Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … ·...

18
American Marketing Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing. http://www.jstor.org Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Author(s): F. Robert Dwyer, Paul H. Schurr and Sejo Oh Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51, No. 2 (Apr., 1987), pp. 11-27 Published by: American Marketing Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251126 Accessed: 15-02-2016 12:29 UTC REFERENCES Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251126?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Transcript of Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … ·...

Page 1: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

American Marketing Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing.

http://www.jstor.org

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Author(s): F. Robert Dwyer, Paul H. Schurr and Sejo Oh Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51, No. 2 (Apr., 1987), pp. 11-27Published by: American Marketing AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251126Accessed: 15-02-2016 12:29 UTC

REFERENCESLinked references are available on JSTOR for this article:

http://www.jstor.org/stable/1251126?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents

You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 2: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

F. Robert Dwyer, Paul H. Schurr, & Sejo Oh

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships

Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently on exchange between buyers and sellers. Un- fortunately, most of the research and too many of the marketing strategies treat buyer-seller exchanges as discrete events, not as ongoing relationships. The authors describe a framework for developing buyer- seller relationships that affords a vantage point for formulating marketing strategy and for stimulating new research directions.

UMMARIZING 15 years of debate on the con- ceptual domain of marketing, Hunt (1983a) con-

cludes that ". . . the primary focus of marketing is the exchange relationship" (p. 9; also see Ferber 1970; Kotler 1972; Kotler and Levy 1969; Kotler and Zalt- man 1971; Luck 1969, 1974). The relative perma- nence of that view has been instituted by the recent theoretical advances it has fostered. Examples include Frazier's (1983a) framework for interorganizational exchange, Bagozzi's (1975, 1979) developing theory of exchange, and Weitz's (1981) contingency model of selling. Exchange also occupies a central role in the unfolding political economy framework (Achrol, Reve, and Ster 1983; Amdt 1983; Stern and Reve 1980) and a host of more specialized empirical stud- ies.

Each of the works cited relies on the notion of exchange for four key conceptual benefits. First, ex-

F. Robert Dwyer is Associate Professor of Marketing and Sejo Oh is a doctoral student in marketing, University of Cincinnati. Paul H. Schurr is Associate Professor of Marketing, State University of New York, Al- bany. The authors thank Chuck Brunner and the JM reviewers for help- ful comments on previous drafts. Partial funding for this research was provided by the College of Business Administration, University of Cin- cinnati.

change serves as a focal event between two or more parties. Second, exchange provides an important frame of reference for identifying the social network of in- dividuals and institutions that participate in its for- mation and execution. Third, it affords the opportu- nity to examine the domain of objects or psychic entities that get transferred. Finally, and most important, as a critical event in the marketplace it allows the careful study of antecedent conditions and processes for buyer- seller exchange.

Despite the importance generally ascribed to the idea of exchange, marketing research has largely ne- glected the relationship aspect of buyer-seller behav- ior while tending to study transactions as discrete events. The lack of attention to antecedent conditions and processes for buyer-seller exchange relationships is a serious omission in the development of marketing knowledge.

Ongoing buyer-seller relationships take many dif- ferent forms. Ardt (1979) noted the tendency of or- ganizational exchange to be circumscribed by long- term associations, contractual relations, and joint ownership. Dubbing these phenomena "domesticated markets," he argued that within such ongoing rela- tions "transactions are planned and administered in- stead of being conducted on an ad hoc basis" (p. 70).

Arndt correctly emphasized the prominence of ex-

Journal of Marketing Vol. 51 (April 1987), 11-27. Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 11

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 3: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

change relationships in industrial and institutional markets, but the notion of relationship management may also apply to consumer markets. Ardt's exten- sive list of relational bonds in business marketing con- trasts with his seemingly perfunctory illustrations of consumer relations: ". .. consumer cooperative so- cieties in Great Britain and Scandinavia, . . . book or record clubs, season tickets for sports and the arts, and, in a way, subscriptions to newspapers and mag- azines, and credit cards" (p. 71). Let us take note of other pervasive consumer behaviors: frequent flyer programs, church and professional club memberships, personal service patronage (lawyers, barbers, physi- cians), and the implicit bonds that underlie brand loy- alty. Thus, both business marketing and consumer marketing benefit from attention to conditions that foster relational bonds leading to reliable repeat business.

Objectives Our principal goal is to outline a framework for de- veloping buyer-seller relationships. First we briefly contrast discrete and relational exchange using con- cepts from modem contract law. Because the contract law conception of discrete exchange is an idealized fiction, we suggest problem areas and issues where it seems judicious either to overlook or underscore re- lational dimensions. We rely on Macneil's (1980) provocative work to suggest what relational properties may be of consequence in buyer-seller exchange. Then, after brief conjecture about the benefits and costs of relational exchange, we propose a five-phase model by which relationships are formed. Utilizing the work of Scanzoni (1979), Thibaut and Kelley (1959), and other exchange theorists, we emphasize hypothesized transitions and key distinctions between phases. Fi-

nally, we pivot on the framework to propose a mar- keting research agenda and outline three key facets of managing buyer-seller relationships.

Discrete and Relational Exchange Discrete Transactions The idea of a discrete transaction is the foundation on which concepts of relationship are built. According to Macneil (1980, p. 60), the archetype of discrete trans- action is manifested by money on one side and an easily measured commodity on the other.

Discreteness is the separating of a transaction from all else between the participants at the same time and before and after. Its [pure form], never achieved in life, occurs when there is nothing else between the parties, never has been, and never will be.

Notice that the concept of discrete transaction specif- ically excludes relational elements. Discrete transac-

tions are characterized by very limited communica- tions and narrow content. The identity of parties to a transaction must be ignored or relations creep in. A one-time purchase of unbranded gasoline out-of-town at an independent station paid for with cash approx- imates a discrete transaction.

Relational Exchange It is the departure from the anchor point of discrete- ness that underlies a strong customer franchise (or, from a buyer's standpoint, a reliable team of sup- pliers). We posit that a strong customer franchise (or supplier base) depends on the nature of the relational contract between a buyer and seller.

Macneil (1978, 1980) differentiates discrete trans- actions from relational contracts, relational exchange, along several key dimensions. Most important is the fact that relational exchange transpires over time; each transaction must be viewed in terms of its history and its anticipated future. The basis for future collabora- tion may be supported by implicit and explicit as- sumptions, trust, and planning. Relational exchange participants can be expected to derive complex, per- sonal, noneconomic satisfactions and engage in social exchange. Because duties and performance are rela- tively complex and occur over an extended time pe- riod, the parties may direct much effort toward care- fully defining and measuring the items of exchange. Third parties may be called in to adjudicate, and other customized mechanisms for collaborating and resolv- ing conflict may be designed.

Table 1 summarizes Macneil's characterization of discrete and relational polar archetypes of exchange on 12 contractual dimensions. Consistent with the

preceding discussion, for example, a consumer might buy peaches at farmers' market or a grocer may buy bags in quantity from any of several sources. The

products can be easily evaluated, paid for with cash, and carted away. There is no prolonged negotiation, paying cash for the goods consummates the transac- tions, and the mutual dependence situation quickly ends. All situational and process characteristics ap- proximate a discrete transaction.

Table 1 suggests that relational aspects start to ap- pear when the buyer pays by check or the seller sched- ules delivery for next week. That is, dependence is

prolonged, performance is less obvious, uncertainty leads to deeper communication, the rudiments of co-

operative planning and anticipation of conflict arise, and expectations of trustworthiness may be cued by personal characteristics.

Though a detailed review of Macneil's dimensions is beyond the scope of our article, Table 1 serves two important purposes. First, it dramatizes the multidi- mensionality of exchange. Within marketing, our eventual needs for theory and practice may require

12 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 4: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

TABLE 1 A Comparison of Discrete Transactions and Relational Exchange'

Contractual Elements Discrete Transactions Relational Exchange

Situational characteristics Timing of exchange

(commencement, duration, and termination of exchange)

Number of parties (entities taking part in some aspect of the exchange process)

Obligations (three aspects: sources of content, sources of obligation, and specificity)

Expectations for relations (especially concerned with conflicts of interest, the prospects of unity, and potential trouble)

Process characteristics Primary personal relations (social

interaction and communication)

Contractual solidarity (regulation of exchange behavior to ensure performance)

Transferability (the ability to transfer rights, obligations, and satisfactions to other parties)

Cooperation (especially joint efforts at performance and planning)

Planning (the process and mechanisms for coping with change and conflicts)

Measurement and specificity (calculation and reckoning of exchange)

Power (the ability to impose one's will on others)

Division of benefits and burdens (the extent of sharing of benefits and burdens)

Distinct beginning, short duration, and sharp ending by performance

Two parties

Content comes from offers and simple claims, obligations come from beliefs and customs (external enforcement), standardized obligations

Conflicts of interest (goals) and little unity are expected, but no future trouble is anticipated because cash payment upon instantaneous performance precludes future interdependence

Minimal personal relationships; ritual-like communications predominate

Governed by social norms, rules, etiquette, and prospects for self- gain

Complete transferability; it matters not who fulfills contractual obligation

No joint efforts

Primary focus on the substance of exchange; no future is anticipated

Little attention to measurement and specifications; performance is obvious

Power may be exercised when promises are made until promises are executed

Sharp division of benefits and burdens into parcels; exclusive allocation to parties

Commencement traces to previous agreements; exchange is longer in duration, reflecting an ongoing process

Often more than two parties involved in the process and governance of exchange

Content and sources of obligations are promises made in the relation plus customs and laws; obligations are customized, detailed, and administered within the relation

Anticipated conflicts of interest and future trouble are counterbalanced by trust and efforts at unity

Important personal, noneconomic satisfactions derived; both formal and informal communications are used

Increased emphasis on legal and self-regulation; psychological satisfactions cause internal adjustments

Limited transferability; exchange is heavily dependent on the identity of the parties

Joint efforts related to both performance and planning over time; adjustment over time is endemic

Significant focus on the process of exchange; detailed planning for the future exchange within new environments and to satisfy changing goals; tacit and explicit assumptions abound

Significant attention to measuring, specifying, and quantifying all aspects of performance, including psychic and future benefits

Increased interdependence increases the importance of judicious application of power in the exchange

Likely to include some sharing of benefits and burdens and adjustments to both shared and parceled benefits and burdens over time

'Adapted from Macneil (1978, 1980).

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 13

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 5: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

fewer than 12 dimensions, but clearly the limited fo- cus of past research (on power, personal relations) re- flects less than full consideration of the properties of exchange. Thus, the characterization of polar trans- actional archetypes on 12 dimensions prompts us to consider sweeping arrays of diverse transactional forms.

Second, Table 1 should underscore the need to make "practical" distinctions between discrete and rela- tional exchange-especially in the present embryonic stages of inquiry. As our simple examples of the farmers' market and cash-and-carry grocery bag trans- actions establish, the notion of instantaneous ex- change between anonymous partners who will never interact in the future is an abstracted model that does not exist in the real world. Even the simplest model of discrete exchange must postulate what Macneil (1980) calls a "social matrix": an effective means of communication, a system of order to preclude killing and stealing, a currency, and a mechanism for en- forcement of promises. Hence, some elements of a "relationship" in a contract law sense underlie all transactions.

This argument does not mean we should discard the concept of discrete exchange. Indeed, Goldberg (1979) suggests that treating exchange as a discrete transaction directs attention to three important issues: (1) how do economic actors make choices from an array of alternatives, (2) what market outcomes will result from the simultaneous choices of individual ac- tors, and (3) how do outcomes depend on the structure of alternatives (competition)? It "is an extremely use- ful analytic construct and should properly be viewed as a special case-a subclass of exchange. . . . [I]n many contexts explicit recognition of relational ele- ments adds heat but sheds no light" (p. 95).

Relational Marketing: The Marriage of Buyer and Seller To the extent that relational exchange contributes to product differentation and creates barriers to switch- ing, it can provide a competitive advantage (Day and Wensley 1983). Despite this potential, sellers com- monly fail to see the necessity of managing their re- lationships with customers. Noting that exchange ac- tivity typically intensifies subsequent to the initial sale in financial services, consultancy, maintenance/re- pair/operating (MRO) supply systems, and capital goods industries, Levitt (1983, p. 111) states that

.. the sale merely consummates the courtship. Then the marriage begins. How good the marriage is de- pends on how well the relationship is managed by the seller.

Though asymmetrical in his assignment of re- sponsibility for relationship management to the seller (only one "spouse"), Levitt's marriage analogy is fit-

ting. In fact, research analyzing the interpersonal at- traction and the interdependence relationships be- tween husbands and wives provides an apt framework for describing the evolution of buyer-seller relations. As McCall (1966, p. 197-8) points out:

Marriage [is a] restrictive trade agreement. The two individuals agree to exchange only with one another, at least until such time as the balance of trade be- comes unfavorable in terms of broader market con- siderations.

Within the husband-wife relationship the benefits of companionship, intimacy, procreation and parent- ing, personal growth, shared household maintenance, and social support are only one side of the ledger. On the other side marriage typically forecloses social and sexual options, brings expanded responsibility, de- mands care and nurturance, and can entail costly dis- solution.

Buyer-seller relations involve analogous benefits and costs. The former include reduced uncertainty, managed dependence (Spekman, Strauss, and Smith 1985), exchange efficiency, and social satisfactions from the association. Foremost is the possibility of significant gains in joint-and consequently individ- ual-payoffs as a result of effective communication and collaboration to attain goals. The buyer's percep- tion of the effectiveness of the exchange relation, then, is a significant mobility barrier and a potential com- petitive advantage for the seller that insulates the latter from price competition.

It is possible, however, that real or anticipated costs outweigh the benefits of relational exchange. Main- tenance of the association requires resources. Parties with highly divergent goals may spend considerable economic and psychic resources in conflict and hag- gling processes. More important may be the oppor- tunity costs of foregone exchange with alternative partners. A titanium fabricator that ties up 25% of next year's shop capacity at a 20% margin may lock itself out of another large job yielding a 25% margin. Al- ternatively, a consumer who opens a checking ac- count but orders only a small quantity of checks may be hedging against the possibility of an opportunity to bank elsewhere for reduced charges or expanded ser- vice.

Jackson (1985) has given principal attention to in- dustrial marketing situations like the latter example in which the buyer incurs high switching costs. She fo- cuses on switching costs related more to the techno- logical and usage characteristics of the product (e.g., computers and communication systems requiring on- going service or technical extension) than to the per- formance level of the exchange partner. Among other factors, we suggest that the buyer's anticipation of high switching costs gives rise to the buyer's interest in

maintaining a quality relationship.

14 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 6: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

Figure 1 goes farther to delineate the realm of pos- sibilities of dyadic motivations for relational ex- change. Framed in the exchange theory language of Thibaut and Kelley (1959), the axes define each par- ty's motivational investment in (the expected net ben- efits from) a relationship. The model has been devel- oped recently in considerable detail in the analysis of marketing channel member relations (Anderson and Narus 1984). Thibaut and Kelley theorize that a party assesses the overall costs and rewards from the total association against the level of outcomes available from alternatives outside the association. They use the terms "comparison level" (CL) and "comparison level for alternatives" (CLai), respectively, to denote the two bases for evaluating relationship outcomes. For ex- ample, for the Metro Theater's season ticket holder, CL includes certainty of priority seating for the full array of plays, perhaps a discount from the single show rate, an efficient purchase process, plus a possible deepening identity with the playhouse and resultant prestige in the "arts community." The seller's CL comprises the dependable, certain ticket revenue, ef- ficiently generated by season ticket sales, and espe- cially renewals.

By highlighting the mutual motivational invest- ments of the parties, Figure 1 reveals that Levitt's (1983) discussion of seller-managed relations covers only one of several exchange forms. This fact should not denigrate the significance of seller-managed re- lational exchanges. Rather, by illuminating situations

FIGURE 1 The Hypothesized Realm of Buyer-Seller

Relationships

Seler's motivational investment in relationship

Buyer's market

Buyer-maintained '"^ relation

SeUer's market No

Exchange

of buyer-supported relationships and bilateral rela- tionship maintenance, Figure 1 suggests contingent seller roles. Toyota shares its production schedules with suppliers and has carefully knit the Toyota City man- ufacturing complex. Similarly, NASA and a home- owner exemplify buyer-managed exchange as they or- chestrate contractor performance in rocket assembly and major remodeling, respectively. Seller attempts at leadership roles in these associations seem unneces- sary and ill advised. Also, bilateral relationship main- tenance seems the essence of Shapiro's (1985) "stra- tegic partnership" between buyer and seller, and is illustrated by industrial joint ventures.

Finally, Figure 1 allows transactions devoid of significant relational elements. In these instances for either or both of the parties, CL and CLai are ap- proximately equal. Exchange still may occur, but when one party's access to alternatives (CLat) is greater than the other's, one of two possible situations of asym- metric power obtains (cf. Dwyer and Walker 1981). For completeness we depict the realm of "no ex- change." There are no concessions or inducements that one party is willing to offer that will provide sufficient satisfactions for the other to motivate exchange (Alderson 1965, p. 84).

As a map of exchange possibilities, Figure 1 pro- vides a good representation of the topography. It is not a road map, however, in that it offers little detail on the routes to the northeast quadrant. Obviously, many of the costs and benefits from buyer-seller re- lations cannot be assessed on an a priori basis. Using the marriage analogy once more, we need to consider how practically discrete transactions (casual dating) might progress into more durable associations sup- ported by shared goals, planning, and commitment to the relationship.

The Relationship Development Process

Relationships evolve through five general phases identified as (1) awareness, (2) exploration, (3) ex- pansion, (4) commitment, and (5) dissolution (cf. Scanzoni 1979). Each phase represents a major tran- sition in how parties regard one another.

Phase I. Awareness

Awareness refers to party A's recognition that party B is a feasible exchange partner. Situational proximity between the parties facilitates awareness. Just as a family is more likely to be acquainted with adjacent neighbors than with those down the street, buyers are apt to become aware of local merchants and brands advertised in frequently viewed media.

Interaction between parties has not transpired in phase 1. Though there may be "positioning" and

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 15

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 7: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

"posturing" by the parties to enhance each one's own attractiveness to a specific (or general) other, these actions are unilateral. Any type of bilateral interac- tion-even tacit coordination (Schelling 1960)-marks the beginning of the next phase of possible relation- ship development.

Phase II. Exploration

Exploration refers to the search and trial phase in re- lational exchange. In this phase potential exchange partners first consider obligations, benefits and bur- dens, and the possibility of exchange. Trial purchases may take place. The exploration phase may be very brief, or it may include an extended period of testing and evaluation. Seller S may give buyer B due con- sideration in promotions and store placement; B may attend to S's ads and linger at the display. This eval- uation may result in a trial purchase, but the explor- atory relationship is very fragile in the sense that min- imal investment and interdependence make for simple termination. The exploration phase is conceptualized in five subprocesses (cf. Scanzoni 1979): (1) attrac- tion, (2) communication and bargaining, (3) devel- opment and exercise of power, (4) norm develop- ment, and (5) expectation development.

Attraction. Attraction is the initiating process of the exploration phase. It results from the degree to which buyer and seller achieve-in their interaction with each other-a reward-cost outcome in excess of some minimum level (CLa,t) (Secord and Backman 1974). Rewards are derived from the tangible and in-

tangible gratifications of association; costs include economic (money, inconvenience) or social deter- rents.

The interpersonal attraction literature has given principal attention to rewards. They may be rooted in perceived similarity of beliefs, values, or personality. Also, complementary resources, including money, in- formation, services, legitimacy, and status, encourage favorable perceptions of benefits and burdens. Rec- ognizing both contingent and noncontingent reward sources (John 1984; Lusch and Brown 1982), Lott and Lott (1974) catalog several types of rewards that may lead to attraction.

* Rewards directly provided by other, e.g., -customer provides payment -seller's product delivers functional benefits

* Characteristics of other as a source of reward, e.g., -sports prowess of alma mater sparks alumni

pride -"we were the first . .. McDonnell Douglas" -"an official sponsor of the 1984 Olympics"

* Other's attitude similarity as a reinforcement of own competence, e.g., -sales representative builds identity bonds with

prospect

Communication and bargaining. Bargaining is de- fined as the process whereby in the face of resistance parties rearrange their mutual distributions of obli- gations, benefits, and burdens. Perceived willingness to negotiate may be a significant aspect of attraction which, by itself, signals that the potential exchange partner sees possible value in an exchange relation- ship. There are dramatic relational consequences when the parties actually bargain.

A significant indicator of development or progressive change in any association is found at the point where partners perceive that the potential rewards are great enough to take the trouble, go to the bother, and ex- pend the psychic and physical energies necessary to negotiate (Scanzoni 1979, p. 72).

Within developing relations there is often some re- luctance to engage in bargaining. Initially, parties talk around the issues, hinting at their preferences or stat- ing them offhandedly while evidencing interest in the other's goals (Leigh and Rethans 1984; Pruitt 1981). Through questions and answers, buyers and sellers develop a process of turn taking, making interaction easier (Knapp 1978; LaFrance and Mayo 1978). To know each other very well, they may try to reveal specific information about themselves, their needs, or their resources. If the relationship is to survive this stage, intimate disclosure must be reciprocated (Cozby 1973; Davis and Skinner 1974). Later, when the par- ties are both projecting their association into the fu- ture, there may be a lesser need for strict-reciprocity accounting in that the future holds ample opportunity for and expectations of balancing.

Now we risk diluting the contended significance of bargaining and communication in relationship de-

velopment. We note that the behaviors described- though typical in business-to-business exchange-seem characteristic of only a portion of consumer transac- tions, namely those involving high priced durable goods and complex services (cf. Dwyer 1984, p. 680). On the surface, administered pricing and mass merchan-

dising for low priced items seem to preclude explicit bargaining. We emphasize, however, that uncertainty and the "stakes" of the exchange have important ef- fects on the extent and nature of bargaining. That is, a consumer may explicitly negotiate a quantity dis- count on doughnuts when setting up an after-church breakfast reception (high stakes); a single roll (low stakes) will probably involve no haggling-unless the baker attempts to sell an unfamiliar variety (uncer- tainty) when sold out of the consumer's favorite.

There are obvious selling efficiencies from ad-

16 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 8: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

ministered pricing. Also, administered pricing is use- ful for managing the aspirations of millions of con- sumers linked to the bargaining "stance" of the seller (see Raiffa 1982, p. 13). Thus, for good reason com- munication is less than complete in this setting. Bar- gaining and efforts at coordination are largely tacit (Alderson 1957, p. 130; Schelling 1960). Sellers in- teract with "representatives" of the market constitu- ency when they enlist focus group participants and survey respondents. Furthermore, purchase postpone- ment, stockpiling, and the like are subtle forms of tacit bargaining for low priced consumable goods that have dramatic consequences when summed across millions of households. The rare instances of explicit bargain- ing-as in suggestions, complaints, and redress re- quests-should be especially highly regarded by sell- ers; they reflect consumer goals, priorities, and relational involvement with the brand or store.

Finally, we emphasize that negotiation, by itself, does not lead to an enduring relationship. It is pos- sible for haggling to transpire in what is practically a discrete transaction, such as an estate sale or flea mar- ket. In such cases, neither party expects a future with the other (Weitz 1981), and the style and tone of their negotiation strategies reflect this fact (Raiffa 1982).

We therefore propose that, though it is possible for buyers and sellers to bargain over terms to what is essentially a discrete contract, a relationship seems unlikely to form without bilateral communication of wants, issues, inputs, and priorities. Especially as the parties themselves change over time and their respec- tive environments exert variable demands, it is inev- itable that the valuation of outcomes in the buyer-seller association fluctuates. By looking for or granting ac- commodation within a current rather than a new ex- change association, the buyer and seller verify their mutual investment in the relationship.

Power and justice. Though convenient for discus- sion, separating the adjoining processes of bargaining and power is impossible in reality. With a richer tra- dition in marketing than the former, power is con- ceived as the ability to achieve intended effects or goals (Dahl 1957). Party A's power over B is determined by B's dependence on A for valued resources. B's dependence on A is high when there are limited al- ternative sources of those valued resources (Emerson 1962; Thibaut and Kelley 1959). Thus, concessions are granted or obtained as a result of power brought to bear in bargaining.

Resources mediated by A on which B is dependent can take many forms (cf. French and Raven 1959), but for our purposes it is useful to conceive of their application as "just" or "unjust" sanctions. Exercise of an unjust power source would control or influence the action of B to promote A's own goals without B's

consent, against B's will, or without B's understand- ing (Buckley 1967; Raven and Kruglanski 1970). Ex- ercise of a just power source, in contrast, implies vol- untary compliance and behaviors for the promotion of collective goals.1 Thus, when A attempts to dominate or coerce B into some behavior without providing suf- ficient rewards-direct or indirect (Lusch and Brown 1982)-to lead B to perceive that compliance is worthwhile, B may elect to terminate the association. With minimal interdependencies at this stage, break- off is fairly easy. If, however, A's power exercise is perceived as "just," and B complies, the association passes from one "where individualistic interests are of prime concern to one where [joint] interests are taking on importance" (Scanzoni 1979, p. 75). Indeed, the successful exercise of power may be a crucial dis- tinction for locating a relationship on a continuum be- tween the exploratory and expansion phases. The fol- lowing examples clarify this point.

As deregulation intensified competition in finan- cial services in the early 1980s, many banks increased their efforts to segment markets and partition oper- ating costs. The result was a diversity of approaches to encourage small depositors to use automatic tellers instead of expensive bank personnel. Some banks im- posed up to $1 charges for teller-assisted withdrawals from small accounts. Others emphasized education and prize incentives for using automatic tellers. Applying the relationship development framework, we would predict poor account retention by the former ap- proach. No matter what explanation of economic real- ities is used to support the program, its coercive, self- serving flavor jeopardizes its legitimacy. In contrast, the education/reward approach addresses joint goals. In turn, it expands the interdependence of the parties as the bank has a more profitable market segment and account holders have made relational transaction-spe- cific investments by learning to use the automatic tell- ers.

Norm development. The norms and standards of conduct that mark a relational contract take form in the exploration phase of relationship development. Norms provide "guidelines for the initial probes that potential exchange partners may make towards each other" (Scanzoni 1979, p. 68). Norms are "expected patterns of behavior" (Lipset 1975, p. 173). By adopt- ing norms and establishing standards of conduct, emerging exchange partners start setting the ground rules for future exchange.

'Buckley (1967) uses the terms "legitimate" and "nonlegitimate" power where we use "just" and "unjust." Our choice of terminology is intended to avoid confusion with French and Raven's (1959) tax- onomy of power sources (expert, referent, legitimate, etc.), which has been used frequently in sales and channels research (cf. Gaski 1986; Spiro and Perreault 1979).

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 17

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 9: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

The concept of norms that exist "prior to, and are brought into the social [exchange]" (Ekeh 1974, p. 45) is illustrated in the script theoretic work of Leigh and Rethans (1984). More than 40% of the purchasing agents in their sample described the following ex- pected activities in a "post quotation negotiation pro- cess": (1) salesperson arrival at purchasing agent's of- fice, (2) exchange greeting/small talk, (3) buyer opens negotiation on price, (4) salesperson response, . . . (7) exchange of parting comments. Such generalized expectations guide perceptions of social exchange and exert powerful influences on behavior.

Once parties come together and begin to exchange rewards, they often establish norms that did not exist prior to the interaction. Thus, "spontaneous consen- sus" (Fox 1974) may support initial exchange be- tween customer and barber, but at the same time the experience will shape expectations for the next trans- action (Brickman 1974). Very much in harmony with our notion of "just" power, Fox (1974) indicates that persons "who share common goals are capable of al- locating roles among themselves in the light of what they perceive as 'functional necessities'" (p. 86).

Expectations development. Relational expecta- tions concern conflicts of interest and the prospects for unity and trouble. These expectations may either enhance or diminish contractual solidarity. Trust is an important concept in understanding expectations for cooperation and planning in a relational contract. Go- lembiewski and McConkie (1975) go further to sug- gest that "perhaps there is no other single variable which so thoroughly influences interpersonal and intergroup behavior" (p. 131). Trust is a concept only recently brought into the focus of buyer-seller interaction re- search. Schurr and Ozanne (1985) rely on Blau (1964) and Rotter (1967) to define trust as "the belief that a party's word or promise is reliable and a party will fulfill his/her obligations in an exchange relation- ship" (p. 940). In a simulation of industrial purchas- ing, Schurr and Ozanne found that buyers' expecta- tions about trust and bargaining stance significantly affected attitudes and behavior toward their current supplier. Low trust stimulated less favorable attitudes, communications, and bargaining behavior with re- spect to the current supplier.

Pruitt (1981, p. 101) believes trust and a desire to coordinate with another party are closely related. He suggests that a party desiring coordination with a trusted other is likely to take high-risk coordinative behav- iors. Examples of high-risk moves include (1) a large concession that seeks reciprocation, (2) a proposal for compromise, (3) a unilateral tension-reduction action, and (4) candid statements about one's motives and priorities.

Examples of sustained measures to engender trust

include buyers' maintenance of good credit standing and sellers' use of implicit stimulants of trust (e.g., brand names, trademarks, logos) and explicit guar- antees (Schurr and Ozanne 1985). However, direct experience is likely to be the principal basis for judg- ing trustworthiness in the exploratory phase. It is a key facet of Swan's (Swan and Nolan 1985; Swan, Trawick, and Silva 1985) conceptual framework for the salesperson's development of customer trust.

In summary, the five subprocesses are important aspects of the exploration phase because they enable each party to gauge and test the goal compatibility, integrity, and performance of the other.

Phase lIM. Expansion

Expansion refers to the continual increase in benefits obtained by exchange partners and to their increasing interdependence. The five subprocesses introduced in the exploration phase also operate in the expansion phase. The critical distinction is that the rudiments of trust and joint satisfactions established in the explo- ration stage now lead to increased risk taking within the dyad. Consequently, the range and depth of mu- tual dependence increase. "[T]he association has de- veloped or evolved significantly from one character- ized by probing, testing examination, and so on, to one characterized by continual enlargement of the kinds of rewards that partners supply one another, and thus increased interdependence" (Scanzoni 1979, p. 791).

Frazier (1983a,b) has framed the expansion pro- cess as a consequence of each party's satisfaction with the other's role performance and its associated re- wards. That is, exchange outcomes in the exploratory phase provide a test of the other's ability and will- ingness to deliver satisfaction (Blau 1964). When a party fulfills perceived exchange obligations in an ex- emplary fashion, that party's attractiveness to the other increases (Thibaut and Kelley 1959). Hence motiva- tion to maintain the relationship increases, especially because high-level outcomes reduce the number of al- ternatives an exchange partner might use as a replace- ment (Frazier 1983b, p. 159). The resulting percep- tions of goal congruence and cooperativeness lead to interactions beyond those strictly required at the out- set.

The intensive business growth strategies of market penetration and product development (Ansoff 1957) depend on the process of expansion. For example, Ci- tibank used newspaper ads and mail directed toward current loan customers to attract applicants for an in- novative second mortgage product in Baltimore. The program built Citibank market presence in an histor- ically weak area and, more importantly, enabled Ci- tibank to use the process for "upselling." That is, ap- plicants increased their loan amounts and purchased other financial services after discussions with a Citi-

18 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 10: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

bank loan officer (Advertising Age 1986). In a similar, buyer-managed expansion Procter & Gamble has deepened its relationship with a telemarketing distrib- utor to (1) sell diapers to parents of premature infants, (2) serve incontinent adults, and (3) most recently, identify key decision makers at prospective accounts for institutional cooking oils.

Phase IV. Commitment Commitment refers to an implicit or explicit pledge of relational continuity between exchange partners. At this most advanced phase of buyer-seller interdepen- dence the exchange partners have achieved a level of satisfaction from the exchange process that virtually precludes other primary exchange partners who could provide similar benefits. The participants have not ceased attending to alternatives, but maintain their awareness of alternatives without "constant and fre- netic testing" (Scanzoni 1979, p. 87). Customer (seller) loyalty is achieved.

Typically the notion of commitment connotes sol- idarity and cohesion, but these synonyms are vague. We need to consider three measurable criteria of com- mitment (Scanzoni 1979): inputs, durability, and con- sistency.

Inputs. The first criterion of commitment is that the parties provide relatively high levels of inputs to the association (Blau 1964). Significant economic, communication, and/or emotional resources may be exchanged.

Durability. Second, there should be some dura- bility of the association over time. According to Macneil (1980, p. 95), "organic solidarity consists of a com- mon belief in effectiveness of future exchange."

A persevering relationship itself may or may not have content stability, depending on the environmen- tal adjustments required and the willingness of the participants to make such adjustments (Scanzoni 1979). Durability presumes the parties can discern the ben- efits attributable to the exchange relation and antici- pate an environment that will abet continued effective exchange. Given these expectations, the parties can bond themselves in such a way as to encourage their continued investment in the relation. Williamson (1983) argues in this vein that exchange of "hostages" (bi- lateral exchange of transaction-specific human or physical assets) communicates credibility of commit- ment to the relationship, and thus supports expanded alliance and exchange. The predominant problem in franchising illustrates this point.

Franchisees invest in the franchisor's inventories, signs, and promotion. Franchisors train their dealers and provide specialized knowledge on business tech- niques. Neither party would incur these costs without at least some expectation that the relationship will continue long enough for him to recoup his expen- ditures (Goldberg 1979, p. 99).

The expectations of franchisee continuation derive from nonrefundable franchise fees, covenants not to compete, and anticipated relocation expenses from franchisor-owned sites. Royalties based on a percent- age of gross receipts reflect a sharing formula that makes termination in a "hot" market less attractive for a franchisor than would a flat rate for all franchisee services. In consumer markets, similar investments seem evident in security deposits, delayed rebates, cu- mulative purchase credits, and the like.

Consistency. The third aspect of commitment is the consistency with which the inputs are made to the association. In terms of the other's expectations, when a party's input levels fluctuate the other party will have difficulty predicting the outcomes from exchange. In- consistency on the part of the former reflects low commitment and leads to a reduced reliance by the latter on the outcomes of the exchange. A key dis- tinction of the commitment phase is that the parties purposefully engage resources to maintain the rela- tionship. Indeed, Levinger and Snoek (1972) anal- ogize that just as physical-chemical bonds tend toward entropy, social bonds tend to weaken and dissolve un- less actively maintained.

Many forces can strain a relationship, including increased costs of transaction, decreased obstacles as- sociated with interacting with an alternative exchange partner, and changing personal or organizational needs resulting in diminished valuation of rewards. In con- trast, pressure to adjust rather than dissolve a rela- tionship is fueled by the ongoing benefits accruing to each partner. These benefits include the certainty from mutually anticipated roles and goals, the efficiency stemming from amelioration or role or identity bar- gaining (McCall and Simmons 1966), and the confi- dence in exchange effectiveness that comes from trust.

Phase V. Dissolution The possibility of withdrawal or disengagement has been implicit throughout our relationship development framework. That is, not every dyadic linkage of which the buyer or seller is aware enters the exploration phase, and not every relation probed and tested in exploration enters expansion or becomes soldered by commit- ment. To this point we have merely relied on the basic exchange theory calculus (Emerson 1962; Raven and Kruglanski 1970; Thibaut and Kelley 1959; Figure 1) to explain breakup. This model is a powerful analyt- ical perspective, but it leaves unexplained the pro- cesses of dissolution.

Such processes have great consequence when they occur after parties have reached the status of high interdependence characteristic of the expansion and commitment phases. Termination of personal rela-

tionships is a significant source of psychological, emotional, and physical stress (cf. Bloom, Asher, and

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 19

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 11: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

White 1978; Hill, Rubin, and Peplau 1976). From an- ecdotal evidence, the dissolution of commercial re-

lationships extracts parallel tolls. Consider the trauma of Coca-Cola's attempted discontinuation of "old" Coke, Kodak's costly exit from instant photography, and the lengthy process of antitrust litigation that often ends distribution channel relationships (e.g., Mon- santo Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp. 1984).

Unfortunately, little is known about disengage- ment. There are probably several trajectories for dis- solution and we risk oversimplification by devoting four stages to relationship development while consol-

idating termination into a single phase. Though some scholars have found it useful to conceive of dissolu- tion as the reverse of relationship formation (cf. Alt- man and Taylor 1973; Miller and Parks 1982), we think it productive to depart from such reasoning. Figure 1 and our framework emphasize bilateral (though not

necessarily equal) efforts for relationship develop- ment; dissolution, in contrast, is more easily initiated

unilaterally. Furthermore, the accumulating evidence seems to contradict the reversal hypothesis.

Much of the empirical work has been conducted

by Baxter (1979, 1983; Baxter and Philpott 1982), po- sitioned within a four-stage conceptual framework from Duck (1982). This model posits that dissolution be-

gins with an intrapsychic stage in which one party pri- vately evaluates his or her dissatisfactions with the other

party, concluding that costs of continuation or mod- ification outweigh benefits. Subsequently, the rela-

tionship enters an interactive phase in which the par- ties negotiate their unbonding. Dissolution then is

presented publicly in the social phase. Finally, "grave dressing," social and psychological recovery from the

breakup, concludes the process-though neither party returns to their prerelationship state.

Emphasizing the interactive phase in her studies, Baxter (1985) identifies two key dimensions of strat-

egies for disengagement: directness and other-orien- tation. Direct strategies explicitly state to the other party one's desire to leave a relationship; indirect strategies try to accomplish breakup without an explicit state- ment of the aim. "Other-orientation captures the de-

gree to which the disengager attempts to avoid hurting the other party in the break-up" (p. 247). The parsi- mony of Baxter's distinctions makes them a promis- ing starting point for examining dissolution of buyer- seller relationships.

Advantages and Disadvantages of the Model

We argue that marketing research has largely ne-

glected relational elements of buyer-seller exchange. Macneil's (1980) depiction of contrasting features of discrete and relational exchange leads to our concep- tion of dyadic motivations for alternative exchange forms, Figure 1. To account for interactive processes

that might diminish or magnify mutual motivations-

perceptions of costs and benefits from sustained ex-

change-we propose a framework for relationship de-

velopment. Figure 2 is a skeletal summary of the model that

highlights primary transitions and phase characteris- tics. Awareness is a unilateral, pre-exchange process. Mutual considerations and dyadic interactions initiate the exploration phase, which is basically a testing pe- riod for the relationship. Repeated exchange may re- flect an extended testing period. The exchange asso- ciation is easily terminated at this stage. However, if the parties effectively communicate, negotiate roles that reflect "just" inputs from the parties, and form

expectations for promising future interactions, the as- sociation enters the expansion stage. The five subpro- cesses support a new trajectory of deepening inter-

dependence in the expansion phase. The commitment

phase then supports high levels of mutual dependence by circumscribing the exchange relation with value structures and contractual mechanisms that ensure its

durability. Disengagement from the highly interde-

pendent phases of expansion and commitment is not a reversal of the process. It may be complex and costly. It is a poorly understood strategic marketing process.

We caution that the model is built primarily on

conceptual foundations and empirical evidence from

exchange theory and its offspring-marital theory, bargaining theory, and power theory. Much remains to be done in distinguishing commercial, work, and

romantic relations. Also, the model is presented ab-

stractly. It lacks conceptual detail and obvious ways to operationalize key variables.

In this abstract form, however, the framework has

advantages. We attempt to offer a model that has suf-

ficient generality to cover both interfirm and con- sumer relationships. Though the emphasis of moder contract law seems to be on interfirm behaviors, the

process model has its roots in interpersonal phenom- ena. Multiparty decision making and higher stakes

distinguish interfirm from consumer relationship de-

velopment, but similar factors may come into play in

certain consumer buying situations and seem easily accommodated by the framework. Thus, we contend that the model supports the "logic of discovery" (Hunt 1983b, p. 21-5) by suggesting ideas and categories for grouping phenomena. Like the buying center con-

cept, the model affords a framework for unifying and

extending our understanding. To illustrate we pose di-

rections for research and managerial efforts.

Research Directions Transitions

Initial research efforts should confront the basic prem- ise of the relationship development framework, grad-

20 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 12: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

FIGURE 2 The Relationship Development Process

Relationship phase

1. Awareness

2. Exploration

3. Expansion

4. Commitment

Enabling Subprocesses for Deepening Dependence _~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

0 Seller's dependence on buyer

Phase characteristics

1. Unilateral considerations of potential exchange partners.

2. Dyadic interaction occurs. A gradual increase in inter- dependence reflects bilateral testing & probing. Termination of the fragile association is simple.

3. A successful power source exercise marks the beginning of Expansion. Mutual satis- faction with customized role performance supports deepening interdependence. Additional gratifications are sought from the current exchange partner, rather than from an alternative partner.

4. Contractual mechanisms and/or shared value systems ensure sustained interdependence. Mutual inputs are significant & consistent. Partners resolve conflict & adapt.

Buyer's dependence on seller 0

o

2

:0 I.

o

m,

I

4O

I

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 13: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

ual expansion of interdependence. With an historical emphasis on transactions as discrete events, market- ing has made significant progress toward understand- ing the transition from awareness to exploration. This progress is well illustrated in Smith and Swinyard's (1982) review and integration of information response models. Importantly, in their integrated model they note the significant role of behavioral experience with the product in the formation of higher order beliefs and affect.

We know relatively little, however, about the im- portant probing and testing processes of the explora- tion phase. Do the parties apply hypothesis testing heuristics? If so, what are the origins of their expec- tations? Do the "stakes" affect the "power" of the tests? What is the latitude of "just" power exercise across power sources and exchange partners?

If a relationship survives the exploration and ex- pansion stages, the transition to commitment requires high levels of goal congruence or "airtight" enforce- ment mechanisms (hostages or other sanctions). Because inherently imperfect human information pro- cessing transpires in complex and uncertain environ- ments, it may be impossible to engineer fully self- enforcing mechanisms to support the deepening in- terdependencies of commitment. Thus, relationship evaluation in the antecedent phases may emphasize attributed motives over quality role performance.

Negative transitions, relationship terminations or rollbacks, merit careful study also. Especially for the commitment phase, the marital metaphor and the evi- dence offered by Baxter (1985) compel us to frame disengagement as something other than the reversal of development. Uncoupling from this stage of high interdependence tends to render transaction-specific investments obsolete or leave deep sentimental scars that may block out intermediate relational levels. Even in bilateral agreements for "fading away" or "pseudo- deescalation" the parties "maintain the pretense of a continuing relationship, meanwhile intending total non- contact with one another" (Baxter 1985, p. 248).

The transition from the expansion back to the ex- ploratory phase may be less dramatic. Scaling back may not make relationship investments totally obso- lete or leave deep scars. Perhaps neither party wishes to foreclose the possibility of deeper interdependence in the future, though the current situation warrants a winding down. Obviously, when parties hold differ- ent perceptions of the status of the relationship, dis- engagement may be troublesome. A distributor who has built his business on a particular equipment line sees the manufacturer's direct sales efforts as a neg- ative transition that obviates any state of high depen- dence in the future. Meanwhile, the manufacturer may have intended the move merely to complement the

distributor network, anticipating an expanded product line in the next decade.

Finally, it is important to note that a great number of enduring exchange situations may compress explo- ration and expansion phases. Jackson's (1985) "lost- for-good" category of exchange, characterized by high buyer switching costs, is illustrative. Reasoning prin- cipally from Williamson's (1975) transaction cost economics, she proposes that factors tending to impel internalization also favor relational exchange over re- current spot contracting. Briefly, such factors include frequent interactions, auditability/certainty of perfor- mance, and the high degree to which durable trans- action-specific investments are required. In such cases we might expect extended negotiations between the parties and relatively high reliance on reputations of trustworthiness, contingent claims contracts, and third- party mediational mechanisms.

Negotiation The second item on the research agenda is the study of buyer-seller interactions as bargaining processes. Negotiation provides an excellent framework for re- search on relational exchange because its rich tradi- tions address important antecedent conditions, com- munications, and power structures affecting exchange partners who must divide benefits and burdens, re- solve conflicts, plan, and exercise power.

Arndt (1979) amplified Johnston and Bonoma's (1977) designation of negotiation as a fundamental re- sponsibility of marketing. Negotiations have been given little attention in the marketing literature, but some progress has been made (cf. Clopton 1984; Dwyer 1984; Schurr and Ozanne 1985). These studies have been of a transactional (tactical) nature and more must be done to study what Arndt has called "contractual" and "structural" negotiations. The former cover the terms of exchange over a period of time; the latter apply to the "form and intensity of long-term and deeply committing interorganizational relations" (p. 73). Again, we posit the possibility of more subtle, per- haps tacit, parallel forms in consumer relations.

The negotiation laboratory may be a suitable start- ing point for development and evaluation of measures of key constructs in the framework. Within the con- trolled environment, measures can be efficiently ad- ministered and tested for their sensitivity to experi- mental manipulations of dependence, role performance, and communication. Three constructs seem critical at the present stage of our understanding of the process of relationship development: trust, commitment, and disengagement.

Trust. As a pivotal facet of expectations devel- opment, trust deserves priority attention. Its role is

22 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 14: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

perhaps best summarized by Sullivan and Peterson (1982, p. 30): ". .. where the parties have trust in one another, then there will be ways by which the two parties can work out difficulties such as power con- flict, low profitability, and so forth." We offer this logic in our discussion of transitions to commitment. That is, it might be impossible to cover all contin- gencies in a formal contract for sustained cooperation, but if the partners have trust it may be unnecessary to cover all contingencies.

Recent work on trust in marketing (Schurr and Ozanne 1985; Swan and Nolan 1985) has only scratched the surface of its rich conceptual and empirical foun- dations in interpersonal and small group research (cf. Worchel 1979; Zand 1972). As an outcome measure of dyadic interaction, the trust scale developed by Sul- livan et al. (1981; Sullivan and Peterson 1982) has shown reliability and nomological validity. Its appli- cation to buyer-seller relations, especially interfirm relations (trust as an organizational, vis-d-vis per- sonal, facet), warrants careful evaluation.

Finally, trust in the relationship development framework provides a vantage point for unifying the research traditions on marketing channel power and conflict (cf. Gaski 1984; John 1984). Much of the channels work is replete with implicit reference to trust as an aspect of expert and referent power, coopera- tion, and the reliability of threats and promises. In- deed, John's article seems key for wedding the insti- tutional economists' concern with market failure from opportunism and the social psychologists' concern with ineffective group performance due to lack of coop- eration and risking (trust). The former researchers re- gard opportunism as an inherent human characteristic that surfaces whenever it is unchecked by competitive structures or governance modes fitting the complexity and uncertainty in the environment. The latter em- phasize social learning as a route to trust, expanded interdependence, and group/system effectiveness.

Commitment. Commitment represents the highest stage of relational bonding and has been defined clearly in terms of three measurable dimensions: inputs, du- rability, and consistency. Seemingly, these facets can be applied with great versatility to the study of inter- firm and consumer relations. Relatively auditable and trackable operationalizations provide criteria and sys- tem status measures that make possible the careful study of relationship processes such as conflict manage- ment, joint decision making/coordination, and sys- tem adaptation. Comparative analysis across power systems, lifestyle segments, and product technologies likewise is supported.

Dissolution. Our discussion of disengagement processes is the most speculative. Though we ac-

knowledge the stream of research on micro aspects of consumer satisfaction/dissatisfaction (cf. Oliver 1980), there has been no systematic study of the uncoupling of parties from highly evolved relationships. Anec- dotally, the lure of treble damages in the antitrust arena seems to prompt many acrimonious interfirm sepa- rations that might otherwise have been avoided or re- solved peacefully via negotiation or contract arbitra- tion (Goldberg 1979). In the Baxter (1985) framework, antitrust disengagement is direct and not other-di- rected. In contrast, GM and Toyota have prearranged termination for their Nova joint venture; it is direct and other-directed. Is this a fruitful taxonomic scheme for evaluating consumer and interfirm breakups? What other environmental structures support or discourage dissolution? Again, Macneil (1980, 1978) and the marriage metaphor (Scanzoni 1982) are suggestive.

Exploratory, inductive work that classifies many relationship dissolutions seems potentially productive for evaluating the efficiency and effectiveness of the processes. We anticipate that dyadic perceptions of the process may not be congruent and that, in the face of resistance, one party's other-directed efforts at dis- solution may revert to self-defense.

Decision Models

There are significant differences in the managerial evaluation of discrete and relational transactions. Es- sentially, evaluation of the former works from a stim- ulus-response model (Arndt 1979; Johnston and Bonoma 1977) and that of the latter from a capital budgeting model (Day and Wensley 1983). Customer acquisition costs can be considered as investments offset by discounted "lifetime" customer valuation of ben- efits and burdens (Jackson 1985). Market segmenta- tion then is based more explicitly on response patterns and other relational considerations. We call on the power of advanced mathematical models to structure this complexity in relationship marketing.

Morrison et al.'s (1982) model of retail customer behavior at Merrill Lynch illustrates the research di- rection we are affirming. More specifically, we see great promise from enhancements to their model, namely a customer grouping algorithm, an expanded transition matrix, and response functions for different marketing inputs. The last would model the marketing programming impact on the transition probabilities for the groups between each phase of relationship devel- opment.

Applying the Framework Even in its propositional form the model makes two contributions to managerial action. First, it affords compelling post hoc explanations for the success or

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 23

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 15: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

failure of many current marketing practices. Second, it stimulates thinking in new directions of marketing programming.

The brief sections that follow are richer in pro- gram affirmation than program generation. Modest in- novations seem more in tune with the embryonic char- acter of our model. Nevertheless, we see great promise in creative imitation of some of the relational mar- keting practices exemplified in our three groups of managerial issues: performance metering, conflict management, and erecting exit barriers.

Performance Metering

Within any sustained association it is incumbent upon the parties to appraise their current satisfaction and signal each other of changing outcome priorities, role requirements, and growth opportunities. Two funda- mental managerial tactics offer sensible approaches. First, the seller can improve the conduits of com- municationfrom customers. Warranty cards, demon- strations and exhibitions, the retailer's customer ser- vice desk, and product use (e.g., recipe) contests are standard in this effort. Toll-free hotlines and sales- person followup are less common essentials of this aspect of relational marketing (Peters and Austin 1985).

The second approach is to obtain, unobtrusively, high-quality information on customer priorities and satisfactions within the exchange association. For meaningful relational marketing the seller needs to know whether purchases are intensifying or waning, expanding or contracting. Further, to the extent pos- sible, the seller will want to anticipate each custom- er's changing lifestyle, or business emphasis, and consequent shifts to new products and services. Low cost databases are making it operationally possible to track an increasing proportion of such behaviors un- obtrusively on an industrial account and household level. Rebate requests, coupon redemptions, credit card purchases, and registration data are rich with rela- tional marketing potential. When these data are com- bined with other data bases (e.g., Simmons and PRIZM) for media and lifestyle profiles, a new level of buyer-seller intimacy is opened-even for products historically mass marketed. They afford improved marketing efficiency from account clustering and pro- gram targeting, plus better and expanded customer service and satisfaction. AT&T has taken this ap- proach for targeting new programs of packaged long- distance services and networking opportunities for owners of personal computers. In contrast, a pack- aged goods marketer has coded and stored correspon- dence from 8 million brand users, but has initiated no analysis or followup relationship marketing since the initial response to each letter.

Conflict Management

Our model of relationship development highlights a process of ever-expanding interdependency between buyer and seller. Indeed, each party's gratifications from the other's role performance and increasing re- liance on role expectations secure the parties in a web of interdependencies. Conflict-divergence of goals and role preferences (Pondy 1967)-is predictable within the relationship just as periods of resource scarcity, misperceptions, and changing values and concepts of fair play are inevitable (cf. Ster and Gorman 1969; Thomas 1976).

Consistent with the managerial charge for perfor- mance metering is our second managerial concern, the constructive role of buyer-seller conflict. The destruc- tive consequences of conflict seem well catalogued: hostility, bitterness, strikes, violence, polarization of third parties, and isolationism. However, total suppression of conflict means a relationship has lost its vitality or parties are separating before fully ex- ploring the promise of their continued association (Hirshman 1970). We emphasize here the purported functional benefits of conflict (cf. Assael 1969; Rosenberg 1974), which include (1) more frequent and effective communications between the parties and the establishment of outlets to express grievances, (2) a critical review of past actions, (3) a more equitable distribution of system resources, (4) a more balanced power distribution in the relationship, and (5) stan- dardization of modes of conflict resolution.

These are hardly pioneering ideas, yet the current state of affairs does not appear to yield this full spec- trum of benefits. A national survey has shown that the majority of dissatisfied consumers who enlist the help of government agencies have made unsuccessful at- tempts to obtain redress from the seller (Harris and Associates 1977). In part, buyer redress attempts with the seller fail because buyers and sellers have incon- gruent norms of redress (Dwyer and Doroff 1981). Relationship marketing demands the establishment of mutually accepted redress norms.

Further, Weick (1979) has suggested that the cus- tomer service department in some organizations has evolved into being primarily a buffer to insulate man- agement from bad news from customers. In contrast, the possibilities for preserving and deepening the re- lationship by wholesome redress procedures and out- comes ought to fuel significant conflict management activity. Tracking the "back-end" profitability of cus- tomers for whom they have quickly resolved com- plaints versus that of customers who have not com- plained, Omaha Steaks-a purveyor of choice meats through the mail-finds the former are more profit- able (Kesler 1985). Thus, customer access to stan-

24 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 16: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

dardized procedures that reflect informed considera- tion of customer redress norms deserves highest priority.

Exit Barriers

Relational marketing requires an exchange structure that makes termination of the association unattractive. Consistent delivery of economic and psychosocial benefits in each transaction is critical but, as further motivation for the parties to resolve conflict to main- tain their relationship, it may be helpful to create structural disincentives for relational dissolution.

Exit barriers seem less common in consumer mar- kets than in industrial and organizational markets. Still, the prevalence of exit barriers in consumer relations and their strategic utility compel recognition. Con- sider the following examples.

* Frequent flier programs effectively maintain re- lational bonds when "bonus miles" are awarded in proportion to the flier's number of alternative carriers to each destination.

* Delayed rebates support ongoing exchange, such as accumulated proof of purchase seals used as

currency in a manufacturer's gift catalogue. * Rental deposits are essentially performance

bonds.

* A consumer durable goods "investment" ties the customer to frequent repurchase of specific con- sumable supplies.

We believe there are many additional opportuni- ties for implementing and tuning these practices. In

particular, status rewards or social recognition for re- lational longevity offer promise. Like the Gallon Do- nor in blood marketing or the President's Council in fund raising, there could be value in recognizing 5-, 10-, and 25-year subscribers to Time or three-time Buick buyers. In comparison, dissolution is encouraged by record clubs that reward termination (not loyalty) with attractive (re)enrollment offers.

Conclusion Prompted by Amdt's (1979) and Macneil's (1980) contrasts of discrete and relational exchange, our prin- cipal goal is to develop a framework for developing buyer-seller relationships. We emphasize three im-

portant caveats. First, though all transactions have some relational properties, it makes sense to consider many exchanges as "practically discrete." Second, there are bilateral sets of costs and benefits to relational ex-

change; a durable association is not necessarily desir- able. Third, because the model's eclectic conceptual and empirical origins are not proximal to marketing, it is highly propositional.

The marital metaphor seems parsimonious and

generative. For example, it directs research attention to the inherently dyadic process of power and bar-

gaining, flags trust as a pivotal specific expectancy, and underscores our ignorance about disengagement. Practically, the model affirms and suggests several avenues for relational marketing conduct. We are hard

pressed to identify anything more central to market-

ing.

REFERENCES Achrol, Ravi Singh, Torger Reve, and Louis W. Ster (1983),

"The Environment of Marketing Channel Dyads: A Frame- work for Comparative Analysis," Journal of Marketing, 47 (Fall), 55-67.

Advertising Age (1986), "Citicorp Boosts Results by Mixing Media" (January 27), 52-3.

Alderson, Wroe (1957), Marketing Behavior and Executive Action. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.

(1965), Dynamic Marketing Behavior. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.

Altman, Irwin and Dalmas A. Taylor (1973), Social Penetra- tion: The Development of Interpersonal Relationships. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc.

Anderson, James C. and James A. Narus (1984), "A Model of the Distributor's Perspective of Distributor-Manufacturer Working Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 48 (Fall), 62-74.

Ansoff, J. Igor (1957), "Strategies for Diversification," Har- vard Business Review (September-October), 113-24.

Arndt, Johan (1979), "Toward a Concept of Domesticated Markets," Journal of Marketing, 43 (Fall), 69-75.

(1983), "The Political Economy Paradigm: Foun- dation for Theory Building in Marketing," Journal of Mar- keting, 47 (Fall), 44-54.

Assael, Henry (1969), "Constructive Role of Interorganiza- tional Conflict," Administrative Science Quarterly, 14 (De- cember), 573-82.

Bagozzi, Richard P. (1975), "Marketing as Exchange," Jour- nal of Marketing, 39 (October), 32-9.

(1979), "Toward a Formal Theory of Marketing Exchanges," in Conceptual and Theoretical Developments in Marketing, O. C. Ferrell, Stephen W. Brown, and Charles W. Lamb, Jr., eds. Chicago: American Marketing Asso- ciation, 431-47.

Baxter, Leslie A. (1979), "Self-Disclosure as a Relationship Disengagement Strategy," Human Communication Re- search, 5 (Spring), 215-22.

(1983), "Relationship Disengagement: An Exami- nation of the Reversal Hypothesis," Western Journal of Speech Communication, 47 (Spring), 85-98.

(1985), "Accomplishing Relationship Disengage- ment," in Understanding Personal Relationships, Steve Duck

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 25

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 17: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

and Daniel Perlmand, eds. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Pub- lications, Inc., 243-65

and J. Philpott (1982), "Attribution-Based Strate- gies for Initiating and Terminating Relationships," Com- munication Quarterly, 30 (Summer), 217-24.

Blau, P. M. (1964), Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Bloch, Peter H. and Grady D. Bruce (1984), "Product In- volvement as Leisure Behavior," in Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 11, Thomas C. Kinnear, ed. Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research, 197-202.

Bloom, Bernard L., Shirley J. Asher, and Stephen W. White (1978), "Marital Disruption as a Stressor: A Review and

Analysis," Psychological Bulletin, 85, 867-94. Brickman, P. (1974), Social Conflict. Lexington, MA: D. C.

Heath and Company. Buckley, Walter F. (1967), Sociology and Modern Systems

Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Clopton, Stephen W. (1984), "Seller and Buying Firm Factors

Affecting Industrial Buyers' Negotiation Behavior and Out- comes," Journal of Marketing Research, 21 (February), 39- 53.

Cozby, Paul C. (1973), "Self-Disclosure: A Literature Re- view," Psychological Bulletin, 79 (January), 73-91.

Dahl, Robert A. (1957), "The Concept of Power," Behavioral Science (July), 201-15.

Davis, John D. and Adrian E. G. Skinner (1974), "Reciprocity of Self-Disclosure in Interviews: Modeling or Social Ex- change?," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 29 (June), 779-84.

Day, George S. and Robin Wensley (1983), "Marketing The- ory with a Strategic Orientation," Journal of Marketing, 47 (Fall), 79-89.

Duck, Steven W. (1982), "A Topography of Relationship Dis- engagement and Dissolution," in Personal Relationships, 4: Dissolving Personal Relationships, Steven Duck and Ro- bin Gilmour, eds. New York: Academic Press, Inc.

Dwyer, F. Robert (1984), "Are Two Better Than One? Bar- gaining Behavior and Outcomes in an Asymmetrical Power Relationship," Journal of Consumer Research, 11 (Sep- tember), 680-3.

and Ronald J. Domoff (1981), "The Congruency of Manufacturer Redress Actions and Consumer Redress Norms and Expectations," in Educators' Conference Proceedings, Series #47, Kenneth Berhardt et al., eds. Chicago: Amer- ican Marketing Association, 162-5.

and Orville C. Walker, Jr. (1981), "Bargaining in an Asymmetrical Power Structure," Journal of Marketing, 45 (Winter), 104-15.

Ekeh, P. P. (1974), Social Exchange: The Two Traditions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Emerson, Richard M. (1962), "Power Dependence Rela- tions," American Sociological Review, 27 (February), 31- 41.

Ferber, Robert (1970), "The Expanding Role of Marketing in the 1970s," Journal of Marketing, 34 (January), 29-30.

Fox, Alan (1974), Beyond Contract: Work Power and Trust Relations. London: Faber Ltd.

Frazier, Gary L. (1983a), "Interorganizational Exchange Be- havior: A Broadened Perspective," Journal of Marketing, 47 (Fall), 68-78.

(1983b), "On the Measurement of Interfirm Power in Channels of Distribution," Journal of Marketing Re- search, 20 (February), 158-66.

French, John and Bertram Raven (1959), "The Basis of Social Power," in Studies in Social Power, Dorwin Cartwright, ed. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 150-67.

Gaski, John F. (1984), "The Theory of Power and Conflict in Channels of Distribution," Journal of Marketing, 48 (Sum- mer), 9-29.

(1986), "Interrelations Among a Channel Entity's Power Sources: Impact of the Exercise of Reward and Coercion on Expert, Referent, and Legitimate Power Sources," Journal of Marketing Research, 23 (February), 62-77.

Goldberg, Victor P. (1979), "The Law and Economics of Ver- tical Restrictions: A Relational Perspective," Texas Law Review, 58, 91-129.

Golembiewski, R. T. and M. McConkie (1975), "The Cen- trality of Interpersonal Trust in Group Processes," in The- ories of Group Process, C. L. Cooper, ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Harris, Louis and Associates (1977), Consumerism at the Crossroads, A Study Conducted for Sentry Insurance. Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute.

Hill, Charles T., Zick Rubin, and Letitia A. Peplau (1976), "Breakups Before Marriage: The End of 103 Affairs," Journal of Social Issues, 32, 147-68.

Hirshman, A. 0. (1970), Exit, Voice and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Hunt, Shelby D. (1983a), "General Theories and the Funda- mental Explanada of Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 47 (Fall), 9-17.

(1983b), Marketing Theory; The Philosophy of Marketing Science. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.

Jackson, Barbara B. (1985), Winning and Keeping Industrial Customers: The Dynamics of Customer Relationships. Lex- ington, MA: D. C. Heath and Company.

John, George (1984), "An Empirical Investigation of Some Antecedents of Opportunism in a Marketing Channel," Journal of Marketing Research, 21 (August), 278-89.

Johnston, Wesley J. and Thomas V. Bonoma (1977), "Re-

conceptualizing Industrial Buying Behavior: Toward Im-

proved Research Approaches," in Contemporary Market-

ing Thought, Barnett A. Greenberg and Danny N. Bellenger, eds. Chicago: American Marketing Association, 247-51.

Kesler, Lori (1985), "Steak Company Welcomes Customers' Grilling," Advertising Age (October 17), 36-7.

Knapp, Mark L. (1978), Nonverbal Communication in Human Interaction, 2nd ed. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Win- ston, Inc.

Kotler, Philip (1972), "A Generic Concept of Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 36 (April), 46-54.

and Sidney J. Levy (1969), "Broadening the Con-

cept of Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 33 (January), 10-15.

and Gerald Zaltman (1971), "Social Marketing: An

Approach to Planned Social Change," Journal of Market-

ing, 35 (July), 3-12. LaFrance, Marianne and Clara Mayo (1978), Moving Bodies:

Nonverbal Communication in Social Relationships. Mon- terey, CA: Brooks/Cole.

Leigh, Thomas W. and Aro J. Rethans (1984), "A Script- Theoretic Analysis of Industrial Purchasing Behavior," Journal of Marketing, 48 (Fall), 22-32.

Levinger, G. and J. D. Snoek (1972), Attraction in Relation- ship: A New Look at Interpersonal Attraction. Morristown, NJ: General Learning Press.

Levitt, Theodore (1983), The Marketing Imagination. New York: The Free Press.

Lipset, S. M. (1975), "Social Structure and Social Change," in Approaches to the Study of Social Structure, P. M. Blau, ed. New York: The Free Press.

Lott, Albert J. and Bernice E. Lott (1974), "The Role of Re-

26 / Journal of Marketing, April 1987

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Page 18: Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Source: Journal of ... 640 INDUSTRIAL MARKETING … · Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships Marketing theory and practice have focused persistently

ward in the Formation of Positive Interpersonal Attitudes," in Foundation of Interpersonal Attraction, T. L. Huston, ed. New York: Academic Press, Inc.

Luck, D. (1969), "Broadening the Concept of Marketing- Too Far," Journal of Marketing, 33 (July), 53-5.

(1974), "Social Marketing: Confusion Com- pounded," Journal of Marketing, 38 (October), 70-2.

Lusch, Robert F. and James R. Brown (1982), "A Modified Model of Power in the Marketing Channel," Journal of Marketing Research, 19 (August), 312-23.

Macneil, Ian R. (1978), "Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neoclassical and Re- lational Contract Law," Northwestern University Law Re- view, 72, 854-902.

(1980), The New Social Contract, An Inquiry into Modern Contractual Relations. New Haven, CT: Yale Uni- versity Press.

McCall, George J. and J. L. Simmons (1966), Identities and Interactions. New York: The Free Press.

McCall, Michael M. (1966), "Courtship as Social Exchange: Some Historical Comparisons," in Kinship and Family Or- ganization, B. Farber, ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 190-210.

Miller, G. and M. Parks (1982), "Communication in Dissolv- ing Relationships," in Personal Relationships, 4: Dissolv- ing Personal Relationships, Steve W. Duck, ed. New York: Academic Press, Inc.

Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp. (1984), 104 S. Ct. 1464, 684 F. 2d 1226.

Morrison, Donald G., Richard D. H. Chen, Sandra L. Karpis, and Kathryn E. A. Britney (1982), "Modeling Retail Cus- tomer Behavior at Merrill Lynch," Marketing Science, 1 (Spring), 123-42.

Oliver, Richard L. (1980), "A Cognitive Model of the Ante- cedents and Consequences of Satisfaction Decisions," Journal of Marketing Research, 17 (November), 460-9.

Peters, Tom and Nancy Austin (1985), "Managing by Walk- ing Around," California Management Review, 28 (Fall), 9-34.

Pondy, Louis R. (1967), "Organizational Conflict: Concepts and Models," Administrative Science Quarterly, 12 (Sep- tember), 296-320.

Pruitt, Dean G. (1981), Negotiation Behavior. New York: Ac- ademic Press, Inc.

Raiffa, Howard (1982), The Art and Science of Negotiation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Raven, B. H. and A. W. Kruglanski (1970), "Conflict and Power," in The Structure of Conflict, Paul Swingle, ed. New York: Academic Press, Inc., 69-109.

Rosenberg, Larry J. (1974), "A New Approach to Distribution Conflict Management," Business Horizons, 17 (October), 67-74.

Rotter, Julian B. (1967), "A New Scale for the Measurement of Interpersonal Trust," Journal of Personality, 35 (4), 651- 65.

Scanzoni, J. (1979), "Social Exchange and Behavioral Inter-

dependence," in Social Exchange in Developing Relation-

ships, R. L. Burgess and T. L. Huston, eds. New York: Academic Press, Inc.

(1982), Sexual Bargaining: Power Politics in the American Marriage. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Schelling, Thomas (1960), The Strategy of Conflict. Cam-

bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Schurr, Paul H. and Julie L. Ozanne (1985), "Influences on Exchange Processes: Buyers' Preconceptions of a Seller's Trustworthiness and Bargaining Toughness," Journal of Consumer Research, 11 (March), 939-53.

Secord, Paul F. and Carl W. Backman (1974), Social Psy- chology, 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company.

Shapiro, Benson (1985), "Close Encounters of the Fourth Kind: The Latest Selling Evolution," working paper, Harvard Business School.

Smith, Robert E. and William R. Swinyard (1982), "Infor- mation Response Models: An Integrated Approach," Jour- nal of Marketing, 46 (Winter), 81-93.

Spekman, Robert E., Deborah Strauss, and Ruth Belk Smith (1985), "Antecedents of Collaborative Relations Between Buyers and Sellers: An Exploratory Investigation from the Buyer's Perspective," mimeo, University of Maryland.

Spiro, Rosann L. and William D. Perreault, Jr. (1979), "In- fluence Use by Industrial Salesmen: Influence-Strategy Mixes and Situational Determinants," Journal of Business, 52 (July), 435-55.

Stem, Louis and Ronald Gorman (1969), "Conflict in Distri- bution Channels: An Exploration," in Distribution Chan- nels: Behavioral Dimensions, Louis Stem, ed. New York: Houghton-Mifflin Company, 156-75.

and Torger Reve (1980), "Distribution Channels as Political Economies: A Framework for Comparative Anal- ysis," Journal of Marketing, 44 (Summer), 52-64.

Sullivan, Jeremiah and Richard B. Peterson (1982), "Factors Associated with Trust in Japanese-American Joint Ven- tures," Management International Review, 22, 30-40.

, ,Naoki Kameda, and Justin Shimada (1981), "The Relationship Between Conflict Resolution Approaches and Trust-A Cross Cultural Study," Academy of Management Journal, 24 (4), 803-15.

Swan, John E. and Johannah Jones Nolan (1985), "Gaining Customer Trust: A Conceptual Guide for the Salesperson," Journal of Personal Selling and Sales Management, 5 (No- vember), 39-48.

, I. Frederick Trawick, and David Silva (1985), "How Industrial Salespeople Gain Customer Trust," Industrial Marketing Management, 14 (August), 203-11.

Thibaut, John W. and Harold H. Kelley (1959), The Social Psychology of Groups. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Thomas, Kenneth (1976), "Conflict and Conflict Manage- ment," in Handbook of Industrial and Organizational Psy- chology, Marvin D. Dunnette, ed. Chicago: Rand Mc-

Nally, Inc., 889-935. Weick, Karl (1979), The Social Psychology of Organizing, 2nd

ed. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Inc.

Weitz, Barton A. (1981), "Effectiveness in Sales Interactions: A Contingency Framework," Journal of Marketing, 45 (Winter), 85-103.

Williamson, Oliver (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free Press.

(1983), "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to

Support Exchanges," American Economics Review, 73

(September), 519-40. Worchel, Philip (1979), "Trust and Distrust," in Social Psy-

chology and Intergroup Relations, W. B. Austin and S. Worchel, eds. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing Co.

Zand, Dale E. (1972), "Trust and Managerial Problem Solv-

ing," Administrative Science Quarterly, 117 (2), 229-39.

Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships / 27

This content downloaded from 92.45.56.74 on Mon, 15 Feb 2016 12:29:09 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions