Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

120
Econs 501 - Microeconomic Theory I WELCOME!!! TA: Will Ottenheimer (Office hours Tuesdays 1 โ€“ 2 pm) MWG and Munoz-Garcia Mondays (Assignments) Recitations: Fridays 12-1pm (Hulbert 23) Course website: โ—ฆ https://anaespinolaarredondo.com/econs-501- microeconomic-theory-i/ Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Transcript of Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Page 1: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WELCOME!!! TA: Will Ottenheimer (Office hours Tuesdays 1

โ€“ 2 pm) MWG and Munoz-Garcia Mondays (Assignments) Recitations: Fridays 12-1pm (Hulbert 23) Course website:โ—ฆ https://anaespinolaarredondo.com/econs-501-

microeconomic-theory-i/

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Page 2: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preferences and Utility

Page 3: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

How can we formally describe an individualโ€™s preference for different amounts of a good?

3

How can we represent his preference for a particular list of goods (a bundle) over another?

We will examine under which conditions an individualโ€™s preference can be mathematically represented with a utility function.

Page 4: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference and Choice

4

Page 5: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference and Choice

5

Page 6: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Advantages:

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

Preference-based approach: โ—ฆ More tractable when the set of alternatives

๐‘‹๐‘‹has many elements.

Choice-based approach: โ—ฆ It is based on observables (actual choices)

rather than on unobservables (I.P)

Page 7: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Preferences: โ€œattitudesโ€ of the decision-maker towards a set of possible alternatives ๐‘‹๐‘‹.

For any ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘‹๐‘‹, how do you compare ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅand ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ? I prefer ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ to ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ (๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ป ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) I prefer ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ to ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ (๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ) I am indifferent (๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)

7

Page 8: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preferences

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 8

Page 9: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Completeness:โ—ฆ For an pair of alternatives ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘‹๐‘‹, the

individual decision maker: ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ป ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, or ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, or both, i.e., ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 9

Page 10: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Not all binary relations satisfy Completeness.

Example:โ—ฆ โ€œIs the brother ofโ€: John โŠ Bob and Bob โŠ

John if they are not brothers.โ—ฆ โ€œIs the father ofโ€: John โŠ Bob and Bob โŠ John

if the two individuals are not related.

Not all pairs of alternatives are comparable according to these two relations.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 10

Page 11: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 11

Page 12: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 12

Page 13: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 13

Page 14: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 14

Page 15: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Sources of intransitivity:a) Indistinguishable alternatives

a) Examples?

b) Framing effectsc) Aggregation of criteriad) Change in preferences

a) Examples?

15

Page 16: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

โ€ข Example 1.1 (Indistinguishable alternatives):โ—ฆ Take ๐‘‹๐‘‹ = โ„ as a piece of pie and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ป ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ if ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ’

1 (๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) but ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ~๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ if ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ < 1(indistinguishable).โ—ฆ Then,

1.5~0.8 since 1.5 โˆ’ 0.8 = 0.7 < 10.8~0.3 since 0.8 โˆ’ 0.3 = 0.5 < 1

โ—ฆ By transitivity, we would have 1.5~0.3, but in fact 1.5 โ‰ป 0.3 (intransitive preference relation).

16

Page 17: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Preference-Based Approach

Other examples: โ—ฆ similar shades of gray paint

โ—ฆ milligrams of sugar in your coffee

17

Page 18: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Utility Function

18

Page 19: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Utility Function

19

Page 20: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Utility Function

20

Page 21: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

21

Page 22: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

22

Page 23: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

23

Page 24: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 24

Page 25: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

25

Page 26: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 26

Page 27: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Desirability

27

Page 28: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Indifference sets

28

Page 29: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Upper contour set (UCS){y โˆˆ โ„+: y โ‰ฟ x}2

Indifference set{y โˆˆ โ„+: y ~ x}2

Lower contour set (LCS){y โˆˆ โ„+: y โ‰พ x}2

x1

x2

x

Indifference sets

29

Page 30: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Indifference sets

Note: โ—ฆ Strong monotonicity (and monotonicity)

implies that indifference curves must be negatively sloped. Hence, to maintain utility level unaffected along all

the points on a given indifference curve, an increase in the amount of one good must be accompanied by a reduction in the amounts of other goods.

30

Page 31: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

31

Page 32: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

Convexity 1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 32

Page 33: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

33

Page 34: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

Convexity 2

34

Page 35: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

35

Page 36: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x1

x2

ฮปx + (1โˆ’ฮป)y โ‰ปz

UCS

xx

yy

z

Convexity of Preferences Strictly convex preferences

36

Page 37: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences Convexity but not strict convexity

37

โ€“ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ† ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ~๐‘ง๐‘งโ€“ Such preference relation

is represented by utility function such as

๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

where ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 are substitutes.

Page 38: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences Convexity but not strict convexity

38

โ€“ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ† ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ~๐‘ง๐‘งโ€“ Such preference relation

is represented by utility function such as

๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = min{๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2}

where ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž, ๐‘๐‘ > 0.

Page 39: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

Example 1.6

39

๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 Satisfiesconvexity

Satisfies strict convexity

๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 โˆš X

min{๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2} โˆš X

๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

12 + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

12 โˆš โˆš

๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ12 + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

2 X X

Page 40: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

1) Taste for diversification: โ—ฆ An individual with

convex preferences prefers the convex combination of bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, than either of those bundles alone.

40

โ€ข Interpretation of convexity

Page 41: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

Interpretation of convexity2) Diminishing marginal rate of substitution:

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€1,2 โ‰ก ๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•/๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•/๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

โ—ฆ MRS describes the additional amount of good 1 that the consumer needs to receive in order to keep her utility level unaffected.

โ—ฆ A diminishing MRS implies that the consumer needs to receive increasingly larger amounts of good 1 in order to accept further reductions of good 2.

41

Page 42: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x1

x2

A

B

C

D

1 unit = โˆ‡x2

1 unit = โˆ‡x2

โˆ‡x1 โˆ‡โˆ‡x1

Convexity of Preferences

Diminishing marginal rate of substitution

42

Page 43: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 43

Page 44: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Convexity of Preferences

44

Page 45: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

45

Page 46: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

46

Page 47: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Quasiconcavity

47

Page 48: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

48

Page 49: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

1x

2x

( ) ( )u x u y=

x

y

( )1x yฮฑ ฮฑ+ โˆ’

( )( )1u x yฮฑ ฮฑ+ โˆ’

Quasiconcavity

49

Page 50: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

50

Page 51: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

51

Page 52: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Concavity implies quasiconcavity

52

Page 53: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 53

Page 54: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

1x2x

u

( )1 14 4

1 2 1 1,u x x x x= +

Quasiconcavity

Concave and quasiconcave utility function (3D)

54

๐‘ข๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) = ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

14๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

14

Page 55: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

55

Page 56: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

2x 1x

v

( )6 64 4

1 2 1 1,v x x x x=

Quasiconcavity

Convex but quasiconcave utility function (3D)

56

๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) = ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

64๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

64

Page 57: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

57

Page 58: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

โ€ขAdvanced Microeconomic Theory 58

Page 59: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):โ—ฆ Let us consider the case of only two goods,

๐ฟ๐ฟ = 2.

โ—ฆ Then, an individual prefers a bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ =(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) to another bundle ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = (๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2) iff ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅcontains more units of both goods than bundle ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, i.e., ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2.

โ—ฆ For illustration purposes, let us take bundle such as (2,1).

59

Page 60: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

Page 61: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):1) UCS:โ—ฆ The upper contour set of bundle (2,1) contains

bundles (๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) with weakly more than 2 units of good 1 and/or weakly more than 1 unit of good 2:

๐‘ˆ๐‘ˆ๐‘ˆ๐‘ˆ๐‘€๐‘€ 2,1 = {(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) โ‰ฟ (2,1) โŸบ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฅ 2, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ฅ 1}

โ—ฆ The frontiers of the UCS region also represent bundles preferred to (2,1).

61

Page 62: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):2) LCS: โ—ฆ The bundles in the lower contour set of

bundle (2,1) contain fewer units of both goods:

๐ฟ๐ฟ๐‘ˆ๐‘ˆ๐‘€๐‘€ 2,1 = {(2,1) โ‰ฟ (๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2) โŸบ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ค 2, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ค 1}

โ—ฆ The frontiers of the LCS region also represent bundles with fewer unis of either good 1 or good 2.

62

Page 63: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

Page 64: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):4) Regions A and B: โ—ฆ Region ๐ด๐ด contains bundles with more units of

good 2 but fewer units of good 1 (the opposite argument applies to region ๐ต๐ต).

โ—ฆ The consumer cannot compare bundles in either of these regions against bundle 2,1 .

โ—ฆ For him to be able to rank one bundle against another, one of the bundles must contain the same or more units of all goods.

64

Page 65: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):5) Preference relation is not complete:โ—ฆ Completeness requires for every pair ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ

and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, either ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ or ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ (or both).โ—ฆ Consider two bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ โ„+

2 with bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ containing more units of good 1 than bundle ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ but fewer units of good 2, i.e., ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 < ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 (as in Region B)

โ—ฆ Then, we have neither ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ nor ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ.

65

Page 66: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):6) Preference relation is transitive:โ—ฆ Transitivity requires that, for any three

bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ง๐‘ง, if ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘งthen ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง.

โ—ฆ Now ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง means ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ and๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™ for all ๐‘™๐‘™ goods.

โ—ฆ Then, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™ implies ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง.

66

Page 67: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):7) Preference relation is strongly monotone:โ—ฆ Strong monotonicity requires that if we

increase one of the goods in a given bundle, then the newly created bundle must be strictly preferred to the original bundle.

โ—ฆ Now ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ implies that ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ for all good ๐‘™๐‘™ and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘˜ > ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜ for at least one good ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

โ—ฆ Thus, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ implies ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and not ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ.

โ—ฆ Thus, we can conclude that ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ป ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ.67

Page 68: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):8) Preference relation is strictly convex:โ—ฆ Strict convexity requires that if ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ

๐‘ง๐‘ง and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ง๐‘ง, then ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ง๐‘ง for all ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ 0,1 .

โ—ฆ Now ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘ง implies that ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™ for all good ๐‘™๐‘™.

โ—ฆ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ง๐‘ง implies, for some good ๐‘˜๐‘˜, we must have ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘˜ > ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜.

68

Page 69: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Quasiconcavity

Example 1.7 (continued):โ—ฆ Hence, for any ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ 0,1 , we must have that

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘™ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™ for all good ๐‘™๐‘™๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘˜ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜ > ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜ for some ๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ—ฆ Thus, we have that ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ง๐‘ง and ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰  ๐‘ง๐‘ง, and so

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ง๐‘งand not ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฟ ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

โ—ฆ Therefore, ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ง๐‘ง.

69

Page 70: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

70

Page 71: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

71

Page 72: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functionsโ—ฆ Marginal utilities:

๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

> 0 and ๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

> 0

โ—ฆ A diminishing MRS

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1,๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 =๐›ผ๐›ผ๐ด๐ด๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

๐›ผ๐›ผโˆ’1๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2๐›ฝ๐›ฝ

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐ด๐ด๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝโˆ’1 =๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

which is decreasing in ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1. Hence, indifference curves become flatter as ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

increases.

72

Page 73: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

2x

1xIC

A

B

CD

1 unit 1 unit

2in xโˆ‡โˆ‡

2xโˆ‡

Common Utility Functions

Cobb-Douglas preference

73

Page 74: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

74

Page 75: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

Perfect substitutes

75

2A

A

2BB

AslopeB

= โˆ’

2x

1x

Page 76: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

76

Page 77: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 77

Page 78: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

Perfect complements

78

2x

1x

2 ฮฒฮฑฮฒฮฑ

1 2

ฮฒฮฑ

1u Aฮฑ=2 2u Aฮฑ=

2 1x xฮฒฮฑ

=

Page 79: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

79

Page 80: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

80

Page 81: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

CES preferences

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

2x

1xฯƒ = โˆž 8ฯƒ =

1ฯƒ =0.2ฯƒ =

0ฯƒ =

} Cobb-Douglas

Perfect complement

Perfect substitutes

Page 82: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functionsโ—ฆ CES utility function is often presented as

๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ

2= ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

๐œŒ๐œŒ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2๐œŒ๐œŒ

1๐œŒ๐œŒ

where ๐œŒ๐œŒ โ‰ก ๐œŽ๐œŽโˆ’1๐œŽ๐œŽ

.

82

Page 83: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

83

Page 84: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

MRS of quasilinear preferences

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Page 85: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Common Utility Functions

โ—ฆ For ๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = ๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2, the marginal utilities are

๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2

= ๐‘๐‘ and ๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

= ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

which implies

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1,๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 =๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•๐œ•

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1๐‘๐‘

โ—ฆ Quasilinear preferences are often used to represent the consumption of goods that are relatively insensitive to income.โ—ฆ Examples: garlic, toothpaste, etc.

85

Page 86: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Continuous Preferences

In order to guarantee that preference relations can be represented by a utility function we need continuity.

Continuity: A preference relation defined on ๐‘‹๐‘‹ is continuous if it is preserved under limits. โ—ฆ That is, for any sequence of pairs

(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘›, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘›) ๐‘›๐‘›=1โˆž with ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘› โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘› for all ๐‘›๐‘›

and lim๐‘›๐‘›โ†’โˆž

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘› = ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ and lim๐‘›๐‘›โ†’โˆž

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘› = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, the preference relation is maintained in the limiting points, i.e., ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ป ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

Page 87: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Continuous Preferences

โ—ฆ Intuitively, there can be no sudden jumps (i.e., preference reversals) in an individual preference over a sequence of bundles.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

Page 88: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Continuous Preferences

Lexicographic preferences are not continuous

โ—ฆ Consider the sequence ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘› = 1๐‘›๐‘›

, 0 and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘› =(0,1), where ๐‘›๐‘› = {0,1,2,3, โ€ฆ }.โ—ฆ The sequence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘› = (0,1) is constant in ๐‘›๐‘›.

โ—ฆ The sequence ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘› = 1๐‘›๐‘›

, 0 is not:

It starts at ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 = 1,0 , and moves leftwards to ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = 1

2, 0 , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ3 = 1

3, 0 , etc.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

Page 89: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x1

x2

1

10 โ…“ ยฝยผx 4 x 3 x 2 x 1

y n, โˆ€n, y 1 = y 2 = โ€ฆ = y n

lim x n = (0,0)n โ†’โˆž

Continuous Preferences

Thus, the individual prefers:๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 = 1,0 โ‰ป 0,1 = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = 12

, 0 โ‰ป 0,1 = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ3 = 13

, 0 โ‰ป 0,1 = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ3

โ‹ฎ But,

lim๐‘›๐‘›โ†’โˆž

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘›๐‘› = 0,0 โ‰บ 0,1= lim

๐‘›๐‘›โ†’โˆž๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘›

Preference reversal!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

Page 90: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Existence of Utility Function

If a preference relation satisfies monotonicity and continuity, then there exists a utility function ๐‘ข๐‘ข(๏ฟฝ)representing such preference relation.

Proof:โ—ฆ Take a bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  0. โ—ฆ By monotonicity, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ 0, where 0 = (0,0, โ€ฆ , 0). That is, if bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰  0, it contains positive amounts

of at least one good and, it is preferred to bundle 0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Page 91: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Existence of Utility Functionโ—ฆ Define bundle ๐‘€๐‘€ as the bundle where all

components coincide with the highest component of bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ:

๐‘€๐‘€ = max๐‘˜๐‘˜

{๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘˜} , โ€ฆ , max๐‘˜๐‘˜

{๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘˜}

โ—ฆ Hence, by monotonicity, ๐‘€๐‘€ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ.

โ—ฆ Bundles 0 and ๐‘€๐‘€ are both on the main diagonal, since each of them contains the same amount of good ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

Page 92: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x2

x1

Existence of Utility Function

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Page 93: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Existence of Utility Functionโ—ฆ By continuity and monotonicity, there exists a

bundle that is indifferent to ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ and which lies on the main diagonal.โ—ฆ By monotonicity, this bundle is uniqueOtherwise, modifying any of its components

would lead to higher/lower indifference curves.

โ—ฆ Denote such bundle as ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ)

โ—ฆ Let ๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , which is a real number.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

Page 94: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Existence of Utility Function

โ—ฆ Applying the same steps for another bundle ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰  ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, we obtain

๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)and let ๐‘ข๐‘ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , which is also a real number.

โ—ฆ We know that ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ~ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ)๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ~ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

โ—ฆ Hence, by transitivity, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ iff๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ~ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ) โ‰ฟ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘ก๐‘ก(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) ~๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Page 95: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Existence of Utility Functionโ—ฆ And by monotonicity,

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โŸบ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โŸบ ๐‘ข๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข๐‘ข(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)

โ—ฆ Note: A utility function can satisfy continuity but still be non-differentiable. For instance, the Leontief utility function,

min{๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1,๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2}, is continuous but cannot be differentiated at the kink.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Page 96: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approach

We now focus on the actual choice behavior rather than individual preferences.โ—ฆ From the alternatives in set ๐ด๐ด, which one would

you choose?

A choice structure (โ„ฌ, ๐‘๐‘(๏ฟฝ)) contains two elements:1) โ„ฌ is a family of nonempty subsets of ๐‘‹๐‘‹, so that

every element of โ„ฌ is a set ๐ต๐ต โŠ‚ ๐‘‹๐‘‹.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

Page 97: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approachโ—ฆ Example 1: In consumer theory, ๐ต๐ต is a

particular set of all the affordable bundles for a consumer, given his wealth and market prices.

โ—ฆ Example 2: ๐ต๐ต is a particular list of all the universities where you were admitted, among all universities in the scope of your imagination ๐‘‹๐‘‹, i.e., ๐ต๐ต โŠ‚ ๐‘‹๐‘‹.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

Page 98: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approach

2) ๐‘๐‘(๏ฟฝ) is a choice rule that selects, for each budget set ๐ต๐ต, a subset of elements in ๐ต๐ต, with the interpretation that ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต) are the chosen elements from ๐ต๐ต.

โ—ฆ Example 1: In consumer theory, ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต) would be the bundles that the individual chooses to buy, among all bundles he can afford in budget set ๐ต๐ต;

โ—ฆ Example 2: In the example of the universities, ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต) would contain the university that you choose to attend.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

Page 99: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approachโ—ฆ Note: If ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต) contains a single element, ๐‘๐‘(โ‹…) is a

function; If ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต) contains more than one element, ๐‘๐‘(โ‹…

) is correspondence.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

Page 100: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approach

Example 1.10 (Choice structures):โ—ฆ Define the set of alternatives as

๐‘‹๐‘‹ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}

โ—ฆ Consider two different budget sets๐ต๐ต1 = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ} and ๐ต๐ต2 = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}

โ—ฆ Choice structure one (โ„ฌ, ๐‘๐‘1(๏ฟฝ))๐‘๐‘1 ๐ต๐ต1 = ๐‘๐‘1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ}

๐‘๐‘1 ๐ต๐ต2 = ๐‘๐‘1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ}

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Page 101: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Choice Based Approach

โ€ข Example 1.10 (continued):โ—ฆ Choice structure two (โ„ฌ, ๐‘๐‘2(๏ฟฝ))

๐‘๐‘2 ๐ต๐ต1 = ๐‘๐‘2 ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ}๐‘๐‘2 ๐ต๐ต2 = ๐‘๐‘2 ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ}

โ—ฆ Is such a choice rule consistent?We need to impose a consistency requirement

on the choice-based approach, similar to rationality assumption on the preference-based approach.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Page 102: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consistency on Choices: the Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Page 103: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference

(WARP): The choice structure (โ„ฌ, ๐‘๐‘(๏ฟฝ))satisfies the WARP if:1) for some budget set ๐ต๐ต โˆˆ โ„ฌ with ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐ต๐ต,

we have that element ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ is chosen, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ต),then

2) for any other budget set ๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„ฌ where alternatives ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ are also available, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ, and where alternative ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is chosen, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ), then we must have that alternative ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ is chosen as well, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘๐‘(๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

Page 104: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP

Example 1.11 (Checking WARP in choice structures):โ—ฆ Take budget set ๐ต๐ต = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ} with the choice

rule of ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ. โ—ฆ Then, for budget set ๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}, the โ€œlegalโ€

choice rules are either:๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ}, or ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ง๐‘ง}, or

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Page 105: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP

Example 1.11 (continued):โ—ฆ This implies, individual decision-maker cannot

select ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰  {๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ}

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰  {๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰  {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ}

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

Page 106: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP

Example 1.12 (More on choice structures satisfying/violating WARP:โ—ฆ Take budget set ๐ต๐ต = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ} with the choice

rule of ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ}.โ—ฆ Then, for budget set ๐ต๐ตโ€ฒ = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}, the โ€œlegalโ€

choices according to WARP are either:๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ}, or

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ง๐‘ง}, or ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ง๐‘ง}

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Page 107: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP

Example 1.12 (continued):โ—ฆ Choice rule satisfying WARP

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

B

Bโ€™

C(Bโ€™)

C(B)

yx

Page 108: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

WARP

Example 1.12 (continued):โ—ฆ Choice rule violating WARP

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

B

Bโ€™

C(Bโ€™)

C(B)

y

x

Page 109: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets Consumption set: a subset of the

commodity space โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ, denoted by ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โŠ‚ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ,whose elements are the consumption bundles that the individual can conceivably consume, given the physical constrains imposed by his environment.

Let us denote a commodity bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ as a vector of ๐ฟ๐ฟ components.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 109

Page 110: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets

Physical constraint on the labor market

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 110

Page 111: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x

Beer inSeattleat noon

Beer inBarcelona

at noon

Consumption Sets

Consumption at two different locations

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 111

Page 112: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets

Convex consumption sets:โ—ฆ A consumption set ๐‘‹๐‘‹ is convex if, for two

consumption bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘‹๐‘‹, the bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ

is also an element of ๐‘‹๐‘‹ for any ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ (0,1).

โ—ฆ Intuitively, a consumption set is convex if, for any two bundles that belong to the set, we can construct a straight line connecting them that lies completely within the set.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 112

Page 113: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

Assumptions on the price vector in โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ:

1) All commodities can be traded in a market, at prices that are publicly observable. This is the principle of completeness of markets It discards the possibility that some goods

cannot be traded, such as pollution.

2) Prices are strictly positive for all ๐ฟ๐ฟ goods, i.e., ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 for every good ๐‘˜๐‘˜. Some prices could be negative, such as pollution.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 113

Page 114: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

3) Price taking assumption: a consumerโ€™s demand for all ๐ฟ๐ฟ goods represents a small fraction of the total demand for the good.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 114

Page 115: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

Bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+๐ฟ๐ฟ is affordable if

๐‘๐‘1๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 + โ‹ฏ + ๐‘๐‘๐ฟ๐ฟ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐ฟ๐ฟ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘คor, in vector notation, ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค.

Note that ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ is the total cost of buying bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ =(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ๐ฟ๐ฟ) at market prices ๐‘๐‘ = (๐‘๐‘1, ๐‘๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘๐ฟ๐ฟ), and ๐‘ค๐‘ค is the total wealth of the consumer.

When ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+๐ฟ๐ฟ then the set of feasible consumption

bundles consists of the elements of the set:๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ๐ฟ : ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค}

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 115

Page 116: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

p2

p1- (slope)

{x โˆˆโ„+:p โˆ™x = w}2

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

๐‘๐‘1๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 = ๐‘ค๐‘ค โŸน

๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 =๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘๐‘2

โˆ’๐‘๐‘1

๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 116

โ€ข Example: ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+2 : ๐‘๐‘1๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค}

Page 117: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

x1

x3

x2

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

โ€ข Example: ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค = {๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+3 : ๐‘๐‘1๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ2 + ๐‘๐‘3๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ3 โ‰ค

๐‘ค๐‘ค}โ—ฆ Budget hyperplane

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 117

Page 118: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

Price vector ๐‘๐‘ is orthogonal to the budget line ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค.โ—ฆ Note that ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ค๐‘ค holds for any bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ on the

budget line.โ—ฆ Take any other bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ which also lies on ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค.

Hence, ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘ค๐‘ค.โ—ฆ Then,

๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ = 0 or ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ โˆ†๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ = 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 118

Page 119: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

โ—ฆ Since this is valid for any two bundles on the budget line, then ๐‘๐‘ must be perpendicular to โˆ†๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ on ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค.

โ—ฆ This implies that the price vector is perpendicular (orthogonal) to ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 119

Page 120: Econs 501-Microeconomic Theory I

Consumption Sets: Economic Constraints

The budget set ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค is convex.โ—ฆ We need that, for any two bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โˆˆ

๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค, their convex combination๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ

also belongs to the ๐ต๐ต๐‘๐‘,๐‘ค๐‘ค, where ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ (0,1).

โ—ฆ Since ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค and ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค, then ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐‘๐‘๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + ๐‘๐‘ 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ

= ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 120