Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

81
Understanding the Causes of the Housing Bubble in the United States Tu Nguyen Advisor: Dr. John Abell Presented to the Department of Economics in partial fulfillment of the requirements for a Bachelor of Arts degree with Honors Randolph College Lynchburg, Virginia

Transcript of Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Page 1: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding the Causes of the Housing Bubble

in the United States

Tu Nguyen

Advisor: Dr. John Abell

Presented to the Department of Economics

in partial fulfillment of the requirements

for a Bachelor of Arts degree with Honors

Randolph College

Lynchburg, Virginia

May 9th, 2015

Page 2: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -1-

Abstract

This paper attempts to explain the causes of the recent housing bubble in the United

States in a multidisciplinary approach. A review of the literature suggests that there are economic

and psychological theories behind the bubble. A housing bubble index is introduced to gauge the

existence of a bubble in the market. A 2-stage least squares regression analysis using the Newey

West Estimator method is used to empirically test these theories. The results indicate that

government housing subsidies and the media are significant determinants of the housing bubble

index. In addition, the lagged dependent variable being significant with a high t value suggests

that the housing bubble had a strong momentum and built a virtuous cycle within itself.

However, these findings must be taken with caution because it is still not known whether the

Newey West Estimator method can be applied to cointegrated time series data.

Page 3: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -2-

Table of Contents

Section I: Introduction …………………………………………………………………………... 3

Section II: Literature Review ……………………………………………………………………. 5

Section III: Data and Method …………………………………………………………………... 15

Section IV: Model ……………………………………………………………………………… 24

Section V: Results ……………………………………………………………………………… 29

Section VI: Limitations ………………………………………………………………………… 40

Section VII: Policy Implications ……………………………………………………………….. 42

Appendix A …………………………………………………………………………………….. 43

Appendix B …………………………………………………………………………………….. 45

References ……………………………………………………………………………………… 47

Page 4: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -3-

I. Introduction

Seven years have passed since 2008 but the effects of the financial crisis are still being

felt. On September 15, 2008, Lehman Brothers, the fourth-largest investment bank in the United

States at the time, collapsed after a great struggle to avoid bankruptcy. The collapse of Lehman

Brothers paralyzed the global financial system, threatening to bring it down. A number of large

financial institutions such as AIG and Citigroup faced the threat of bankruptcy, which was then

prevented by a huge bank bailout package by the federal government. However, the bank bailout

package from the government, together with an economic stimulus package in 2009, was not

enough to keep the US economy and the global economy from going into a recession. Three

economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Luttrell, Atkinson, and Rosenblum (2013),

estimated that this financial crisis has cost the U.S. economy at least 40 to 90 percent of one

year’s output, a value of $6 trillion to $14 trillion. The Global Financial Crisis of 2008 is

considered by many economists to be the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression.

Realizing the long-lasting damage of the recent crisis, one will naturally ask, what caused

the global financial crisis? There are many theories to explain the causes of the financial crisis of

2008. However, the general consensus is that the primary cause of the financial breakdown was

the credit crisis following the burst of the housing bubble. Steven Gjerstad and Vernon Smith

found that, historically, housing bubbles have been a leading indicator in eleven out of the

fourteen economic recessions since 1929 (Gjerstad & Smith, 2013). It does not require much

thought to realize that financial bubbles, in particular housing bubbles, have had significant

impacts on the economy and people’s lives. However, Yan, Woodard, & Sornette (2012) pointed

out that bubbles have been ignored at the policy level. To be specific, they mentioned that not

until the global financial crisis did government officials acknowledge the importance of

Page 5: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -4-

understanding and forecasting bubbles in general, including housing bubbles (Yan, Woodard, &

Sornette, 2012). Therefore, it is safe to claim that a thorough understanding of housing bubbles is

necessary to prevent another recession from happening in the future.

By far, the majority of the literature on housing bubbles focuses on developing theoretical

models to explain the phenomenon. The Log-Periodic Power Law bubble model or its

modifications are often employed to study the dynamics of bubbles and crashes (Yan et. al,

2012; Ohnishi, Mizuno, Shimizu, & Watanabe, 2011; Kivedal, 2013). Some other researchers

attempted to find out the causes of the housing bubble graphically by looking for the correlation

between certain macroeconomic indicators, which will be discussed in the following section, and

periods of housing booms (Liebowitz, 2009). A number of analysts have conducted empirical

research to identify the existence of housing bubbles in the market, but so far only a few

attempted to find out the causes of bubbles empirically (Escobari, Damianov, & Bello, 2012;

Mayer, 2011; Kohn & Bryant, 2011). In this paper, I will develop an econometric model to

explain the causes of housing bubbles in a multidisciplinary approach that hopefully might allow

policy makers to prevent another catastrophe from happening in the future by making smart

decisions when the bubble is still in its early stages.

The paper is laid out as follows: Section II will cover the literature on housing bubbles in

the United States, including the definition and some theories that aim to explain the causes of the

bubbles. Section III will go into detail on the method and data used in the study. Section IV will

describe the econometric model employed in the paper. Section V will detail the results and

implications of the quantitative analysis. Finally, Section VI will specify some limitations of this

study and provide recommendations and suggestions for future research.

II. Literature Review

Page 6: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -5-

So what exactly is a housing bubble, or even a bubble in general? The following is a

definition of bubbles which has been widely accepted among economists, by Charles

Kindleberger, a prominent economic historian and author of several books on financial crises:

A bubble may be defined loosely as a sharp rise in the price of an asset or a range of

assets in a continuous process, with the initial rise generating expectations of further rises

and attracting new buyers – generally speculators interested in profits from trading in the

asset rather than its use or earnings capacity (cited in Eatwell, Milgate, & Newman, 1987,

p. 281).

A housing bubble will then be defined accordingly, by replacing the word “asset” from

the above definition with “real estate”. The definition is straightforward. However, it is not an

easy task to determine whether a bubble is forming at a specific point in time, not to mention

trying to explain the causes of the bubble. For example, before the bursting of the housing bubble

in 2006, there was a strong debate among scholars around the existence of a bubble in the real

estate market. In fact, “there still does not appear to be a cohesive theory or persuasive empirical

approach with which to study bubble and crash conditions” (Vogel, 2009, p. i).

Since the bubble burst, researchers have started trying to explain what conditions led to

the bubble. However, a review of the literature suggests that a general consensus on the causes of

the housing bubble has not been reached. Ben Bernanke (2009), former chairman of the Federal

Reserve, cited the inflows of global savings into the United States as the main cause of the recent

housing bubble. He argued that the surplus of available funds led financial institutions to

compete for borrowers, thus making it easier for households and businesses to obtain credit. In

addition, the large inflows of global savings drove down interest rates in the United States, which

made it cheaper for investors to borrow money. As a result, more people took out loans to invest

Page 7: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -6-

in the real estate market. Furthermore, the lending process was poorly done as lenders took on

higher risks by approving subprime mortgage loans to borrowers with bad credit. Lenders might

have believed in borrowers’ ability to refinance loans because with rising house prices,

borrowers could just take out loans to buy a house with little down payment, add nominal

improvements, sell it quickly after a few weeks, and still profit from the price increase. The rapid

expansion of mortgage lending resulted in the housing boom in the U.S. Eventually, when

investors realized home prices were overvalued, the whole system collapsed. Borrowers with low

creditworthiness could not repay their loans, and large lenders declared bankruptcy.

Furthermore, Bernanke (2009) argued that the saving inflows from abroad not only

affected the mortgage market but also drove down returns on traditional long-term investments,

causing investors to look for alternatives. To meet the increasing demand for new investments,

the financial industry creatively designed securities that combined individual loans in intricate

ways. Later, these new securities turned out to involve hidden and significant risks that were not

fully understood by both investors and designers of the securities in the first place.

Contrary to Bernanke (2009) who believed foreign savings were the primary cause of the

housing bubble, many researchers pointed to the U.S. government as the culprit (Gerardi et al.,

2008; Liebowitz, 2009; Wallison, 2009). These scholars suggest that the underlying cause of the

bubble is believed to be the U.S. government’s efforts to increase home ownership, especially

among low-income and minority groups, represented through the Community Reinvestment Act

of 1977 (CRA) and the affordable-housing mission of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the 1990s.

According to this line of thinking, instead of providing subsidies to these underserved groups,

through regulatory and political pressure, the government forced banks into making loans that

would not be normally advisable (Wallison, 2009). As a result, banks had to reduce their lending

Page 8: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -7-

standards to make mortgage financing accessible to more people. The decline in mortgage

lending standards allowed mortgages in some cases to require virtually no down payment, which

helped increase the homeownership rates. The Alternative Mortgage Transactions Parity Act of

1982 aided in the process by removing restrictions against mortgage loans with exotic features,

such as ARM and interest-only mortgages (Sherman, 2009). As a result, from 1995, when

lending quotas from CRA became effective, to 2005, the homeownership rate saw a surge from

64 percent to 69 percent:

Figure 1. Homeownership Rate in the United States

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

61.0

62.0

63.0

64.0

65.0

66.0

67.0

68.0

69.0

70.0

Homeownership Rate in the United States (1985-2014)

Hom

eow

ners

hip

Rate

(Pe

rcen

t)

Source: U.S. Census Bureau

The rise in homeownership in turn led to an increase in house prices, which eventually

created a bubble. When the bubble burst, many homeowners having received subprime

Page 9: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -8-

mortgages were not able to make their payments. The reason for these defaults is

straightforward. Low-income or bad credit borrowers took out no or little down payment home

loans because they believed that during the housing boom, their home price would rise

substantially, thus increasing their home equity1. As a result, they would soon be qualified for

traditional mortgage loans or they could turn around and sell their house for a higher return.

Unfortunately, the truth was harsh. One thing to notice is that the interest rate associated with

these no or little down payment loans was set to rise after one or two years. In addition, the Fed

started raising the interest rate in 2004 in an attempt to slow down the economy. These two

combined effects caused the loan payments to expand significantly. As a result, these borrowers

soon defaulted after the housing bubble burst in 2006. To be specific, it is estimated that

homeowners who used subprime mortgages to purchase their homes ended up in foreclosure

more than 6 times as often as those who used prime mortgages (Gerardi et al., 2008). As a result,

the financial system got into trouble. This would have been prevented with stricter underwriting

standards.

Moreover, lots of changes to the regulatory framework which took place in the late 20th

century might have contributed to housing bubbles in the U.S. (Sherman, 2009). A brief history

of financial deregulation in the United States is included in Appendix A.

Some researchers believed that interest rates played a significant role in fueling the

housing bubble. According to White (2009), the Fed’s expansionary monetary policy provided

the means for unsustainable housing prices and risky mortgage financing. From 2001 to 2006 the

Fed kept the federal funds rate well below its targeted level suggested by the Taylor rule2, which

1 Home equity: The amount of the house that the homeowner truly owns. If s/he sells the house and pays off bank loans, the value of the home equity is the difference between the market value and the mortgage. The homeowner can build up his/her equity if the home’s value rises.2 Taylor rule: it=π t+r¿

t+aπ (π t−π¿t )+ay ( y t− y¿

t ), where it is the nominal federal funds rate, π t is the inflation

rate, r¿t is the real federal funds rate, π¿

t is the target inflation rate, y t is the log of real output, y¿t is the log of

Page 10: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -9-

is a monetary-policy rule that stipulates how much the Federal Reserve should adjust the nominal

interest rate to stabilize the economy in the short-term and still maintain its long-term growth.

The Taylor-rule gap – the amount by which the Taylor rule policy setting exceeded the actual

federal funds rate – reached 200 basis points in the period 2003-2005. During this period, there

were times when the real federal funds rate was negative. As a result, other market interest rates,

being heavily influenced by the federal funds rate, were also being kept low. At that time, a

person could profit by borrowing at the low interest rate to buy a residential property and by

keeping it for a period of time; the property’s price would keep up with the inflation rate, which

was higher than the interest rate. The considerable lowering of short-term interest rates by the

Fed not only helped increase the total dollar amount in mortgages but also made Adjustable-rate

mortgages (ARMs) cheaper relative to 30-year fixed-rated mortgages. As a result, the share of

new ARMs more than doubled from 2001 to 2004. The increase in riskier investments made the

market more vulnerable to a shock. In addition, since the value of real estate property, a long-

lived asset, depends on the discounting of its future cash flows, the fall in interest rates in the

2000s made real estate prices “seem like bargains” (White, 2009, p. 119). As a result, demand

for and prices of existing houses increased, and there was a surge in construction of new housing

on undeveloped land. A housing bubble had been formed.

Recently, Shiller (2005), among many scholars, has drawn on the study of human

psychology to explain the causes of the housing bubble. Shiller emphasized irrational exuberance

as the main culprit. Irrational exuberance is defined as a heightened state of speculative fervor. In

the case of the housing market, investors were confident that house prices would keep rising (or

at least could not drop) because land is limited. This belief drove prices up to levels way beyond

the underlying value that could not be explained by fundamentals.

potential output, and in most cases, aπ=a y=0.5 .

Page 11: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -10-

According to Shiller, the housing bubble started with a sharp increase in house prices,

accompanied by great public excitement and a decline in credit underwriting standards. Seeing

the new opportunity, people wanted to participate in the market. They talked about these price

increases with their friends and their relatives. Shortly after that, the media featured stories of

people getting rich, causing more enthusiasm among the general public. As more people were

willing to participate in the housing market because of the herd mentality, prices were elevated

further. The increase in prices again attracted more and more people. As a result, house prices

were pushed up far above intrinsic values. A bubble had been formed.

Shiller’s argument is based on a fundamental theory in psychology, the conformity

theory. It suggests that people tend to change their opinions and perceptions in ways that are

consistent with group norms. They will be inclined to follow and mimic what others are saying

or doing. According to Deutsch and Gerard (1955), there are two main reasons for this human

behavior: informational influence and normative influence. Informational influence suggests

people conform because they want to make sound judgments, and they assume that when the

majority agree on something, the majority must be right. This happens when a person lacks

knowledge or is in an unclear situation and has to look to the group for guidance. The fact that

people usually take the judgments of others into consideration when making their own

conclusion is not surprising because since birth, they have learnt that “the perceptions and

judgments of others are frequently reliable sources of evidence about reality” (Deutsch and

Gerard, p. 635). On the other hand, normative influence leads people to conform because they

are afraid of the negative consequences of appearing deviant. Schachter (1951) pointed out that

individuals who deviate from group norms are usually disliked and rejected by others. Since it is

Page 12: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -11-

human nature to be liked and to want to be accepted by others, people will change their behavior

and opinion in order to fit in with the group.

In addition, there is another concept in psychology that needs a closer look, group

polarization. Group polarization refers to the tendency for groups through group discussion to

make decisions that are more extreme than initial tendencies (Moscovici & Zavalloni, 1969).

Therefore, if in the beginning the majority of group members lean toward a risky position on an

issue, the group’s position becomes even riskier after group discussion. It should also be noted

that the judgments expressed by the group consensus will usually be adopted by group members

as their personal opinions.

Finally, confirmation bias, a psychological tendency to search for and interpret evidence

in a way that confirms one’s initial beliefs, might have influenced how people behave during the

bubble. It has been found that people normally seek information that they consider supportive of

an existing hypothesis and avoid information that is not supportive of that hypothesis because

human beings tend to overestimate their own judgments. In addition, even ambiguous evidence

will be interpreted in a way that backs up one’s existing belief. Confirmation bias is also found to

be pervasive and strong (Nickerson, 1998).

These ideas from the psychology discipline may explain why there was a sharp increase

in speculators in the housing market in the early 2000s. An average person with poor knowledge

of the financial industry would still be willing to be a part of the housing hype as s/he heard

stories of the housing market from the media and from other people. S/he would be well-

convinced that since everyone was talking about it, the housing market was a great place to

invest. Indeed, no one wanted to miss out on this opportunity. On top of that, further interactions

between people with the same interest in the housing market would strengthen their initial

Page 13: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -12-

interest in real estate. Furthermore, even when there were warnings of a housing bubble by

prominent economists, people tended to avoid these warnings and look for additional evidence

that supported their existing belief in the profitability of their investments in the housing market.

As shown, word of mouth might have helped inflate the housing bubble. However, word

of mouth alone could not be capable of creating such strong hype in the real estate market. There

must have been a greater channel that spread the real estate hype among large groups of people.

Indeed, Shiller (2005) asserted that in general, “significant market events generally occur only if

there is similar thinking among large groups of people, and the news media are essential vehicles

for the spread of ideas” (p. 85). Under the mechanism of informational influence as described

above, the media could have contributed to the house price increase by featuring stories of

people getting rich quickly from the real estate market. As a result, it is probably no coincidence

that the first speculative bubble ever recorded – the Dutch tulip mania of the 1630s3 – occurred

shortly after the world’s earliest printed newspapers appeared in Europe (Stephens, 1994).

Recognizing the influence of the media on the housing bubble, Shiller (2007) noted that,

...the feedback that creates bubbles has the primary effect of amplifying stories that

justify the bubble; I called them “new era stories.” The stories have to have a certain

vividness to them if they are to be contagious and to get people excited about making

risky investments. Contagion tends to work through word of mouth and through the news

media. It may take a direct price-to-price form, as price increases generate further price

increases (p. 9).

Agreeing with Shiller (2007), Soo (2013) created a sentiment index by studying news coverage

in 20 city markets covered by the Case-Shiller home price index. She found that sentiment has a 3 After tulips were brought into the Netherlands from Turkey, they became a favorite flower in the country. In addition, it took a long time to grow these tulips. As a result, they were highly sought after. Supply could not catch up with demand. As a result, speculators began to enter the market, which helped drive the prices up even further and created the tulip mania.

Page 14: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -13-

significant effect on housing prices. It can predict over 70 percent of the variation in national

house price growth.

Finally, a housing bubble can be understood graphically through a supply-demand model

that allows extrapolative expectations, expectations about the future values of something

extrapolated from its observed past values, as shown in Figure 2.

Figure 2. Supply-Demand Bubble Model

Initially, the market is in equilibrium at point A. Suppose there is a shock in the housing

market, causing demand to shift from D0 to D1. At the original price P0, consumers would now

like to buy Q1 instead of Q0 while suppliers still find it profitable to supply only Q0. This creates

Page 15: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -14-

a situation of excess demand from Q1 to Q0. In the basic supply-demand model, the excess

demand will lead to a price increase to P1 and, as a result, quantity supplied will increase while

quantity demanded will decrease; the new equilibrium would be at point B. However, in the

bubble model, there are extrapolative price expectations. Hence, the rising price from P0 to P1

will shift the demand curve to D2 and increase quantity demanded to Q2. Again, the higher

demand causes a shortage from B’ to B, which is greater than the initial shortage of Q1 – Q0. As

can be expected, instead of equilibrating the market, the increase in price drives it further away

from equilibrium. The larger shortage will put an upward pressure on price, causing it to rise to

P2. If expectations are extrapolative, demand will shift to D3, causing an ever greater shortage

from C’ to C. As has been shown, with extrapolative expectations, the more the price rises, the

more people want to buy and therefore the price and demand keep rising. Interestingly, if we

connect the quantity demanded at each price level, we will have a demand curve that is upward

sloping. This is a peculiar feature of the bubble model (Colander, 2009).

III. Data and Method

Page 16: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -15-

In this research, I am going to not only test whether some of the variables suggested by

previous researchers actually contributed to the housing bubble but also quantify the irrational

exuberance in the market.

First, before getting to the econometric model, I would like to define a proxy for the

housing bubble. A consensus has not been reached on the best method to estimate a housing

bubble. Many previous researchers used the ratio approach and some used the user cost

approach4. Among these, the ratio approach is the most commonly used method to study a

housing bubble. It generally includes two different ratios, price to rent ratio and price to income

ratio (Chen, 2012, p. 20).

In finance, the Price - Earnings ratio (P/E ratio) is an important metric when it comes to

valuing stocks. Generally speaking, a high P/E ratio reflects the expectation of higher growth in

the future. In addition, the higher the P/E ratio, the more overpriced the market. A review of the

literature suggests researchers have agreed that there is a similar P/E ratio for the housing

market, with “P” being a house’s current market value and “E” being the value at which it could

be leased. To be more specific, the earning of a house, E, is often calculated as the total values of

all the expected future rents discounted back to the present. Therefore, the house price-to-rent

ratio is a metric that reflects the relative cost of owning versus renting. Economic theory suggests

that if house prices rise way beyond rents, potential homebuyers will choose to rent, therefore

reducing the demand for houses. As a result, house prices will be brought down in line with

rents.

The ratio is considered to be an important measure of a potential deviation of housing

prices from their fundamental values. The common argument in favor of this ratio is that if the

4 The user cost approach is a model that is built upon the proposition that the cost of renting should be equivalent to the all-in risk-adjusted cost of homeownership.

Page 17: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -16-

price-to-rent ratio remains high for a long period of time, it must be because house prices are

being sustained by unrealistic expectations of future gains rather than being supported by

fundamental rental value. This signals a potential bubble. This measure has been used by many

researchers to study house price bubbles (Kivedal, 2013; Leamer, 2002; Krainer & Wei, 2004;

McCarthy & Peach, 2005). For example, Leamer (2002) recommended using the housing P/E

ratio to proxy a bubble. If the P/E increases dramatically, there is a chance of a bubble in the

market. He found that P/Es in the San Francisco Bay Area rose faster relative to those in the Los

Angeles metro area during the period 1991-2002. This signaled a bubble in San Francisco

compared to Los Angeles. Similarly, Krainer and Wei (2004), using data from the Office of

Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) and the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, found

that in the early 2000s, house prices were departing from fundamentals, which are implied rental

values. However, they also warned that price-rent ratio can rise without signaling a bubble.

In this research, I also use the P/E ratio to proxy a housing bubble. However, it is a

daunting task to measure the prices and earnings of houses in the market on a national level, and

I could not find such data. Therefore, instead I have decided to use the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S.

National Home Price Index available from the S&P Dow Jones Indices website for ‘P’ and the

Owners’ Equivalent Rent of Residences Index (OERI) from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

for ‘E’. The S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index, which covers nine major census

divisions, measures changes in the prices of single-family, detached residences by comparing the

sale prices of the same properties over time. It is a widely used barometer of the U.S. housing

market. OER is the implicit rent that owner occupants would have to pay if they were renting

their houses. For example, an OER index of 200 (relative to a base year value of 100 in 1982)

indicates that Owners’ Equivalent rents had risen 100 percent since 1982. This P/E ratio is

Page 18: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -17-

similar to what Krainer and Wei (2004) proposed in their study. However, I have decided to use

the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index instead of the OFHEO national house

price index as suggested by Krainer and Wei because the OFHEO data are only collected from

transactions or appraisals associated with mortgages securitized by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac,

which are mostly prime loans. On the other hand, the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home

Price Index is computed using all available arm’s length transactions, including those financed

with other types of mortgages, such as Alt-A and subprime (Goetzmann et al., 2012, p. 6). As a

result, the S&P/Case-Shiller Index is more comprehensive and relevant to the purpose of this

study.

I then created a Housing Bubble Index by taking a ratio of those two indices. A value of 1

means the housing market is priced appropriately. Assuming that the real estate market is

forward looking, home price is essentially the present value of future rent payments. Hence, it is

expected that an appropriately priced market will result in a HBI value of 1. The farther the index

deviates from 1, the higher the chance there is a housing bubble. This happens when house prices

rise at a higher rate than rental values. A plot of the housing bubble index is presented below.

Figure 3. Housing Bubble Index

Page 19: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -18-

1986

-01-01

1987

-04-01

1988

-07-01

1989

-10-01

1991

-01-01

1992

-04-01

1993

-07-01

1994

-10-01

1996

-01-01

1997

-04-01

1998

-07-01

1999

-10-01

2001

-01-01

2002

-04-01

2003

-07-01

2004

-10-01

2006

-01-01

2007

-04-01

2008

-07-01

2009

-10-01

2011

-01-01

2012

-04-01

2013

-07-01

00.20.40.60.8

11.21.41.61.8

Housing Bubble Index (1986 - 2014)

Hou

sing

Bub

ble

Inde

x

Source: S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index and Owners’ Equivalent Rent

of Residences Index.

As can be seen in figure 3, the Housing Bubble Index seems to do a reasonable job of

measuring bubbles in the real estate market. It captures a small bubble in the late 1980s that,

according to Shiller (2005), reflects regional bubbles on the West Coast and the East Coast. In

addition, it shows the great boom and bust in the real estate market in the 2000s.

Studying the factors that led to the housing bubble, Kohn and Bryant (2011) found that

personal income was one of the significant variables in their models. Therefore, I decide to

include a variable for real disposable income per capita as a measure of housing affordability. I

hypothesize that higher real disposable income per capita will result in a higher chance that a

bubble will happen because people will be confident to spend more during good times. Data for

real disposable income per capita are obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’

database.

Page 20: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -19-

In addition, a variable that tracks the amount of government housing subsidies is included

in order to account for the various changes in governmental regulations that aimed at increasing

homeownership, especially the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977 and the affordable-

housing mission of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Since there were so many changes in the

regulatory framework, the use of dummy variables to test for structural breaks is not efficient.

On the other hand, as suggested by the literature, these regulations aimed to increase

homeownership by allowing low-income and bad-credit borrowers to take out more affordable

home mortgages. Similary, housing subsidies have been granted to increase the accessibility to

public housing, especially for low-income households. As a result, the amount of government

housing subsidies might be a good and practical proxy for these regulatory changes. It is

assumed that whenever the Democratic Party is in power, the amount of government subsidies

for low-income households tend to increase and more regulation is expected. On the other hand,

when the Republican Party is in power, the government will likely cut back on government

subsidies and lax regulation is expected. This implies that there might be a positive correlation

between government housing subsidies and change in the regulatory framework. Consequently,

housing subsides is used to proxy for regulatory changes.

Like many other researchers, I believe that interest rates played an important role in

fueling the housing bubble. However, in my model, I will not include the federal funds rate as

suggested by White (2009). Since the federal funds rate is the interest rate banks charge each

other on interbank loans, ordinary market participants will not be able to borrow at that rate.

Therefore, it might not be a good proxy for the housing bubble. Instead, I am going to use the

spread between the rate on conventional, conforming 30-year fixed-rate mortgages and the rate

on treasury-indexed 1-year adjustable rate mortgages. The lower the spread, the more profitable

Page 21: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -20-

for investors to invest in the short term rather than in the long term, thereby increasing the

amount of speculation in the real estate market. Data for these interest rates are taken from

Freddie Mac.

Moreover, in an attempt to account for the psychological theory of the crowd, household

home mortgages liability (measured as a flow) will be included in the model. Initially, I would

have liked to have a variable that tracks the number of investors in the real estate market.

However, such data cannot be found. Therefore, the flow of the household home mortgages

liability will be used as a replacement. A plot of the household home mortgages liability is

included below.

Figure 4. Flow of the household home mortgages liability.

Jan-86

May-87

Sep-88

Jan-90

May-91

Sep-92

Jan-94

May-95

Sep-96

Jan-98

May-99

Sep-00

Jan-02

May-03

Sep-04

Jan-06

May-07

Sep-08

Jan-10

May-11

Sep-12

Jan-14

-400000

-200000

0

200000

400000

600000

800000

1000000

1200000

1400000

Flow of the household home mortgages li-ability (1986 - 2014)

Flow

of

hous

ehol

d ho

me

mor

tage

s lia

bil-

ity (

Mill

ions

of

Dol

lars

)

Source: Federal Reserve Flow of Funds Z1 release.

Page 22: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -21-

As can be seen from the plot, this series has a constantly rising trend through 2006,

suggesting rising household liabilities as they keep taking out more and more home loans. The

gradual increase from 1997 to 2006 might be explained by the herd behavior. People took out

more home loans to invest in the real estate market as they saw other people profiting from

housing. After the housing collapse and the financial crisis, the numbers fell quickly to zero or

even negative as people were scared and began paying off their debts.

Finally, I will test whether the media helped fuel the housing bubble by including a

variable that tracks the change in total articles from one year to another on the housing market. I

will follow the method used by Glynn, Huge, and Hoffman (2008). In their research, the authors

studied the impact of the media on the housing bubble by conducting a newspaper content

analysis on articles that were focused on the real estate market. They searched for articles

appearing in the New York Times, the Minneapolis Star Tribune, the Houston Chronicle, and the

San Francisco Chronicle because these are the representative newspapers for the four different

regions in the US – the Northeast, the Midwest, the South, and the West respectively. They

obtained desired articles by using the following search string on the Lexis-Nexis database:

((real estate OR housing w/5 bubble OR dream OR speculat!) OR (home sales OR

housing starts w/5 increas!) OR (housing w/5 sure bet) OR (hous! prices w/ rise OR

rising) OR (housing OR real estate w/ 5 good time OR good buy OR expan!) OR

(mortgage w/5 innovation) OR (reduce! w/5 down payment) OR (mortgage w/5 interest

only OR negative amortization OR no-doc OR predatory OR hybrid OR 2/28) OR

(Subprime w/ 5 increase OR popular!) OR (housing OR real estate OR mortgage w/5

crash! OR bust OR burst! OR freez! OR slump! OR slowdown OR meltdown OR

collaps! OR fall OR falling OR default OR tight! OR delinquent OR negative equity OR

Page 23: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -22-

crunch) OR (foreclosure w/5 increas! OR high!) OR (housing starts OR home sales OR

real estate sales w/5 decreas! OR fewer) OR (bankrupt! OR unemployed w/5 home

builder OR mortgage lender OR mortgage broker)) (p. 10).

Where:

OR means either term can be present

w/5 means terms must be within five words of each other. For example, housing w/5

bubble requires housing to occur within five words of bubble

! returns variations of a term. For example, speculat! means the search will return all

documents containing the following words: speculated, speculating, speculation, etc.

According to the authors, this search term string “was deemed suitable for appropriate

selection of a sample”, with the precision rate above or close to 80% (Glynn et al., p. 10). In this

paper, I will make some minor modifications to their method. First, instead of conducting a

newspaper content analysis5, I will simply count the total number of articles that the search

engine returns. Second, I will conduct a comprehensive study by looking at all the U.S.

newspapers instead of only the four as mentioned by the authors. Finally, I will divide their

search string into two separate parts and make 2 different variables: one that might inflate the

bubble and one that might deflate the bubble. I will then calculate the ratio between the two

variables. Here is the search string for the “inflation” variable:

((real estate OR housing w/5 bubble OR dream OR speculat!) OR (home sales OR

housing starts w/5 increas!) OR (housing w/5 sure bet) OR (hous! prices w/ rise OR

5 Newspaper content analysis is technique aimed at determining the meaning and purpose of newspaper articles by studying and evaluating the details and implications of the content in each article.

Page 24: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -23-

rising) OR (housing OR real estate w/ 5 good time OR good buy OR expan!)OR

(mortgage w/5 innovation) OR (reduce! w/5 down payment) OR (mortgage w/5 interest

only OR negative amortization OR no-doc OR predatory OR hybrid OR 2/28)OR

(Subprime w/5 increase OR popular!)).

Below is the search string for the “deflation” variable:

((housing OR real estate OR mortgage w/5 crash! OR bust OR burst! OR freez! OR

slump! OR slowdown OR meltdown OR collaps! OR fall OR falling OR default OR

tight! OR delinquent OR negative equity OR crunch) OR (foreclosure w/5 increas! OR

high!) OR (housing starts OR home sales OR real estate sales w/5 decreas! OR fewer)

OR (bankrupt! OR unemployed w/5 home builder OR mortgage lender OR mortgage

broker)).

An increasing inflate/deflate ratio means that there is more news that favors the market than that

which hinders the market, and therefore there is a higher chance of the existence of a bubble.

The sample period for the regression analysis is 1986-I to 2014-III. All the data used are

quarterly data.

Page 25: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -24-

IV. Model

My model is as follows:

HBI t=α 0+∑i=0

k

α 1, i Income t−k+∑i=0

k

α 2 ,i Subsidy t−k+∑i=0

k

α3 ,i Mortgagest−k+∑i=0

k

α 4 , i Interestt−k+∑i=0

k

α 5 ,i Mediat−k+∑i=1

k

α 6 ,i HBI t−k+ε 1t .

(1)

Mediat=β0+∑i=0

k

β1, i HBI t−k+∑i=0

k

β2 ,iConsumer t−k+ε2 t . (2)

with HBI t and Mediat being the endogenous variables and the rest of the variables being

exogenous variables.

α 0 and β0 are intercept terms.

ε 1t and ε 2t are error terms.

HBI t is the value of the housing bubble index at time t .

Incomet is the level of real disposable income per person at time t .

Subsidyt is the amount of housing subsidies given by the government at time t .

Mortgagest is the amount of household home mortgages liability at time t .

Interest t is the difference between the rate on 30-year fixed-rate conventional

mortgages and the rate on treasury-indexed 1-year adjustable rate mortgages at time t .

Mediat is the inflate/deflate ratio mentioned above at time t .

Consumert is the consumer sentiment index

Kohn and Bryant (2011) conducted an econometric analysis using structural equation

modeling (SEM) to determine the factors that caused the housing bubble in the 2000s. Using

Page 26: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -25-

median asking price as a proxy for the house price boom, they found that for the pre-bubble

period, only personal income and vacancy rates were statistically significant. However, for the

bubble period from 1997 to 2007, CPI, housing inventory, population, vacancy rates, and median

asking rents were significant. In addition, the R2s in both periods were high, at or above .8. In

their research, Kohn and Bryant decided to use the SEM method to address the problems with

multicollinearity found in their earlier work.

Different from Kohn and Bryant, in my study, I propose a simultaneous-equation model

because I believe there is a bi-directional causality between HBI t and Mediat. This means the

media will help fuel the bubble, and the increase in housing prices will, in turn, lead to more

articles talking about the housing market. If the method of Ordinary Least Square (OLS) is

applied to each equation separately, disregarding the other equation in the system, the

coefficients estimated will be biased and inconsistent. A proof of why it is not appropriate to

apply the OLS regression to each equation separated is included in Appendix B.

Therefore, I will use the method of two-stage least squares (2SLS) developed by Henri

Theil (1953) and Robert Basmann (1957) to estimate the coefficients of all independent variables

in the system. The 2SLS method requires that both equations be identified. If HBI t is the only

independent variable in equation (2), this equation is under-identified. As a result, the consumer

sentiment index, a measure of consumers’ attitudes towards the current state of the economy, is

added as one of the explanatory variables in the second equation. It is believed that a high

consumer confidence will help inflate the media hype. Data for the consumer sentiment index is

obtained from the University of Michigan Consumer Sentiment Index from the Federal Reserve

Bank of St. Louis.

Page 27: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -26-

Having ensured that the system of regression equations is identified, I will now be able to

conduct a 2SLS regression. To apply this method, I will first substitute (2) into (1) and move

both the HBI t terms to the left hand side to obtain a reduced-form equation where only

exogenous or predetermined variables appear on the right hand side and then regress HBI t on all

the predetermined variables in the whole system. Doing so will help rid the model of the possible

correlation between HBI t and ε 2t . The new equation is of the form:

HBI t=П0+П 1 Income t+П2 Subsidyt +П3 Mortgages t+П4 Interestt +П5Consumer t+ε3 ,t .

(3)

Where ε 3 ,t is the usual OLS residual. Again, I have simplified the model by excluding all the lag

terms. From the above equation (3), I will get

HBI t=П0+ П1 Income t+П 2 Subsidyt +П 3 Mortgages t+ П4 Interest t + П5Consumer t .

(3’)

by using Stata to run an OLS regression. Similarly, after substituting (1) into (2) and following

the steps outlined above, I get

Mediat=П0+П 1 Income t+П2 Subsidyt +П3 Mortgages t+П4 Intere st t+П5 Consumert +ε 4 ,t .

(4)

Running the OLS regression will give

Mediat=П0+ П 1 Income t+П2 Subsidyt + П3 Mortgages t+П4 Interest t +П5Consumer t .

(4’)

From here, I will estimate the second equation (2) by replacing the endogenous variable

HBI tby HBI t. I will then run an OLS regression on this modified equation to get an estimation of

Mediat. Now it is appropriate to apply OLS because HBI t is uncorrelated with the new error term

Page 28: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -27-

as the sample size gets larger. Similarly, I will estimate the first equation (1) by replacing the

endogenous variable Mediat by Mediat and run an OLS regression to get an estimation of HBI t.

Finally, the following ad hoc estimation of lagged variables test is used to determine how

far back the lag variables should be included in the model:

1. Run an OLS regression with no lag variables and record the adjusted R squared.

2. Take a variable that is believed to have a lag effect, say Incomet. Introduce the 1-

period lag, Incomet−1, into the model.

3. Run the OLS regression again with the new variable and record the new adjusted R

squared.

4. If the adjusted R squared increases and the regression coefficients of the lagged

variables are statistically significant, then keep the new variable in the model.

Otherwise, remove it from the model.

5. If the new lag variable is believed to belong to the model, introduce the 2-period lag,

Incomet−1 in this case, into the model and repeat steps 3-5.

6. If the new lag variable is removed, move on to a different variable and repeat steps 2-

5.

Finally, for this econometric model, I predict that a higher personal income per capita

will result in a higher chance that a bubble will happen because people will be confident to spend

more in good times (positive coefficient). Second, as suggested by previous researchers, the

media also help fuel the housing bubble. Therefore, the coefficients on Media are expected to be

positive. Third, the lower the spread between the rate on 30-year fixed-rate conventional

mortgages and the rate on treasury-indexed 1-year adjustable rate mortgages, the higher the value

Page 29: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -28-

of the housing bubble index because investors are then encouraged to invest in the short term,

thus increasing speculation in the market. This implies a negative coefficient on Interest t. Fourth,

the coefficients on Subsidy are expected to be positive since a larger amount of federal housing

subsidies granted will lead to a higher demand for housing among low-income households, thus

a higher demand in general. Fifth, a higher amount of household home mortgages liability poses

higher risks to the market. As people take out more and more loans, they will also purchase more

houses. As explained in chapter 2, because of the herd mentality, more people will be induced to

be a part of the housing hype. As a result, house prices rise significantly, increasing the chance

that a bubble exists (positive coefficient). Sixth, the lagged observations of the dependent

variable are included to represent the dynamic nature of the model. They are expected to have

positive coefficients because the literature suggests that the housing bubble has a strong

momentum built in itself, which reinforces itself through a virtuous cycle. Finally, in the second

equation, the higher the value of the housing bubble index, the higher the inflate/deflate ratio

(positive coefficient). Moreover, the higher the consumer sentiment index, the larger the media

hype. As a result, the expected coefficient of Consumert is positive.

The expected signs for the first equation are summarized in the following table:

Table 1. Expected signs

Variables Expected Signs

Incomet +

Mortgagest +

Subsidyt _

Page 30: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -29-

Mediat +

Interest t _

HBI t −i +

V. Results

First, the ad hoc estimation of lagged variables test was used. It was found that HBI t−1,

which is the 1-period lag of the dependent variable, was the only significant lagged variable in

the model.

Second, it is suggested by the literature that the majority of time series data have a

problem of spurious correlation problem, in which there is a strong relationship between two or

more variables even though it is not caused by a real causal relationship. The reason is that time

series data typically increase over time. A spurious regression, in which the dependent variable

and one or more independent variables are spuriously correlated, will tend to inflate the t-scores

and the overall fit of the model. The most probable cause of spurious correlation is non-

stationary time series. Therefore, before running the regression, I ran an Augmented Dickey-

Fuller Test to determine if there were any non-stationary variables in the model. The null

hypothesis was that the variable considered had a unit root, meaning the variable was non-

stationary. It turned out that all but Mediat and Interest t are non-stationary. This signaled a

problem of spurious correlation.

Page 31: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -30-

Table 2. Augmented Dickey-Fuller test results

Variables t score

Incomet -0.724

Mortgagest -1.718

Subsidyt -0.884

Mediat -4.249

Interest t -3.527

HBI t -0.792

Consumert -2.282

The traditional approach to address the nonstationarity problem is to take the first differences

of every variable and use them in place of the original variable in the equation. For example,

HBI t would be replaced by HBI t−HBI t−1. However, “using first differences tends to throw away

information that economic theory can provide in the form of equilibrium relationships between

the variables when they are expressed in their original units” (Studenmunt and Cassidy, 2011, p.

Page 32: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -31-

424). As a result, the author suggests not using first differences until the model has been tested

for cointegration. A set of variables is said to be cointegrated if there is a long-run equilibrium

relationship between the variables. In addition, if the set of variables is cointegrated, it is possible

that linear combinations of non-stationary variables can actually be stationary. As a result, after

figuring out that there was a problem of nonstationarity, I decided to test the model for

cointegration. It was found that the nonstationary variables were cointegrated as can be seen in

Table 3. Therefore, the equation can be estimated in its original units.

Table 3. Augmented Dickey-Fuller test of residuals

Variables t score

Residuals (1st equation) -8.198***

Residuals (2nd equation) -5.326***

*** = 0.01 significance level

I then ran a 2-stage least squares regression using the procedure outlined above. Results for the

first equation are included in Table 4.

Page 33: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -32-

Table 4. 2SLS OLS Regression Results for Equation 1.

Dependent variable: Housing Bubble Index (HBI)

Number of observations 115

R-squared 0.9896

Adjusted R-squared 0.9890

Variable Coefficient t score

Incomet 2.71e-06 1.75*

Mortgagest -2.51e-08 -0.71

Subsidyt -1.65e-06 -2.34**

Mediat .1085954 1.9*

Interest t -.0043091 -0.62

HBI t−1 .9535441 31.78***

* = 0.10 significance level

Page 34: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -33-

** = 0.05 significance level

*** = 0.01 significance level

Results for the second equation are summarized in Table 5.

Table 5. 2SLS OLS Regression Results for Equation 2.

Dependent variable: Media

Number of observations 115

R-squared 0.2581

Adjusted R-squared 0.2448

Variable Coefficient t score

HBI t .659465 4.41***

Consumert .0109252 5.25***

Running the Breusch-Godfrey LM test for autocorrelation for both equations gave:

Table 6. Breusch-Godfrey test results

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

lags(p) | chi2 df Prob > chi2

-------------+-------------------------------------------------------------

4 | 68.548 4 0.0000

Page 35: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -34-

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4 | 44.625 4 0.0000

H0: no serial correlation

This means both of the equations have autocorrelation problems, which makes OLS not

the best linear unbiased estimator method. Hence, the Newey West Estimator, a method of

correcting serial correlation in the error terms, is used to solve this problem. The Newey West

approach, however, requires stationary variables. Yet, the literature does not support or oppose

the use of Newey West for cointegrated time series data. As a result, I conducted two regression

analyses, one with Newey West approach that used original units and one with first differences.

Results for the Newey West analysis are given in Tables 7 and 8.

Page 36: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -35-

Table 7. 2SLS Newey West Regression Results for Equation 1.

Dependent variable: Housing Bubble Index (HBI)

Number of observations 115

R-squared 0.9896

Adjusted R-squared 0.9890

Variable Coefficient t score

Incomet 2.71e-06 1.60

Mortgagest -2.51e-08 -0.68

Subsidyt -1.65e-06 -2.36**

Mediat .1085954 1.77*

Interest t -.0043091 -0.63

HBI t−1 .9535441 25.15***

Page 37: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -36-

Table 8. 2SLS Newey West Regression Results for Equation 2.

Dependent variable: Media

Number of observations 115

R-squared 0.2581

Adjusted R-squared 0.2448

Variable Coefficient t score

HBI t .659465 1.35

Consumert .0109252 4.56***

In order to make it easier to understand the magnitude of these coefficients, I have

calculated the mean value of the change of the housing bubble index from one quarter to the next

quarter, which is 0.0018 unit.

As can be seen from Table 4 and Table 7, the t values of all the variables in the model

decreased. This was expected because the autocorrelation problem tends to inflate the t values.

Three of the variables in my model were significant. The coefficient of Mediat suggested that a

one-unit increase in the inflate/deflate ratio would cause the HBI index to rise by .1085954 unit.

Page 38: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -37-

As the literature suggests, human beings tend to follow the majority opinion. Therefore, when

there are more articles that favor the housing market than those that oppose it, more people are

willing to participate in the market. The increase in demand will then help increase home prices

further. In addition, Subsidyt was significant and had the expected sign. The most interesting

result, however, was that the lagged dependent variable, HBI t−1 was statistically significant with

a very high t-score. This implied that the housing bubble index had a strong momentum from one

period to the next.

In sum, the model did a fairly good job in explaining the housing bubble. An adjusted R-

squared of 0.99 suggested 99% of the change in the housing bubble index was explained by the

variables in the model. In addition, the Ramsey RESET test showed that there were no omitted

variables. It is also interesting to note that HBI t−1 was statistically significant at a very high

level, indicating the virtuous cycle built in a housing bubble. This implied that when there is a

sign of a housing bubble, policy makers should act quickly to prevent the bubble from

developing through its own feedback loop. However, these findings must be taken with caution

because it is still not known whether the Newey West Estimator method can be applied to

cointegrated time series data.

As mentioned above, I also ran a 2SLS OLS regression analysis using first differences.

Results for this analysis are presented in Table 9 and Table 10.

Page 39: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -38-

Table 9. 2SLS OLS Regression Results using first differences – Equation 1.

Dependent variable: Housing Bubble Index (HBI)

Number of observations 114

R-squared 0.4748

Adjusted R-squared 0.4453

Variable Coefficient t score

Incomet .000017 1.44

Mortgagest -8.89e-08 -1.06

Subsidyt 6.06e-06 0.418

Mediat .2992383 1.54

Interest t -.0335719 -1.46

HBI t−1 .8955135 4.43***

Page 40: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -39-

Table 10. 2SLS OLS Regression Results using first differences – Equation 2.

Dependent variable: Media

Number of observations 114

R-squared 0.0010

Adjusted R-squared -0.0170

Variable Coefficient t score

Consumert .0012041 0.29

HBI t .2128104 0.16

As expected, using differences lowered the t-statistics of all the variables in the model. In

addition, the adjusted R-squared also diminished. It might be because “using first differences

tends to throw away information that economic theory can provide in the form of equilibrium

relationships between the variables when they are expressed in their original units” (Studenmunt

and Cassidy, 2011, p. 424). As can be seen from Table 9, the lagged dependent variable was the

only significant variable in the model.

Page 41: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -40-

VI. Limitations

First, since this research is conducted using data from 1986 to 2014, it cannot account for

all kinds of government legislation, which have contributed to the weakening of lending

standards. Two of the most important ones are the Depository Institutions Deregulation and

Monetary Control Act in 1980 and the Garn-St. Germain Depository Institution Act in 1982. As

a result, the findings of this study might not reflect the true role of the government in creating the

housing bubble. A study that goes back further in time is required to properly understand the

impacts of government regulations/deregulations on the housing bubble.

Second, there is a concern with the way the Owners’ Equivalent Rent of residences is

computed, which affects the validity of my housing bubble index. Drake and Silver (2014)

pointed out in their article that the Bureau of Labor Statistics determines the Owners’ Equivalent

Rent by asking ordinary American homeowners the following question: “If someone were to rent

your home today, how much do you think it would rent for monthly, unfurnished, and without

utilities?” They believe this question is imprecise and subjective. Someone without proper

knowledge of economics would not know the answer to this question and would typically give

an estimation that is highly questionable. Therefore, future researchers should look for a more

reliable rent index or better still, find the actual levels of house prices and rents instead of using

indexes.

Page 42: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -41-

Third, the search string used to find the inflate/deflate ratio is not perfect. Although

Glynn et al. (2008) indicates that it has a precision rate at above or close to 80 percent,

sometimes the search returns results that should belong to the inflate variable instead of deflate

variable or vice versa. Future researchers should try to find a better mechanism to quantify the

influence of the media on the housing bubble.

Fourth, there might be a misspecification problem. As noted in Section III, some of the

variables used in the model might not be the best proxies. For example, housing subsidies are

used as a proxy for regulatory changes assuming that there is an indirect relationship, operating

through the political framework, between housing subsidies and changes in regulation. Hence,

future research should attempt to test the robustness of this study by using better proxies for

many of the variables in this paper and comparing the results.

Finally, there are some econometrics problems that have not been satisfactorily addressed

in the study. The issues with serial autocorrelation and nonstationarity are two of those. As a

result, future researchers should attempt to find better methods to address these issues.

Page 43: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -42-

VII. Policy Implications

As can be seen from Section V, the lagged variable HBI t−1 is statistically significant with

a relatively high coefficient, indicating the virtuous cycle inherent in a housing bubble. As a

result, in the presence of an increase in the housing bubble index, policy makers should make

smart decisions to impose preemptive countercyclical policies before the housing bubble gets

worse. It is recommended that when the bubble is still in its early stages, government should

impose more regulations. In addition, since the interest rates might have an impact on the media

coverage, which directly influence the housing bubble, the Fed should also consider raising

interest rates in a timely manner to help deal with the bubble.

Page 44: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -43-

Appendix A

In the 1970s, most states still had usury laws from earlier years, which placed limits on

the interest rates banks could offer on deposits. This became a constraint as inflation rose. In

1978, the Supreme Court made a decision that the usury laws of a bank’s home state, instead of

the borrower’s home state, applied to bank lending across states. This provided an incentive for

banks to relocate to states that were less regulated to utilize the favorable interest rate regulations

in their new home state across their operations around the country. As a consequence, some

states, such as South Dakota and Delaware, eliminated their usury ceilings to attract investors.

The result was that even though usury laws were still effective in nearly every other state, banks

were able to charge any interest rate they wanted nationwide. Moreover, in the 1970s, inflation

caused market interest rates to rise beyond the ceilings mandated by Regulation Q6. As a result,

investors had to look for alternatives to traditional deposit accounts. Money market mutual

funds, which had no restrictions on rates of return, were born. Realizing the higher potential

profits, investors began to relocate their investments from regulated accounts in depositary

institutions to these mutual funds. In 1980, in an attempt to help banks and savings and loans

compete with money market mutual funds, Congress passed the Depository Institutions

Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980. It allowed depository institutions to charge

rates comparable to those in the market. Furthermore, in 1982, the Garn-St. Germain Act of 1982

6 Regulation Q is a Federal Reserve Board regulation that imposed interest rate ceilings on bank deposits.

Page 45: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -44-

was introduced. It allowed thrifts to engage in commercial loans up to 10 percent of assets. It

also gave thrifts powers to act more like a bank, not just a specialized mortgage lending

institution (Sherman, 2009).

The financial deregulation of the 1980s caused the competition for deposits to go out of

control. Many institutions offered large brokered deposits at above-market rates to attract capital.

The savings and loans industry saw a rapid expansion with a great inflow of deposits. With the

expanded powers of thrifts, savings and loan associations started to invest in condominiums and

other commercial real estate. This meant that the investment portfolios of these associations

consisted of a greater proportion of higher-risk loans and a smaller proportion of traditional

home mortgage loans. The increase in investments in the real estate market caused house prices

to increase. The boom in real estate finally burst in the mid-1980s (Sherman, 2009).

The financial deregulation continued after the burst of the housing boom.7 In 1986, the Federal

Reserve reinterpreted the Glass-Steagall restrictions, which had authorized banks to obtain up to

5 percent of gross revenues in their investment banking business. In 1996, the Federal Reserve

raised the limit further to 25 percent, effectively abolishing the Glass-Steagall Act. In addition,

the banking industry also moved towards greater consolidation. The Riegl-Neal Interstate

Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 eliminated restrictions on interstate banking and

branching. Later, in 1999, the passage of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act removed regulations that

prevented the merger of banks, stock brokerage companies, and insurance companies. As a

result, mega-banks were able to form. It is argued that the consolidation in banking made it

harder for regulators to not only oversee different business lines of the same institution but also

keep pace with the innovations in financial markets. The growth of new derivatives instruments8

7 This refers to the housing boom in the 1980s (Shiller, 2008).8 A derivative is a contract that derives its value from the price of an underlying asset.

Page 46: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -45-

posed problems for regulators. Derivatives trading increased from a total outstanding nominal

value of $106 trillion in 2001 to $531 trillion in 2008 (Goodman, 2008). This rapid growth in

derivatives trading overwhelmed the legal infrastructure of the industry. Regulators could not

keep track of the actual contracts made by commercial banks and often had to rely on the self-

regulation of firms to avoid potential risks (Sherman, 2009).

Appendix B

To prove that it is not appropriate to apply the OLS method for each equation separately, I will

first simplify my model by discarding all the lag terms (The result would still hold for the

original model). Therefore, the simplified model is now:

HBI t=α 0+α1 Incomet+α2 Subsidy t+α 3 Mortgages t+α4 Interest t+α5 Mediat+ε1 t

Mediat=β0+ β1 HBI t+β2Consumer t+ε2 t

Then I will prove that HBI t and ε 2t in equation (4) are correlated.

First, notice that the classical linear regression model requires that E(ε1 t)=E(ε2 t)=0,

E(ε1 t2)=E(ε2 t

2)=σ2, E(ε1 t ε2 t)=0, and

cov (Income t , ε1 t)=cov (Subsidy t , ε1 t)=cov ( Mortgagest , ε1 t)=cov ( Interestt , ε 1t)=cov (Mediat , ε1 t)=0

where E( A) refers to the expected value of A.

Now I will substitute (4) into (3) to obtain

HBI t=α 0+α1 Incomet+α2 Subsidy t+α 3 Mortgages t+α4 Interestt+α5 ( β0+β1 HBI t+β2 Consumert+ε2 t )+ε1 t .

HBI t=α 0+α1 Incomet+α2 Subsidy t+α 3 Mortgages t+α4 Interestt+α5 β0+α 5 β1 HBI t+α5 β2Consumer t+α 5 ε2 t+ε 1t .

HBI t−α 5 β1 HBI t=α 0+α 1 Incomet +α 2 Subsidyt+α3 Mortgagest+α 4 Interest t+α 5 β0+α 5 β2 C onsumer t+α5 ε2 t+ε1 t .

(1−α5 β1 ) HBI t=α 0+α 1 Incomet +α 2 Subsidyt+α3 Mortgagest+α 4 Interest t+α 5 β0+α 5 β2 Consumert+α5 ε2 t+ε1 t .

Page 47: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -46-

Let 1−α5 β1=p, we have:

HBI t=α0

p+

α1

pIncomet +

α2

pSubsidyt+

α3

pMortgages t+

α 4

pInterest t+

α 5 β0

p+

α5 β2Consumert

p+

α 5 ε2 t

p+

ε1t

p.

In addition,

E ( HBI t )=α 0

p+

α1

pIncome t+

α2

pSubsidy t+

α3

pMortgages t+

α 4

pInterest t +

α5 β2 Consumert

p+

α 5 β0

p.

because E(ε1 t)=E(ε2 t)=0 and the expectation value of all the exogenous and constant terms do

not change.

Subtracting E(HBI t) from HBI t results in

HBI t−E ( HBI t ) = 1

1−α 5 β1 ε 1t +

α 51−α 5 β1

ε2t .

Moreover,

ε 2t−E(ε2 t)=ε2 t−0=ε2 t

Therefore,

cov ( HBI t , ε2 t )=E [ HBI t−E ( HBI t ) ][ε2 t−E (ε2 t )]

¿ E( 11−α5 β1

ε1 t ε2 t+α 5

1−α5 β1ε2 t

2)

¿ 11−α 5 β1

E ( ε1t ε2 t )+α 5

1−α5 β1E (ε2 t

2)

¿0+ α 51−α5 β1

σ2

¿ α 51−α 5 β1

σ 2 ,

which is different from zero. Hence, HBI t and ε 2t are correlated, violating the assumption of the

classical linear regression model.

Page 48: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -47-

References

Basmann, R.L. (1957). A generalized classical method of linear estimation of coefficients in a

structural equation. Econometrica. Vol. 25, 77-83

Bernanke, B.S. (2009). “Four questions about the financial crisis”. Speech at Morehouse

College, Atlanta, GA, March 14.

Case, K. E., & Shiller, R. J. (2003). Is there a bubble in the housing market?. Brookings Papers

on Economic Activity, 2003(2), 299-362.

Chen, D. R. (2012). An empirical analysis of house price bubble: a case study of Beijing housing

market (Doctoral dissertation, Lincoln University). Retrieved from

http://researcharchive.lincoln.ac.nz/bitstream/10182/5212/5/Chen_MCM.pdf

Colander, D. (2009). Economics (8th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

Deutsch, M. & Gerard, H. B. (1955). A study of normative and informational social influences

upon individualjudgment. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 55, 629-636.

Drake, C. & Silver, M. (2014, March 27). The absurd way the U.S. measures inflation: Your

rent. Fortune. Retrieved from http://fortune.com/2014/03/27/the-absurd-way-the-u-s-

measures-inflation-your-rent/

Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., & Newman, P. (Eds). (1987). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of

Economics. New York: Stockton Press.

Page 49: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -48-

Escobari, D., Damianov, D. S., & Bello, A. (2012). A time series test to identify housing

bubbles. Journal of Economics and Finance, 1-17.

Gerardi, K., Shapiro, A. H., & Willen, P. S. (2008). Subprime outcomes: Risky mortgages,

homeownership experiences, and foreclosures. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Working

paper 07-15.

Gjerstad, S. & Smith, V. (2013). Balance sheet crises: Causes, consequences and responses. Cato

J., 33, 437.

Glynn, C., Huge, M., & Hoffman, L. (2008). “Did the Media Help Inflate the Housing Bubble?

Media Coverage of Real Estate Markets in Times of Change.” Presented at the

Association for Education in Journalism & Mass Communication Annual Conference.

Goetzmann, W. N., Peng, L., & Yen, J. (2012). The subprime crisis and house price appreciation.

The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 44(1-2), 36-66.

Kivedal, B.K. (2013). Testing for rational bubbles in the US housing market. Journal

of Macroeconomics, 38, 369-381.

Kohn, J., & Bryant, S. K. (2011). Factors Leading to the U.S. Housing Bubble: A Structural

Equation Modeling Approach. Research in Business and Economics Journal.

Krainer, J, & Wei, C. (2004). House Prices and Fundamental Value. Federal Reserve Bank of

San Francisco Economic Letter, 2004-27.

Leamer, E. (2002). Bubble trouble. Your Home Has a P/E Ratio Too, UCLA Anderson Forecast

Quarterly.

Liebowitz, S. J. (2009). Anatomy of a train wreck: Causes of the mortgage meltdown. Housing

America: Building Out of a Crisis, 287, 292-98

Luttrell, D., Atkinson, T., & Rosenblum, H. (2013). Assessing the costs and consequences of the

Page 50: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -49-

2007-09 financial crisis and its aftermath. Economic Letter, 8-7.

Mayer, C. (2011). Housing bubbles: A survey. Annu. Rev. Econ., 3(1), 559-577.

McCarthy, J., & Peach, R. W. (2005). Is there a “bubble” in the housing market now?

Network Financial Instrument, 2005-PB-01.

Moscovici, S., & Zavalloni, M. (1969). The group as a polarizer of attitudes. Journal of

personality and social psychology, 12(2), 125.

Nickerson, R. S. (1998). Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises. Review

of general psychology, 2(2), 175.

Ohnishi, T., Mizuno, T., Shimizu, C., & Watanabe, T. (2012). Power laws in real estate prices

during bubble periods. International Journal of Modern Physics. Vol. 16, 61-81.

Schachter, S. (1951). Deviation, rejection and communication. Journal of Abnormal and Social

Psychology, 46, 190-207.

Sherman, M. (2009). A short history of financial deregulation in the United States. Center for

Economic and Policy Research.

Shiller, R. J. (2005). Irrational exuberance. Random House LLC.

Shiller, R. J. (2007). Understanding recent trends in house prices and home ownership (No.

w13553). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Shiller, R. J. (2008). Historic turning points in real estate. Eastern Economic Journal, 34(1), 1-

13.

Soo, C.K. (2013). Quantifying animal spirits: news media and sentiment in the housing market,

Working paper, University of Michigan

Stephens, M. (1994). History of newspapers. Collier’s Encyclopedia.

Studenmund, A. H., & Cassidy, H. J. (2011). Using econometrics: A practical guide. Boston,

Page 51: Economics Honors Paper - Tu Nguyen - 2015

Understanding Housing Bubble -50-

MA: Addison Wesley.

Theil, H. (1953). Repeated Least-Squares Applied to Complete Equation Systems. The Hague:

The Central Planning Bureau, The Netherlands.

Vogel, H. L. (2009). Prologue. Financial market bubbles and crashes (p. i). Cambridge

University Press.

Wallison, P. J. (2009). Cause and effect: government policies and the financial crisis. Critical

Review, 21(2-3), 365-376.

White, L. H. (2009). Federal Reserve policy and the housing bubble. Cato J., 29, 115.

Yan, W., Woodard, R., & Sornette, D. (2012). Leverage Bubble. Physica A, 391, 180-186.