Economics 2010c: Lecture 3 The Classical Consumption ModelSep 09, 2014  · 2 Linearizing Euler...

27
Economics 2010c: Lecture 3 The Classical Consumption Model David Laibson 9/9/2014

Transcript of Economics 2010c: Lecture 3 The Classical Consumption ModelSep 09, 2014  · 2 Linearizing Euler...

  • Economics 2010c: Lecture 3The Classical Consumption Model

    David Laibson

    9/9/2014

  • Outline:

    1. Consumption: Basic model and early theories

    2. Linearization of the Euler Equation

    3. Empirical tests without “precautionary savings effects”

  • 1 Application: Consumption.

    Sequence Problem (SP): Find () such that

    (0) = sup{}∞=0

    0

    ∞X=0

    ()

    subject to a static budget constraint for consumption,

    ∈ Γ ()

    and a dynamic budget constraint for assets,

    +1 ∈ Γ³ ̃+1 ̃+1

    ´

    Here is the vector of assets, is consumption, is the vector of financialasset returns, and is the vector of labor income.

  • For instance, consider the case where the only asset is cash-on-hand (so iscash-on-hand) and consumption is constrained to lie between 0 and Then,

    ∈ Γ () ≡ [0 ]

    +1 ∈ Γ³ ̃+1 ̃+1

    ´≡ ̃+1( − ) + ̃+1

    0 = 0

  • • We will always assume that ̃ is exogenous and iid.

    — However, in the welfare state, ̃ is not independent of See Hubbard,Skinner, and Zeldes (1995).

    • We will always assume that is concave (00 0 for all 0).

    • We will usually assume lim↓0 0() =∞ so 0 as long as 0

    — I’ll highlight exceptions to this rule.

  • 1.1 Bellman Equation representation

    • The state variable, is stochastic, so it is not directly chosen (rather adistribution for +1 is chosen at time ).

    • It is more convenient to think about as the choice variable.

    Bellman Equation:

    () = sup∈[0]

    {() + (+1) } ∀

    +1 = ̃+1(− ) + ̃+1

    0 = 0

  • 1.2 Necessary Conditions

    • First Order Condition:0() = ̃+10(+1) if 0 0() ≥ ̃+10(+1) if =

    • Envelope Theorem: 0() = 0(). Prove this. What if = ?

    • Euler Equation:

    0() = ̃+10(+1) if 0 0() ≥ ̃+10(+1) if =

  • 1.3 Perturbation intuition behind the Euler Equation:

    • What is the cost of consuming dollars less today?

    Utility loss today = · 0()

    • What is the (discounted, expected) gain of consuming ̃+1 dollars moretomorrow?

    Utility gain tomorrow = h³̃+1

    ´· 0(+1)

    i

    Let’s now rederive the Euler Equation:

  • 1. Suppose 0() ̃+10(+1) Then cut by and raise +1 bỹ+1 to generate a net utility gain:

    ·h−0() + ̃+10(+1)

    i 0

    This perturbation is always possible on the equilibrium path, so:

    0() ≥ ̃+10(+1)

    2. Suppose 0() ̃+10(+1) then raise by and cut +1 bỹ+1 to generate a net utility gain:

    ·h0()− ̃+10(+1)

    i 0

    This perturbation is possible on the equilibrium path as long as so:

    0() ≤ ̃+10(+1) as long as

  • It follows that

    0() = ̃+10(+1) if 0() ≥ ̃+10(+1) if =

  • 1.4 Important consumption models:

    1.4.1 Life Cycle Hypothesis: Modigliani & Brumberg (1954)

    • ̃ = = 1

    • Perfect capital markets (and no moral hazard), so that future labor incomecan be exchanged for current capital.

  • • Bellman Equation:

    () = sup≤

    {() + (+1) } ∀

    +1 = (− )

    0 = ∞X=0

    − e• Sometimes referred to as “eating a pie/cake problem.”

    • Euler Equation implies,

    0() = 0(+1) = 0(+1)

    • Hence, consumption is constant.

  • Budget constraint:∞X=0

    − = 0∞X=0

    − eSubstitute Euler Equation, 0 = to find

    ∞X=0

    − 0 = 0∞X=0

    − eSo Euler Equation + budget constraint implies

    0 =µ1− 1

    ¶⎛⎝0 ∞X=0

    − e⎞⎠ ∀

    Consumption is an annuity. What’s the value of your annuity?

    Remark 1.1 Friedman’s Permanent Income Hypothesis (Friedman, 1957) ismuch like Modigliani’s Life-Cycle Hypothesis.

  • 1.4.2 Certainty Equivalence Model: Hall (1978)

    • ̃ = = 1

    • Quadratic utility: () = − 22

    — This admits negative consumption.

    — And this does not imply that lim↓0 0() =∞

    • Can’t sell claims to labor income.

  • • Bellman Equation:

    () = sup{() + (+1) } ∀

    +1 = (− ) + ̃+1

    0 = 0

    ∞X=0

    − ≤∞X=0

    − e (BC)• Euler Equation implies, = +1 = + (consumption is a randomwalk w/o drift):

    +1 = + +1

    • So ∆+1 can not be predicted by any information available at time

  • Budget constraint at date :

    ∞X=0

    − + = +∞X=1

    − e+

    ∞X=0

    − + = +∞X=1

    − e+Substitute = + to find

    ∞X=0

    − = +∞X=1

    − e+So Euler Equation + budget constraint implies

    =µ1− 1

    ¶⎛⎝ + ∞X=1

    − e+⎞⎠ ∀

  • 2 Linearizing Euler Equation

    Recall Euler Equation:

    0() = +10(+1)

    Want to transform this equation so it is more amenable to empirical analysis.

    Assume that +1 is known at time .

    Assume is an isoelastic (i.e., constant relative risk aversion) utility function,

    () =1− − 11−

    (Aside: lim→11−−11− = ln . Important special case.)

  • Note that

    0() = −

    We can rewrite the Euler Equation as

    − = +1

    −+1

    1 = exphln³+1

    −+1

    ´i1 = exp [−+ +1 − ln(+1)]

    where − ln = and ln+1 = +1

    Since, ln(+1) = ln(+1)− ln() we write,

    1 = exp [+1 − − ∆ ln +1]

  • Assume that ∆ ln +1 is conditionally normally distributed. So,

    1 = exp∙+1 − − ∆ ln +1 +

    1

    22∆ ln +1

    ¸

    Taking the natural log of both sides yields,

    ∆ ln +1 =1

    (+1 − ) +

    2∆ ln +1

  • 3 Empirical tests without precautionary savings

    effects

    Recall Euler Equation:

    0() = +10(+1)

    We write the linearized Euler Equation in regression form:

    ∆ ln +1 =1

    (+1 − ) +

    2∆ ln +1 + +1

    where +1 is orthogonal to any information known at date

    The conditional variance term is often referred to as the “precautionary savingsterm,” (more on this later).

  • We sometimes (counterfactually) assume that ∆ ln +1 is constant (i.e.,independent of time). So the Euler Equation reduces to:

    ∆ ln +1 = constant+1

    (+1 − ) + +1

    When we replace the precautionary term with a constant, we are effectivelyignorning its effect (since it is no longer separately identified from the otherconstant term: )

  • Hundreds of papers have estimated a linearized Euler Equation:

    ∆ ln +1 = constant+1

    +1 + + +1

    The principal goals of these regressions are twofold:

    1. Estimate 1 , the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS) =∆ ln +1+1

    For example, see Hall (1988).

    • For this model, the EIS is the inverse of the CRRA.

  • 2. Test the orthogonality restriction: {Ω ≡ information set at date } ⊥+1

    • In other words, test the restriction that information available at time does not predict consumption growth in the following regression

    ∆ ln +1 = constant+1

    +1 + + +1

    • For example, does the date expectation of income growth, ∆ ln+1predict date + 1 consumption growth?

  • ∆ ln +1 = constant+1

    +1 + ∆ ln+1 + +1

    ∈ [01 08] so ∆ ln+1 covaries with ∆ ln +1 (e.g., Campbell andMankiw 1989, Shea 1995, Shapiro 2005, Parker and Broda 2014).

    • Orthogonality restriction is violated: information at date predicts con-sumption growth from to + 1

    • In other words, the assumptions (1) the Euler Equation is true, (2) theutility function is in the CRRA class, (3) the linearization is accurate, and(4) ∆ ln +1 is constant, are jointly rejected.

  • A note on Shea’s methodology (for estimating ∆ ln+1)

    1. Assign respondents to unions with national or regional bargaining

    • national: trucking, postal service, railroads

    • regional: lumber in Pacific Northwest, shipping on East Coast

    2. Assign respondents to dominant local employer

    • automobile worker living in Genesee County, MI (GM’s Flint plant)

  • Why does expected income growth predict consumption growth?

    • Leisure and consumption expenditure are substitutes (Heckman 1974, Ghezand Becker 1975, Aguiar and Hurst 2005, 2007)

    • Work-based expenses

    • Households support lots of dependents in mid-life when income is highest(Browning 1992, Attanasio 1995, Seshadri et al 2006)

    • Households are liquidity constrained and impatient (Deaton 1991, Carroll1992, Laibson 1997).

  • • Some consumers use rules of thumb: = (Campbell and Mankiw1989, Thaler and Shefrin 1981)

    • Welfare costs of smoothing are second-order (Cochrane 1989, Pischke1995, Browning and Crossley 2001)