EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal...

147
03/12/2018 1 EC202 2018/9 MICHAELMAS TERM SLIDE PACK five sections: Firm / Consumer / General Equilibrium / Risk & Uncertainty / Welfare first slide of each lecture has green border full versions at http://darp.lse.ac.uk/ec202 for more, contact [email protected] THE FIRM: Lectures 1 - 4 Quantities z i amount of input i z = (z 1 , z 2 , , z m ) input vector Z input requirement set q amount of output (single firm) q f output of firm f Prices and profits w i price of input i w = (w 1 , w 2 , , w m ) input-price vector p price of output profits Functions production function C cost function H i conditional demand for input i S supply function D i ordinary demand for input i Other Lagrange multiplier (min cost) elasticity of demand

Transcript of EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal...

Page 1: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

1

EC202 2018/9MICHAELMAS TERM SLIDE PACK

• five sections: Firm / Consumer / General Equilibrium / Risk & Uncertainty / Welfare• first slide of each lecture has green border• full versions at http://darp.lse.ac.uk/ec202

• for more, contact [email protected]

THE FIRM:Lectures 1 - 4

Quantitieszi amount of input i

z = (z1, z2 , , zm ) input vector

Z input requirement set

q amount of output (single firm)

qf output of firm f

Prices and profitswi price of input i

w = (w1, w2 , , wm) input-price vector

p price of output

profits

Functions production function

C cost function

Hi conditional demand for input i

S supply function

Di ordinary demand for input i

Other Lagrange multiplier (min cost)

elasticity of demand

Page 2: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

2

Inputs A first step

Characterise the basic constraint facing a firm

Use the production function (z1, z2, , zm)

• written equivalently (z)

• gives maximum output that can be produced from inputs z

Suppose a given amount of q of output is required

Then the basic constraint is (z) q

This basic constraint can be used in several ways

The input requirement set Z

“Inside”: feasible but inefficient

Boundary: feasible and technically efficient

“Outside”: Infeasible

Z(q)

q < (z)

q = (z)

q > (z)

z1

z2

Pick a particular output level q

Find a feasible input vector z

Repeat to find all such vectors for given q Get the input-requirement set: Z(q) := {z: (z) q}

Page 3: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

3

z1

z2

If Z smooth and strictly convex…

Pick two boundary points

Draw the line between them

Intermediate points lie in the interior of Z

Combination of two techniques may produce more output

What if we changed some of the assumptions?

z

z

Z(q)

q< (z)

q = (z")

q = (z') Important role of convexity

If Z smooth but not convex…

z1

z2

in this region there is an indivisibility

Join two points across the “dent”

Z(q)

Take an intermediate point

Point lies in infeasible zone

Page 4: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

4

z1

z2

If Z convex but not smooth

Slope of the boundary is undefined at this point

q = (z)

Isoquants

Pick a particular output level q

Find the input requirement set Z(q)

The isoquant is the boundary of Z: { z : (z) = q }

Think of the isoquant as an integral part of the set Z(q)

(z)i(z) := ——zi .

j (z)——i (z)

If the function is differentiable at zthen the marginal rate of technical substitution is the slope at z:

Where appropriate, use subscript to denote partial derivatives. So

Gives rate at which you trade off one input against another along the isoquant, maintaining constant q

Page 5: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

5

z1

z2

Draw input-requirement set Z(q)

Isoquant, input ratio, MRTS Boundary: contour of the function

{z: (z)=q}

An efficient point

Input ratio describes one production techniquez2°

z1°

Slope of ray: input ratio

z2 / z1= constant

Slope of boundary: Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution

The isoquant is the boundary of Z

Higher slope: increased MRTS

z′

MRTS21=1(z)/2(z)

MRTS21: implicit “price” of input 1 in terms of 2

Higher “price”: smaller relative use of input 1

MRTS and substitution Responsiveness of input ratio to MRTS

z1

z2

low

z1

z2

high

Page 6: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

6

Homothetic contours Curves: the isoquant map

Oz1

z2

Ray through the origin: a given input ratio

Same MRTS where ray cuts each isoquant

Contours of a homogeneous function

Curves: the isoquant map

Oz1

z2 Point z°: inputs that will produce q

Point tz°: inputs that will produce t rq

tz1°

tz2°

z2°

z1°

tz°

q

trq

Page 7: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

7

z2

q > (z)

Boundary: feasible and efficient

Inputs and outputq

0

The cone: q ≤ (z1, z2)

Interior: feasible but inefficient

“Outside”: infeasibleq < (z) q = (z) The expansion path through 0

This case: CRTS(tz) = t (z)Double inputs and output exactly doubles

Relationship to isoquants

z2

q

0

Take any production function

Horizontal “slice”: given q level

Project down to get the isoquant

Repeat to get isoquant map

Isoquant map is the projection of the set of technically efficient points

Page 8: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

8

Marginal products

Measure the marginal change in output w.r.t. this input

(z)MPi = i(z) = ——

zi .

Pick a technically efficient input vector

Keep all but one input constant

• Any z such that q= (z)

• The marginal product

CRTS production function again

z2

q

0

Vertical slice: keep one input constant

Broken line: path for z2 = const

Let’s look at its shape

Page 9: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

9

Marginal Product for CRTS production function

z1

q

(z)

Shaded area: feasible set

A section of the production function

Boundary: technically efficient points

Input 1 is essential:If z1 = 0 then q = 0

Slope of tangent: MP of input 1

(z)

Slope depends on value of z1…

1(z) falls with z1 (or stays constant) if is concave

The optimisation problemA classic microeconomic task:

• max some objective function (profits?)

• subject to defined constraints

Translate this into a formal problem

Choose q and z to maximise Π ≔ ∑• subject to (z) q

• and q 0, z 0

Q1: what should we assume about p and wi?• constant? (perfect markets)

• depend on quantities q and zi? (monopoly, monopsony)

• something else? (next term’s lectures)

Q2: would it be useful to break the problem down?

Page 10: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

10

A standard optimisation method Suppose is a differentiable function

Then we can set up a Lagrangian to take care of the constraints

Write down the First Order Conditions (FOC)

Check out second-order conditions

Use FOC to characterise solution

L (... )

L (... ) = 0z

2 L (... ) z2

z* = …

Stage 1 optimisationAssume perfect competition

• this means all prices are exogenously given

• so p and w are fixed

Suppose we take a given target output level

• this fixes q

• so revenue pq is constant and can be ignored in the optimisation

So the stage-1 problem is

• “maximise profits”: constant ∑

• equivalent to “minimise costs”: ∑

Page 11: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

11

Isocost lines

z1

z2

w1z1 + w2z2 = c

w1z1 + w2z2 = c'

w1z1 + w2z2 = c"

Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant

One such “isocost” line for each value of the constant c

Arrow: indicates the order of the isocost lines

Use this to derive optimum

Cost-minimisation

z1

z2

z*

Arrow shows objective of the firm

Shaded area: constraint on optimisation

These two define the stage-1 problem

Point z*: solution to the problem

minimisem

wizii=1

subject to (z) q

q

Solution depends on the shape of the input-requirement set

What would happen in other cases?

Page 12: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

12

Convex Z, touching axis

z1

z2

Here MRTS21 > w1 / w2 at the solution.

z* Input 2 is “too expensive”

and so isn’t used: z2* = 0

Non-convex Z

z1

z2

But note that there’s no solution point between z* and z**

z*

z**

There could be multiple solutions.

Page 13: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

13

z1

z2

Non-smooth Z

z* z* is unique cost-

minimising point for q

True for all positive finite values of w1, w2

q (z) + [q – (z)]

Cost-minimisation: strictly convex Z

1 (z) = w1

2 (z) = w2

… … … m(z) = wm

q = (z )

m

wi zii=1

Use the objective function ...and output constraint

...to build the Lagrangian

Minimise

Differentiate w.r.t. z1, ..., zm ; set equal to 0

Because of strict convexity we have an interior solution

... and w.r.t

A set of m + 1 First-Order Conditions

Denote cost minimising values by *

m

So we find: z∗z∗

• MRTS = input price ratio

Page 14: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

14

The solution: Solve the FOC to get three important expressions:

1. The cost-minimising value for each input ∗ w,

2. The cost-minimising value for the Lagrange multiplier∗ ∗ w,

3. The minimised value of cost itself

w, ≔ minz

Properties of C

w1

C

C(w, q)

Dark curve: cost of q as function of w1

Cost is non-decreasing in input prices

Cost is increasing in output, if continuous

C(w, q+q)

Cost is concave in input prices°

C(tw+[1–t]w,q) tC(w,q) + [1–t]C(w,q)

C(w,q) ———— = zj

*

wj

Slope illustrates Shephard’s Lemma

z1*

Page 15: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

15

What happens to cost if w changes to tw

z1

z2q

C(tw,q) = i t wizi* = t iwizi

* = tC(w,q)

Point z*: cost-minimising inputs for w, given q

• z*

Point z*: also cost-minimising inputs for tw, given q

• z*

So we have:

The cost function is homogeneous of degree 1 in prices

Stage 2 optimisation: Average and marginal cost

p

C/q

Green curve: average cost curve

Cq

Marginal cost cuts AC at its minimum

qq

Slope of AC depends on RTS

Page 16: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

16

Revenue and profits

q qq qqq

p

C/qCq

Horizontal line: a given market price p

Large rectangle: Revenue if output is q

q*

Small rectangle: Cost if output is q

Difference: Profits if output is q

Profits vary with q

Point q*: Maximum profits

price = marginal cost

What happens if price is low...

p

C/qCq

price < average cost

qq* = 0

Page 17: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

17

Profit maximisation

From FOC if q* > 0:

p = Cq (w, q*)

C(w, q*) p ————

q*

In general:

p Cq (w, q*)

pq* C(w, q*)

“Price equals marginal cost”

“Price covers average cost”

covers both the cases: q* > 0 and q* = 0

Objective: choose q to max

pq – C (w, q) “Revenue minus minimised cost”

The first response function

m

wi zi subject to q (z), z ≥ 0i=1

Review the cost-minimisation problem and its solution

Cost-minimising value for each input:

zi* = Hi(w, q), i=1,2,…,m

The firm’s cost function:

C(w, q) := min wizi{(z) q}

Hi is the conditional input demand function Demand for input i, conditional on given output level q

The “stage 1” problem

The solution function

Choose z to minimise

Page 18: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

18

Mapping into (z1,w1)-space

z1

z2

z1

w1

Left-hand panel: conventional case of Z the slope of the tangent: value of w1

Repeat for a lower value of w1

…and again to get…

Green curve: conditional demand curve

H1(w,q)

Constraint set is convex, with smooth boundary

Response function is a continuous map:

Another map into (z1,w1)-space

z1

z2

z1

w1

Left-hand panel: nonconvex ZStart with a high value of w1

Repeat for a very low value of w1

Points “nearby” `work the same wayBut what happens in between?

A demand correspondence

Constraint set is nonconvex

Response is discontinuous: jumps in z*

Map multivalued at discontinuity

Page 19: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

19

Put the cost function to work

Use Shephard’s Lemma , ∗ in first response function: • , , (*)

Differentiate (*) with respect to wj

• , , (**)

Order of differentiation is irrelevant ( ) and so

, ,

Special case: put i = j in (**) to get , , Concavity of C implies , 0andso

, 0

Conditional input demand curve

H1(w,q)

z1

w1 Consider the demand for input 1

Consequence of result 2?

“Downward-sloping” conditional demand

In some cases it is also possible that Hi

i = 0

Corresponds to the case where isoquant is kinked: multiple w values consistent with same z*

Page 20: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

20

The second response function

From the FOC:

p Cq (w, q*), if q* > 0

pq* C(w, q*)

“Price equals marginal cost”

“Price covers average cost”

Review the profit-maximisation problem and its solution

pq – C (w, q)

The “stage 2” problem

q* = S (w, p) S is the supply function

(again it may actually be a correspondence)

Profit-maximising value for output:

Choose q to maximise:

Prices and supply of output Take the FOC from last slide: , ∗

Substitute in the supply function ∗ ,

, , (*)

Differentiate (*) with respect to wj:• , , , , , 0

• ,, ,

, ,

Differentiate (*) with respect to p:• , , , 1

• ,, ,

Page 21: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

21

The firm’s supply curve

C/q

Cq

p

q

AC (green) and MC (red) curves

For given p read off optimal q*

Continues down to p Check what happens below p

p_ –

q_|

Case illustrated is for with first decreasing AC, then increasing AC, Response is a discontinuous map: jumps in q*

Multivalued at the discontinuity

Supply response given by q=S(w,p)

The third response function

Demand for input i, conditional on output q

zi* = Hi(w,q)

q* = S (w, p) Supply of output

zi* = Hi(w, S(w, p) )

Di(w,p) := Hi(w, S(w, p) )

Now substitute for q* :

Demand for input i (unconditional )

Stages 1 & 2 combined…

Recall the first two response functions:

Use this to analyse further the firm’s response to price changes

Use this to define a new function:

Page 22: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

22

Demand for i and the price of j

Differentiate w.r.t. wj: Dji(w, p) = Hj

i(w, q*) + Hqi(w, q*)Sj(w, p)

= Hji(w, q*) + Ciq(w, q)Sj(w, p)

Take the basic relationship Di(w, p) = Hi(w, S(w, p))

This and the result on Sj(w, p) give us a decomposition formula:

“substitution effect”

“output effect”Cjq(w, q*) Dj

i(w, p) = Hji(w, q*) Ciq(w, q*)

Cqq(w, q*) .

Substitution effect is just slope of conditional input demand curve

Output effect is [effect of wj on q][effect of q on demand for i]

Results from decomposition formula

The effect wi on demand for input j equals the effect of wj

on demand for input i

Take the general relationship:

Now take the special case where j = i:

If wi increases, the demand for input i cannot rise

Ciq(w, q*)Cjq(w, q*)Dj

i(w, p) = Hji(w, q*)

Cqq(w, q*) .

Ciq(w, q*)2

Dii(w, p) = Hi

i(w, q*) Cqq(w, q*).

Page 23: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

23

Input-price fall: substitution effect

Change in cost

conditional demand curve

pric

e fa

ll

z1

w1

H1(w,q)

*z1

z1* : initial equilibrium

grey arrow: fall in w1

shaded area: value of price fall

z1

Input-price fall: total effect

pric

e fa

ll

z1

w1

*z1

z1* : initial equilibrium

green line: substitution effect

z1** : new equilibrium

**

Page 24: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

24

The short-run problem

subject to q (z), q 0, z 0, and zm =zm

:= pq –m

wizii=1

Letq be the q for which zm =zm would be chosen in the unrestricted problem

Choose q and z to maximise

{zm =zm } C(w, q, zm ) := min wi zi The solution function with

the side constraint

~ _

Short-run demand for input i:

Hi(w, q, zm) =Ci(w, q, zm )~ _ ~ _

From Shephard’s Lemma

C(w, q) C(w, q, zm ) ~ _

By definition of cost function

Short-run AC ≥ long-run AC

So, dividing by q:~ _C(w, q) C(w, q, zm )______ _________q q

MC, AC and supply in the short and long run

C/q

Cq

q

p

q

C/q

Cq

~

~

green curve: AC if all inputs variable

q : given output level

red curve: MC if all inputs variable

black curve: AC if input m kept fixed

brown curve: MC if input m kept fixed

LR supply curve follows LRMC

SR supply curve follows SRMC

Supply curve steeper in the short run

SRAC touches LRAC at given output

SRMC cuts LRMC at given output

Page 25: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

25

Conditional input demand

H1(w,q)

z1

w1 Brown curve: demand for input 1

“Downward-sloping” conditional demand

Conditional demand curve is steeper in the short run

H1(w, q, zm)~ _

Purple curve: demand for input 1 in problem with the side constraint

Key concepts

Basic functional relations

price signals firm input/output responses

Hi(w,q)

S (w,p)

Di(w,p)

Hi(w, S(w,p)) = Di(w,p)

demand for input i, conditional on output

supply of output

demand for input i(unconditional )

And they all hook together like this:

Page 26: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

26

Market supply

q1

p

low-cost firm 1

q2

p

high-cost firm 2

p

q1+q2

both firms

Supply curve firm 1 follows MC Supply curve firm 2 follows MC Horizontal line: a given price Sum individual firms’ supply of output Repeat… Market supply curve is locus of these points

Market supply (2)

low-cost firm

p'

high-cost firm

p"

p'

both firms

p"

q1 q2 q1+q2

Below p' neither firm is in the market

Between p' and p'' only firm 1 is in the market

Above p'' both firms are in the market

pp p

Page 27: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

27

Take two identical firms…

p'

p

4 8 12 16

q1

p'

p

4 8 12 16

q2

Sum to get aggregate supply

24 328 16

p'

p

q1 + q2

Page 28: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

28

••• • • •• •• • • ••

Numbers and average supply

p

4 8 12 16

average(qf)

p'

Rescale to get average supply of the firms Compare with S for just one firm Repeat to get average S of 4 firms …average S of 8 firms

… of 16 firms

••

The limiting case

p

4 8 12 16

average(qf)

p'

The limit: continuous “averaged” supply curve

A solution to the non-existence problem?

A well-defined equilibrium

averagesupply

averagedemand

Firms’ outputs in equilibrium

Page 29: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

29

Industry supply: negative externality

S

S2 (q1=1)

S2 (q1=5)

S1 (q2=1)

S1 (q2=5)

MC1+MC2

q2

firm 2 alone

p

MC1+MC2

both firms

q1+ q2

p

q1

firm 1 alone

p

Each firm’s S-curve (MC) shifted by the other’s output

The result of simple MC at each output level

Industry supply allowing for interaction

Market equilibrium: number of firms price = marginal cost

Entry mechanism: • if p C/q gap is large then another firm could enter• applying this iteratively determines the size of the industry

price average cost

determines output of any one firm

determines number of firms

(0) Assume that firm 1 makes a positive profit

(1) Is pq – C ≤ set-up costs of a new firm?• …if YES then stop. We’ve got the eqm # of firms• …otherwise continue:

(2) Number of firms goes up by 1

(3) Industry output goes up

(4) Price falls (D-curve) and firms adjust output (individual firm’s S-curve)

(5) Back to step 1

Page 30: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

30

Firm equilibrium with entry

p

q3

marginalcost

average cost

output of firm

p

q1

1

pric

e AC (purple) and MC (red)

Use MC to get supply curve

Use price to find output

Profits in temporary equilibrium

Price-taking temporary equilibrium

nf = 1

Allow new firms to enter

p

q2

234

p

q4

p

qN

In the limit entry ensures profits are competed away

p = C/q

nf = N

Monopoly – model structure

We are given the inverse demand function• p = p(q)• Gives the price that rules if the monopolist delivers q to the market• For obvious reasons, consider it as the average revenue curve (AR)

Clearly, if pq(q) is negative (demand curve is downward sloping), then MR < AR

Differentiate to get monopolist’s marginal revenue (MR):• p(q) + pq(q)q• pq(ꞏ) means dp(ꞏ)/dq

Total revenue is:• p(q)q

Page 31: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

31

Average and marginal revenue

q

p

AR

AR curve is just the market demand curve

Total revenue: area in the rectangle underneath

Differentiate total revenue to get marginal revenue

MR

Monopoly – optimisation problem Introduce the firm’s cost function C(q)

• Same basic properties as for the competitive firm

From C we derive marginal and average cost:• MC: Cq (q)• AC: C(q) / q

Given C(q) and total revenue p(q)q profits are: • (q) = p(q)q C(q)

The shape of is important:• We assume it to be differentiable• Whether it is concave depends on both C() and p()• Of course (0) = 0

Firm maximises (q) subject to q ≥ 0

Page 32: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

32

Monopoly – solving the problem

This condition gives the solution• from above get optimal output q*

• put q* in p(ꞏ) to get monopolist’s price• p* = p(q* )

Check this diagrammatically

Evaluating the FOC:• p(q) + pq(q)q Cq(q) = 0 • p(q) + pq(q)q = Cq(q) • MR = MC

First- and second-order conditions for interior maximum:• q(q) = 0 • qq(q) < 0

Problem is “max (q) s.t. q ≥ 0,” where:• (q) = p(q)q C(q)

Monopolist’s optimum

q

p

AR

AR and MR (green)

AC(purple) and MC (red)

q*: optimum where MC=MR

MR

AC

MC

p*: monopolist’s optimum price

q*

p*

: monopolist’s profit

Page 33: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

33

Monopoly – pricing rule

This gives the monopolist’s pricing rule:

• p(q) =

…can be rewritten as:• p(q) [1+1/] = Cq(q)

First-order condition for a maximum:• p(q) + pq(q)q = Cq(q)

Introduce the elasticity of demand :• := d(log q) / d(log p) = p(q) / qpq(q)

• < 0

Cq(q)———1 +

Monopoly – analysing the optimum

Take the basic pricing rule• p(q) = Cq(q)

———1 + 1/

Clearly as | | decreases:• output decreases• gap between price and marginal cost increases

Use the definition of demand elasticity• p(q) Cq(q) • p(q) > Cq(q) if | | < ∞• “price > marginal cost”

What happens if | | ≤ 1 ( -1)?

Page 34: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

34

Monopolistic competition: 1

Take linear demand curve (AR)

Standard marginal and average costs

Optimal output for single firm

output of firm

MC AC

MR

AR

p

q1

MR curve derived from AR

Price and profits

outcome is effectively the same as for monopoly

Monopolistic competition: 2

output of firm

p

q1

Page 35: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

35

THE CONSUMER:Lectures 5 - 8

Quantitiesxi consumption of good i

x = (x1, x2 , , xn ) consumption vector

X consumption set

Ri resource stock of good i

R = (R1,R2 ,,Rn) resource endowment

Prices and incomepi price of good i

p = (p1, p2 , , pn) price vector

y money income

FunctionsU utility function

C cost (expenditure) function

Hi compensated demand for good i

Di ordinary demand for good i

V indirect utility function

Other Lagrange multiplier (min cost)

Lagrange multiplier (max utility)

utility level

The budget constraint

x1

Slope determined by price ratiox2

Two important cases determined by

1. … amount of money income y

2. …vector of resources R

2

p1 – __p2

A typical budget constraint

“Distance out” of budget line fixed by income or resources

Page 36: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

36

Case 1: fixed nominal income

x1

x2 Budget constraint determined by the two end-points Examine the effect of changing p1

by “swinging” the boundary

y .

.__p1

Budget constraint is

n

pixi ≤ yi=1

x2

Case 2: fixed resource endowment

R

Budget constraint determined by “resources” endowment R

Examine the effect of changing p1

by “swinging” the boundary thus:

Budget constraint is

n n

pixi ≤ piRii=1 i=1

x1

Page 37: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

37

x1

x2

Revealed Preference

x

Market prices determine a person's budget constraint Suppose the person chooses bundle x Use this to introduce Revealed Preference

x′

Axiom of Rational Choice

Consumer always makes a choice and selects the most preferred bundle that is available

Essential if observations are to have meaning

Weak Axiom of Revealed PreferenceWeak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)

If x RP x' then x' not-RP x

If x was chosen when x' was available then x' can never be chosen whenever x is available

Suppose that x is chosen when prices are p

Now suppose x' is chosen at prices p'

This must mean that x is not affordable at p':

If x' is also affordable at p then:

Page 38: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

38

x1

x2

WARP in action

Take the original equilibrium

Now let the prices change…

WARP rules out points like x° as possible solutions

x

x′

Clearly WARP induces a kind of negative substitution effect

But could we extend this idea…?

Trying to extend WARP

x1

x2 Take basic idea of revealed preference

Invoke revealed preference again

Invoke revealed preference yet again

Draw the “envelope”

Is this an “indifference curve”…?

No. WARP does not rule out cycles of preference

You need an extra axiom to progress further on this

x''

x

x'

Page 39: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

39

The (weak) preference relation

The basic weak-preference relation:

x ≽ x'

"Basket x is regarded as at least as good as basket x' …"

…and the strict preference relation…

x ≻ x'

“ x ≽ x' ” and not “ x' ≽ x ”

From this we can derive the

indifference relation

x ~ x'

“ x ≽ x' ” and “ x' ≽ x ”

Fundamental preference axioms

Completeness

Transitivity

Continuity

Greed

(Strict) Quasi-concavity

Smoothness

For every x, x' X either x ≽ x' is true, or x' ≽ x is true, or both statements are true

For all x, x', x" X if x≽x' and x'≽x" then x ≽ x"

For all x' X the not-better-than-x' set and the not-worse-than-x' set are closed in X

Page 40: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

40

x1

x2

Continuity

Take consumption bundle x°

Construct two bundles, xL with Less than x°, xM

with More

Draw the set of points like xL and the set like xM

Draw a path joining xL , xM

If there’s no “jump” you can draw this blue curve

xL

xM

x°What about the boundary points between the two shaded sets?

Do we jump straight from a point marked “better” to one marked “worse"?

The utility function

Representation Theorem:• given completeness, transitivity, continuity

• preference ordering ≽ can be represented by a continuous utility function

In other words there exists some function U such that• x ≽ x' implies U(x) U(x')

• and vice versa

U is purely ordinal• defined up to a monotonic transformation

So we could, for example, replace U(•) by any of the following• log( U(•) )

• ( U(•) )

• φ( U(•) ) where φ is increasing

All these transformed functions have the same shaped contours

Page 41: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

41

x2

0

Utility function and indifference curves

0 x2

Take a slice at given utility level Project down to get contours

Again take a slice… Project down to get same contours

Draw U* = φ(U)

Draw function U

U*U

The greed axiom

x1

Pick any consumption bundle in X

Gives a clear “North-East” direction of preference

x2

(b) What can happen if consumers are not greedy

(a) Greed implies that these bundles are preferred to x'

Bliss!

x'

x1

x2 (b)(a)

Page 42: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

42

ICs are smooth…

ICs strictly concaved-contoured

I.e. strictly quasiconcave

Pick two points on the same indifference curve

x1

x2

Draw the line joining them

Any interior point must line on a higher indifference curve

Conventionally shaped indifference curves

(-) Slope is the Marginal Rate of Substitution

U1(x) .—— .U2 (x) .

C

A

B

Slope well-defined everywhere

Other types of IC: Kinks

x1

x2Strictly quasiconcave

C

A

B

But not everywhere smooth

MRS not defined here

Page 43: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

43

C

A

B

Other types of IC: not strictly quasiconcave

x2

Case 1: Slope well-defined everywhere

Case 1: Not quasiconcave

Case 2: Quasiconcave but not strictly quasiconcave

x1

x2

x1

Case 2Case 1

The problem

Maximise consumer’s utility

U(x)U assumed to satisfy the standard “shape” axioms

Subject to feasibility constraint

x X

and to the budget constraint

n

pixi ≤ yi = 1

Assume consumption set X is the non-negative orthant

The version with fixed money income

Page 44: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

44

The primal problem

x1

x2

x*

There's another way of looking at this

The consumer aims to maximise utility…

Subject to budget constraint (green set)

max U(x) subject ton

pi xi yi=1

Defines the primal problem

x*: Solution to primal problem

The dual problem

x*

Alternatively the consumer could aim to minimise cost…

Subject to utility constraint

Defines the dual problem

x*: Solution to the problem

minimisen

pixii=1

subject to U(x)

Cost minimisation by the firm

But where have we seen the dual problem before?

x2

x1

z1

z2

z*

q

x*

x2

x1

Page 45: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

45

A lesson from the firm

z1

z2

z*

q

x1

x2

x*

Compare cost-minimisation for the firm…

…and for the consumer

The difference is only in notation

So their solution functions and response functions must be the same

U(x)+ λ[ – U(x)]

Cost-minimisation: strictly quasiconcave U

U1 (x ) = p1

U2 (x ) = p2

… … … Un (x ) = pn

= U(x )

n

pi xii=1

Use the objective function…and utility constraint

…to build the Lagrangian

Minimise

Differentiate w.r.t. x1, …, xn and set equal to 0

Because of strict quasiconcavity we have an interior solution

… and w.r.t

A set of n + 1 First-Order Conditions

Denote cost-min values with a *

Page 46: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

46

From the FOC

Ui(x) pi——— = —Uj(x) pj

MRS = price ratio “implicit” price = market price

If both goods i and j are purchased and MRS is defined then…

Ui(x) pi——— —Uj(x) pj

If good i could be zero then…

MRSji price ratio “implicit” price market price

The solution

Solve FOC to get a cost-minimising value for each good…

xi* = Hi(p, )

…for the Lagrange multiplier

* = *(p, )

…and for the minimised value of cost itself

The consumer’s cost function or expenditure function is defined asC(p, ) := min pi xi

{U(x) }

Page 47: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

47

Main results are immediate

Shephard's Lemma gives demand as a function of prices and utilityHi(p, ) = Ci(p, )

H is the “compensated” or conditional demand function

Properties of the solution function determine behaviour of response functions

Downward-sloping with respect to its own price, etc…

“Short-run” results can be used to model side constraints

For example rationing

The cost function has same properties as for the firm

Same problem as for firm; so results are the same

Comparing firm and consumer

n

minpixix i=1

+ [ – U(x)]

Cost-minimisation by the firm… …and expenditure-minimisation by the consumer …are effectively identical problems So the solution and response functions are the same:

xi* = Hi(p, )

C(p, )

m

minwiziz i=1

+ [q – (z)]

Solution: C(w, q)

zi* = Hi(w, q) Response:

Problem:

Firm Consumer

Page 48: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

48

n

U(x) + [ y – pi xi ]i=1

The Primal and the Dual…

There’s an attractive symmetry about the two approaches to the problem

…constraint in the primal becomes objective in the dual…

…and vice versa

In both cases the ps are given and you choose the xs. But…

n

pixi+ [ – U(x)]i=1

A useful connection

x1

x2

x*

Compare the primal problem of the consumer…

…with the dual problem

Two aspects of the same problem

So we can link up their solution functions and response functions

x1

x2

x*

Page 49: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

49

n

y pi xii=1

U(x)

Utility maximisation

U1(x ) = p1

U2(x ) = p2

… … …Un(x ) = pn

n

+ μ[ y – pi xi ]i=1

Use the objective function…and budget constraint

…to build the Lagrangean

Maximise

Differentiate w.r.t. x1, …, xn and set equal to 0

… and w.r.t

A set of n+1 First-Order Conditions

Denote utility maximising values with a *

n

y = pi xii=1

If U is strictly quasiconcave we have an interior solution

From the FOC

Ui(x) pi——— = —Uj(x) pj

MRS = price ratio “implicit” price = market price

If both goods i and j are purchased and MRS is defined then…

Ui(x) pi——— —Uj(x) pj

If good i could be zero then…

MRSji price ratio “implicit” price market price

(same as before)

Page 50: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

50

The solutionGet U-maximising value for each good and Lagrange multiplier

• xi* = Di(p, y), i = 1,…,n

• * = *(p, y)

Also for the maximised value of utility itself

The indirect utility function is defined as• V(p, y) := max U(x)

pixi y}

• V is non-increasing in every price, decreasing in at least one price• … is increasing in income y• … is quasi-convex in prices p• …is homogeneous of degree zero in (p, y)• …satisfies “Roy's Identity”

Another useful connection Indirect utility function maps

prices and budget into maximal utility: = V(p, y)

The indirect utility function works like an "inverse" to the cost function

Cost function maps prices and utility into minimal budget: y = C(p, )

The two solution functions have to be consistent with each other.

Therefore we have:= V(p, C(p, ))

Odd-looking identities can be useful

0 = Vi(p,C(p,))+Vy(p,C(p,)) Ci(p,)

0 = Vi(p, y) + Vy(p, y) xi* Shephard’s Lemma

Function-of-a-function rule

Rearrange to get Roy’s identity

xi* = – Vi(p, y)/Vy(p, y) The right-hand side is just Di(p, y)

Page 51: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

51

Utility and expenditure

n

min pixix i=1

+ [ – U(x)]

Utility maximisation …and expenditure-minimisation by the consumer …are effectively two aspects of the same problem

xi* = Hi(p, )

C(p, ) Solution: V(p, y)

xi* = Di(p, y) Response:

Problem:

Primal Dualn

max U(x) + μ[ y – pi xi ]x i=1

So their solution and response functions are closely connected:

The max-utility problem again

n

pixi* = y

i=1

U1(x*) = p1U2(x*) = p2

… … … Un(x*) = pn

x1* = D1(p, y)

x2* = D2(p, y)

… … … xn

* = Dn(p, y)npi Di(p, y) = yi=1

The n + 1 first-order conditions, assuming all goods purchased

Gives a set of demand functions, one for each good: functions of prices and incomes

A restriction on the n equations. Follows from the budget constraint

Solve this set of equations:

The primal problem and its solutionn

max U(x) + [ y – pi xi ]i=1

Lagrangian for the max U problem

Page 52: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

52

The response function Primal problem response function is

demand for good i:xi

* = Di(p,y)

Should be treated as just one of a set of n equations

The system has an “adding-up” property:

∑ ,

Follows from budget constraint: LHS is total expenditure

Each equation is homogeneous of degree 0 in prices and income. For any t > 0:

xi* = Di(p, y )= Di(tp, ty)

Again follows from the budget constraint

Effect of a change in income y

x1

x*

Take the equilibrium at x*

Suppose income rises

New equilibrium at x**

x**

x2

Demand for each good does not fall if it is “normal”

But could the opposite happen?

Page 53: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

53

An “inferior” good

x1

x*

Same original budget, different preferences

Again suppose income risesEquilibrium shifts from x** to x**

x2

Demand for good 1 rises, but…

Demand for “inferior” good 2 falls

Can you think of any goods like this?

How might it depend on the categorisation of goods?

x**

Effect of a change in price

x1

x*

Again take the original equilibrium

Allow price of good 1 to fall

Big blue arrow: the effect of the price fall

x**

x2

Small blue arrows: “journey” from x* to x** broken into two parts

°

Page 54: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

54

A fundamental decomposition

Take the two methods of writing ∗:p, = p,

Two representations of same thing

Use cost function to substitute for y:p, = p, p,

Differentiate with respect to pj:p, = p, p, p,

= p, p, ∗

Implicit relation in prices and utility

Uses (1) y = C(p,) (2) function-of-a-function rule and (3) Shephard’s Lemma

Rearrange to get:

p, p, ∗ p, This is the Slutsky equation

The Slutsky equation

Gives fundamental breakdown of effects of a price change

Income effect: “I'm better off if the price of jelly falls; I’m worse off if the price of jelly rises. The size of the effect depends on how much jelly I am buying…

Substitution effect: “When the price of jelly falls and I’m kept on the same utility level, I prefer to switch from icecream for dessert”

x**

Dji(p,y) = Hj

i(p,) – xj* Dy

i(p,y)

x*

…if the price change makes me better off then I buy more normal goods, such as icecream”

Page 55: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

55

The Slutsky equation: own-price

Dii(p,y) = Hi

i(p,) – xi* Dy

i(p,y)

Set j = i to get the effect of the price of ice-cream on the demand for ice-cream

Hii (own-price substitution effect)

must be negative

Dyi is non-negative for normal goods

Theorem: if the demand for i does not decrease when y rises, then it must decrease when pi rises

Follows from the results on the firm

Price increase means less disposable income

So the income effect of a price rise must be non-positive for normal goods

Important special case

Price fall: normal good

compensated (Hicksian) demand curve

pric

e fa

ll

x1

p1

H1(p,)

*x1

Initial equilibrium at x*1

first red arrow: price fall, substitution effect

both red arrows: total effect, normal good

For normal good income effect must be positive or zero

ordinary demand curve

x1**

second red arrow: income effect, normal good

D1(p,y)

Page 56: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

56

Consumer equilibrium: another view

Rx1

x2

x*

Type 2 budget constraint: fixed resource endowmentBudget constraint with endogenous income

Consumer's equilibrium

Its interpretation

Equilibrium is familiar: same FOCs as before

The offer curve

Rx1

x2

x*

x***

x**

Take the consumer's equilibrium

Let the price of good 1 rise

Let the price of good 1 rise a bit more

Draw the locus of points

This path is the offer curve

Amount of good 1 that household supplies to the market

Page 57: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

57

supply of good 1

p1

Household supply

Flip horizontally , to make supply clearer Rescale the vertical axis to measure price of good 1

Plot p1 against x1

This path is the household’s supply curve of good 1

R supply of good 1

x2

x*

x***

x**

The curve “bends back” on itself

Why?

Decomposition – another look

Function of prices and income

Differentiate with respect to pj : dxi

* dy— = Dj

i(p, y) + Dyi(p, y) —

dpj dpj

= Dji(p, y) + Dy

i(p, y) Rj

Income itself now depends on prices

Now recall the Slutsky relation: Dj

i(p,y) = Hji(p,) – xj

* Dyi(p,y)

The indirect effect uses function-of-a-function rule again

Just the same as on earlier slide

Use this to substitute for Dji:

dxi*

— = Hji(p,) + [Rj – xj

*] Dyi(p,y)

dpj

The modified Slutsky equation

Take ordinary demand for good i:xi

* = Di(p,y)

Substitute in for y :xi

* = Di(p, j pjRj)

Page 58: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

58

The modified Slutsky equation:

Substitution effect has same interpretation as before

Two terms to consider when interpreting the income effect

The second term (in the income effect) is just the same as before

The first term (in the income effect) makes all the difference:• Negative if the person is a net demander• Positive if the person is a net supplier

dxi*

── = Hji(p, ) + [Rj – xj

*] Dyi(p,y)

dpj

Application: savings

Rx1

x2

x*

Resource endowment is non-interest income profile Slope of budget constraint increases with interest rate, r

Consumer's equilibrium

Its interpretation

Determines time-profile of consumption

What happens to saving when the interest rate changes…?

x1,x2 are consumption “today” and “tomorrow”

Page 59: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

59

Application: labour supply

R

x1

x2

x*

Endowment: total time & non-labour income Slope of budget constraint is wage rate

Consumer's equilibrium

Determines labour supply

Will people work harder if their wage rate goes up?

x1,x2 are leisure and consumption

The two aspects of the problem

x1

x2

x*

Primal: Max utility subject to the budget constraint

Dual: Min cost subject to a utility constraint

x1

x2

x*

What effect on max-utility of an increase in budget?V(p, y) C(p,)

V

What effect on min-cost of an increase in target utility?

C

Page 60: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

60

Interpreting the Lagrange multiplier

Differentiate with respect to y:

Vy(p, y) = i Ui(x*)Diy(p, y) + * [1 – i piDi

y(p, y)]

The solution function for the primal:

V(p, y) = U(x*) = U(x*) + * [y – i pixi* ]

At the optimum, either the constraint binds or Lagrange multiplier is zero

Use the ordinary demand functions

Rearrange:Vy(p, y) = i[Ui(x*)–*pi]Di

y(p,y)+* = *

Lagrange multiplier in the primal is MU of income

Differentiate with respect to and rearrange:C(p, ) = i [pi–*Ui(x*)] Hi

(p, )+* = *

The solution function for the dual:C(p, ) = ipi xi

* = ipi xi* – * [U(x*) – ]

Same argument as above

Lagrange multiplier in the dual is MC of utility

We can also show:. * = 1/ * A useful connection between C and V

The problem of valuing utility change

x1

x*

Take the consumer's equilibrium

and allow a price to fall...

Obviously the person is better off.

'

x**

x2

...but how much better off?

Page 61: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

61

Story number 1 (CV)Price of good 1 changes

• p: original price vector

• p': vector after price change

This causes utility to change • = V(p, y)

• ' = V(p', y)

Value this utility change in money terms:• what change in income would bring a person

back to the starting point?

Define the Compensating Variation:• = V(p', y – CV)

Amount CV is just sufficient to undoeffect of going from p to p'

original utility level restored at new prices p'

original utility level at prices p

new utility level at prices p'

The compensating variation

x1

x**

x*

A fall in price of good 1

Reference point is original utility level

Red line: CV measured in terms of good 2

x2

Page 62: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

62

Story number 2 (EV)Price of good 1 changes

• p: original price vector

• p': vector after price change

This causes utility to change • = V(p, y)

• ' = V(p', y)

Value this utility change in money terms:• what income change would have been needed

to bring the person to the new utility level?

Define the Equivalent Variation:• ' = V(p, y + EV)

Amount EV is just sufficient to mimiceffect of going from p to p'

new utility level reached at original prices p

original utility level at prices p

new utility level at prices p'

The equivalent variation

x1

x**

x*

' Price fall as before

Reference point is the new utility level '

Red line: EV measured in terms of good 2

x2

Page 63: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

63

Welfare change as – (cost)

Equivalent Variation as –(cost):

EV(pp') = C(p, ') – C(p', ')

Compensating Variation as –(cost):

CV(pp') = C(p, ) – C(p', )

(–) change in cost of hitting utility level . If positive we have a welfare increase

(–) change in cost of hitting utility level '. If positive we have a welfare increase

Using these definitions we also have

CV(p'p) = C(p', ') – C(p, ')

= – EV(pp')

Looking at welfare change in the reverse direction, starting at p' and moving to p

Cost-of-living indices

An approximation:i p'i xiIL = ———i pi xi

ICV .

An index based on CV:

C(p', )ICV = ————

C(p, )

What's the change in cost of hitting the base utility level ?

What's the change in cost of buying the base consumption bundle x?This is the Laspeyres index (the basis for the Consumer Price Index)

An index based on EV:

C(p', ')IEV = ————

C(p, ') An approximation:

i p'i x'iIP = ———i pi x'iIEV .

What's the change in cost of hitting the new utility level ' ?

What's the change in cost of buying the new consumption bundle x'?This is the Paasche index .

Page 64: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

64

Another (equivalent) form for CV

Assume that the price of good 1 changes from p1 to p1' while other prices remain unchanged. Then we can rewrite the above as:

CV(pp') = C1(p, ) dp1

Use the cost-difference definition:CV(pp') = C(p, ) – C(p', )

(–) change in cost of hitting utility level . If positive we have a welfare increase

Using definition of a definite integral

Further rewrite as:

CV(pp') = H1(p, ) dp1Using Shephard’s lemma again

CV is an area under the compensated demand curve

p1

p1'

p1

p1'

Compensated demand and the value of a price fall (CV)

CompensatingVariation

compensated (Hicksian) demand curve

pric

e fa

ll

x1

p1

H1(p, )

*x1

The initial equilibrium

price fall: (welfare increase)

shaded area: value of price fall, relative to original utility level

The CV provides an exact welfare measure

But it’s not the only approach

Page 65: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

65

Compensated demand and the value of a price fall (EV)

x1

EquivalentVariationpr

ice

fall

x1

p1

**

H1(p, )

compensated (Hicksian) demand curve

As before but use new utility level as a reference point

price fall: (welfare increase)

Shaded area: value of price fall, relative to new utility level

The EV provides another exact welfare measure

But based on a different reference point

Other possibilities…

Ordinary demand and the value of a price fall

x1

pric

e fa

ll

x1

p1

***x1

D1(p, y)

Initial equilibrium at x1*

price fall: (welfare increase)

Yellow area: an alternative method of valuing the price fall?

Consumer'ssurplus

ordinary (Marshallian) demand curve

CS provides an approximatewelfare measure

Page 66: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

66

Three ways of measuring the benefits of a price fall

x1

pric

e fa

ll

x1

p1

**

H1(p, )

*x1

H1(p,)

D1(p, y)

Summary of the three approaches.

Illustrated for normal goods

For normal goods: CV CS EV

For inferior goods: CV > CS > EV

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM:Lectures 9 - 12

Quantitiesqi aggregate net output of good i

xi aggregate consumption of good i

Ri resource stock of good i

Rih resource holding by h of i

qif net output by f of i

xih consumption by h of i

[x1,x2 , …] allocation across households

[q1,q2 , …] allocation across firms

Prices and incomespi market price of good i

i shadow price of good i

f profits of firm f

yh money income of h

FunctionsUh utility function of h

f production function of firm f

Ei excess demand for good i

OtherN replication factor

h reservation utiity for h

fh share of h in the profits of f

Q technology set

A Attainable set

B “better than” set

K Coalition

Page 67: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

67

Approaches to outputs and inputs

–z1

–z2

...–zm

+q

=

q1

q2

...qn-1

qn

NET OUTPUTS

q1

q2

qn-1

qn

...

A standard “accounting” approach

An approach using “net outputs”

How the two are related

Outputs: +net additions to the

stock of a good

Inputs: reductions in the

stock of a good

Intermediate goods:

0your output and my input cancel each other out

A simple sign convention

OUTPUT INPUTS

z1

z2

...

zm

q

The technology set Q

q1

0Q

Page 68: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

68

Tradeoff in inputs

(given q1 = 500)

(given q1 = 750)

q4

q3

high input

q2

q1

Tradeoff between outputs

Again take slices through Q

For low level of inputs

low input

For high level of inputs

CRTS

Page 69: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

69

q2

q1

The technology set Q and the production function

A view of set Q: production possibilities of two outputs.

The frontier is smooth (many basic techniques)

Feasible but inefficient points in the interior

(q) < 0

Feasible and efficient points on the boundary

(q) = 0Infeasible points outside the boundary

(q) > 0

q Q (q) 0

(q1, q2,…,qn) nondecreasing in each qi

Boundary is the transformation curve

Slope: marginal rate of transformation

MRTij := j (q) / i (q)

The Crusoe problem

max U(x) by choosing x and q subject to...

joint consumption-production decision

• x X logically feasible consumption

• (q) 0 technical feasibility: equivalent to “q Q ”

• x q + R materials balance: can’t consume more than available from net output + resources

Page 70: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

70

Crusoe’s problem and solution

x2

0x1

Shaded green area: attainable set with R1= R2 = 0

Positive stock of resource 1: stretches to right

More of resources 3,…,n : stretches “outwards

Curves: Crusoe’s preferences

Attainable set derived from technology and materials balance condition

purple line: gives the FOC

MRS = MRT:

U1(x) 1(q)—— = ———U2(x) 2(q)

• x*

x*: the optimum

Profits and income at shadow prices

We know that there is no system of prices Invent some “shadow prices” for accounting purposesUse these to value national income

1 2 ... n profits1q1 + 2q2 +...+ nqn

value ofresource stocks

1R1 + 2R2 +...+ nRn

value ofnational income

1[q1+R1] +...+ n[qn+Rn]

Page 71: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

71

National income contours

1[q1+ R1] + 2[q2+ R2 ] = const

q1+R1

q2+R2

“National income” of the Island

Dark area: attainable setx2

x10

Using shadow prices we’ve broken down the Crusoe problem into a two-step process:

1.Profit maximisation2.Utility maximisation

Shaded triangle: Island’s “budget set” Use budget set to maximise utility

red lines: Iso-profit – income max

1(x) 1—— = —2(x) 2

U1(x) 1—— = —U2(x) 2

x*

Page 72: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

72

A separation result

By using “shadow prices” … max U(x) subject tox q + R(q) 0

max U(x) subject ton

i xi yi=1

n

max i [ qiRisubj. toi=1

(q) 0

…a global maximisation problem …is separated into sub-problems:

1. An income-maximisation problem

Maximised income from 1 is used in problem 2

2. A utility maximisation problem

Crusoe problem: another view

A: the attainable set

x2

x10

A = {x: x q + R, (q) 0}

purple line: prices B: the “Better-than-x*” set

A

B

12

B = {x: U(x) U(x*)}

Big arrows: decentralisation

x* maximises income over A

x* minimises expenditure over B

x*

Page 73: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

73

Optimum cannot be decentralised

x2

x1

Attainable set is nonconvex

x*: the consumer optimum

x°:maximise profits given prices

Implied prices: MRT=MRS

Production responses do not support the consumer optimum In this case the price system “fails”

A

x*

Crusoe's island tradesx2

x1

x**

x1**q1

**

x2**

q2**

x*: equilibrium on the island Price differences: possibility of trade Max income at world prices (top left)

Trade enlarges attainable set (shaded triangle)

q**,x**: equilibrium with trade

x* is Autarkic eqm: x1*= q1

*; x2*=q2

*

World prices: revalue national income

In this equilibrium the gap between x**

and q** is bridged by imports & exports

World prices

q**

x*

Domestic prices

Page 74: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

74

The nonconvex case with world tradex2

x1x1

**q1**

x2**

q2**

A′A

x*: equilibrium on the island purple line: world prices

x*

Max income at world prices (top left)

q**,x**: equilibrium with trade

Attainable set before trade (A) & after trade (A′)

Trade “convexifies” the attainable set

x**

q**

What is an economy?

Resources (stocks)

U1, U2 ,…

,…

R1 , R2 ,…

nh of these

nf of these

n of these

Households (preferences)

Firms (technologies)

Page 75: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

75

An allocation

A collection of bundles (one for each of the nh households)

[x] := [x1, x2, x3,… ]

[q] := [q1, q2, q3,… ]

p := (p1, p2, …, pn)

utility-maximising

^

profit-maximising

^

A competitive allocation consists of:

A set of prices (used by households and firms)

A collection of net-output vectors (one for each of the nf firms)

{ } { , h=1,2,…,nh }

How a competitive allocation works

qf: from f’s profit maximisation

p qf(p) xh: from h’s utility maximisation

Firms' behavioural responses map prices into net outputs

{ , f=1,2,…,nf } Hholds’ behavioural responses map prices and incomes into demands

p, yh xh(p) Grey box: the competitive allocation

Page 76: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

76

What does household h possess?

Resources R1h, R2

h, …

1h, 2

h, …

Rih 0,

i =1,…,n

Shares in firms’ profits

0 fh 1,

f =1,…,nf

Incomes

Resources

Profits

Rents

Shares in firms

Net outputs

Prices

Page 77: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

77

The fundamental role of prices

Net output of i by firm f depends on prices p:

qif = qi

f(p)

Supply of net outputs

Thus profits depend on prices:n

f(p):= pi qif(p)

i=1

So incomes can be written as: n nf

yh = pi Rih + f

h f(p)i=1 f=1

Again writing profits as price-weighted sum of net outputs

Income depends on prices : yh = yh(p)

Income = resource rents + profits

yh(•) depends on ownership rights that h possesses

Prices in a competitive allocation

Large box: allocation as a collection of responses

Put the price-income relation into household responses

Gives a simplified relationship for households

p qf(p){ , f=1,2,…,nf }

{ } { , h=1,2,…,nh }p, yh xh(p)p Small box: summarise the relationship

p [q(p)]

[x(p)]

Page 78: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

78

The price mechanism

d

resource distribution

R1b, R2

b, …

R1a, R2

a, …

share ownership

1b, 2

b, …

1a, 2

a, …

System takes as given the property distribution

Property distribution consists of two collections Prices then determine incomes

[y]

Prices and incomes determine net outputs and consumptions

[q(p)][x(p)]

Brief summary below…

adistribution

prices

allocation

What is an equilibrium?

What kind of allocation is an equilibrium?

Again we can learn from previous presentations:• must be utility-maximising (consumption) • must be profit-maximising (production)• must satisfy materials balance (the facts of life)

We can do this for the many-person, many-firm case

Page 79: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

79

Uh(xh), subject ton

pi xih yh

i=1

Competitive equilibrium: basics

Households maximise utility, given prices and incomes

Firms maximise profits, given prices

For each h, maximise

For all goods the materials balance must hold

n

pi qif, subject to f(qf ) 0

i=1

For each f, maximise

For each i:

xi qi + Ri

Consumption and net output

“Obvious” way to aggregate consumption of good i?

nh

xi = xih

h=1

An alternative way to aggregate:

xi = max {xih }

h

Appropriate if i is a rival good Additional resources needed for each additional person consuming a unit of i

Opposite case: a nonrival good Examples: TV, national defence…

Aggregation of net output:nf

qi := qif

f=1

if all qf are feasible will q be feasible? Yes if there are no externalities Counterexample: production with congestion…

Page 80: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

80

Competitive equilibrium: summary

A set of prices p Everyone maximises at those

prices p

It must be a competitive allocation

Demand cannot exceed supply: x ≤ q + R

The materials balance condition must hold

Alf’s optimisation problem

x1aR1

a

R2a

x2a

Oa

Ra: resource endowment

Preferences (cyan curves)

Prices (red line) & budget constraint (shaded)

Ra

x*a

x*a: equilibrium

Budget constraint is

2 2

pi xia ≤ pi Ri

a

i=1 i=1

Alf sells some of 2 for good 1 by trading with Bill

Page 81: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

81

Bill’s optimisation problem

x1bR1

b

R2b

x2b

Ob

Rb: resource endowment

Preferences (green curves)

Prices (red line) & budget constraint (shaded)

x*b: equilibrium

Bill sells good 1 in exchange for 2

Budget constraint is

2 2

pi xib ≤ pi Ri

b

i=1 i=1 Rb

x*b

Combine the two problems

Bill’s problem (flipped)

Price-taking trade moves agents from [R]…

Superimpose Alf’s problem

x1b R1

b

R2b

x2b

Ob

…to competitive equilibrium allocation [x*]

This is the Edgeworth box

Width: R1a + R1

b

Height: R2a + R2

b

x1aR1

a

R2a

x2a

Oa

[R]

[x*]

Page 82: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

82

Response to changes in prices

x1a

R2a

x2a

Oa

Ra •

R1a

Ra: Alf’s endowment

Curve through Ra:Alf’s res. utility Alf’s preference map

No trade if p1 is too high

Trades offered as p1 falls

••

•••••• •

Red curve: Alf’s offer curve

x1b

R2b

x2b

ObR1

b

Rb•

x1b

R2b

x2b

Ob

R1b

Rb•

Response to changes in prices (2)

•••

••••

••

Ob Bill’s similar situation…

…diagram inverted

No trade if p1 is too low

Trades offered as p1 rises

Bill’s offer curve

Page 83: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

83

Edgeworth Box and CE

x2b

Ob

x1a

x2a

Oa

x1b

R1b

R1a

R2a

R2b

• [x*]

[x*]: where offers are consistent

By construction [x*] is CE:

Price-taking U-maximising Alf Price-taking U-maximising Bill Satisfies materials balance

[R]: property distribution Draw in the two offer curves

[R]•

Coalitions

K2

K1

K0

Viewed as nh separate individuals

A coalition K…

…is formed by any subgroup

The population…

Page 84: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

84

A formal approach

An allocation is blocked by a coalition if the coalition members can do better for themselves

Equilibrium conceptUse the idea of blocking to introduce a solution concept

• if allocation is blocked a coalition could stop it happening

• such an allocation could not be a solution to the trading game

So we use the following definition of a solution:• the Core is the set of unblocked, feasible allocations

Let’s apply it in the two-trader case• In a 2-person world there are few coalitions:

{Alf }

{Bill}

{Alf & Bill}

• let’s see what allocations are blocked by them…

• …and what remains unblocked

Page 85: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

85

Ob

Oa

x1b

x1a

x2a

x2b

x1a

x2a

x2b

[xb]

x1b

b

The 2-person core

Purple line: the contract curve

a: Alf’s reservation IC through [R]

{Bill} blocks allocations below res IC

{Alf, Bill} block allocations off the CC

Blue segment: the resulting core

{Alf} blocks allocations below res IC

[xa]

b: Bill’s reservation IC through [R]

Points on contract curve: can’t be blocked by {Alf,Bill}

If indifference curves are everywhere differentiable……then MRS is everywhere well defined In this case contract curve is locus of common tangencies

a

[R]

[xa]: Bill gets all advantage from trade

[xb]: Alf gets all advantage from trade

Ob

Oa

x1b

x1a

x2a

x2b

The core and CE [R]: the endowment point blue segment: 2-person core

[R]

x*: competitive equilibrium

[x*] A competitive equilibrium must always be a core allocation

Page 86: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

86

Ob

Oa

x1b

x1a

x2a

x2b

The core and CE (2)Indifference curves yielding multiple equilibria

Endowment point [R] fixes reservation utility[x*]: Equilibrium, low p1/p2

[x**]: Equilibrium, high p1/p2

Dark blue segment: the core

•[x*]

•[x**]b

a

• [R]

A simple result… and a question Every CE allocation must belong to the core

It is possible that no CE exists

What about core allocations which are not CE?• Remember we are dealing with a 2-person model• Will there always be non-CE points in the core?

To find out, let's clone the economy• economy replicated by a factor N, so there are 2N persons• start with N = 2• Alf and twin brother Arthur have same preferences and endowments• likewise the twins Bill and Ben

Now there are more possibilities of forming coalitions• so more blocking!

Core

CE

{Alf & Bill}

{Alf}{Bill}

{Arthur & Ben}

{Arthur}{Ben}

{Alf & Arthur}{Alf, Arthur &Bill}{Alf, Arthur &Ben} {etc, etc}

{Bill&Ben}{Bill, Ben &Alf}

Page 87: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

87

Effect of cloning on the core

New allocation is not a solution…

But it shows that the core must have become smaller

Dark blue segment: the 2-person core

{Alf,Arthur,Bill} can block [xa] at ½–way mark

The Ben twin is left outside the coalition

[R]

Are the extremes still core allocations in the 4-person economy?

°

[xa], [xb]: the extremes of the two-person core

[xa]

[xb]

How the blocking coalition works

Alf xa = ½[xa+Ra]

Arthur xa = ½[xa+Ra]

Bill [2Ra +Rb – 2xa]——————2Ra + Rb

Consumption within the coalition equals the coalition’s resources

So the allocation is feasible

Big box: consumption in the coalitionSum to get resource requirement

Ben Rb

Small box: consumption out of coalition

Page 88: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

88

If N is bigger: more blocking coalitions?

numbers of…a-tribe b-tribe

Dark blue segment: the 2-person core

An arbitrary allocation - can it be blocked?

500 250

310360

400

450

We’ve found the blocking coalition

If line is not a tangent this can always be done

Draw a line to the endowmentTake N=500 of each tribe Divide the line for coalition numbers

[R]

[xb]

[xa]

In the limit

If N a coalition can be found dividing the line to [R] in any proportion you want

Only if the line is like this will the allocation be impossible to block

With the large N the core has “shrunk” to the set of CE

[R]

[xa]

[x*]

[xb]

Page 89: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

89

Aggregates

From household’s demand functionxi

h = Dih(p, yh)= Dih(p, yh(p) )

Because incomes depend on prices

So demands are just functions of pxi

h = xih(p)

“Rival”: extra consumers require additional resources. Same as “consumer: aggregation”

If all goods are private (rival) then aggregate demands can be written:

xi(p) = h xih(p)

xih(•) depends on holdings of

resources and shares

From firm’s supply of net output qi

f = qif(p)

standard supply functions/ demand for inputs

Aggregate:qi = f qi

f(p)valid if there are no externalities.

Derivation of xi(p)

Alf Bill The Market

p1

x1a x1

b x1

p1 p1

panel 1: Alf’s demand curve for good 1 panel 2: Bill’s demand curve for good 1 Horizontal line: one particular price Sum to get consumers’ demand Repeat to get the market demand curve

Page 90: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

90

Derivation of qi(p)

q1

p

low-costfirm

q2

p

high-cost firm

p

q1+q2

both firms

Supply curve firm 1 (from MC) Supply curve firm 2 Pick any price Sum of individual firms’ supply Repeat… The market supply curve

Subtract q and R from x to get E:

Demand

p1

x1

p1

Res

ourc

e st

ock

R1

1

E1

p1

Ei(p) := xi(p) – qi(p) – Ri

p1

Supplyq1

Page 91: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

91

Equilibrium in terms of Excess Demand

Equilibrium is characterised by a price vector p* 0 such that:

For every good i:

Ei(p*) 0

For each good i that has a positive price in equilibrium (i.e. if pi

* > 0):Ei(p*) = 0

If this is violated, then somebody, somewhere isn't maximising…

The materials balance condition (dressed up a bit)

You can only have excess supply of a good in equilibrium if the price of that good is 0

Using E to find the equilibrium

Five steps to the equilibrium allocation

1. From technology compute firms’ net output functions and profits

2. From property rights compute household incomes and thus household demands

3. Aggregate the xs and qs and use x, q, R to compute E

4. Find p* as a solution to the system of E functions

5. Plug p* into demand functions and net output functions to get the allocation

But this raises some questions about step 4

Page 92: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

92

Two fundamental properties…

Walras’ Law. For any price p:n

pi Ei(p) = 0i = 1

You only have to work with n-1 (rather than n) equations

Homogeneity of degree 0. For anyprice p and any t > 0 :

Ei(tp) = Ei(p)

You can normalise the prices by any positive number

Reminder: these hold for any competitive allocation, not just equilibrium

Price normalisation

We may need to convert from n numbers p1, p2,…pn to n1 relative prices The precise method is essentially arbitrary The choice of method depends on the purpose of your model It can be done in a variety of ways:

You could divide by

to give a

a numéraire

standard value system

pn

neat set of n-1 prices

plabourpMarsBar

“Marxian” theory of valueMars bar theory of valueset of prices that sum to 1

This method might seem strange

But it has a nice property

The set of all normalised prices is convex and compact

n

pii=1

Page 93: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

93

Normalised prices, n = 2

(1,0)

(0,1)

J={p: p0, p1+p2 = 1}

•(0, 0.25)

(0.75, 0) p1

p2 Purple line: set of normalised prices

Point on the line: the price vector (0,75, 0.25)

The existence problem

Imagine a rule that moves prices in direction of excess demand:• “if Ei >0, increase pi” • “if Ei <0 and pi >0, decrease pi”• An example of this under “stability” below

This rule uses the E-functions to map the set of prices into itself

An equilibrium exists if this map has a “fixed point” • a p* that is mapped into itself?

To find the conditions for this, use normalised prices• p J• J is a compact, convex set• So the mapping has a fixed point

We can examine this in the special case n = 2 • In this case normalisation implies that p2 1 p1

Page 94: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

94

Existence of equilibrium?

E10

1p1

(a) E-functions are: continuous, bounded below

(b) No equilibrium price where E crosses the axis

(c) E never crosses the axis

E0

1p1

E10

p1

(c)

(a)

(b)

p1*

Multiple equilibria

E10

1

p1 (a) Three equilibrium prices

(b) Suppose there were more of resource 1

(c) Suppose there were less of resource 1

E0

1

p1

E10

p1

(c)

(a)

(b)

Page 95: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

95

Adjustment and stability

Adjust prices according to sign of Ei:• If Ei > 0 then increase pi

• If Ei < 0 and pi > 0 then decrease pi

A linear tâtonnement adjustment mechanism:

Define distance d between p(t) and equilibrium p*

Given WARP, d falls with t under tâtonnement

Globally stable…

0

1

E1

Excess supply

Excess demand

E1(0)

p1(0)

E1(0)

p1(0)

p1

If E satisfies WARP thenthe system must converge…

Start with a very high price

Yields excess supply Under tâtonnement price falls

Start instead with a low price

Under tâtonnement price rises

Yields excess demand

p1*

Page 96: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

96

Not globally stable…

0

1

E1

Excess supply

Excess demand

p1

Start with a very high price

…now try a (slightly) low price

Start again with very low price

Check the “middle” crossing

…now try a (slightly) high price

Here WARP does not hold

Two locally stable equilibria

One unstable

Decentralisation again

A: The attainable setx2

x10

A = {x: x q+R, (q) 0}

purple line: prices B: The “Better-than-x* ” set

A

B

p1p2

B = {hxh: Uh(xh) Uh(x*h)}

Decentralisation if A, B are convex

x* maximises income over A

x* minimises expenditure over B

x*

Page 97: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

97

A non-convex technology

inputou

tput

The case with 1 firm

Rescaled case of 2 firms,

… 4 , 8 , 16

A: Limit set of averaging process

B: The “Better-than” set

A

• q*

q'B

Limiting attainable set is convex

Equilibrium q* is sustained by a mixture of firms at q° and q'

“separating” prices and equilibrium

Non-convex preferences

x1

x2

The case with 1 person

Rescaled case of 2 persons,

B: better-than set, continuum of consumers

A: the attainable set

A

“separating” prices and equilibrium

Limiting better-than set is convex

Equilibrium x* is sustained by a mixture of consumers at x° and x'

• x*

x'

B

Page 98: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

98

UNCERTAINTY AND RISK:Lectures 13 - 15

Quantitiesx scalar payoff under state x vector payoff under state Ri

resource stock of good i

Prices and incomepi price of good i

y money income

certainty-equivalent income

L loss

insurance premium

FunctionsU utility function

u felicity function

Other

state of the world set of all states of the world

P prospect

probability of state proportionate bond holding

r rate of return

E expectation

absolute risk aversion

relative risk aversion

Concepts state-of-the-world pay-off (outcome) x X prospects {x: }

ex ante before the realisation

ex post after the realisation

time

The ex-ante view

The ex-post view

The "moment of truth"

The time line

Page 99: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

99

The state-space diagram: #

xBLUE

xREDO

Consumption space under uncertainty: 2 states

P0: a prospect in the 1-good 2-state case

P0

payoff if RED occurs

45°

Payoffs: components of a prospect in the 2-state case

Diagonal: no equivalent in choice under certainty

The state-space diagram: #=3

The idea generalises: here we have 3 states

xBLUE

O

= {RED,BLUE,GREEN}

•P0

A prospect in the 1-good 3-state case

Page 100: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

100

Ranking prospects

xBLUE

xREDO

Greed: Prospect P1 is preferred to P0

Contours of the preference map

P1

P0

Implications of Continuity

xBLUE

xREDO

“Holes” in IC: preferences would violate continuity

P0

Remove holes to impose continuity

P0: an arbitrary prospect

E

Find point E by continuity

Income is the certainty equivalent of P0

Page 101: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

101

Reinterpret quasiconcavity

xBLUE

xREDO

Take an arbitrary prospect P0

Given continuous indifference curves…

P0

E

…find the certainty-equivalent prospect E

Points in the interior of line P0E represent mixtures of P0 and E

If U strictly quasiconcave P1 is preferred to P0

P1

A change in perception

xBLUE

xREDO

The prospect P0 and certainty-equivalent prospect E (as before)

Suppose RED begins to seem less likely

P0

P1

E

Then prospect P1 (not P0) appears equivalent to E

Green curves: ICs after the change

This alters the slope of the ICs

Page 102: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

102

The independence axiom

Let P(z) and P′(z) be any two distinct prospects such that the payoff in state-of-the-world is z• x = x′ = z

If U(P(z)) ≥ U(P′(z)) for some z then U(P(z)) ≥ U(P′(z)) for all z

One and only one state-of-the-world can occur• So, assume that the payoff in one state is fixed for all prospects• Level at which payoff is fixed has no bearing on the orderings over

prospects where payoffs differ in other states of the world

We can see this by partitioning the state space for > 2

Independence axiom: illustration

A case with 3 states-of-the-world

Compare prospects with the same payoff under GREEN

Ordering of these prospects should not depend on the size of the payoff under GREEN

xBLUE

O

What if we compare all of these points…?

Or all of these points…?

Or all of these?

Page 103: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

103

The “revealed likelihood” axiom Let x and x′ be two payoffs such that x is weakly preferred to x′

Let 0 and 1 be any two subsets of

Define two prospects:

• P0 := {x′ if 0 and x if 0}

• P1 := {x′ if 1 and x if 1}

If U(P1) ≥ U(P0) for some such x and x′ then U(P1) ≥ U(P0) for all such x and x′

Induces a consistent pattern over subsets of states-of-the-world

Revealed likelihood: example

1 apple ≽ 1 banana1 cherry ≽ 1 date

apple appleapple

apple

applebanana banana

apple apple appleapple bananabanana

bananaP2:P1:

States of the world (only one colour will occur)

Assume preferences over fruit

Consider these two prospects

Choose a prospect: P1 or P2?

Another two prospects

Is your choice between P3 and P4

the same as between P1 and P2?

cherry cherrycherry

cherry

cherrydate date

cherry cherry cherrycherry datedate

dateP4:P3:

Page 104: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

104

A key resultA result that is central to the analysis of uncertainty

Introducing the three new axioms:• State irrelevance

• Independence

• Revealed likelihood

…implies that preferences must be representable in the form of a von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function:

ux

Alternatively, write as Eux• “expectation” uses the numbers to weight payoff evaluations ux

Implications of vNM structure (1)

xBLUE

xREDO

Slope where it crosses the 45º ray?

A typical IC

Ratio RED/BLUE : from vNM structure

So all ICs have same slope on 45º ray

RED– _____BLUE

Page 105: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

105

Implications of vNM structure (2)

xBLUE

xREDO

RED– _____

BLUE

P0: given income prospectvNM structure: slope is given

Ex

Mean income, Ex

P0

P1

P

Extend line through P0 and P to P1

By quasiconcavity U( ) U(P0)

April 2018

Risk aversion and concavity of u

Use the interpretation of risk aversion as quasiconcavity

If individual is risk averse then U( ) U(P0)

Given the vNM structure…• u(Ex) REDu(xRED) + BLUEu(xBLUE)• u(REDxRED+BLUExBLUE) REDu(xRED) + BLUEu(xBLUE)

So the function u is concave

Page 106: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

106

The “felicity” function

u

xxBLUE xRED

If u is strictly concave then person is risk averse

If u is a straight line then person is risk-neutral

xBLUE, xRED: payoffs in states BLUE and RED

Diagram plots utility level (u) against payoffs (x)

If u is strictly convex then person is a risk lover

u of the average of xBLUE

and xRED higher than the expected u of xBLUE and of xRED

u of the average of xBLUE and xRED equals the expected u of xBLUE and of xRED

Attitudes to risk

u(x)

xBLUExxREDEx

Risk-loving

u(x)

xBLUExxREDEx

Risk-neutral

u(x)

xBLUExxREDEx

Risk-averse

Shape of u associated with risk attitude

Neutrality: will just accept a fair gamble

Aversion: rejects some better-than-fair gambles

Loving: accepts some unfair gambles

Page 107: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

107

Risk premium and risk aversion

xBLUE

xREDO

RED– _____

BLUE

: certainty equivalent income

P0: given income prospect

Slope gives probability ratio

Ex

Ex: mean income

Orange gap: the risk premium

P0

P

Risk premium:

Amount that amount you

would sacrifice to eliminate

the risk

Useful additional way of

characterising risk attitude

Risk premium: an example

u

u(x)

xBLUE

xxRED

u(xBLUE)

u(xRED)

Ex

u(Ex)

Eu(x )

Expected payoff and the utility of expected payoff

Expected utility and the certainty-equivalent

The risk premium again

Utility values of two payoffs

Page 108: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

108

Change the u-function

u

xBLUExxRED

u(xBLUE)

u(xRED)

Ex

Take u-function and distribution of x as before

Now make the u-function “flatter”

u(xBLUE)

Making the u-function less curved reduces the risk premium Ex

…and vice versa

More of this later

Absolute and relative risk aversionDefine absolute and relative risk aversion for scalar payoffs

uxx(x) uxx(x)(x) := ; (x) := x

ux(x) ux(x)• For risk-averse individuals • For risk-neutral individuals

independent of scale and origin of u• can see this from the definitions• are two different ways of capturing “curvature” of u

The definitions are linked:

(x) = x (x)

d(x) d(x) = (x) + x dx dx

Page 109: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

109

Special cases: CARA and CRRA1. Constant Absolute Risk Aversion

• Assume that (x) = for all x

• Felicity function must take the form

1 u(x) = ex

2. Constant Relative Risk Aversion

• Assume that (x) = for all x

• Felicity function must take the form

1 u(x) = x1

1

Each induces a distinctive pattern of indifference curves…

Constant Absolute Risk AversionCase where = ½Slope of IC is same along 45° ray (standard vNM)

For CARA slope of IC is same along any 45° linexBLUE

xREDO

Page 110: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

110

Constant Relative Risk AversionCase where = 2Slope of IC is same along 45° ray (standard vNM)For CRRA slope of IC is same along any ray

ICs are homotheticxBLUE

xREDO

Lotteries

Consider lottery as a particular type of uncertain prospect

Take an explicit probability model

Assume a finite number of states-of-the-world

Associated with each state are:• A known payoff x ,• A known probability ≥ 0

Lottery is probability distribution over the “prizes” x, =1,2,…,• The probability distribution is just the vector := (,,…,)

• Of course, + +…+ = 1

What about preferences?

Page 111: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

111

The probability diagram: #=2

BLUE

RED (1,0)

(0,1)

interior of line: cases where 0 < < 1

Vertical: probability of state BLUEEndpoints: cases of perfect certainty

Horizontal: probability of state RED

Marked point: the case (0.75, 0.25)

•(0, 0.25)

(0.75, 0)

Only points on the purple line make sense

This is an 1-dimensional example of a simplex

The probability diagram: #=3

0

BLUE

RED

Third axis corresponds to probability of state GREEN

(1,0,0)

(0,0,1)

(0,1,0)

Vertices of triangle: three cases of perfect certainty

Interior of triangle: cases where 0 < < 1

•(0, 0, 0.25)

(0.5, 0, 0)

(0, 0.25 , 0)

Marked point: the case (0.5, 0.25, 0.25)

Only points on the purple triangle make sense,

This is a 2-dimensional example of a simplex

Page 112: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

112

Preferences over lotteries Take probability distributions as objects of choice

• lotteries °, ', ",…

Each lottery has same payoff structure• state-of-the-world has payoff x• probability ° or ' or " … depending on which lottery

Axioms of preference over lotteries • Transitivity over lotteries

• If °≽' and ' ≽ " then °≽"

• Independence of lotteries• If °≽ ' and (0,1) then ° ]" ≽ ' ] "

• Continuity over lotteries• If °≻'≻" then there are numbers and such that• ° ]" ≻ ' and ' ≻ ° ]"

Basic result Take the axioms transitivity, independence, continuity Imply that preferences must be representable in the form of a

von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function:

ux

or equivalently:

where ux

So we can also see the EU model as a weighted sum of s

Page 113: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

113

-indifference curves

ICs over probabilities: straight lines

Increase in the size of BLUE increases slope

(1,0,0)

(0,0,1)

(0,1,0) .

Trade

Page 114: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

114

Contingent goods: equilibrium trade

Oa

Ob

xREDa

xREDb

xBLUEb

xBLUEa

1st diagonal: certainty line for Alf Alf's indifference curves (Cyan)

2nd diagonal: certainty line for Bill

Bill's indifference curves (Green)

• Endowment point (top left)

Red line: eqm prices & allocation

Trade: problems

Do all these markets exist? • If there are states-of-the-world…

• …there are n of contingent goods

• Could be a huge number

Consider introduction of financial assets

Take a particularly simple form of asset:• a “contingent security”

• pays $1 if state occurs

Can we use this to simplify the problem?

Page 115: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

115

Attainable set: buying a risky asset

xBLUE

xRED

P

P0

y

y_

_ _

A

P : endowment

P0: if all resources put into bonds

Green area: all points belong to A

Can you sell bonds to others?

Can you borrow to buy bonds?

Bottom right: If loan shark willing to finance

[1+rº]y_

[1+r' ]y_

y+r′, y+r_ _

[1+r′ ]y, [1+r]y_ _

Attainable set: insurance

xBLUE

xRED

Py

y_

_ _

A

P0: endowment

P : Full insurance at premium

Green area: all points belong to A

Can you overinsure?

Can you bet on your loss?

P0y0 – L

y0

L –

Page 116: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

116

A

1

5

7

4

6

3

2

Consumer choice with a variety of financial assets

xBLUE

xRED

Payoff if all in cash (1)

Payoff if all in bond 2

Payoff if all in bond 3, 4, 5,…

Lines joining: payoffs from mixtures

Green area: attainable set

P*: the optimum

5

4

P*

only bonds 4 and 5 used at the optimum

Problem and its solution

But corner solutions may also make sense…

Page 117: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

117

A

Consumer choice: safe and risky assets

xBLUE

xRED

y

y_

_

P*

P0

A: attainable set, portfolio problem

_ P

P : equilibrium -- playing safe

P0: equilibrium, "plunging"

P*: equilibrium, mixed portfolio

Results (1)Will the agent take a risk?

Can we rule out playing safe?

Consider utility in the neighbourhood of = 0

Eu( + r) ———— | = uy( ) E r

|

uy is positive

So, if expected return on bonds is positive, agent will increase utility by moving away from = 0

Page 118: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

118

Results (2) Examine the effect on * of changing a parameter

• take the FOC for an interior solution E (ruy( + *r)) = 0

• differentiate this equation w.r.t. the parameter• for example differentiate w.r.t. endowment (initial wealth)

E (ruyy( + *r)) + E (r2 uyy( + *r)) */ = 0

* E (ruyy( + *r)) —— = – ———————— E (r2 uyy( + * r))

• denominator is unambiguously negative

• to sign the numerator we need to impose more structure

• if ARA is decreasing then numerator is positive

Theorem: If an individual has a vNM utility function with DARA and holds a positive amount of the risky asset then the amount invested in the risky asset will increase as initial wealth increases

A

A: Attainable set, portfolio problem

An increase in endowment

P*

xBLUE

xRED

y

y_

_ P**

o

y+_

y+_

ICs: DARA Preferences

P*: Equilibrium

Arrow: increase in endowment Light dotted line: locus of constant

P**: New equilibrium

Page 119: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

119

xRED

A

A rightward shift in the distribution

xBLUE

y

y_

_

P**

P*

P0

o

A; Attainable set, portfolio problem

_ P

ICs: DARA Preferences

P*: Equilibrium

Arrow: change in distribution

Light dotted line: locus of constant

P**: new equilibrium

A

An increase in spread

xBLUE

xRED

y

y_

_

P*

P0

A; Attainable set, portfolio problem

_ P

P*: equilibrium, given preferences Arrow: Increase r′, reduce r

y+*r′, y+*r_ _

P* stays put So must have reducedYou don’t need DARA for this

Page 120: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

120

WELFARE:Lectures 16 - 19

Quantitiesqi

f net output by f of i

xih consumption by h of i

Rih ownership by h of resource i

Prices and incomepi price of good i

yh money income of h

Th tax revenue raised from h

loss

Functions constitution

Ch cost function of h

Uh utility function of h

Vh indirect utility function of h

vh utility of h as function of f production function of firm f

W social welfare function

social evaluation function

Other social state

set of all social states

utility possibility set

Social objectives Two dimensions of social objectives

objective 1

Set of feasible social states

A social preference map?

Assume we know the set of all social states

How can we draw a social preference map?

Can it be related to individual preferences?

Page 121: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

121

Elements of a constitution

Social states • can incorporate all sorts of information: • economic allocations, • political rights, etc

Individual (extended) preferences over • ≽ ' means that person h thinks state is at least as good

as state '

An aggregation rule for the preferences so as to underpin the constitution• A function defined on individual (extended) preferences

The social ordering and the constitutionWhere does this ordering come from?

Presumably from individuals' orderings over • assumes that social values are individualistic

Define a profile of preferences as• a list of orderings, one for each member of society

• (≽ , ≽ , ≽ , …)

The constitution is an aggregation function • defined on a set of profiles

• yields an ordering ≽

So the social ordering is ≽ = (≽ , ≽ , ≽ ,…)

Page 122: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

122

Axioms and a resultUniversality

• should be defined for all profiles of preferences

Pareto Unanimity• if all consider that is better than ', then the social ordering should rank

as better than '

Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives• if two profiles are identical over a subset of then the derived social

orderings should also be identical over this subset

Non-Dictatorship• no one person alone can determine the social ordering

Kenneth Arrow’s Theorem:

There is no constitution satisfying these axioms

Relaxing universalityCould it be that the universal domain criterion is just

too demanding?Should we insist on coping with any and every set of

preferences, no matter how bizarre?Perhaps imposing restrictions on admissible

preferences might avoid the Arrow impossibility resultHowever, we run into trouble even with very simple

versions of social states

Page 123: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

123

Alf, Bill, Charlie decide

' "

pref

eren

ce

defence spending

AlfBill

Charlie

1-dimensional social statesScaling of axes is arbitraryThree possible states

Views about defence spending

Each individual has dramatically different views

But all three sets of preferences are “single peaked”

How do they decide?

′ ≻ ?

Alf Bill Charlie Verdict

′′ ≻ ′?

≻ ′′?

Bill

Alf, Bill, Charlie decide (2)

pref

eren

ce

defence spending

Bill

' "

Alf

Charlie

Same states as before

Same preferences as before

Now Bill changes his mind

Now one set of preferences is no longer “single peaked”

How do they decide?

′ ≻ ?

Alf Bill Charlie Verdict

′′ ≻ ′?

≻ ′′?

Page 124: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

124

Alternative voting systems…Relaxing IIA involves an approach that modifies the

type of “aggregation rule”Simple majority voting may make too little use of

information about individual orderings or preferences Here are some alternatives:

• de Borda (weighted voting)• Single transferable vote• Simple elimination voting

None of these is intrinsically ideal • Consider the results produced by third example

The IOC Decision Process

An elimination process 1997: Appears to give an orderly convergence

• Athens is preferred to Rome irrespective of the presence of other alternatives

1993: Violates IIA• Ordering of Sydney, Peking depends on whether other alternatives are

present

Page 125: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

125

A definition of efficiency

The basis for evaluating social states: vh()

the utility level enjoyed by person h under social state

A social state is Pareto superior to state ' if:1. For all h: vh() vh(')2. For some h: vh() > vh(')

Note the similarity with the concept of blocking by a coalition

“feasibility” could be determined in terms of the usual economic criteria

A social state is Paretoefficient if:1. It is feasible 2. No other feasible state

is Pareto superior to

Derive the utility possibility set From the attainable set A

AA

(x1a, x2

a)(x1

b, x2b)

a)

2 )a=Ua(x1

a, x2a)

b=Ub(x1b, x2

b)

…take an allocation

Evaluate utility for each agent

Repeat to get utility possibility set

a

b

Page 126: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

126

Finding an efficient allocation

max L( [x ], [q], ) :=

U1(x1) + hh [Uh(x h) h] f f f (q f) + i i[qi + Ri xi]

where xi = h xih, qi = f qi

f

Differentiate L w.r.t xih. If xi

h, xjh positive at the optimum:

hUih(xh) = i hUj

h(xh) = j

Differentiate L w.r.t qif. If qi

f , qjf nonzero at the optimum:

f if (qf) = i f j

f (qf) = j

Interpreting the FOC

Uih(xh) i

———— = —Uj

h (xh) j

for every firm:MRT = shadow price ratio

for every household: MRS = shadow price ratio

From the FOCs for any household h and goods i and j:

if(qf) i

———— = —j

f (qf) j

From the FOCs for any firm fand goods i and j:

Page 127: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

127

Ob

Oa

x1b

x1a

x2a

x2b

Efficiency in an Exchange Economy

Purple: the contract curve

Cyan: Alf’s indifference curves

Green: Bill’s indifference curves

Set of efficient allocations is the contract curve

Includes cases where Alf or Bill is very poor

Allocations where MRS12

a = MRS12b

253

Efficiency with production

Contours: h’s indifference curves

0

slope of dashed line: MRS

h’s consumption in the efficient allocation

MRS = MRT at efficient point

x2h

x1h

xh^

Dark green: firm f’s technology set

f’s net output in the efficient allocation

q2f

q1f

qf^

Page 128: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

128

Two welfare theorems

Welfare theorem 1• Assume a competitive equilibrium

• What is its efficiency property?

THEOREM: if all consumers are greedy and there are no externalities then a competitive equilibrium is efficient

Welfare theorem 2• Pick any Pareto-efficient allocation

• Can we find a property distribution d so that this allocation is a CE for d?

THEOREM: if, in addition to conditions for theorem 1, there are no non-convexities then an arbitrary PE allocation be supported by a competitive equilibrium

255

Ob

Oa

x1b

x1a

x2a

x2b

Supporting a PE allocation

purple curve: contract curve

Support allocation by a CE

This needs adjustment of the initial endowment

Lump-sum transfers may be tricky to implement

Allocations where MRS12

a = MRS12b

red dot: an efficient allocation

pink line: supporting prices

[x]^

[R]

green dot: property distribution

red arrow: lump-sum transfer

p1p2

Page 129: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

129

Individual household behaviour

Household h’s indifference curves

0

Supporting price ratio = MRS

:h’s consumption in the efficient allocation

h’s consumption in the allocation is utility-maximising for h

x2h

x1h

h’s consumption in the allocation is cost-minimising for h

xh^

p1p2

Supporting a PE allocation (production)

Green area: irm f’s technology set

0

Supporting price ratio = MRT

: f’s net output in the efficient allocation

p1p2

f’s net output in the allocation is profit-maximising for f

q2f

q1f

qf^

258

Page 130: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

130

Firm f makes “wrong” choice

q2f

0q1

f

Firm f ’s production function violates second theorem

Suppose we want to allocate to f

Introduce prices

f's chooses at those prices

p1p2

qf~

qf^

Big fixed-cost component to producing good 1

“market failure” once again

PE allocations – two issues

good

2

0good 1

Same production function

Implicit prices for MRS=MRT

Competitive outcome

Issue 1 – what characterises the PE?

Issue 2 – how to implement the PE

or at second red dot?

Is PE at first red dot…?

Page 131: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

131

Indecisiveness of PE

a

b Construct set as before

Dots on boundary: 2 efficient points

Boundary points cannot be compared on efficiency grounds

First shading: Points superior to

v

v

Second shading: points superior to '

and ' cannot be compared on efficiency grounds

261

“Potential” Pareto superiority

Define to be potentially superior to ' if :• there is a * which is actually Pareto superior to '

• * is “accessible” from

To make use of this concept we need to define accessibility• use a tool from the theory of consumer welfare

CVh(' ): the monetary value the welfare change for person h…• …of a change from state ' to state • …valued in terms of the prices at

CVh > 0 means a welfare gain; CVh < 0 a welfare loss

THEOREM: a necessary and sufficient condition for to be potentially superior to ' is

h CVh(' ) > 0

262

Page 132: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

132

Applying potential superiority

a

is not superior to ' and ' is not superior to

* is superior to

There could be lots of points accessible by lump-sum transfers

' is potentially superior to

Blue shading: points accessible from '

v

b

v

v*

263

Re-examine potential superiority

a

b

v

v

points accessible from

points accessible from

Blue shading: process from to ', as before

Yellow shading: process in reverse from ' to

Combine the two

is potentially superior to and …

is potentially superior to !

264

Page 133: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

133

Production externalityOne firm influences another’s production conditions

• affects other firms’ cost curves

• if firm f’s output produces an externality

• production & cost function of firm g has f’s output as a parameter

When f produces good 1 it causes pollution• could affect other firms g = 1, 2, …, f – 1, f + 1, …, nf

• the more f produces good 1, the greater the damage to g

How much damage?• consider the impact of pollution on firm g

• will enter the production function g()Use the firm’s transformation curve

Externality: Production possibilities

low emissions by firm f

q1g

q2g

high emissions by firm f

Firm g affected by others' output of good 1 Φ ;

If g() = 0 an increase in negative externality results in g() > 0

Production possibilities, firm g

g() < 0

g() = 0g() > 0 Production possibilities, if firm

f’s emissions increase

Page 134: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

134

Find conditions for efficiency Problem is to maximise U1(x1) subject to:

, 1, … ,

Φ ; 0, 1, … ,, 1, …

The LagrangianΣ · Σ Φ · Σ

FOCs for an interior maximum. For all h, f: , 1, 2, … ,

ΦΦ ·

Φ , 2, … ,

Interpretation

Evaluate marginal impact of f’s output using good 2 as numeraire:

≔1

Φ

Φ ·

From first of the FOCs:

=

Use the definition of . Then the other FOCs giveΦ

Φ

This is the efficiency criterion:• instead of the condition “MRT=shadow price ratio” • we have a modified marginal rule

Page 135: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

135

Efficiency with production externality

1 1— = —2 2

1 1— = — + externality 2 2

q1`

q2f

f

qf^

qf~

Production possibilities

Taking account of externality

If externality is ignored

Produce less of good 1 for efficiency

Production externality: policy

Take the modified FOC

Rearrange:

Introduce market prices:

A tax/subsidy:

The term t “corrects” the market prices• for a negative externality we have t > 0 (a tax)

• for a positive externality we have t < 0 (a subsidy)

Page 136: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

136

Externality: a private solution? Efficient outcome through individual initiative?

Assume (1) just two firms (2) just two goods• assumption (1) may be important

• assumptions (2) is unimportant

Firm 1’s output of good 1 imposes costs on firm 2

Full information:• each firm knows the other’s production function

• externality is common knowledge

• activity can be monitored

• communication is costless

Firm 2 (victim) has an interest in communicating• does this by setting up a financial incentive for firm 1

• how should this be structured?

The victim’s problem and solutionFirm 2 (the victim) offers firm 1 a side-payment

• accounted for in the computation of profits

• a is a control variable for firm 2 in the maximisation problem:

max,

Φ q2 ;

FOCs: Φ q2 ; 0

1dΦ q2 ;

ddd

0

Using the definition of the externality and rearranging:

1 Φ q2 ;dd

0

dd

Page 137: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

137

The perpetrator’s problem and solutionFor firm 2’s plan to work, firm 1 has to know about it

• realises that bribe is conditional on a variable under its own control

• has the maximisation problem:

max Φ q1

FOCs: dd

Φ q1 0

Φ q1 0, 2, … ,

Substituting in from firm 2’s solution and rearranging:Φ q1

Φ q1

This is exactly the condition for efficiency!

Private solution: result Bribe function has internalised the externality

• Firm 2 conditions side-payment on observable output of good 1

• Firm 1’s responds rationally to the side-payment

FOC conditions same as before• Private solution induces an efficient allocation

• Implements the same allocation as the Pigovian tax

• But no external guidance is required

It should be independent of where the law places the responsibility for the pollution (Coase’s result)

Page 138: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

138

x1 0

x2

Price distortion: efficiency loss

Production possibilities

An efficient allocation

Some other inefficient allocation

•x

•x*

p*

At x* producers and consumers face same prices At x producers and consumers face different prices

Price "wedge" forced by the distortion

Waste measurement: a method

To measure loss we use a reference point

Take this as competitive equilibrium• defines a set of reference prices

Quantify the effect of a notional price change:• pi := pi – pi*• This is [actual price of i] – [reference price of i]

Evaluate the equivalent variation for household h :• EVh = Ch(p*,h) – Ch(p, h) – [y*h – yh]• This is (consumer costs) – (income)

Aggregate over agents to get a measure of loss,

Page 139: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

139

x1 0

x2

If producer prices constant…

Production possibilities

Reference allocation and prices

Actual allocation and prices

•x

•x*

p*

Measure cost in terms of good 2

Losses to consumers are C(p*, ) C(p, )

Cost of at prices p

C(p, )

Cost of at prices p*

C(p*, )

Change in valuation of output

p

is difference between |C(p*, ) C(p, )| and

Efficiency loss: policy

p1

compensateddemand curve

p1

p1*

x1h

x1h

x1*

Equilibrium price and quantityThe tax raises consumer price…

…and reduces demand

Gain to the government

Loss to the consumer

Waste

A model of a commodity tax

Waste given by size of triangle

Sum over h to get total waste

Known as deadweight loss of tax

Page 140: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

140

Tax: computation of waste

The tax imposed on good 1 forces a price wedge

• p1 = tp1* > 0 where p1

* is the untaxed price of the good

h’s demand for good 1 is lower with the tax:

• x1** = x1

* x1h and x1

h < 0

Revenue raised by government from h:

• Th = tp1* x1

**= x1**p1 > 0

Absolute size of loss to h is

• h= ∫ x1h dp1 ≈ x1

** p1 − ½ x1hp1 = Th − ½ t p1

* x1h > Th

Use the definition of elasticity

• := p1x1h / x1

hp1< 0

Net loss from tax (for h) is

• h = h− Th = − ½tp1* x1

h = − ½tp1x1** = − ½t Th

Overall net loss from tax is ½ |tT

p1

compensateddemand curve

p1

p1*

x1h

x1h

Size of waste depends upon elasticity

low: relatively small waste

high: relatively large waste

Redraw previous example

p1

p1

p1*

x1h

x1h

p1

p1

p1*

x1h

x1h

x1h

p1

p1

x1h

p1*

Page 141: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

141

Using a SWF

a

b

: the utility-possibility set

Red dot: social-welfare optimum?

Social welfare contours

W defined on utility levels

Not on orderings

Imposes several restrictions…

..and raises several questions

W(a, b,... )

“Veil of ignorance”: formalisation

Individualistic welfare:W(1, 2, 3, ...)

use theory of choice under uncertainty to find shape of W

vN-M form of utility function: u(x)

Equivalently:

probability assigned to u : cardinal utility function,

independent of utility payoff in state

A suitable assumption about “probabilities”?

nh1

W = — hnh h=1

welfare is expected utility from a "lottery on identity“

Replace by set of identities {1,2,..., nh}:

h hh

An additive form of the welfare function

Page 142: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

142

Questions about “equal ignorance”

h

identity

|

nhh|

1

|

2

|

3

|

Construct a lottery on identity

Light blue: “equal ignorance” assumption

Pink: people know their identity with certainty

Dark blue: Intermediate case

The “equal ignorance” assumption: h = 1/nh

But is this appropriate?

Or should we assume that people know their identities with certainty?

Or is the "truth" somewhere between?

From an allocation to social welfare

From the attainable set...

AA

(x1a, x2

a)(x1

b, x2b)

...take an allocation

Evaluate utility for each agent

Plug into W to get social welfare

a)

2 )a=Ua(x1

a, x2a)

b=Ub(x1b, x2

b)

W(a, b)

Take the individualistic welfare modelW(1, 2, 3, ...)

Assume everyone is selfish: h = Uh(xh) , h=1,2,..., nh

Substitute in the above:W(U1(x1), U2(x2), U3(x3), ...)

What happens to welfare if we vary the allocation in A?

Page 143: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

143

Varying the allocation Differentiate w.r.t. xi

h : dh = Ui

h(xh) dxih

The effect on h if commodity i is changed

Sum over i: n

dh = Uih(xh) dxi

hi=1

The effect on h if all commodities are changed

Differentiate W with respect to h:nh

dW = Wh dh

h=1

Changes in utility change social welfare

Substitute for dh in the above:nh n

dW = Wh Uih(xh) dxi

h

h=1 i=1

So changes in allocation change welfare

The SWF maximum problem

First component of the problem: W(U1(x1), U2(x2), U3(x3), ...)

The objective function

Second component of the problem: nh(x) 0, xi = xi

hh=1

Feasibility constraint

The Social-welfare Lagrangian:nhW(U1(x1), U2(x2),...) − ( xh )

h=1

Constraint subsumes technological feasibility and materials balance

FOCs for an interior maximum:Wh (...) Ui

h(xh) − i(x) = 0From differentiating Lagrangianwith respect to xi

h

Page 144: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

144

Solution to SWF maximum problem

From FOCs: Ui

h(xh) Uiℓ(xℓ)

——— = ———Uj

h(xh) Ujℓ(xℓ)

MRS equated across all h

We’ve met this condition before - Pareto efficiency

Also from the FOCs: Wh Ui

h(xh) = Wℓ Uiℓ(xℓ)

social marginal utility of ice cream equated across all h

Relate marginal utility to prices:Ui

h(xh) = Vyhpi

This is valid if all consumers optimise

Substituting into the above:Wh Vy

h = Wℓ Vyℓ

At optimum the welfare value of $1 is equated across all h. Call this common value M

Differentiate the SWF w.r.t. {yh}:nh

dW = Wh dh

h=1

Social welfare, income, expenditure

nh

= M dyh

h=1

nh

= WhVyh dyh

h=1

Social welfare can be expressed as:W(U1(x1), U2(x2),...) = W(V1(p,y1), V2(p,y2),...)

SWF in terms of direct utility and in terms of indirect utility

Changes in utility and change social welfare related to income

Differentiate the SWF w.r.t. pi :nh

dW = WhVihdpi

h=1

.

Changes in utility and change social welfare related to pricesnh

= –WhVyh xi

hdpih=1

nh

= – M xihdpi

h=1

THEOREM: in the neighbourhood of a welfare optimum welfare changes are measured by changes in national income / national expenditure

Page 145: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

145

Income-distribution space: nh=2

Bill's

income

Alf'sincome

O

The income space: 2 persons

y: An income distribution

y

45°

Note the similarity with diagrams used in the analysis of uncertainty

Alf'sincome

Welfare contours

Eyya

yb

Ey

y

y: An arbitrary income distribution Contours of W Mirror image: swap identities

Pink diagonal: distributions with same mean

Anonymity implies symmetry of W

: Equally-distributed-equivalent

Ey is mean income

Principle of Transfers: Richer-to-poorer transfers increase welfare

Quasi-concavity of W implies that social welfare respects this principle

is income that, if received by all, would yield same level of soc welf as y

≔ is prop of income society

would give up to eliminate inequality

Page 146: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

146

Using the inequality-sensitive SWF Rearrange the last equation:

• = Ey [1 ]• “welfare = mean income [1 inequality]”

It makes sense to write W in the special additive formnh1W = — yh= E yh

nh h=1

• function is the social evaluation function

Also makes sense to take constant relative-inequality aversion:1y = —— y1 –

1 –

• is the index of inequality aversion• the larger is , the larger is I for any given income distribution

Social views: inequality aversion

½

yb

yaO

yb

yaO

yb

yaO

= 0: Indifference to inequality

= ½: Mild inequality aversionyb

yaO

= : Strong inequality aversion

= : Priority to poorest

“Benthamite” case ( = 0): nh

W= yh

h=1

Atkinson SWF, general case ( ):

nh

W = [yh]1 / [1 ]h=1

“Rawlsian” case ( ): W = min yh

h

Page 147: EC202 Handout - London School of Economicsdarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/EC202/EC202_Handout.pdf · Diagonal line: set of points where cost of input is c, a constant One such “isocost” line

03/12/2018

147

Social values and welfare optimum

ya

yb The income-possibility set Y

Welfare contours ( = ½)

Welfare contours ( = 0)

Welfare contours ( = )

Y derived from set A

Nonconvexity, asymmetry come from heterogeneity of households

y* maximises total income irrespective of distribution

y*** gives priority to equality; then maximises income subject to that

Y

y*

y***

y** y** trades off some income for greater equality

=

( = 0

= ½

Microeconomics in practice: Social welfare in the US

• Source: Current Population Surveys• Equivalised incomes, 2015 USD

35,000

40,000

45,000

50,000

55,000

60,000

65,000

70,000

75,000

80,000

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

EDE Income US: 1967-2015