Economist Insights 11 February2

download Economist Insights 11 February2

of 2

Transcript of Economist Insights 11 February2

  • 7/29/2019 Economist Insights 11 February2

    1/2

    Economist InsightsMoving target

    11 February 2013Asset management

    The announcement last November of Mark Carneys

    appointment as the next Governor of the Bank of England

    was accompanied by much lauding. We have been reminded

    that he was voted Central Banker of the Year 2012 bynumerous magazines including the Wall Street Journal and

    EuroMoney. Chancellor George Osborne described him as

    [t]he outstanding central banker of his generation.

    The markets were looking for some sort of momentous

    announcement when Governor Carney faced public cross-

    examination by the UK parliaments Treasury Committee

    last week. In previous speeches he had indicated some

    interest in quite revolutionary ideas. In the event, markets

    were disappointed; Governor Carneys comments were quite

    measured and he left his options open. Those hoping for big

    changes in UK monetary policy may have been excited by

    Governor Carneys calls for regular reviews of the monetarypolicy framework. Before anyone gets too excited it is worth

    remembering that such reviews were undertaken at the Bank

    of Canada and the framework was left basically unchanged.

    The big changes to the framework that some are calling for

    are a switch to either price level targeting (PLT) or nominal

    GDP targeting (NGDPT). Both these ideas have been much

    discussed in the market and in the financial press over the

    last year.

    The idea behind PLT is that the inflation rate shouldnt just be

    close to target, but should average close to the target overtime. So if inflation is above target for a few years, under PLT

    the central bank would need to have inflation belowtarget

    for a few years so that it balances out. Under normal inflation

    targeting the central bank would just try to get inflation back

    to target but would stop inflation going below. For long-

    term investors, PLT should give more predictable inflation

    outcomes than inflation targeting.

    The challenge to implementing PLT in the UK is that inflation

    has been above target for several years resulting in a big

    positive gap from the price level (see chart). This would

    require the Bank of England to hike rates immediately to

    correct for the overshoot not a policy that anyone really

    wants. This is why the focus has generally been on nominal

    GDP targeting.

    Joshua McCallum

    Senior Fixed Income Economist

    UBS Global Asset Management

    [email protected]

    Gianluca Moretti

    Fixed Income Economist

    UBS Global Asset Management

    [email protected]

    Source: ONS, UBS Global Asset Management

    Governor Mark Carney, soon to take up his

    appointment as next Governor of the Bank of England,

    gave evidence to the UK parliaments Treasury

    Committee last week. The market may have been

    looking for an announcement of big changes for UK

    monetary policy, but Governor Carneys commentsleft his options open. He stressed the importance of

    flexible inflation targeting, but did not go as far as

    recommending price level targeting or nominal GDP

    targeting, which some commentators were looking for.

    Un-level

    Percentage deviation of price level or nominal GDP from hypothetical

    targets (starting point is May 1997 for both RPIX with 2.5% inflation

    and nominal GDP with 5% growth, and December 2003 for CPI with2% inflation).

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

    RPIX Gap CPI Gap (Dec 2003) Nominal GDP Gap

  • 7/29/2019 Economist Insights 11 February2

    2/2

    NGDPT targeting is based on the idea that the central bank

    cannot choose whether increased liquidity will end up as

    higher inflation or higher real growth. Since nominal GDP is

    effectively the sum of real growth and inflation, as a target

    it is arguably more appropriate. If real growth is moving

    around trend, there is little to distinguish NGDPT from PLT.

    Where NGDPT differentiates itself is in a recession. Unlike

    inflation targeting, NGDPT could actually require the central

    bank to loosen policy even if inflation is already at or above

    target. Higher inflation would then be acceptable because it

    is offsetting the shortfall in real growth. The hope would also

    be that further monetary stimulus could even spur a recovery

    in real growth. In contrast to PLT, recent UK experience

    suggests that a NGDPT regime would require even looser

    monetary policy for a very long time (see chart).

    So NGDPT would allow for looser monetary policy even while

    inflation is above target. If you think this sounds remarkably

    like what the Bank of England has been doing for the last

    few years, then you are absolutely right. Yet this is widely

    accepted; after all, the recession is a good reason for the

    Bank of England to keep monetary policy loose not only

    to help the economy and job creation, but also becauseweak growth should eventually bring down inflation. In

    other words, a sufficiently malleable inflation target can be

    a pretty good proxy for NGDPT. This is exactly the point that

    Governor Carney made when he stressed the importance of

    flexible inflation targeting.

    The key idea that Governor Carney put forward last week

    was that flexible inflation targeting requires the central bank

    to meet the inflation target at some point in the future, but

    the central bank can explicitly change that time horizon if

    necessary. Traditionally the Bank of England has aimed to

    get inflation down to target over a two year horizon, but

    flexibility could allow it to extend that time horizon so that

    policy could stay loose for longer in order to support growth.

    The big drawback of nominal GDP targeting is that the

    average consumer, or average employer, or even average

    investor, has no idea what the level of nominal GDP is.

    However, they do have a pretty good idea of what inflation

    is because they experience inflation when they go shopping.

    There is a risk from NGDPT that inflation expectations

    become unanchored because monetary policy remains loose

    even after the economy has recovered (to make up for the

    shortfall in nominal GDP during the recession). The 1970s

    demonstrated quite clearly that rising inflation expectations

    can spiral out of control. This could paradoxically lead to a

    central bank with a NGDPT regime being forced to tighten

    policy to shrink real GDP before the economy has recovered.

    If you want nominal GDP growth of 5% per annum but

    inflation is spiralling out of control at 8% you actually need

    real GDP toshrinkby 3%.

    There is a parallel between NGDPT and the idea of credible

    irresponsibility (seeEconomist Insights, 17 September 2012).

    A commitment to nominal GDP would allow a central bank

    to credibly ignore inflation. This would be most important for

    a country where inflation expectations have been anchored

    belowwhere the central bank wants them. This is not the

    case for the UK, but it does suggest that if any country

    should be first to try NGDPT it is Japan.

    Another explanation for Governor Carneys focus on flexible

    inflation targets is that he knows that to change the central

    bank regime now would look like opportunism. Investors

    and consumers would come to doubt the governments

    commitment to any monetary regime if they change the

    regime at exactly the point when it is most convenient forthemselves. If they change it once, might they not change

    it again? Here is the advantage of the regular reviews

    that the Bank of Canada has in place changes look less

    opportunistic when they follow a pre-scheduled review.

    So if we are not going to see the introduction of NGDPT in

    the UK, what changes will the new Governor put in place?

    The first change would likely be an explicit variation in the

    time horizon over which the Bank of England will aim to

    get inflation down to target at the moment, that will be a

    lot longer than expected, and this would be communicated

    explicitly. The second change could be more explicit

    conditional commitments to keep rates low until certain

    criteria are met, much like the Federal Reserve has done. The

    third change is likely to be that Governor Carney will be more

    focused on longer-term inflation expectations than short-

    term inflation expectations (for example, looking at 5 year

    -5 year forward breakeven inflation). All of these measures

    would make the Bank of England look a lot more like the

    Federal Reserve, but maybe that is the objective?

    The views expressed are as of February 2013 and are a general guide to the views of UBS Global Asset Management. This document does not replace portfolio and fund-specific materials. Commentary is at a macro or strategy level and is not with reference to any registered or other mutual fund. This document is intended forlimited distribution to the clients and associates of UBS Global Asset Management. Use or distribution by any other person is prohibited. Copying any part of this publicationwithout the written permission of UBS Global Asset Management is prohibited. Care has been taken to ensure the accuracy of its content but no responsibility is acceptedfor any errors or omissions herein. Please note that past per formance is not a guide to the future. Potential for profit is accompanied by the possibility of loss. The value ofinvestments and the income from them may go down as well as up and investors may not get back the original amount invested. This document is a marketing communication.Any market or investment views expressed are not intended to be investment research. The document has not been prepared in line with the requirements of any jurisdiction

    designed to promote the independence of investment research and is not subject to any prohibition on dealing ahead of the dissemination of investment research. Theinformation contained in this document does not constitute a distribution, nor should it be considered a recommendation to purchase or sell any particular security or fund.The information and opinions contained in this document have been compiled or arrived at based upon information obtained from sources believed to be reliable and in goodfaith. All such information and opinions are subject to change without notice. A number of the comments in this document are based on current expectations and are consideredforward-looking statements. Actual future results, however, may prove to be different from expectations. The opinions expressed are a reflection of UBS Global AssetManagements best judgment at the time this document is compiled and any obligation to update or alter forward-looking statements as a result of new information, futureevents, or otherwise is disclaimed. Furthermore, these views are not intended to predict or guarantee the future performance of any individual security, asset class, marketsgenerally, nor are they intended to predict the future performance of any UBS Global Asset Management account, portfolio or fund. UBS 2013. The key symbol and UBS are among the registered and unregistered trademarks of UBS. All rights reserved. 22733

    http://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20120917.pdfhttp://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20120917.pdfhttp://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20120917.pdfhttp://www.ubs.com/content/dam/static/asset_management/global/research/insights/economist-insights-20120917.pdf