Demographics, Redistribution, and Optimal In⁄ation · 2017. 2. 25. · Demographics,...

31
Demographics, Redistribution, and Optimal Ination James Bullard, FRB of St. Louis Carlos Garriga, FRB of St. Louis Christopher J. Waller, FRB of St. Louis 2012 BOJ-IMES Conference Demographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance The views expressed herein do not necessarily reect those of the FOMC or the Federal Reserve System.

Transcript of Demographics, Redistribution, and Optimal In⁄ation · 2017. 2. 25. · Demographics,...

  • Demographics, Redistribution, and OptimalInflation

    James Bullard, FRB of St. LouisCarlos Garriga, FRB of St. Louis

    Christopher J. Waller, FRB of St. Louis

    2012 BOJ-IMES ConferenceDemographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance

    The views expressed herein do not necessarily reflect those ofthe FOMC or the Federal Reserve System.

  • Inflation and Demography

    I Can observed low inflation outcomes be related todemographic factors such as an aging population?

    I A basic “back-of-the-envelop” suggests NOI Consider an economy were capital and money are perfectsubstitutes

    r = δ+ n =1

    1+ π

    I The effect of a permanent increase in n′ > n increases thereturn of capital r ′ > r and inflation decreases to π′.

    I Countries with relatively young (old) populations would haverelatively low (high) inflation rates, all else equal.

  • Inflation and Demography: Japan

  • Inflation and Demography: USA

  • Objective

    I Understand the determination of central bank objectives whenpopulation aging shifts the social preferences for redistributionand its implications for inflation.

    I The intergenerational redistribution tension is intrinsic inlife-cycle models.

    I Young cohorts do not have any assets and wages are the mainsource of income.

    I Old generations cannot work and prefer a high rate of returnfrom their savings.

    I When the old have more (less) influence over redistributivepolicy, the rate of return of money is high (low).

  • Objective

    I Approach: Based on Bullard and Waller (2004) but withdynamics

    I Use a direct mechanism to decide the allocations. A babyboom corresponds to putting more weight on the young of aparticular generation relative to past and future generations.

    I This mechanism can replicate any steady state allocationarising from a political economy model with populationgrowth or decline.

  • Outline Presentation

    I Effi cient economy and intergenerational redistributionI Constrained effi ciency and redistributionI Optimal Wedges: Capital taxes=InflationI Numerical examples

    I Transitory demographicsI Persistent demographic changes

  • Model

  • Environment

    I Two-period OLG model with capital.I Discrete time t = ...,−2,−1, 0, 1, 2, ...I Population growth Nt = (1+ n)Nt−1 where N0 = 1I Preferences: U(c1,t , c2,t+1) = u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)I Neoclassical production F (Kt ,Nt ) and constant depreciation δI Per capital resource constraint

    c1,t +1

    1+ nc1,t−1 + (1+ n) kt+1 = f (kt ) + (1− δ) kt .

  • Social Preferences and Optimal Allocations

    I The objective function weights current and future generationsaccording to

    V (k0) = max{βλ−1u(c2,0) +∞

    ∑t=0

    λt [u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)]}.

    subject to the resource constraint.I Optimality conditions imply

    u′(c1,t )u′(c2,t )

    =λt−1λt

    β(1+ n)

    and

    (1+ n)u′(c1,t )u′(c1,t+1)

    =λt+1λt

    [1− δ+ f ′(kt+1)

    ].

  • Steady State

    I Effi cient production: the steady state stock of capital ks isdetermined by

    f ′(ks ) = (1+ n)λ−1 + δ− 1,

    For λ < 1, the economy is dynamically effi cient. When λ = 1,the economy satisfies the golden rule f ′(k∗) = n+ δ.

    I Effi cient consumption cs1 and cs2 solve

    u′(cs1 ) = β(1+ n)u′(cs2 )

    cs1 +cs21+ n

    + (δ+ n)ks = f (ks ).

  • Market Implementation: Intergenerational Redistribution

    I Consumers: Representative newborn solves

    max u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)

    s.t. c1,t + st = wt lt + T1,t ,

    c2,t+1 = (1− δ+ rt+1)st + T2,t+1.The optimality condition

    u′(wt lt − st +T1t ) = βu′ [(1− δ+ rt+1)st + T2,t+1] (1+ rt+1).

    I Intergenerational redistribution:

    T1,t +T2,t1+ n

    = 0.

  • No Intergenerational Redistribution (Ramsey)

    I In the absence of intergenerational redistribution

    V (k0) = max{βλ−1u(c2,0) +∞

    ∑t=0

    λt [u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)]}

    s.t. c1,t = fl (kt ) l − (1+ n)kt+1,c2,t = [1− δ+ fk (kt )] kt ,

    I Optimality conditions (endogenous multipliers γ1,t ,γ2,t)

    u′(c1,t )u′(c2,t )

    =λt−1λt

    β(1+ n)γ1,tγ2,t

  • Markets Redistribute: Capital taxes/inflationI The intergenerational decision of savings (capital) is morecomplicated:

    (1+ n) u′(c1,t )︸ ︷︷ ︸↑savings

    =λt+1λt

    u′(c1,t+1)fl ,kl

    1+ n︸ ︷︷ ︸↑wage rate

    +βu′(c2,t+1)[1− δ+ fk + fk ,kst1+ n︸ ︷︷ ︸]

    ↓return all savings

    I Effi cient wedges

    u′(c1,t )βu′(c2,t+1)

    =

    [1− δ+ fk

    ( st−11+n

    )(1+ φkt+1)

    ](1+ φλt+1)

    .

    where

    φk =kfk ,kfk

    < 1; φλt+1 = λu′(c1,t+1)u′(c1,t )

    fk ,k

    (st−11+ n

    )l

    1+ n< 1

  • Money and Capital

    I The optimal intergenerational redistribution determines theequilibrium interest rate.

    I These parameters determine inflation when capital and moneyare perfect substitutes.

    I Per capita money growth rate evolves

    Mt+1 (1+ n) = (1+ zt )Mt

    I Arbritrage then implies that

    fk (kt ) =1

    1+ πt=1+ n1+ zt

    .

    I Money is priced as an asset that is held in zero net supply(Woodford’s (2003) “cashless” economy).

  • Quantitative Illustration

  • Functional Forms

    I Preferences:

    U(c1,t , c2,t+1) =c1−σ1,t1− σ + β

    c1−σ2,t+11− σ ,

    I Technology:f (k) = Akα

  • Parameterization

    Parameter Valueα 0.35A 10

    l = δ 1σ 2n 0.99630

    β 0.97930

  • Steady State

  • Capital Stock

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.50.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    Intergenerational Discounting(λ)

    Cap

    ital S

    tock

    E fficientConstrained

  • Consumption Young

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5

    0.45

    0.5

    0.55

    0.6

    0.65

    Intergenerational Discounting ( λ)

    Con

    sum

    ptio

    n Yo

    ung(

    %)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Inflation (n

  • Inflation (n=0)

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5

    -0.015

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    Intergenerational Discounting( λ)

    Infla

    tion

    EfficientConstrained

  • Transitional Dynamics:Demographics and Inflation

  • Intergenerational Redistribution: Transitory

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 900.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6In

    terg

    ener

    atio

    nal D

    isco

    untin

    g ( λ

    )

  • Inflation and Demographics: Transitory

    10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015In

    flatio

    n (A

    nnua

    lized

    ) EfficientConstrained

  • Interest Rates and Demographics: Transitory

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.5

    -0.4

    -0.3

    -0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2In

    tere

    st R

    ates

    (% C

    hang

    e)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Intergenerational Redistribution: Permanent

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 900.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6In

    terg

    ener

    atio

    nal D

    isco

    untin

    g ( λ

    )

  • Inflation and Demographics: Permanent

    10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    x 10-3In

    flatio

    n (A

    nnua

    lized

    )EfficientConstrained

  • Interest Rates and Demographics: Permanent

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.5

    -0.4

    -0.3

    -0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2In

    tere

    st R

    ates

    (% C

    hang

    e)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Conclusions

    I Study the interaction between population demographics, thedesire for redistribution in the economy, and the optimalinflation rate.

    I The intergenerational redistribution tension is intrinsic inlife-cycle models.

    I Young cohorts do not have any assets and wages are the mainsource of income.

    I Old generations cannot work and prefer a high rate of returnfrom their savings.

    I When the old have more (less) influence over redistributivepolicy, the rate of return of money is high (high).