Disputes in International Investment and Trade...Introduction International investment and trade...

38
Disputes in International Investment and Trade Ralph Ossa, Robert W. Staiger and Alan O. Sykes University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford April 2019 Ossa, Staiger and Sykes University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 1 / 28

Transcript of Disputes in International Investment and Trade...Introduction International investment and trade...

Disputes in International Investment andTrade

Ralph Ossa, Robert W. Staiger and Alan O. Sykes

University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford

April 2019

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 1 / 28

Introduction

International investment and trade agreements employ disputesettlement procedures that differ markedly along three key dimensions

standing (i.e., the right to file grievances)

the nature of the remedy

the remedial period

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 2 / 28

Introduction

International investment and trade agreements employ disputesettlement procedures that differ markedly along three key dimensions

standing (i.e., the right to file grievances)

the nature of the remedy

the remedial period

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 2 / 28

Introduction

International investment and trade agreements employ disputesettlement procedures that differ markedly along three key dimensions

standing (i.e., the right to file grievances)

the nature of the remedy

the remedial period

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 2 / 28

Introduction

International investment and trade agreements employ disputesettlement procedures that differ markedly along three key dimensions

standing (i.e., the right to file grievances)

the nature of the remedy

the remedial period

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 2 / 28

Introduction

In the state-to-state dispute settlement (SSDS) procedures of atypical trade agreement, only governments have standing

private investors also have standing in the investor-state disputesettlement (ISDS) procedures employed by investment agreements

Trade agreements typically employ tariff retaliation as the remedy forviolation of the agreement

the award of cash damages is the norm in investment disputes

And trade agreements typically provide for only prospective remedies

the damages awarded in investment disputes routinely cover past aswell as future harms

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 3 / 28

Introduction

In the state-to-state dispute settlement (SSDS) procedures of atypical trade agreement, only governments have standing

private investors also have standing in the investor-state disputesettlement (ISDS) procedures employed by investment agreements

Trade agreements typically employ tariff retaliation as the remedy forviolation of the agreement

the award of cash damages is the norm in investment disputes

And trade agreements typically provide for only prospective remedies

the damages awarded in investment disputes routinely cover past aswell as future harms

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 3 / 28

Introduction

In the state-to-state dispute settlement (SSDS) procedures of atypical trade agreement, only governments have standing

private investors also have standing in the investor-state disputesettlement (ISDS) procedures employed by investment agreements

Trade agreements typically employ tariff retaliation as the remedy forviolation of the agreement

the award of cash damages is the norm in investment disputes

And trade agreements typically provide for only prospective remedies

the damages awarded in investment disputes routinely cover past aswell as future harms

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 3 / 28

Introduction

These differences underpin major policy debates and controversies

Senator Elizabeth Warren: “Conservatives who believe in U.S.sovereignty should be outraged that ISDS would shift power fromAmerican courts ... to unaccountable international tribunals.Libertarians should be offended that ISDS effectively would offer a freetaxpayer subsidy to countries with weak legal systems. Andprogressives should oppose ISDS because it would allow bigmultinationals to weaken labor and environmental rules.”A letter signed by 230 law/economics professors: ISDS “underminesthe important roles of our domestic and democratic institutions,threatens domestic sovereignty, and weakens the rule of law.”William Davey: the WTO system of prospective redemies givesviolators “a three-year free pass.”

We develop parallel models of trade agreements and investmentagreements and employ them to study these differences

we argue that the differences can be understood as arising from thefundamentally different problems that trade and investment agreementsare designed to solve

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 4 / 28

Introduction

These differences underpin major policy debates and controversies

Senator Elizabeth Warren: “Conservatives who believe in U.S.sovereignty should be outraged that ISDS would shift power fromAmerican courts ... to unaccountable international tribunals.Libertarians should be offended that ISDS effectively would offer a freetaxpayer subsidy to countries with weak legal systems. Andprogressives should oppose ISDS because it would allow bigmultinationals to weaken labor and environmental rules.”

A letter signed by 230 law/economics professors: ISDS “underminesthe important roles of our domestic and democratic institutions,threatens domestic sovereignty, and weakens the rule of law.”William Davey: the WTO system of prospective redemies givesviolators “a three-year free pass.”

We develop parallel models of trade agreements and investmentagreements and employ them to study these differences

we argue that the differences can be understood as arising from thefundamentally different problems that trade and investment agreementsare designed to solve

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 4 / 28

Introduction

These differences underpin major policy debates and controversies

Senator Elizabeth Warren: “Conservatives who believe in U.S.sovereignty should be outraged that ISDS would shift power fromAmerican courts ... to unaccountable international tribunals.Libertarians should be offended that ISDS effectively would offer a freetaxpayer subsidy to countries with weak legal systems. Andprogressives should oppose ISDS because it would allow bigmultinationals to weaken labor and environmental rules.”A letter signed by 230 law/economics professors: ISDS “underminesthe important roles of our domestic and democratic institutions,threatens domestic sovereignty, and weakens the rule of law.”

William Davey: the WTO system of prospective redemies givesviolators “a three-year free pass.”

We develop parallel models of trade agreements and investmentagreements and employ them to study these differences

we argue that the differences can be understood as arising from thefundamentally different problems that trade and investment agreementsare designed to solve

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 4 / 28

Introduction

These differences underpin major policy debates and controversies

Senator Elizabeth Warren: “Conservatives who believe in U.S.sovereignty should be outraged that ISDS would shift power fromAmerican courts ... to unaccountable international tribunals.Libertarians should be offended that ISDS effectively would offer a freetaxpayer subsidy to countries with weak legal systems. Andprogressives should oppose ISDS because it would allow bigmultinationals to weaken labor and environmental rules.”A letter signed by 230 law/economics professors: ISDS “underminesthe important roles of our domestic and democratic institutions,threatens domestic sovereignty, and weakens the rule of law.”William Davey: the WTO system of prospective redemies givesviolators “a three-year free pass.”

We develop parallel models of trade agreements and investmentagreements and employ them to study these differences

we argue that the differences can be understood as arising from thefundamentally different problems that trade and investment agreementsare designed to solve

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 4 / 28

Introduction

These differences underpin major policy debates and controversies

Senator Elizabeth Warren: “Conservatives who believe in U.S.sovereignty should be outraged that ISDS would shift power fromAmerican courts ... to unaccountable international tribunals.Libertarians should be offended that ISDS effectively would offer a freetaxpayer subsidy to countries with weak legal systems. Andprogressives should oppose ISDS because it would allow bigmultinationals to weaken labor and environmental rules.”A letter signed by 230 law/economics professors: ISDS “underminesthe important roles of our domestic and democratic institutions,threatens domestic sovereignty, and weakens the rule of law.”William Davey: the WTO system of prospective redemies givesviolators “a three-year free pass.”

We develop parallel models of trade agreements and investmentagreements and employ them to study these differences

we argue that the differences can be understood as arising from thefundamentally different problems that trade and investment agreementsare designed to solveOssa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 4 / 28

Standing

Who should have standing to file a court case and invoke the DSB?

only govs (SSDS)?

or also private agents (ESDS/ISDS)?

To focus on standing, we make two simplifying assumptions which welater relax

nature of the remedy: a court order amounts to “cease and desist,”and there are no damage payments as part of the court’s ruling

the remedial period: compliance is instantaneous, and there is nopre-compliance harm for which additional remedies might be desirable

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 5 / 28

Trade Agreements: Standing

Starting point: trade agreements are primarily concerned with marketaccess commitments

Our model tracks closely basic structure of Maggi and Staiger (2011)

For s ∈ σFT , FT is first best (Γ(s) ≡ γG (s) + γ∗G ∗(s) ≤ 0)For s ∈ σP , P is first best (Γ(s) > 0)

In states of world where obligation of importer gov under theagreement is vague (e.g., P allowed to address “serious injury”)

importer gov chooses τ ∈ FT ,Pforeign complainant chooses whether to file a complaint with DSB todispute a choice of P, DSB will rule based on noisy signal of Γ(s)

Equilibrium disputes reflect opportunistic behavior on the part ofimporter gov or foreign complainant to exploit incompleteness ofcontract and inaccuracy of DSB rulings

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 6 / 28

Trade Agreements: Standing

Let f ∈ G ∗,E ∗ denote foreign complainant with standing

Foreign complainant files iff τ = P and

Pr(DSB ruling is FT | s)× |γ∗f (s)| > c∗f (s) (1)

Importer gov chooses τ = P if either (1) fails or if (1) holds and

Pr(DSB ruling is P | s)× γG (s) > c(s) (2)

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 7 / 28

Trade Agreements: Standing

Assume dispute costs small relative to dispute stakes

Lemma 1.

1. In states s ∈ σFT : If DSB quality is high we have τ = FT and nodispute; if DSB quality is intermediate we have τ = P and a dispute; ifDSB quality is low we have τ = P and no dispute.

2. In states s ∈ σP : If DSB quality is high we have τ = P and no dispute;if DSB quality is intermediate we have τ = P and a dispute; if DSBquality is low we have τ = FT and no dispute.

⇒ Three sources of ineffi ciencies relative to the first best

one associated with the probability of DSB error

one associated with the cost of a dispute

one arising from distorted choices made “in the shadow of the court”

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 8 / 28

Trade Agreements: SSDS vs ESDS

Assumec∗G ∗ = c

∗E ∗ ≡ c∗ (Assumption 1)

|γ∗G ∗(s)| < |γ∗E ∗(s)| (Assumption 2)

⇒ Adopting ESDS rather than SSDS amounts to the foreign govdelegating filing decisions to a more aggressive filer than itself

filing decision under ESDS takes account of private benefits of litigationto the foreign exporters but ignores costs to other foreign actors

Define L (ESDS) as loss relative to first best under ESDS, L (SSDS)as loss relative to first best under SSDS

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 9 / 28

Trade Agreements: SSDS vs ESDS

Let qk(s) ∈ (0, 1/2) be probability that court issues “wrong” ruling

Define ∆E ∗,G ∗ ≡ L (ESDS)− L (SSDS)∆E ∗,G ∗ = ∑

s∈ΩPS

p (s) qk (s) |Γ (s)|+ c (s) + c∗ (s)

+ ∑s∈ΩFT

S

p (s) − [1− qk (s)] |Γ (s)|+ c (s) + c∗ (s) .

The first term is positive

reflecting s ∈ ΩPS where the effi cient choice τ = P was unchallenged

under SSDS but leads to a court filing under ESDS

The second term is also positive

reflecting s ∈ ΩFTS where the importer gov chooses ineffi cient τ = P

with impunity under the SSDS but a filing occurs under ESDSthe exporter gov does not see a filing as worth the dispute cost whilethe importer gov never benefits from a filing, hence value of theagreement to the two govs is reduced by these filings

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 10 / 28

Trade Agreements: SSDS vs ESDS

PropositionGovernments, but not their exporters, should have standing to bringdisputes in an optimally designed trade agreement. That is, an optimallydesigned trade agreement should include SSDS, but not ESDS.

Intuitively, under SSDS the govs themselves would adopt behaviorwhich leads to too much litigation, owing to the negative externaleffects that are not internalized in their decision to litigate

and so granting standing to private actors that would add to this(overly-) litigious behavior will lower the joint surplus obtained by thegovs under the agreement

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 11 / 28

BITs: Standing

Starting point: BITs are primarily concerned with solving a govcommitment problem

BIT used by host gov to make policy commitments to foreign investors

Two changes to the previous model

First, the host (formerly home) gov investment policy ι can be eitherT for “Taking”or FT for “Free Trade”

T a stand-in for a wide variety of investment policies the could amountto a “taking”broadly defined

Example of vague obligation in a BIT

T allowed “for a public purpose, provided that adequate and effectivecompensation is promptly paid”

And second, we introduce an ex-ante foreign investment stage

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 12 / 28

BITs: Standing

Host country small in world capital markets, faces infinitely elasticex-ante supply of foreign capital at world rate of return r ∗

investment made by a single investor facing elastic demand for output;once made, the investment is sunk

investment level I ∗ results in output level Q = I ∗, sold at marketclearing price P(I ∗) yielding operating profits PS (I ∗) = P (I ∗) I ∗ andconsumer surplus CS (I ∗) =

∫ ∞P (I ∗) D (P) dP

production/consumption of this output may generate a negative (local)externality e (I ∗, s) = e (s) I ∗, with either e (s) = 0 or e (s) > P(0)

e (s) = 0 ⇒ ex-post social value of investment isPS (I ∗) + CS (I ∗) > 0: FT is effi cient, s ∈ σFT

e (s) > P(0) and ex-post social value of investment isPS (I ∗) + CS (I ∗)− e (I ∗, s) < 0: T is effi cient, s ∈ σT

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 13 / 28

BITs: Standing

Foreign investor earns return P(I ∗) per unit of FDI under FT andearns 0 under T

Conditional on level of FDI I ∗, host gov receives ex-post payoff of

s ∈ σT : ω (I ∗,T , s) = 0; ω (I ∗,FT , s) = CS (I ∗)− e (I ∗, s) < 0s ∈ σFT : ω (I ∗,FT , s) = CS (I ∗); ω (I ∗,T , s) = CS (I ∗) + κPS (I ∗)

where κ ∈ (0, 1) reflects degree of ex-post ineffi ciency associated withthe host gov’s taking in σFT

Joint ex-post gain from a taking

s ∈ σT : Γ (I ∗, s) = − [PS (I ∗) + CS (I ∗)− e (I ∗, s)] > 0s ∈ σFT : Γ(I ∗, s) = − (1− κ)PS (I ∗) < 0

⇒ ex-post ineffi ciency from taking in σFT goes away as κ → 1, butex-ante ineffi ciency (level of I ∗) remains

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 14 / 28

BITs: Standing

First best

if investor expects first-best treatment, I ∗ satisfies pFT P(I ∗FB)= r∗

if host gov can commit to first-best policies ιFB , ex-ante expectedpayoff for host gov is Es [ω(I ∗FB , ιFB , s)] = p

FT CS(I ∗FB)

Limited commitment (with probability p)

if investor expects limited-commitment treatment, I ∗ satisfiesppFT P

(I ∗C)= r∗

if host gov maintains limited commitment policies ιC , its expectedpayoff is Es

[ω(I ∗C , ιC , s

)]= pFT

[CS(I ∗C)+ (1− p) κPS

(I ∗C)]

Host gov benefits from commitment, foreign investor expects r ∗

either way

⇒ a gov-to-foreign-investor commitment problem

can a BIT serve as a useful commitment device for host gov?

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 15 / 28

BITs: Standing

Prior question: Can an up-front investment incentive program solvethe host gov’s commitment problem?

Lemma 2. An up-front investment incentive program can help solve thehost gov’s commitment problem with regard to foreign investors, but itcannot by itself achieve the first best as long as (1− p) (1− κ) > 0.

Can a BIT improve upon stand-alone investment incentives?

once I ∗ has been sunk, the BIT works just like the trade agreement

Proposition

The introduction of a BIT can lead to effi ciency gains and benefit the hostgovernment relative to stand-alone up-front investment incentives forforeign investors if and only if the quality of the court is suffi ciently highand the quality of domestic institutions is suffi ciently weak.

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 16 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

Assumec∗G ∗ = c

∗I ∗ ≡ c∗ (Assumption 1′)

implying c∗G ∗(I∗, s) = c∗I ∗(I

∗, s) ≡ c∗(I ∗, s) for all s

Assumeγ∗G ∗ < γ∗I ∗ = 1 (Assumption 2′)

implying |γ∗G ∗(I ∗)| < |γ∗I ∗(I ∗)|

⇒ Any difference between a BIT with SSDS vs ISDS must reflectdifferences across the complainants’payoffs from winning in court

the foreign gov’s gain from winning in court is less than the producersurplus that foreign investors would lose in a taking

gov incurs political/diplomatic costs that investors do not internalize

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 17 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

We seek suffi cient conditions for Es [ωI ∗(I ∗I ∗ , s)] > Es [ωG ∗(I ∗G ∗ , s)]

and hence for ISDS to be part of an optimal BIT

Holding investment at the optimal level under a BIT with SSDS (I ∗G ∗)

calculate Es [ωI ∗(I ∗G ∗ , s)]− Es [ωG ∗(I ∗G ∗ , s)] ≡ ∆BIT

Then ∆BIT > 0⇒ Es [ωI ∗(I ∗I ∗ , s)] > Es [ωG ∗(I ∗G ∗ , s)]

given that Es [ωI ∗(I ∗I ∗ , s)] ≥ Es [ωI ∗(I ∗G ∗ , s)]

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 18 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

Let C (I ∗G ∗ , s) ≡ c∗(I ∗G ∗ , s) + c (I ∗G ∗ , s). Then ∆BIT =

(1− p) ∑s∈ΩFT

p (s) (1− qk (s)) (1− κ)PS (I ∗G ∗)− C (I ∗G ∗ , s)

− ∑s∈ΩT

p (s) qk (s) [e (I ∗G ∗ , s)− CS (I ∗G ∗)− PS (I ∗G ∗)] + C (I ∗G ∗ , s) .

The sign of the first line is ambiguous, reflecting the welfare impactsof additional litigation in s ∈ ΩFT

(1− κ) of producer surplus is saved by correct ruling, but at theexpense of host and foreign litigation costs

becomes positive as κ → 0 and as host litigation cost c → 0, and largeas p → 0

The second line is negative, reflecting welfare losses from theadditional litigation in s ∈ ΩT , but goes to 0 as pT → 0

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 19 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

Proposition

Whether investors, in addition to their governments, should have standingto bring disputes in an optimally designed BIT depends on a number ofsubtle tradeoffs. But if the host government is highly ineffi cient inorchestrating takings for s ∈ σFT and bears little cost of defending itself incourt, and if domestic institutions are suffi ciently weak and expropriation issocially effi cient only in unusual circumstances, then it is optimal to giveinvestors standing to bring disputes in a BIT. That is, if κ, c, p and pT aresuffi ciently low, an optimally designed BIT should include both an SSDSand an ISDS.

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 20 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

Intuition

if ineffi cient takings create large ex-post ineffi ciencies, then litigation toavert them can bring substantial gains

if litigation costs for defendants are lower, the costs of increasedlitigation under ISDS relative to SSDS are less burdensome

if domestic institutions are weak, they cannot be counted on to protectinvestors

and if “expropriation” is effi cient only infrequently, the probability ofineffi cient litigation over desirable takings is diminished

Note: while these conditions are plausibly met in some circumstances,the case for ISDS provisions in BITs is far from absolute

perhaps plausible for North-South, not likely for North-North

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 21 / 28

BITs: SSDS vs ISDS

Intuition

if ineffi cient takings create large ex-post ineffi ciencies, then litigation toavert them can bring substantial gains

if litigation costs for defendants are lower, the costs of increasedlitigation under ISDS relative to SSDS are less burdensome

if domestic institutions are weak, they cannot be counted on to protectinvestors

and if “expropriation” is effi cient only infrequently, the probability ofineffi cient litigation over desirable takings is diminished

Note: while these conditions are plausibly met in some circumstances,the case for ISDS provisions in BITs is far from absolute

perhaps plausible for North-South, not likely for North-North

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 21 / 28

Nature of the Remedy

We compare two institutional setups: one in which the court allowsreciprocal retaliation, another in which the court awards cash damages

key assumption: cash value of harm from T suffered by foreign investoris easy to quantify compared to harm from P suffered by foreign gov

PropositionAllowing for retaliation instead of cash damages in a trade agreement isoptimal if (1) the court’s ability to assess cash damages is suffi ciently badrelative to its ability to assess the state of the world, and (2) free trade issuffi ciently likely to be the effi cient policy choice.

PropositionAllowing for cash damages instead of retaliation in a BIT is optimal if (1)the court’s ability to assess cash damages is suffi ciently good relative to itsability to assess the state of the world, and (2) there is a non-trivialprobability that a taking is the effi cient policy.

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 22 / 28

The Remedial Period

What is the optimal “remedial period”?

is it optimal to include retrospective damages in the remedy (damagesfor harm suffered before the case is finally adjudicated)?

or just prospective damages (damages that would arise afteradjudication if the ruling is not obeyed)?

We let δ ∈ [0, 1] parameterize the fraction of harm from the policyaction at issue that occurs prior to the court ruling

all the costs of delay in adjudication including lost profits on exportsales, losses experienced due to impairment of sunk investments

if δ = 0, there is no pre-ruling harm, as in our earlier model; if δ = 1,the harm has all occurred and is a bygone by the time of the ruling

we think of lower values of δ as reasonable for trade disputes

we think of higher values of δ as reasonable for investment disputes

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 23 / 28

The Remedial Period

Building on our earlier results

we assume that the trade agreement has adopted SSDS while the BIThas adopted ISDS

we use β ∈ (0, 1] to denote the fraction of each dollar given up by thehome/host gov that reaches the foreign claimant as damage payments

we assume that the retrospective remedy takes the form of retaliationfor the trade agreement (β small) and cash damages for the BIT (βlarge)

To keep the comparison clean

we continue to assume that the prospective remedy takes the form of acease and desist order for both the trade agreement and the BIT

when δ = 0 and there is no pre-ruling harm, the model collapses to ourearlier model

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 24 / 28

Trade Agreements: Prospective vs Retrospective Damages

PropositionA prospective remedy is optimal for a trade agreement provided that thedegree of litigation delay is suffi ciently short (δ small), transfers in thecontext of a trade dispute are suffi ciently costly (β small) and the qualityof the court is suffi ciently high (q low).

Intuition

for any fixed court quality q, the joint surplus under a trade agreementwith retrospective damages approaches that associated with FT in allstates as β→ 0 and the cost of transfers becomes prohibitive

and if q is fixed at a suffi ciently low level, then as δ→ 0 so thatlitigation delay is suffi ciently short, the joint surplus under a tradeagreement with prospective damages approaches the first best level

which exceeds the joint surplus associated with FT in all states andtherefore beats a system with costly retrospective damages

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 25 / 28

BITs: Prospective vs Retrospective Damages

PropositionA retrospective remedy is optimal for a BIT provided that the degree oflitigation delay is suffi ciently long (δ large), transfers in the context of aBIT are suffi ciently effi cient (β large) and the quality of the court issuffi ciently high (q low).

Intuition

for any fixed court quality q, as δ→ δ, the expected payoff to the hostgov under a BIT with prospective damages approaches that associatedwith a program of up-front investment incentives to foreign investors

and provided that β is not too small, if q is fixed at a suffi ciently lowlevel and for any δ ∈ [0, 1], the expected payoff to the host gov under aBIT with retrospective damages approaches the first best level

which exceeds the expected payoff under a program of up-frontinvestment incentives and therefore beats prospective damages

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 26 / 28

The Remedial Period

Summarizing: If court quality is suffi ciently high (q is suffi cientlylow), prospective damages are employed in trade agreements such asthe WTO while retrospective damages are employed in BITs because

the degree of pre-ruling harm is typically more severe in the context ofinvestment disputes as compared to trade disputes (δ is high forinvestment disputes but low for trade disputes) so that prospectivedamages become a poor option for effective investment agreements

and the available means of making international transfers are much lesseffi cient in the context of trade disputes as compared to investmentdisputes (β is low for trade disputes but high for investment disputes)

making retrospective damages prohibitively expensive in the context oftrade agreements and therefore unattractive in that context

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 27 / 28

Conclusion

International investment and trade agreements employ disputesettlement procedures that differ markedly along three key dimensions

standing, the nature of the remedy, the remedial period

Our results suggest that there are plausible conditions under whichthese broad differences can be viewed as an optimal response to thedifferent environments within which these agreements operate

At the same time, our results indicate that some of the mostcontroversial features of these procedures, such as providing standingfor investors to bring claims against foreign governments in investmentdisputes, are far from universally optimal under all circumstances

This suggests that such features deserve close scrutiny before drawingthe conclusion that they are warranted in the circumstances wherethey are present

Ossa, Staiger and Sykes . ( University of Zurich, Dartmouth and Stanford )Trade & Investment Disputes April 2019 28 / 28