Economist Insights 15 April2

download Economist Insights 15 April2

of 2

Transcript of Economist Insights 15 April2

  • 7/28/2019 Economist Insights 15 April2

    1/2

    Economist InsightsExchange wait

    15 April 2013Asset management

    If you have just graduated from a macroeconomics course

    and are looking for a country to apply your knowledge to,

    then do not look at the UK. The UK economy has been the

    cause of headaches for many economists, including those

    at the Bank of England (BoE), because it does not seemto operate the way it should. One headache has been the

    unusual behaviour of employment and productivity (see

    Economist Insights, 25 March 2013); another has been the

    stubborn persistence of the UK trade deficit.

    Economics professors teach us that a persistent depreciation

    in a countrys currency should lead to an improvement in

    competitiveness and therefore in the trade balance. The pound

    (GBP) has devalued so imports into the UK should be more

    expensive and exports should be cheaper for foreigners. After

    the UK left the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) in 1992, GBP

    depreciated significantly and the trade balance improved as

    expected, moving from a deficit of 4% of GDP to a surplus ofalmost 1% (see chart 1). Conversely, the strong appreciation of

    GBP in the mid-90s caused the trade balance to worsen to a

    deficit of about 3% of GDP.

    Given this past, nicely-fitting pattern, you would have expected

    the 25% depreciation of GBP during 2007-2008 (one of the

    largest on record) to have pushed the trade balance back to

    positive territory. Yet more than four years later, the trade

    balance has shown no real improvement. This failure to react

    has been particularly confounding for the BoE. The BoE had

    hoped that its loose monetary policy would weaken the

    exchange rate and hence help the UK economy grow into amore balanced, export-led economy. The first part was achieved

    but the improvement in the economy and the trade balance

    remain elusive.

    One related factor is certainly the health of the UKs major

    trading partner, the Eurozone. The crisis, fiscal consolidation

    and on-going weakness in the Eurozone have kept demand

    for imports very depressed. Even if the depreciation has

    made UK exports more competitive, if people in the

    Eurozone are not buying very much that price advantage is

    less of an advantage.

    Weak demand in the Eurozone may explain some of the UK

    trade balance underperformance, but on its own it is not

    enough. To fully understand the trade balance developments,

    you also need to examine the composition by types of goodsand services of that balance and how it has evolved since the

    early 1990s.

    Joshua McCallum

    Senior Fixed Income Economist

    UBS Global Asset Management

    [email protected]

    Gianluca MorettiFixed Income Economist

    UBS Global Asset Management

    [email protected]

    Source: ONS, Bank of England, UBS Global Asset Management

    Chart 1: Breaking relationship

    UK trade balance and nominal effective exchange rate (NEER)

    -4

    -3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    NEER (rhs-inverted, deviation from 1990 2012 average)

    Trade Balance (lhs, % of GDP)

    Strong

    Weak

    Q1-1990 Q3-1995 Q1-2001 Q3-2006 Q1-2012

    -20

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    -5

    -10

    -15

    The UK economy has caused headaches for economists

    because it does not seem to operate the way it should,

    noticeably in the stubborn persistence of the UK trade deficit.

    GBP depreciated by 25% during 2007-2008 but four years later

    the trade balance has shown no real improvement. A large

    part of the explanation lies in the change in sector composition

    of the trade balance since the early 1990s. The boom in thefinancial services sector in the 90s caused a strengthening of

    the exchange rate which weakened other sectors. As a result, a

    rebalancing towards a more export-led UK economy may take

    much longer.

    http://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20130325.pdfhttp://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20130325.pdfhttp://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20130325.pdf
  • 7/28/2019 Economist Insights 15 April2

    2/2

    The UK trade balance has always been characterised by a

    surplus in the service sector and a deficit in the goods sector.

    The post-ERM devaluation led to an improvement in the trade

    balance for all sectors with the exception of financial services,

    which retained its surplus broadly unchanged (see chart 2).

    Visit any industrial town in the north of England and they will

    tell you that the sharp and persistent appreciation of GBP in

    the 1990s was very painful for UK goods-producing sectors,

    especially manufacturing. In the following decade the trade

    balance for manufacturing worsened by almost 2.5% of GDP.

    The share of manufactured goods as a percentage of total

    exports fell from 42% in 1998 to just 27% by 2007.

    By contrast, ask anyone in London about exports over that

    period and they will identify one sector that seemed to

    do nicely despite the exchange rate: financial services. The

    financial services sector saw its share of exports double from7% to 14%. Thanks to the strength in financial services in

    particular, the trade deficit only worsened to 3% of GDP. But

    this improvement in services masked the massive weakness in

    exports of manufacturing and other goods (even North Sea

    oil, due to shrinking production and ageing, inefficient power

    stations). Without the services improvement, the trade deficit

    would have been around 6.5% of GDP.

    The manufacturing decline was not just a UK problem.

    Manufacturing sectors across developed markets were in

    relative decline as the principle of comparative advantage

    played out: developed markets specialised in services and niche

    manufacturing while emerging markets specialised in massproduction manufacturing. On top of that natural economic

    occurrence, a number of countries, notably China, kept their own

    exchange rates artificially low in order to gain an even bigger

    advantage for their manufacturers. Even so UK manufacturing

    exports underperformed the rest of the world. In the UK, the

    manufacturing sector was excessively penalised by the relative

    strength of the financial sector. A strong and productive financial

    sector meant counterbalancing exports but also large capital

    inflows and foreign direct investment into the UK. The BoE also

    had to keep interest rates higher to contain inflationary pressure in

    London and the South East, even though the rest of the country

    would have much preferred lower interest rates.

    In short, the UK suffered from an economic condition similar

    to Dutch disease: where one booming sector (finance in the

    UK; in the Netherlands it was gas) causes over-appreciation of

    the exchange rate, higher rates and wage inflation, all of which

    weaken the rest of the economy. This in turn leads to lower

    investment and a decline in the structural capacity of those

    other sectors. Factories shut and skills are lost. Consumers

    become used to buying imported goods, putting further

    pressure on domestic producers.

    This structural decline may go a long way to explaining why

    the massive exchange rate depreciation did not translate into

    improved manufacturing exports. It is hard to quickly increase

    exports when the factories are shut, or the skilled workersare unavailable. And even though interest rates are now low,

    credit availability is so constrained that most firms cannot

    benefit. Imports now make up such a large proportion of goods

    purchases that consumers would have to be extremely sensitive

    to prices before domestic producers would feel much benefit.

    Hence manufacturing has only managed to squeeze out a small

    improvement in trade balance since 2008 and is nowhere near

    its past peak. All other goods, along with the crisis-hit financial

    sector, showed worsening trade balances since 2008. Only

    other services managed to provide an offset, which reinforces

    the message from the manufacturing decline: other servicesectors had the capacity and skills in place to take advantage of

    the lower exchange rate.

    Some anecdotal evidence suggests that UK exporters have

    been using the exchange rate to increase their profit per item,

    rather than to increase market share. Perhaps this reflects

    limited capacity to expand, but at some point it seems likely that

    they will want to expand capacity. Eventually banks will have

    adjusted their balance sheets, or the BoE will have managed

    to incentivise more lending, and cheap credit will flow once

    again. If big trading partners like the Eurozone or (more likely)

    the US manage to grow again, then perhaps the outlook for

    UK manufacturing exports will improve. Economics all too oftentends to assume that the market moves from one equilibrium to

    another very quickly, but in the real world we may have to wait

    longer for the exchange rate to help as long as the BoE can

    keep the currency weak.

    The views expressed are as of April 2013 and are a general guide to the views of UBS Global Asset Management. This document does not replace portfolio and fund-specific materials. Commentary is at a macro or strategy level and is not with reference to any registered or other mutual fund. This document is intended forlimited distribution to the clients and associates of UBS Global Asset Management. Use or distribution by any other person is prohibited. Copying any part of this publicationwithout the written permission of UBS Global Asset Management is prohibited. Care has been taken to ensure the accuracy of its content but no responsibility is acceptedfor any errors or omissions herein. Please note that past per formance is not a guide to the future. Potential for profit is accompanied by the possibility of loss. The value ofinvestments and the income from them may go down as well as up and investors may not get back the original amount invested. This document is a marketing communication.Any market or investment views expressed are not intended to be investment research. The document has not been prepared in line with the requirements of any jurisdictiondesigned to promote the independence of investment research and is not subject to any prohibition on dealing ahead of the dissemination of investment research. The

    information contained in this document does not constitute a distribution, nor should it be considered a recommendation to purchase or sell any particular security or fund.The information and opinions contained in this document have been compiled or arrived at based upon information obtained from sources believed to be reliable and in goodfaith. All such information and opinions are subject to change without notice. A number of the comments in this document are based on current expectations and are consideredforward-looking statements. Actual future results, however, may prove to be different from expectations. The opinions expressed are a reflection of UBS Global AssetManagements best judgment at the time this document is compiled and any obligation to update or alter forward-looking statements as a result of new information, futureevents, or otherwise is disclaimed. Furthermore, these views are not intended to predict or guarantee the future performance of any individual security, asset class, marketsgenerally, nor are they intended to predict the future performance of any UBS Global Asset Management account, portfolio or fund. UBS 2013. The key symbol and UBS are among the registered and unregistered trademarks of UBS. All rights reserved. 22947

    Chart 2: Ill-positioning

    Change in trade balance by sector, % of GDP

    -2.5

    -2.0

    -1.5

    -1.0

    -0.5

    0.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    Other ServicesFinance & Insurance

    ManufacturingBasic Materials & EnergyOther Goods

    2008 20121998 20071990 1997

    Source: ONS, UBS Global Asset Management

    Note: Other Goods includes food, beverage and semi-manufactured products.