7)

    variables are somewhat related, which is also manifest in the

    significant positive correlation between the two.^ From the

    distrihutor s point of view, they both incorporate the notion

    of having to acquire or invest in certain skills to guarantee

    the effective comme rcialization of a client man ufacturer s

    product. Such a commitment is attractive to the distributor

    only if a large volume of

    s les

    is a reasonably guaranteed con-

    sequence of this investment. All other things being equal,

    customization and after-sales support should act as a barrier

    to the interest or involvement of intermediaries in the sales

    process. However, from the point of view of

    firm that wants

    to serve large or remote foreign m arkets, the use of a local dis-

    tributor may be the only practicable way of providing the

    necessary customer-focused infrastructure for installation,

    maintenance, upgrading, and/or training of end users. We

    tried to decompose this dilemma and argue that highly cus-

    tomized products are more likely to be exported by m anufac-

    turers directly because of their singular familiarity w ith their

    core technology. The costs of acquiring these specialized

    technological skills may be prohibitive and economically ir-

    rational for a d istributor. However, in certain cases in w hich

    the d istrihutor already has a portfolio of related products and

    technologies in place, the relative costs of both learning and

    subsequently operationalizing the standard and routinized

    tasks of installation, end-user training, and maintenance are

    likely to be much lower because of both scale and scope ef-

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    22/31

    fects. Therefore, in these circumstances, selling a volume

    product or product family whose commercialization requires

    high levels of support through intermediaries might be less

    problematic. That the two variables have different effects in

    the regression (significantly negative in the case of cus-

    tomization versus insignificantly positive for sales support)

    is therefore an interesting result in itself and goes a certain

    way to support our reasoning. It suggests that customization

    represents a barrier to involving intermediaries, whereas the

    attendant cost of sales support can be managed and may even

    be a source of attractive profit for the distributor given suffi-

    cient trading volume to ensiure scale effects.

    The newness of the technology incorporated had a signifi-

    cant impact on the choice of the entry mode, albeit in the op-

    posite direction to the one we hypothesized. Compared with

    the base case of mature and tested technologies, transactions

    involving products that incorporated more innovative tech-

    nology (and therefore embodied a higher degree of tacit

    knowledge according to the theorists of OC) had a higher

    chance of being dealt with through collaborative arrange-

    ments than being exported. Although this indicates that the

    international market entry forms are influenced by product-

    specific factors, the effects observed directly contradict the

    theoretical prescriptions and findings on technology transfer

    modes of larger firms (Davidson and McFetridge 1985). How-

    ever, they corroborate the recent findings of Robertson and

    Gatignon (1998), who report that firms that experienced

    higher technology uncertainties were more likely to engage

    in alliances.

    Ovu strongest predictor of the chosen foreign entry mode was

    the existing, domestic sales mode of the

    firm.*^

    The effect of

    this variable can be explained in two ways. First, it is a proxy

    for different strategic and structural influence factors that af-

    fect sales channel choice irrespectively of the context. This

    variable therefore partly accounts for unobservable effects

    whose determination was not among the objectives of the

    study. Second, the explanatory effect of this variable is ar-

    guably due to the presence of embedded routines and experi-

    ences with the domestic sales mode. This finding therefore

    supports theoretical propositions that stress the importance

    of firm-specific routines and the path dependence of organi-

    zational outcomes (Madhok 1997). However, further research

    should necessarily use a more refined measure to determine

    to what extent foreign entry decisions axe a result of path de-

    pendency or company marketing strategy.

    The results of this research confirm what the high-tech entre-

    M N GERI L IMPLIC TIONS preneurial manager already knows, namely, that the early de-

    cision of an appropriate mode of exporting is not a trivial

    activity. On the contrary, it is an activity of the most pro-

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    23/31

    found strategic import and has long-term implications. In an

    ideal world, it is likely that any firm would prefer to be in

    charge ofitsdestiny and would chose a direct export mode of

    operation or build up a wholly ow ned subsidiary. Yet the lat-

    ter is usually outside the reach of a young start-up company.

    Exporting, in contrast, is not always an app ropriate choice. If

    there are serious questions regarding the firms ability to pro-

    vide user support in distant markets, the firm may have little

    choice but to choose a more established and recognized dis-

    tributor. In making this choice, the firm is, in effect, subcon-

    tracting a part of its growth strategy to an agent. For the

    distributor, the young firm is only one of several clients. In

    additio n, the firm s bargaining power may be small in com-

    parison with bigger, higher-volume, and longer committed

    clients of the distributor. As a result, a situation with high

    conflict po tential emerges. othe distributor, providing a ser-

    vice to this type of immature firm represents a series of nec-

    essary but highly speculative, specialist investments or sunk

    costs. The distributo r s choice of accepting the innovative

    products of an unknown start-up will therefore depend on

    the projected sales volume. As a result, young firms that can-

    not meet their distributors expectations will be left with no

    other choice than to sell directly.

    Our research has identified several practical implications

    for the managers of technology-based start-ups. We isolate

    three findings that we believe professional managers might

    find helpful. First, those young firms wishing to use distrib-

    utors in foreign m arkets can benefit from using collaborative

    relation ships in their domestic market first. Learning effects

    in managing relationships with intermediaries may be more

    easily gained in the domestic market and at less cost. In

    certain circumstances, this learning may also be less risky

    given, for example, easier communication and/or negligible

    psychic distance. Even for born global firms, market-based

    experimentation in the domestic market may still have

    these advantages.

    Second, firms that sell a highly customized product should

    be prepared to commit appropriate resources to their presales

    and after-sales service strategy given their reliance on direct

    exports. In giving this advice, we are aware that our research

    finding s show that firms appear to choose a mode of foreign

    market entry irrespective of the resource implications of the

    comm ercialization p rocess. Similarly, our findings also show

    that the size or resource endow ment of individua l firms has a

    weak, albeit statistically significant, effect on the choice of

    mode of market entry. In short, it does not appear that re-

    source constraints prevent firms from choosing between the

    two discussed entry modes. Instead, managers should be

    aware that the choice is more likely to be influenced by the

    degree of customization of the product.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    24/31

    Third, it appears that in getting a new, technologically ad-

    vanced product into the market, start-ups with a necessarily

    limited record of achievement should seriously consider col-

    laboration to exploit the track record or reputation of an es-

    tahlished intermediary. The much-quoted concept of

    liability of newness posits that young firms face disadvan-

    tages, because stable relations with clients are not yet estab-

    lished (Briiderl and Schussler 1990; Stinchcomhe 1965). In

    cross-border business relationships, this may amplify into

    what we call the liability of alienness. The reluctance of

    customers to rely on small, untested, and foreign suppliers is

    particularly important in the sensitive field of medical tech-

    nology, as is evidenced in our results. However, this antipa-

    thy to uncertainty by customers can be extended to all users

    of mission-critical technologies provided by young and un-

    proven third-party suppliers. In such circumstances, and

    particularly when there are costly implications for product

    failure or nonperformance, an exclusive dependence on a

    young company provider is not an acceptahle proposition for

    any established corporate user. The use of a trusted distribu-

    tor, or more accurately a value-added reseller, and its existing

    sales force is frequently the only effective way for a young

    high-tech company to present products to mainstream

    customers early in its development. Distributors may also

    be essential for supplying widely dispersed customers in a

    continental-scale market such as the United States or in mar-

    kets where there are major cultural disparities between

    provider and user, such as China.

    Our study is not without limitations. First, we focus on only

    L M T T ONS two distinct entry modes in our analysis, because licensing

    and entry modes requiring direct capital investments were of

    only marginal importance in our sample. Fvurther research on

    those technology start-ups that engage in a wider spectrum of

    entry modes could reveal whether the effects identified by

    our research can account for differences between the involve-

    ment of intermediaries and the completely internalized entry

    decisions when firms set up foreign subsidiaries. Second, for

    the moment, our study cannot reveal any performance impli-

    cations of the choice of different entry modes. Despite the

    availability of data on firm growth, we cannot presently dis-

    tinguish between cause and effect for the majority of firms in

    our sample; that is, either the growth could be a result of the

    chosen entry mode, or vice versa. However, we plan to con-

    tact the participants of our study again in the future to inves-

    tigate long-term performance implications of different market

    entry strategies. Finally, our sample is drawn exclusively

    from high-tech start-ups in the United Kingdom. Further

    research should therefore address whether similar findings

    can be reported from other countries and other industry sec-

    tors characterized hy the presence of internationally operat-

    ing entrepreneurial start-ups.

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    25/31

    Industry NACE Classifications

    Software

    ITandcommunications hardware

    Engineering

    Life sciencesandmedical technology

    Other (mainly electronics, components)

    7220 7260

    3001 3002 3220

    3230

    3320 3330 3340

    2441 2442 331

    3110 3120 3210 3530 2416

    2417

    Notes:TheNACE classification systemis theEuropean Union equivalentofthe standard

    industrial classification code system.

    APPENDIX

    A

    INDUSTRY SECTORS

    INCLUDEDIN THESTUDY

    1

    Innovativeness of Technology

    How wouldyoubest describetheinnovativenessofyour

    productorservice?

    Itincorporates triedandtested combinationsof

    existing technology.

    It

    incorporates

    new

    combinations

    of

    existing

    technology.

    Itincorporates novel technology that has been

    developed elsewhere.

    Itincorporates novel technology thathad to hedevel-

    oped specificallyforthis product by

    youi

    company.

    2

    Customization

    Please describetheextentto which your productor ser

    vice requires

    Individual client

    customization

    low

    substantial

    aaa

    doesnot

    apply

    3 Transaction ost Intensity

    Please describekeycharacteristicsofthe product/service,

    particularlytheextenttowhichitrequires

    low

    substantial

    Technical consultation

    priortosales

    Complexortime-

    consuming installation

    Regular maintenance

    and/or upgrades

    Specialized training

    requiredforfront line

    and sales personnel

    doesnot

    apply

    APPENDIX

    B

    OPERATIONALIZATION

    OF VARIABLES

  • 7/25/2019 entry choices hight-tech.pdf

    26/31

    APPENDIX 3

    CORRELATION TABLE

    5 S S.

    B E. ^

    II II II II II II II II

    S 1 1

    3 I

    E a c c o

    P ^ n o o

    o :r r 3

    03 -^ O O O

    r i g s

    f-i 2 CB CO O

    ^ P- CO cn y

    e. G g

    CD

    S

    L L B .

    CD E . CD CD 0 0

    m tn g 5 n

    Q. O O O H

    d f 5:: tJ

    I

    I i-

    CD

    2 S -a -a