ehg6 3 Richter

download ehg6 3 Richter

of 37

Transcript of ehg6 3 Richter

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    1/37

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    2/37

    1

    1 IntroductionAre corporate social responsibility (CSR) and corporate political activity

    substitutes or complements? The simplistic, popular answer to this question is that they

    are substitutes, since it is easy to classify firms that engage in CSR as being good and

    equally easy to classify firms that attempt to exert political influence as being evil; the

    reality, however, is likely to be more complex. Despite the importance of untangling this

    relationshipwhich potentially has major implications for our understanding of both

    CSR and corporate political activityscarce resources have been devoted to it to date.

    Nevertheless, Lyon and Maxwell (2008) have called for exactly this type of research,

    suggesting that corporate political activities need to be incorporated into an overarching

    framework for CSR.

    For consumers, we think of substitutes as being goods where an individual derives

    the same value from picking some fixed quantity of one good versus another good (e.g.

    wearing a red shirt or wearing a blue shirt gives an individual the same utility) and

    complements as goods where consumers derive the most value from consuming both

    goods simultaneously in appropriate proportions (e.g. left shoes and right shoes only give

    consumers utility when consumed in equal proportions). In the case of CSR and

    corporate political activity, we can think of these as distinct non-market actions firms

    may pursue to manage their external business environment; however, the relationship

    between the two types of non-market strategies is less clear than that between red shirts

    and blue shirts or that between left shoes and right shoes. Does CSR create more value

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    3/37

    2

    for firms when done by itself or when coupled with an appropriate, complementary,

    corporate political stance?

    We could imagine a manager whose only concern is increasing the value of his

    business seeing CSR and lobbying as substitutes and making a choice between one or the

    other: e.g. he could choose (i) to run a firm that derives its profits from choosing a

    cheaper production process that requires heavy pollution (social irresponsibility) and

    lobbying to protect his ability to pollute; or, he could choose (ii) to run a firm that derives

    its profits from selling the same good using a more expensive green production

    technology and hoping to sell it to consumers who appreciate and are willing to pay a

    premium for his efforts to be good, as in Bagnoli and Watts (2003) who argue that

    firms compete for socially responsible consumers.1

    Alternatively, we could imagine a

    manager who is more strategic in his decision-making and sees CSR and lobbying as

    complements: e.g. he could pursue good CSR by developing a (more costly) green

    technology and attempt to gain value from being at the top end of the CSR spectrum by

    lobbying to push the regulatory environment in a direction that benefits his ownership of

    a proprietary socially responsible technology at the expense of his competitors.2 Which

    of these alternative structures for non-market activity creates the most valuable firm?

    The purpose of this paper is to determine whether or not CSR and corporate

    political activity are substitutes or complements. It achieves this goal by merging well-

    known datasets on CSR and firms political activity that to date have only been examined

    1 Fisman, Elfenbein, and McManus (2010) find a similar result when they show that consumers are willingto spend more when goods are linked to charitable giving, at least on eBay.2 In the real world, we see this with companies like Toyota which own the green Prius hybrid technologypushing for higher global fuel economy standards that all manufacturers must meet, rather than percentageincreases in average fuel economy of each manufacturer's fleet--the regulatory measure preferred bymanufacturers of less socially responsible cars that emit more pollutants.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    4/37

    3

    separatelyand analyzing them jointly. First, it examines the peculiarities of the joint

    empirical distribution of firms lobbying behavior and firms CSR; then it tests how CSR

    and lobbying behavior, individually and jointly, impact firms valuations. This research

    reveals that (i) firms at both negative and positive extremes of a CSR index are more

    likely to have lobbied than firms that display more typical levels of socially responsible

    behavior, that (ii) both CSR and lobbying, individual and jointly, explain higher financial

    valuations when comparing firms; and that (iii) more intensive CSR and lobbying work

    as complements when examining individual firms over time since their interaction

    continues to explain higher valuations, however, more intensive CSR and lobbying

    efforts alone may lead to lower valuations within a single firm over time.

    1.1 Literature ReviewPast researchers have studied questions related to CSR and financial performance

    and corporate political activity and financial performance independently. They have not

    considered empirically the possibility that CSR and corporate political activity may be

    related and that good managers may choose to engage in both types of non-market

    strategies. Consequently, prior literature has not considered the joint effects of corporate

    political influence and CSR on firms financial valuations.

    The only consensus that has emerged from the separate lines of research

    regressing measures of CSR and of corporate political influence on measures of firms

    financial performance is that while possible to document the value of either CSR or

    lobbying between firms that it is harder to document eithers value within firms, when

    controlling for persistent firm-fixed factors. One explanation for why the effects

    disappearwithin firms is that good CSR or engaging in political activity may simply be

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    5/37

    4

    symptomatic of good management which is an inherently difficult to measure and,

    plausibly, firm-fixed characteristic. Moreover, to date no study has looked at data on

    both CSR and corporate political activity simultaneously despite some suggestions to

    investigate the potential relationship between the two types of non-market behavior

    both of which may be the result of good management.

    CSR and Financial Performance

    Before CSR was at the forefront of popular media attention,3 the Nobel prize-

    winning economist Milton Freidman (1970) famously quipped that the only social

    responsibility of business is to increase its profits suggesting that there should be no

    link between firms CSR initiatives and their financial performance. Freidman (1970)

    went on to suggest that if there is any relationship, CSR initiatives should be a drag on

    firm performance as they can only be the result of managerial malfeasance. Griffin and

    Mahon (1997) and Margolis, Elfenbein, and Walsh (2009) provide extensive literature

    reviews on the academic debate Friedmans comment sparked, chronicling a large

    number of studies that come to divergent conclusions about CSRs effect on firms

    financial performancesome finding a negative effect, others an inconclusive effect, and

    yet others a positive effect. I highlight only a few key studies and their similarities.

    Leading business strategy scholars, such as Porter and Kramer (2002), have

    suggested that firms can benefit from CSR efforts as existing views of the firm fail to

    take into account managing relationships with all stakeholders, which is precisely where

    CSR may provide firms a competitive advantage. This Organizational Theory View of

    3 A simple search of Google News Trends shows that reporting on the topic of CSR took off in the early2000s: http://www.google.com/archivesearch?q=corporate+social+responsibility&btnG=Search+Archives

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    6/37

    5

    CSR tends to focus all stakeholders rather than just shareholders alone; between firm

    studies tend to be used to support the view. Waddock and Graves (1997a) run a test

    comparing different firms that indicates higher CSR scores predict better financial

    performance. In separate research, Waddock and Graves (1997b) suggest that one reason

    they may find the earlier positive relationship between CSR and financial performance

    may be that firms with higher quality management perform better at CSR. Hillman and

    Keim (2001) find support for the higher quality management argument when they show

    that managers who pay attention to all stakeholders on social fronts are rewarded by

    shareholders when comparing firms. Orlitzky, Schmidt, and Rynes (2003) conduct a

    meta-analysis of studies comparing firms, concluding that in aggregate better CSR has a

    positive effect of firms financial performance.

    In critical re-evaluations of the work showing positive effects of CSR on firms

    financial performance between firms, several more recent studies find that the positive

    effects disappear in tests examining single firms over time (within firm tests), producing

    results more consistent with Friedmans (1970) early predictions and the Economic

    View of CSR. In particular, Moon (2007) finds that most prior research really just

    captured unobserved heterogeneity specific to firms and that once these are controlled

    for, CSR actually has a negative short-run effect on firms valuations. In a similar vein,

    Baron (2009) constructs a theory which suggests that in equilibrium there should be no

    within firm effects to being stronger along observable dimensions of corporate social

    performance since firms choose to engage in such behavior only when pressured to do so

    by non-market stakeholders in their business environment. Baron, Harajoto, and Jo

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    7/37

    6

    (2009) conduct a three-stage least-squares empirical test that largely supports Barons

    (2009) theory.

    Corporate Political Activity and Financial Performance

    Moving to the literature on corporate political activitys effect on firms aggregate

    financial performance, the debate follows a similar pattern: it typically finds a positive

    effect between firms, but a negative or inconclusive effect within firms or when otherwise

    controlling for managerial qualities. In a recent study, Chen, Parsley, and Yang (2010)

    show that portfolios composed of firms that lobby more intensely outperformed

    portfolios of those that lobby less intensely; they caution, however, that simply spending

    the most on lobbying does not necessarily lead to better financial performance as their

    test is one that compares different firms, rather than examining single firms over time.

    Agrawal and Knoeber (1999) find negative relationships between the intensity of various

    measures firms corporate political activity and their financial performance as measured

    by Tobins Q in the US context when controlling for fixed characteristics of the

    management and governance of firms. The Agrawal and Knoeber (1999) result appears

    to hold in other contexts as well: Claessens, Feijen, and Laeven (2008) find that firms

    who make larger campaign contributions in Brazil have a lower Tobins Q, controlling

    for firm fixed factors; and, Wei, Xie, and Zhang (2005) find that more politically

    influential firms in China also have a lower Tobins Q.

    2 Assembling a Dataset on CSR and Corporate Political ActivityTo achieve this papers purpose, I assemble the most comprehensive dataset

    possible based on available CSR and lobbying data. This allows me to begin answering

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    8/37

    7

    whether the two types of non-market strategies are substitutes or complements. My

    dataset is an unbalanced panel covering US firms for the years 1998 through 2005 and

    contains at most 3,350 firms in the cross-section. To construct it, I merged together data

    that appears in (i) the most complete database available on CSR, (ii) public records on

    firms lobbying expenditures, and (iii) firms accounting statements.

    2.1 CSR Data from KLDThe CSR data comes from Kinder, Lydenberg, Domini Research & Analytics

    (KLD) and their KLD STATs dataset. This is the most comprehensive and consequently

    the most widely used CSR dataset for academic research.4

    The sample of firms with

    KLD data available is what limits the cross-section of firms in my sample; KLD scores

    are available primarily for the largest firms by market capitalization.5

    KLD codes directly observable CSR attributes in 7 issue areascorporate

    governance, community engagement, diversity, employee relations, environment,

    humanitarian efforts, and product qualitiesas either CSR strength or concern dummy

    variables. More details on what the attributes are within these issue areas and how the

    data are coded is available in the appendix. As in prior academic research using the KLD

    data, I sum all strength indicators and subtract all the concern indicators to create a KLD

    Index variable.6

    Higher and positive KLD Index scores indicate stronger aggregate CSR

    4 For example, the KLD data is used by, among others: Waddock and Graves (1997); Hillman and Keim

    (2001); Moon (2007); and, Baron, Harajoto, and Jo (2009).5 In addition to using market capitalization as a screen for which firms to include in its sample, KLD alsoincludes some additional firms based on a priori expectations that they are good at CSR; however, thesefirms are easily identifiable as being part of the Domini 400 Social Index firms and hence excludable inrobustness checks. My primary results hold even when excluding Domini 400 firms that would nototherwise be in my sample; more on this follows in a robustness section.6 Unfortunately there is no theory to guide any other kind of aggregation of the data. (Hillman and Keim,2001) The problem with this method of index construction is that it implicitly gives equal weight to each

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    9/37

    8

    records; lower and negative KLD Index scores indicate aggregate social irresponsibility.

    A histogram of the KLD Index indicates that firms CSR levels tend to follow a normal

    distribution with a mean near zero. Summary statistics follow in Table 1.

    Chatterji, Levine, and Toffel (2009) examined the underlying integrity of the

    KLD Data. They find that while it is a reasonable proxy for some types of CSR activity,

    it is a noisy measure that both understates and overstates firms CSR levels.7

    2.2 Lobbying from Public RecordsThe lobbying data I use comes from legally required public disclosures of firms

    lobbying expenditures.8

    It comes from Richter, Timmons, and Samphantharak (2009)

    who coded the Center for Responsive Politics cleaned public records data such that it

    can be merged into other datasets containing additional information on firms, like

    COMPUSTAT for financial accounting data. The lobbying data reliably covers the

    years 1998 through 2005, which limits the time-dimension of my dataset. It is the best

    measure of firms corporate political activity available as firms spend an order of

    magnitude more on lobbying than on (highly correlated) campaign contributions.9

    (Milyo, Primo & Groseclose, 2000; Ansolabehere, Snyder, & Tripathi, 2002)

    From this dataset, I will use two primary variables based on lobbying disclosures

    for my analysis. The first of these is a dummy variable that takes on a value of 1 if firms

    KLD issue, when in reality there is no reason to believe that being a heavy polluter (a KLD concern) shouldbe equally offset by having a minority CEO (a KLD strength).7 Consequently, Chatterji, Levine, and Toffel (2009) advocate using more detailed data when it is availableon specific issues like firms pollution level from public records; however, they provide little guidance onwhat may be a better measure across all CSR issues.8 Firms have been legally required to report all lobbying expenditures in the US since the LobbyingDisclosure Act of 1995.9 Furthermore, existing research has documented that campaign contributions have little impact on thelegislative process and may merely be a form of corporate consumption. (Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo,and Snyder , 2003)

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    10/37

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    11/37

    10

    performance) and corporate political activitys effect (on financial performance).11 I

    construct the Tobins Q variable from COMPUSTAT, such that it equals the market

    value of the firm divided by the book value of the firm. When the variable takes on

    values greater than one, the market perceives the combination of tangible and intangible

    resources the firm has assembled as being worth more than the replacement value of the

    firm; hence, higher values of Tobins Q indicate superior financial performance of the

    firm. Furthermore, a managers goal should be to maximize his Tobins Q value as this

    indicates that he is using the firms resources in the best possible manner.

    Studies using Tobins Q as the dependent variable typically include a set of

    control variables related to other observable characteristics of the firm that are included

    on their financial statements. I take data on the most commonly incorporated control

    variableslog(total assets), leverage, capital intensity, R&D intensity12, and

    log(employees)from COMPUSTAT.13

    3

    The Joint Distribution of CSR and Lobbying

    As a first step in my empirical attempts to discern whether social responsibility

    and lobbying are substitutes or complements, I examine the joint empirical distributions

    of the attributes. This goes beyond the summary statistics of the independent

    distributions of firms lobbying activity and CSR levels provided in Table 1.

    11 For example, in the CSR literature Tobins Q is used by Moon (2007) and Baron, Harajoto, and Jo (2009)

    among others, and in the corporate political activity literature it is used by Agrawal and Knoeber (1999),Claessens, Feijen, and Laeven (2008), and Wei, Xie and Zhang (2005) among others.12 R&D intensity is particular important to include according to a study by McWilliams and Siegl (2000),who claim models that do not include it are misspecified.13 Leverage is defined as Total Debt divided by Total Assets; Capital Intensity is defined as Property, Plantand Equipment (Net) divided by Total Assets; and, R&D Intensity is defined as research and developmentexpenditures divided by Total Assets, using a value of 0 where research and development expenditures hasan N/A observation in COMPUSTAT.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    12/37

    11

    If corporate political activity and CSR were substitutes, then we would expect to

    find that only the most socially irresponsible firms are likely to lobby, since these firms

    have chosen to ignore CSR activity in favor of engaging with political actors. If

    corporate political activity and CSR were complements, then we would expect firms

    lobbying behavior to vary in some other systematic way with their CSR behavior and

    perhaps firms having the best CSR records would be more likely to engage in corporate

    political activity. Of course, it is also possible that there is no relationship between

    corporate political activity and CSR, in which case the distribution of CSR activity

    should look identical for firms regardless of their lobbying (political activity) status.

    3.1 Firms that Lobby have a KLD Index Distribution with Fatter TailsFigure 2 shows overlaid histograms of the density of KLD scores (i) for firms that

    lobby and (ii) for those firms that do not lobby.14

    The first moment, or mean, of both

    distributions appears the same, but the second moment, or variance, appears to differ.

    The graph shows that firms at both extremes of social responsibility are more likely to

    lobby than firms with more typical levels of CSR: the most socially irresponsible and the

    most socially responsible firms are the ones that lobby. While the finding that the most

    socially irresponsible firms lobby could by itself suggest a substitute-like relationship, the

    parallel finding that the most socially responsible firms also lobby is more suggestive of a

    complementary relationship.

    14 Figure A1 in the Appendix shows the Kernel Density functions of the KLD index by lobbying status.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    13/37

    12

    Figure 1 Histograms of KLD Scores, by Lobbying Status

    To test whether the two distributions shown in Figure 1 are different more

    formally, I examine their discrete joint empirical distributions in Table 2. A Chi-squared

    test indicates a very high likelihood that firms that lobby have a different KLD index

    distribution with fatter tails than firms that do not lobby, as the p-value is less than 0.000.

    0.00

    0.05

    0.10

    0.15

    0.20

    0.25

    0.30

    -11 -10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

    Density

    Sum of KLD Strengths/Concerns

    Histograms of KLD Scores, by Lobbying Status

    Firms that DO NOT Lobby

    Firms that DO Lobby

    TABLE 2 - Empirical Distribution Tests

    KLD Strengths minus WeaknessesCounts -11 -10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Tot.

    0 1 1 1 0 5 19 40 113 290 855 1762 2301 1224 487 253 125 43 24 11 2 0 3 0 7560

    1 1 2 7 19 34 52 78 153 200 328 500 495 352 262 172 98 60 41 30 15 11 3 4 2917

    Tot.

    2 3 8 19 39 71 1 18 266 490 1183 2262 2796 1576 749 425 223 103 65 41 17 11 6 4 10477

    Value p-value

    KLD Strengths minus Weaknesses

    Lobbying

    Dummy

    Counts

    Test Statistics

    This table presents the empirical joint distribution counts of the number of firms that fall into certain

    KLD Score and Lobbying categories in the full dataset used in the paper. It also runs tests on the

    categorical densities to show that the distribution for firms that lobbying versus those that do not are

    statistically distinguishable.

    937.127 0.000Pearson Chi-Squared

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    14/37

    13

    Taken together it is clear that the CSR behavior of firms that lobby is different

    than that of firms that do not lobby. Given that the distribution for firms that do lobby is

    fatter at both positive and negative tails, we can preliminarily deduce that lobbying and

    social responsibility are complements, since their distributions vary together in a

    systematic way.

    3.2 KLD Index vs. Lobbying IntensityAnother way to examine the joint empirical distribution of CSR and corporate

    political activity is to look at a scatterplot of KLD Index scores versus the measure of

    lobbying intensity. This appears in Figure 2. It shows that despite firms at the extremes

    of social responsibility being more likely to lobby (as shown in Figure 1), firms at the

    extremes of social responsibility are less likely to lobby as intensively as firms in the

    middle of the social responsibility distribution.

    Figure 2 Scatterplot of Lobbying Intensity vs. KLD Score

    Another way to think about the relationship between substitutes and complements

    .00

    .05

    .10

    .15

    .20

    .25

    .30

    -12 -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12

    Total Number of KLD Strengths minus Concerns

    PercentageofAssetsSpentonLobbying

    Scatterplot of Lobbying Expenditure (% of Assets) by KLD Score

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    15/37

    14

    is to think about what the shape of their indifference curves (or isoquants) should look

    like. If two goods are substitutes, their indifference curve should be straight lines at an

    oblique angle with respect to the origin (as the two inputs should have a constant

    marginal rate of substitution); if two goods are complements their indifference curves

    should be convex with respect to the origin (as their marginal rate of substitution should

    vary with the levels of the two inputs).15 Plotting firms lobbying intensity versus their

    KLD index (which are the axes on an indifference curve/isoquant graph) in Figure 2

    shows that at the upper bounds firms use of CSR and lobbying are convex towards the

    origin, suggesting that they may be complementary inputs managers can use together to

    increase the value of their firms. The problem with treating this graph as if it were an

    indifference curve/isoquant graph, however, is that the utility/output of each firm is not

    held at constant levels across all observations as they should be in a formal test. We can

    include controls to hold other factors influencing firms valuations constant and

    approximate the marginal rate of substitution between CSR and corporate political

    activity in a regression based test I run in the next section.

    4 A Test Linking CSR and Lobbying to Financial PerformanceAs alluded to above, one simple way to test if any two economic variables are

    substitutes or complements involves calculating their marginal rate of substitution. This

    test works because whenever two economic variables are substitutes their marginal rate

    of substitution is constant and whenever they are complements their marginal rate of

    substitution is a function of the underlying variables.

    15 See Appendix Figure A2 for the case of Substitutes and Figure A3 for the case of Complements.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    16/37

    15

    Using this logic, we can test whether CSR and corporate political activity are

    substitutes or complements if we can estimate how they enter into a firms valuation

    since this is a firms equivalent to a utility function which we would need to differentiate

    with respect to our variables of interest to calculate their marginal rate of substitution.

    We can do this since we have data on firms valuations, as measured by Tobins Q, and

    believe that their valuations are a function of CSR and corporate political activity among

    other factors. A firms financial valuation as a function of non-market activity variables

    can be estimated by running regressions of the form:

    where represents the KLD Index variable; represents the Lobbying

    Intensity variable; represents other control variables common in regressions on

    Tobins Q; and, the constant/fixed-effects variable varies depending upon whether we

    want the test to be between orwithin firms.16

    We can then take the coefficient estimates from the above regression and use

    these to approximate the marginal rate of substitution between CSR and corporate

    political activity, which allows us to determine whether or not CSR and corporate

    political activity are substitutes or complements. If the marginal rate of substitution

    between CSR and political activity is a constant then the two inputs to a firms valuation

    are substitutes. If the marginal rate of substitution between CSR and political activity is a

    function of those inputs to a firms valuation then the two variables are complements.

    16 This regression is appropriate if we believe that CSR and lobbying efforts are not functions of financialmarkets contemporaneous valuation of a firm.; otherwise there would be a potentially endogeneity issue.This seems reasonable unless we believe that managers change their current CSR behavior and lobbyefforts in response to the firms current financial market valuations rather than because of a longer term(potentially strategic) commitment to socially responsibility or strategic political activity.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    17/37

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    18/37

    17

    Hence, as a first test, I estimate variations on the between regression:

    We should expect to find a positive and significant coefficient () on the level of CSR

    and a positive and significant coefficient ( on the level of lobbying if each

    independently increases the valuation of firmswhich would be consistent with prior

    research that finds that CSR and lobbying increase firms Tobins Q values when

    comparingfirms. As outlined in the regression framework section above, we should

    expect to find a positive and significant coefficient () on the interaction between the

    level of CSR and lobbying if the two activities are complements between firms and we

    should expect to find a statistically insignificant coefficient () on the interaction term if

    the two non-market activities are substitutes between firms. The results from my

    estimates appear in Table 3.

    The results in Table 3 show positive and significant values on the coefficients for

    CSR (), corporate political activity (), and for the interaction between the two types of

    non-market behavior (). The results for CSR () and for corporate political activity ()

    are consistent with the Organizational Theory View of CSR and with past researchers

    results showing a positive effect corporate political activity on firms financial

    performance when comparingfirms. The result for the interaction coefficient (),

    however, is what we are most interested in, since the purpose of running these regressions

    was to get at whether or not CSR and corporate political activity are substitutes or

    complements; its positive and significant value suggests once again that CSR and

    corporate political activity are complements.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    19/37

    18

    Despite the results, these between firm regressions are subject to the critique

    about unobserved firm-level heterogeneity that proponents of the within firm regressions

    offer. The critique suggests that I might find the above results because of unobservable

    managerial quality such that better managers choose higher CSR levels and higher

    political activity levels, whereas worse managers do not pursue the non-market strategies.

    Hence, if I included firm fixed-effects to control for persistent attributes of managerial

    quality that might be causing the levels of CSR and lobbying intensity that I am

    observing, my positive results could disappear, as higher managerial quality would also

    cause higher levels of Tobins Q for other reasons.

    TABLE 3 - Between Estimates of Influence of CSR and Lobbying on Valuation

    Dependent Variable:

    KLD Score 0.054*** 0.055*** 0.035***

    (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)

    Lobbying (% of Assets) 4.424*** 4.574*** 6.927***

    (0.716) (0.715) (0.776)

    KLD * Lobbying (% of Assets) 3.874***

    (0.505)

    log(Assets) -0.290*** -0.286*** -0.287*** -0.287***

    (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

    Leverage -0.223** -0.278*** -0.223** -0.225**

    (0.091) (0.091) (0.091) (0.091)

    Capital Intensity -0.274*** -0.330*** -0.268*** -0.286***

    (0.079) (0.079) (0.079) (0.079)

    R&D Intensity 7.684*** 7.587*** 7.592*** 7.457***

    (0.236) (0.237) (0.236) (0.236)log(Employees) 0.123*** 0.117*** 0.120*** 0.118***

    (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013)

    Firm Fixed Effects No No No No

    Period Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Number of Obs. 9869 9869 9869 9869

    R Squared 0.201 0.200 0.204 0.209

    Tobins Q

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    20/37

    19

    4.2 Estimates Within Firms Reveal that the Complementary Relationshipbetween CSR and Lobbying is Robust

    If in within firm tests I still find a positive and significant interaction effect ()

    between CSR and lobbying and if managerial decisions are persistent, then my primary

    result that CSR and corporate political activity are complementary is robust.

    Here I run such a test, estimating variations on the within regression:

    The primary difference between the within firms estimates presented here and the

    between firms estimates presented in the prior table are that the within firms estimates

    control for time-persistent unobservable characteristics by including firm dummy-

    variables () in the estimation. Essentially adding the firm dummy-variables () to the

    estimation should control for unobservable managerial talent that may be causing firms to

    engage in CSR or corporate political activity. This is a test that looks at what happens

    inside individual firms over time rather than when comparing different firms as the

    regressions did in the last sub-section.

    We should expect to find a negative and/or insignificant coefficient () on the

    level of CSR and a negative and/or significant coefficient ( on the level of lobbying if

    each independently is a drag on firms valuations or has no measurable effectwhich

    would be consistent with prior researchers within firm studies that suggest unobserved

    managerial quality drives between firm studies results. As mentioned above, we should

    expect to find a positive and significant coefficient () on the interaction between the

    level of CSR and lobbying if the two activities are complements when examining a single

    firm over time if unobserved managerial quality did not drive the between firm result for

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    21/37

    20

    this coefficient. Otherwise a statistically insignificant coefficient () on the interaction

    term would indicate that inside an individual firm over time the two non-market activities

    may be substitutes. The results from my estimates appear in Table 4.

    Consistent with prior researchers within firm tests and the Economic View of

    CSR, the results in Table 4 show negative and/or insignificant values on the coefficients

    for CSR () and for corporate political activity ()suggesting that firms superior social

    performance and the intensity of firms political activity may in fact be symptomatic of

    higher quality management, or some other persistent firm-fixed characteristic, and have

    no real direct effect on their financial performance. Nevertheless, the results in Column 4

    of Table 4 find a positive and significant coefficient on the interaction between firms

    TABLE 4 - Within Estimates of Influence of CSR and Lobbying on Valuation

    Dependent Variable:

    KLD Score -0.013 -0.013 -0.030***

    (0.011) (0.011) (0.011)

    Lobbying (% of Assets) -2.572** -2.549** -0.300

    (1.127) (1.127) (1.192)

    KLD * Lobbying (% of Assets) 3.354**

    (0.589)

    log(Assets) -1.119*** -1.125*** -1.126*** -1.107***

    (0.074) (0.074) (0.074) (0.074)Leverage 0.169 0.166 0.164 0.163

    (0.158) (0.158) (0.158) (0.158)

    Capital Intensity -2.069*** -2.066*** -2.066*** -2.041***

    (0.323) (0.323) (0.323) (0.322)

    R&D Intensity 3.734*** 3.796*** 3.779*** 3.701***

    (0.535) (0.535) (0.535) (0.534)

    log(Employees) 0.217*** 0.217*** 0.217*** 0.222***

    (0.075) (0.075) (0.075) (0.075)

    Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Period Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Number of Obs. 9869 9869 9869 9869

    R Squared 0.776 0.776 0.776 0.777

    Tobins Q

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    22/37

    21

    CSR level and lobbying ()which yet again suggests that CSR and corporate political

    activity are complements. Moreover, it suggests that even when controlling for

    unobservable managerial quality, CSR may indeed improve firms financial performance,

    but only if it is coupled with the appropriate corporate political activityallowing the

    firm to overcome the extra costs that CSR efforts alone impose (as suggested by the

    negative coefficient ).

    If we took the results in Column 4 of Table 4 and held the left hand side

    (valuation level) variable constant, and used the point estimates for the coefficients on

    CSR (), corporate political activity (), and their interaction () to draw a graph, with

    axes representing lobbying intensity and the KLD index, they would generate

    indifference curves that are convex with respect to the origin; this result would be

    consistent (i) with the shape of the scatter plot of the data in Figure 2, (ii) with the

    marginal rate of substitution varying depending upon the level of CSR or the intensity of

    corporate political activity, and most importantly (iii) with the notion that CSR and

    corporate political activity are complementary inputs for firms that when used together

    can raise their valuations despite the negative independent effects of CSR and corporate

    political activity.

    The result that CSR alone may decrease firms valuations is consistent with the

    oft-quoted Milton Friedman (1970) statement that the only social responsibility of

    business is to increase its profits. The result that CSR can become profitable when

    taking into account firms lobbying behavior, however, may also be consistent with

    Friedmans (1970) argument, given that one of the conditions he put on making as much

    money as possible was while conforming to the basic rules of society (those embodied

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    23/37

    22

    in law). To the extent that firms can lobby successfully to alter laws to yield higher

    profits by institutionally requiring others to match their socially responsible behavior or

    to lose out on business opportunities, Freidman would not have been surprised by my

    results. Nevertheless, my results call into question the notion that firms who benefit from

    CSR are really doing well by doing good as many proponents of the Organizational

    Theory View of CSR suggestor if the firms that benefit the most from CSR are only

    doing well by coupling their good with a dose of evil in the form of corporate

    political activity.

    One reason we may find the result that CSR and corporate political activity are

    complements could be that the way firms profit is from the use of social activity as a

    competitive weapon potentially giving them a leg up in their lobbying efforts (Devinney

    2009). If so this may be a classic case of when regulation is acquired by industry and is

    designed and operated primarily for its benefit, otherwise known as regulatory capture.

    (Stigler 1971) Traditionally, regulatory capture has been viewed as something that can

    be very costly to society given its distributional consequences (Dal B, 2006); however,

    if certain firms that are exceptional at some aspect of CSR are more able to capture

    regulators and more able to demand regulation that will be good for society, such as

    reducing aggregate pollution, the normative consequences are less clear.

    4.3 Robustness ChecksI address several possible concerns about robustness of the prior results in this

    sub-section. The key points from Table 3 and Table 4 continue to hold after these

    robustness tests: when comparing firms better CSR, more intensive lobbying, and the

    interaction between better CSR and more intensive lobbying explain higher Tobins Q

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    24/37

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    25/37

    24

    Another sampling concern I tested was sensitivity to outliers. I re-ran the

    regressions in Table 3 and Table 4, excluding the extreme outliers on both lobbying and

    CSR dimensions from the sample. When I exclude both lobbying and CSR extreme

    outliers, my primary result that lobbying and CSR are complements holds up; this

    remains true whether excluding just CSR outliers, just lobbying outliers, or both.17

    The

    one difference I find occurs when I exclude the most extreme outliers on the lobbying

    dimension: I find that in the firm fixed effects (orwithin) regressions, that the negative

    lobbying intensity coefficient becomes statistically insignificant. This suggests that a

    firms lobbying intensity alone has no effect on a firms Tobins Q; interactions between

    lobbying intensity and CSR levels nevertheless remain important because of their

    complementary relationship.

    Disaggregating KLD Strengths/Weaknesses

    As another test of the robustness of the results, instead of using the total KLD

    score as a measure of CSR, I disaggregate the measure into its positive (strengths) and

    negative (concerns) components. Otherwise, the regressions are run as within regressions

    as in Table 4. The results appear in Table 5.

    Table 5 shows that unlike in the Table 4 results, having negative CSR or being

    socially irresponsible (measured by KLD concerns rather than firms placement on an

    aggregate index) does not increases firms valuations as suggested when the entire KLD

    Index is used. Rather, the results in Table 5 suggest that the optimal point for most firms

    17 For robustness I tried defining outliers in various ways; however, the simplest way, which was to use avisual test of the distributions of the data. This led me to exclude firms with a lobbying intensity measuregreater than 0.3 as outliers along the lobbying dimension. It also led me to exclude firms with KLD Indexscores greater than 8 in absolute value as outliers along the CSR dimension.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    26/37

    25

    to maximize their valuations, if lobbying intensity is held at its median value of zero, is

    for firms to set their CSR level near their median value of zero as well.

    We also learn from Table 5 that KLD concerns do not positively complement

    firms lobbying efforts like KLD strengths do. Perhaps this is because the firms with

    KLD concerns are lobbying for different reasonspotentially to cover up their

    irresponsible actions rather than to institutionalize the competitive advantage their CSR

    efforts may be giving them.

    TABLE 5 - Within Estimates, Role of Good/Bad CSR and Lobbying on Valuation

    Dependent Variable:

    KLD Strengths -0.073*** -0.072*** -0.098***(0.015) (0.015) (0.015)

    KLD Concerns -0.040*** -0.040*** -0.027*

    (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

    Lobbying (% of Assets) -2.572** -2.579** -2.501*

    (1.127) (1.124) (1.387)

    KLD Strengths * Lobbying (%) 5.057***

    (0.817)

    KLD Concerns * Lobbying (%) -2.432***

    (0.660)

    log(Assets) -1.102*** -1.125*** -1.108*** -1.076***(0.074) (0.074) (0.074) (0.074)

    Leverage 0.184 0.166 0.179 0.183

    (0.158) (0.158) (0.158) (0.157)

    Capital Intensity -2.061*** -2.066*** -2.059*** -2.045***

    (0.322) (0.323) (0.332) (0.321)

    R&D Intensity 3.775*** 3.796*** 3.821*** 3.737***

    (0.533) (0.535) (0.534) (0.532)

    log(Employees) 0.211*** 0.217*** 0.211*** 0.214***

    (0.075) (0.075) (0.075) (0.075)

    Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes YesPeriod Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Number of Obs. 9869 9869 9869 9869

    R Squared 0.777 0.776 0.777 0.778

    Tobins Q

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    27/37

    26

    5 Discussion: Illustrative CasesWhile there are advantages to analyzing large datasets, over a purely qualitative

    analysis focused on specific cases, there are also some shortcomings. Large dataset

    analysis alone can obscure the story of what firms are actually doing on the ground; so

    far, in this study, it is unclear how firms use their social responsibility positions (positive

    or negative) as complements to their lobbying efforts. Given that there are multiple

    dimensions of social responsibility/ irresponsibility and multiple issues on which firms

    could lobby for policy change or for maintaining the policy status quounderstanding

    how managers combine various non-market positions is particularly important.

    In this section of the paper, I take the extra step to examine individual cases at the

    extremes of the CSR and lobbying distributionshoping to see exactly how firms use

    their social responsibility position as a strategic complement to their lobbying behavior.

    At the negative extreme, Yum! Brands provides an example of how one firm

    complements its relative social irresponsibility with its lobbying efforts by seeking to

    maintain the policy/regulatory status quo. At the positive extreme, Hewlett-Packard

    provides an example of a firm that leverages its relatively positive social responsibility

    position in its lobbying efforts to push for policy changes that would allow them to

    monetize their existing activities and raise their rivals costs.

    5.1 Yum! Brands Complements Social Irresponsible Positionswith Lobbying Efforts aimed at Maintaining the Status Quo

    Yum! Brands, which owns Taco Bell and KFC among other fast-food brands,

    falls into the bottom 5% of firms on the social responsibility index most years in the

    sample. According to KLD, Yum! Brands has particular weaknesses in: paying

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    28/37

    27

    executives and directors at unusually high rates; running into controversies related to

    affirmative action; finding themselves at the center of other diversity disputes; being

    relatively bad at controlling emissions of toxic chemicals; providing employees with poor

    benefits packages; running into other disputes with employees about minimum wage pay

    and failure to pay overtime; issues with practices in its supply chain; and, finally

    concerns over the safety/quality of its products.

    Yum! Brands appears to have lobbied in these areas of weakness in their social

    responsibility position. Most of their legally-required lobbying disclosure reports show

    that Yum! Brands focused on these weaknesses with respect to social issues, such as: on

    the minimum wage, on animal rights issues of suppliers, and on environmental emissions.

    Yum! Brands lobbying disclosure, however, leaves information about specific bills and

    specific positions absent. The only hint of their actual public policy positions, rather than

    simply the issues they lobby on, comes from their annual reports and congressional

    testimony their officers make. Yum! Brands annual reports cite changes in the minimum

    wage as a substantial risk to the company. Testimony by Jonathan Blum, the head public

    affairs officer at Yum! Brands, to the Senate Judiciary Committee in May 2004 indicates

    that Yum! Brands is concerned about the business implications if Yum! Brands had to

    source inputs from ethical suppliers who only use what PETA (People for the Ethical

    Treatment of Animals) calls more humane ways to process live animals into food

    products that if implemented, would cost our company [Yum!] over $50 Million.

    In summary, Yum! Brands appears to have complemented its positions of relative

    social irresponsibility with a lobbying strategy aimed at preserving the policy status

    quowhere preserving the policy status quo would enable Yum! Brands keep input costs

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    29/37

    28

    down at the peril of various market and non-market stakeholders. By focusing on

    maintaining the policy status quo in areas related to their operations, Yum! Brands

    appears to have formulated a non-market strategy dependent on their ability to wring

    value out of a market position that requires them to operate at the margins of government

    regulation vis--vis social issues, making their business particularly sensitive to

    tightening operations around social issues.

    5.2 Hewlett-Packard Complements Socially Responsible Positions withLobbying Efforts advocating for Policy Change towards Firms Strengths

    Hewlett-Packard, which is a multinational information technology services,

    software, and hardware company, falls consistently into the top 5% of firms on the social

    responsibility index. According to KLD, Hewlett-Packard has particular strengths in:

    transparent reporting; charitable giving programs (within and outside of the US); having

    employee volunteer programs; having internal programs that support diversity and

    work/life balance; using clean energy among other environmentally proactive activities;

    and, bringing innovative products to market that are good for consumers.

    Consistent with the strengths in their social responsibility position, Hewlett-

    Packard appears to have lobbied in the same areas: on improving environmental

    standards/transparency; on electronics recycling; on government support for decreasing

    the digital divide/ economic development; and on patent/trademark issues. Hewlett-

    Packards congressional testimony, takes a decidedly different tone than that by Yum!

    Brands; rather, than complaining about difficulties and costs of compliance with existing

    regulations related to social issues, Hewlett-Packard advocates for policy changes and

    supports congressional review of environmental standards, particularly around the firms

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    30/37

    29

    strengths. For example, a June 2005, statement released by David Isaacs, Hewlett-

    Packards Director of Government and Public Policy, lauded efforts by a subcommittee

    of the US Senate Committee on Environment and Public works for its efforts to push for

    new legislation in the area of Electronic Waste, suggesting ways that a bill under

    consideration could leverage the capabilities and expertise of manufacturers to achieve

    efficient and low cost opportunities for all customers while achieving environmentally

    sound management of discarded IT products at the lowest possible cost, while

    minimizing the role and burden on government.

    In summary, Hewlett-Packard appears to have complemented its social

    responsibility position with a lobbying strategy aimed at changing government policy in

    ways that allow it to benefit from the companys existing social responsibility positions,

    which were well in front of existing government regulation and policy at the time they

    were initiated. By positioning themselves ahead of government regulation on social

    issues, Hewlett-Packard appears to have been able to create sustainable value by lobbying

    for government regulation that raised their rivals costs. On the Electronic Waste front,

    Hewlett-Packard successfully advocated for taxing all manufacturers at the time of

    electronics product sales for the cost of future recycling expenses; they were then able to

    benefit from this by also advocating for government subsidies directed at electronic

    product manufacturing firms that successfully recycled electronic products (whether the

    company receiving the subsidy manufactured the original product or a competitor did).

    At the time that Hewlett-Packard advocated for the policy changes, the company was

    already in a position to benefit from the new policy, while their competitors were not as

    well prepared.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    31/37

    30

    6 ConclusionIn this research, I have shown that CSR and corporate political activity function as

    economic complements rather than as economic substitutes. Specifically, I have shown

    that while it is true that most socially irresponsible firms are more likely to have lobbied,

    that it is also the case the most socially responsible firms are also more likely to have

    lobbied. I have also shown that in regressions that compare different firms (between

    tests), that lobbying intensity and CSR intensity both independently and jointly explain

    why some firms have higher valuations than others. More importantly, however, I have

    shown that in regressions that examine individual firms over time (within tests) that the

    interaction between lobbying intensity and CSR quality explains higher valuations,

    whereas CSR quality alone may lead to lower firm valuations. The result that the

    interaction between CSR and corporate political activity remains positive and significant

    in both between andwithin firm tests, unambiguously supports the hypothesis that the

    two non-market strategies, CSR and corporate political activity, are complements.

    My results bridge the findings between proponents of CSRwho build arguments

    based on organizational stakeholder theories and who run between firms tests to find

    empirical support that CSR increases firms valueand the results of critics of CSR

    who build their arguments based on economic theories of shareholder wealth

    maximization and who run within firm tests to find empirical support for the notion that

    CSR does not enhance firm value and may actually destroy it. The reality is that both

    the proponents of CSR and the critics of CSR have valid points; however, both have

    overlooked the complementary relationship between CSR and corporate political activity.

    When we add corporate political activity into the mix, we find that the proponents are

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    32/37

    31

    correct that CSR increases the value of the firm in some circumstances, despite the critics

    also being correct that CSR by itself can decrease the value of the firm, since CSR only

    adds value when complemented with the appropriate level of corporate political activity.

    Moreover, my results have serious implications for our understanding of any

    research on CSR or corporate political activity. If CSR and corporate political activity

    are complementary activities pursued by firms, as this research has shown, we should no

    longer consider the role of CSR or political activity alone without considering the role of

    its complement, since doing so is likely to lead to biased results under most

    circumstances. Researchers attempting to answer valuation-related questions on either

    topic (CSR or corporate political activity) should ideally incorporate data on its

    complement into the analysis. Unfortunately, doing so is often not realistic given data

    availability constraints, in which case researchers should at least acknowledge how the

    complementary relationship between CSR and corporate political activity may bias

    results focused more narrowly on one of the two non-market strategies.

    As a final thought, this research also suggests a greater need for researchers to

    study cases of regulatory capture that while designed by industry primarily for its

    benefit (Stigler 1971) may nevertheless promote positive social outcomes. Since CSR

    and corporate political activity are complements, these should be precisely the cases in

    which CSR is most profitable for firms.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    33/37

    32

    7 ReferencesAgrawal, A.; and, Knoeber, C. R. 1999. Outside Directors, Politics and FirmPerformance. Working Paper. Available on SSRN at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=85310

    Ansolabehere, S.; deFigueiredo, J.; and, Snyder, J. 2003. Why is There so Little Moneyin U.S. Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1), 105-30.

    Ansolabehere, S.; Snyder, J.; and Tripathi, M. 2002. Are PAC Contributions andLobbying Linked? New Evidence from the 1995 Lobby Disclosure Act.Business &Politics (4):2, 2

    Bagnoli, M.; and, Watts, S. G. 2003. Selling to socially responsible consumers:Competition and the private provision of public goods. Journal of Economics &Management Strategy 12(3):41945

    Baron, D.P. 2009. A Positive Theory of Moral Management, Social Pressure, and

    Corporate Social Performance.Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. 18: 7-43.

    Baron, D.P., Harjoto, M.A., and Jo, J. 2009. The Economics and Politics of CorporateSocial Performance Stanford Rock Center for Corporate Governance Working PaperNo. 45.

    Chatterji A.K.; Levine D.I.; and, Toffel M.W. 2009. How well do social ratings actuallymeasure corporate social responsibility?Journal of Economics and ManagementStrategy.18(1): 125169.

    Chen, H.; Parsley, D; and Yang, Y. 2010. Corporate Lobbying and Financial

    Performance Working Paper. Available on SSRN at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1014264

    Claessens, S.; Feijen, E.; and Laeven, L. 2008. Political Connections and PreferentialAccess to Finance: The Role of Campaign Contributions,Journal of FinancialEconomics. 88(3): 554-580.

    Dal B, E. 2006. Regulatory Capture: A Review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy.22(2), 203-225.

    Devinney, T. 2009. Is the Socially Responsible Corporation a Myth? The Good, Badand Ugly of Corporate Social Responsibility. Academy of Management Perspectives.22(3), 44-56.

    Griffin, J.J. and J.F. Mahon, 1997, The Corporate Social Performance and CorporateFinancial Performance Debate: Twenty-FiveYears of Incomparable Research,Businessand Society, 36(1), 531.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    34/37

    33

    Fimsman, R.; Elfenbein, D.; and McManus, B. 2010. Charity as a substitute forreputation: Evidence from an online marketplace. Working Paper. [Available online at:http://www2.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/rfisman/CharitySubstitutesForReputation_042810.pdf]

    Friedman, M. 1970. The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its ProfitsNew York Times Magazine. September 13, 1970.

    Hillman, A. J. and Keim, G. D. 2001. "Shareholder Value, Stakeholder Management,and Social Issues: What's the Bottom Line?" Strategic Management Journal 22(2): 125-139.

    Lyon, T. P; and Maxwell, J. W. 2008. Corporate social responsibility and theenvironment: A theoretical perspective.Review of Environmental Economics andPolicy. 2(2), 240-260.

    Margolis, J.; Elfenbein, H.; and Walsh, J. 2009. Does it pay to be goodand does itmatter? A meta-analysis of the relationship between corporate social and financialperformance. Harvard Business School Working Paper.

    McWilliams, A.; and, Siegel, D. 2000. Corporate social responsibility and financialperformance: Correlation or misspecification? Strategic Management Journal. (21),603-609.

    Milyo, J; Primo, D.M.; and Groseclose, T.J. 2000. "Corporate PAC Contributions inPerspective."Business and Politics 2(1): 7588.

    Moon, J. J. 2007. Essays in empirical analysis of corporate strategy and corporateresponsibility. Dissertation at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.[Available at: http://repository.upenn.edu/dissertations/AAI3271854]

    Orlitzky, M.; Schmidt, F.L.; Rynes, S.L. 2003. "Corporate Social and FinancialPerformance: A Meta-analysis." Organization Studies 24(3): 403-441.

    Porter, M. E. and Kramer, M.R. (2002). "The Competitive Advantage of CorporatePhilanthropy." Harvard Business Review 80(12): 56-68.

    Richter, B.K.; Samphantharak, K.; and Timmons, J.F. 2009. Lobbying and Taxes.American Journal of Political Science. 53(4): 893-909.

    Waddock, S.A. and Graves, S. B. 1997a. The Corporate Social PerformanceFinancialPerformance Link, Strategic Management Journal, 18, 303317.

    Waddock, S. A. and Graves, S. B. 1997b. "Quality of Management and Quality ofStakeholder Relations."Business & Society.36(3): 250-279.

    Wei, Z.; Xie, F.; and Zhang, S. 2005. Ownership Structure and Firm Value in China'sPrivatized Firms: 1991-2001. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.40(1), 87-108.

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    35/37

    34

    8 AppendixTABLE A - KLD Attributes within Issue Areas

    Strength Concern

    Generous Giving Tax Disputes

    Innovative Giving Investment Controversies

    Support for Housing Negative Economic Impact

    Indigenous Peoples Relations Strength Indigenous Peoples Relations Concern

    Non-U.S. Charitable Giving Other

    Volunteer Programs

    Support for Education

    Other Strength

    Strength Concern

    Limited Compensation High Compensation

    Ownership Strength Ownership Concern

    Transparency Strength Transparency Concern

    Political Accountability Strength Political Accountability Concern

    Other Strength Accounting Concern

    Other Concern

    Strength Concern

    CEO Employee Discrimination

    Promotion Non-Representation

    Board of Directors Other Concern

    Family Benefits

    Women/Minority Contracting

    Employment of the Disabled

    Progressive Gay/Lesbian Policies

    Other Strength

    Strength Concern

    Union Relations Strength Union Relations Concern

    No Layoff Policy Health and Safety Concern

    Cash Profit Sharing Workforce Reductions

    Involvement Pension/Benefits Concern

    Strong Retirement Benefits Other Concern

    Health and Safety Strength

    Other Strength

    Strength Concern

    Beneficial Products & Services Hazardous Waste

    Pollution Prevention Regulatory Problems

    Recycling Ozone Depleting Chemicals

    Alternative Fuels Substantial Emissions

    Other Strength Agricultural Chemicals

    Climate Change Policy

    Other Concern

    Strength Concern

    Indigenous Peoples Relations International Labor Concern

    Labor Rights Strength Indigenous Peoples Relations

    Other Strength Burma

    Mexico

    Other Concern

    Strength Concern

    Quality Product Safety

    R&D/Innovation Marketing/Contracting Controversy

    Benefits to Economically Disadvantaged Antitrust

    Other Strength Other Concern

    EmployeeRelations

    Environment

    Hu

    man

    Rights

    Product

    Qualities

    CommunityRelat

    ions

    Corporate

    Governance

    Diversity

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    36/37

    35

    Figure A1 Empirical Kernel Density Function of KLD Scores, by Lobbying Status

    .00

    .04

    .08

    .12

    .16

    .20

    .24

    -14 -12 -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

    Sum of KLD Strengths/Concerns

    ...for Firms that do NOT Lobby

    ...for Firms that DO Lobby

    Density

    Distribution of KLD Scores by Lobbying Status

  • 7/28/2019 ehg6 3 Richter

    37/37

    Figure A2 Illustration of Substitutes:

    Indifference Curve Oblique to Origin and MRS Equals a Constant

    Figure A3 Illustration of Complements:

    Indifference Curve Convex to Origin and MRS a Function of A, B