DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of...

29
Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche Università degli Studi di Brescia Via San Faustino 74/B – 25122 Brescia – Italy Tel: +39 0302988839/840/848, Fax: +39 0302988837 e-mail: [email protected] www.eco.unibs.it These Discussion Papers often represent preliminary or incomplete work, circulated to encourage discussion and comments. Citation and use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author(s). Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università degli Studi di Brescia. Research disseminated by the Department may include views on policy, but the Department itself takes no institutional policy position. DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC GOODS By Rosella Levaggi, Francesco Menoncin Discussion Paper n. 0909

Transcript of DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of...

Page 1: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche

Università degli Studi di Brescia Via San Faustino 74/B – 25122 Brescia – Italy

Tel: +39 0302988839/840/848, Fax: +39 0302988837 e-mail: [email protected] – www.eco.unibs.it

These Discussion Papers often represent preliminary or incomplete work, circulated to encourage discussion and comments. Citation and use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author(s). Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università degli Studi di Brescia. Research disseminated by the Department may include views on policy, but the Department itself takes no institutional policy position.

DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT

AND IMPURE PUBLIC GOODS

By

Rosella Levaggi, Francesco Menoncin

Discussion Paper n. 0909

Page 2: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

Decentralised provision of merit and impurepublic goods

Rosella Levaggi and Francesco MenoncinDipartimento di Scienze Economiche

Via San Faustino 74b25100 Brescia

[email protected]@eco.unibs.it

July 8, 2009

Abstract

In some countries reforms of public service provision have been accom-panied by a parallel process of devolution. However, the application of�scal federalism has not always produced the desired e¤ects. We arguethat this result may depend on two factors: a) a lack of coordination caus-ing a non-optimal allocation of resources at aggregate level; b) a lack ofincentive to coordination. In our model we assume that goods to be pro-vided at local level are impure public goods. This assumption allows us toconsider a more realistic scenario where the production and consumptionof the local public good do not necessarily coincide. In an environmentwith full information and no restriction on the quantities to be providedas the one we propose, �scal federalism is always suboptimal for the wholecommunity, as it may be expected. However, we show that this does notnecessarily mean that in �scal federalism each local authority is worseo¤. This implies that coordination is never the outcome of the strategicinteraction between the actors and that when the assumption of symmet-ric information is removed, Central Government will have to expect somelocal authorities to play strategically against such intervention.

Keywords: Fiscal federalism, decentralisation, impure publicgoods, mobility

J.E.L. I18,H77

1

Page 3: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

1 Introduction

Policy implementation at national and supranational level usually relies on del-egated choices in which either a government agency (acting as an agent) or anautonomous government level is charged with the responsibility of supplyingspeci�c services. The aim of these reforms is to improve e¢ ciency and ulti-mately to increase welfare. However, this process has not always produced thedesired e¤ects. The traditional literature on �scal federalism (see Oates, 1972,and King, 1984, and, for a more detailed review, Oates, 2005) suggests thatthe allocation of functions to local government should follow e¢ ciency princi-ples. The choice of the quantity to be produced should be left to the tier whichis better informed on local preferences, while grants might be used for equityand e¢ ciency reasons. Second generation models (Oates, 2005) suggest thatthe success of �scal federalism depends on the information the agents possessabout: a) speci�c parameters (Levaggi and Smith, 1992; Levaggi, 2008; Akaiand Mikami, 2006; Snoddon and Wen, 2003); b) the behaviour of other agents(Petretto, 2000) and the e¤ects of their decisions on total welfare (Wildasin,2004; Crivelli and Staal, 2006). The �rst issue has been widely studied in theliterature and suggests a trade-o¤between autonomy and control: the local levelis better informed than the centre on the relevant parameters that a¤ect welfareand it can strategically use such information. Central Government should thenbalance the improvement in welfare with the cost deriving from asymmetry ofinformation. The last two issues are related since the need for coordinationoften arises from the presence of spillovers (Besley and Coate, 2003; Wildasinand Ogawa, 2008). These problems open a very interesting debate on the dis-tribution of welfare gains derived from �scal federalism even in a context whereinformation is symmetric. In our opinion this problem has not received the dueattention in the literature and it may well represent one of the main causes forthe observed poor performances of some federal system.A second and rather important consideration is that, although very sophis-

ticated in its modelling approach, most of the literature models local publicgood which may produce spillovers on the other local authorities (exceptionsare Wildasin, 1997 and Levaggi, 2008). However, most of the services producedat local level are either impure public goods or merit goods. The former areboth private goods (increasing utility for the quantity actually bought) and pub-lic goods (for the entire amount produced); the latter are private goods whoseconsumption is �nanced by the Government for equity/redistribution purposes.For these goods the quantity made available to a speci�c community should notnecessarily be produced and made available where they live. In other words,a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may beallowed. The main examples of goods falling into this category are educationand health care. This opens interesting policy questions relating to assignmentof the quantity to be produced, the transfer price and the level of coordinationamong policies that is necessary to achieve a �rst best result.The aim of our paper is to explore the coordination problem that may arise

in a true federal state, without considering the traditional bene�ts arising from

2

Page 4: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

�scal federalism that the literature has long pointed out (Oates, 1972; 2005).We model the production of a merit/impure public good and compare the

welfare properties of three settings a) a centralised system; b) �scal fderalismand c) decentralisation assuming that the quantity demanded in a region maybe produced elsewhere. We will compare the equilibrium conditions and theresults with a more traditional model where mobility is not allowed.In our context where information is complete and symmetric, �scal fed-

eralism is always sub-optimal for the whole community as one might expect.However, this does not mean that each local autority is worse o¤. Some regionsmay in fact be better o¤, usually because of a reduced tax e¤ort due to a reduc-tion in the equalising grant. If Central Government, as in the present example,has perfect knowledge, a �rst best can be reached also in a decentralised systemthrough the use of a matching grant. However, this solution will not be reachedas a coordination game between the two local authorities because coordinationis not welfare improving for both of them.We think that this aspect related to gainers and losers in pure decentralised

decisions may explain why in the actual world, even when we take into accountthe bene�ts deriving from a better knowledge of local prefererence, the gainfrom �scal federalism may be limited, if not negative.The paper is organised as follows: in Section 2 we present the general frame-

work. In Section 3 the �rst best in the case of a centralized solution is computed.Sections 4 and 5 show the cases of �scal federalism and decentralization respec-tively. A discussion and a numerical simulation is left to Section 6. Section 7concludes.

2 The model

The model presented here examines decentralisation in a context where thecommodity produced is an impure local public good with spillovers (Besley andCoate, 2003; Crivelli and Staal, 2006; Wildasin, 1997). We assume that theexternal e¤ects are anonymous and additive within the same local authority,but the distribution among local authorities matters.A country, whose population is normalised to one, is divided into two local

authorities i 2 fa; bg of equal size. Each individual has an exogenous moneyincome, Mk in the range

�Y i; Y i

�, whose density function is assumed to be

uniform. Then, total income in region i is

Yi =1

2

Z Y i

Y i

Mk

Y i � Y idMk =

Y i + Y i4

:

Income is used to buy private commodities and one or zero unit of an im-pure local public good H whose price is equal to pi:Individual�s taste for H isdescribed by the parameter � which is assumed to be uniformly distributed inthe range (0; �), with density function ��1.

3

Page 5: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

One unit of H is bought if � is greater than pi. The utility of buying H isgiven by the di¤erence �� pi if it is positive, otherwise utility is zero. In otherwords, the utility coincides with the demanded quantity. This model is suitableif H is an impure public good. Nevertheless, if H is a merit good, then it isfully subsidised and its utility should coincide with �. Accordingly, the averageutility (i.e. the total demand) for all the agents in region i is given by

Qi =1

2

Z �

pi

(�� �pi)1

�d� =

1

4

�2 � 2�pi� � p2i + 2�p2i�

;

where � = 1 if H is an impure public good, while � = 0 if H is a merit good.In this last case pi represents the marginal utility of the merit good that thedecision maker is willing to �nance.1

Good H also produces a public good that depends on the quantity producedin each region, S. We assume the local public good S has some spillovers, thenwelfare in region i can be modelled as Nota: produces produced ma che altrosi può mettere?

Wi = Yi (1� t� � i) +Qi + �i (Si; Sj) ;i; j 2 fa; bg ;i 6= j:

where t is the central tax rate and � i the local one. The former is set byCentral Government to pursue equity and correct for spillovers, according to thedi¤erent institutional setting (centralisation, �scal federalism, decentralisation);the latter is set by the local authority.The nature of the impure local public good is captured by �i(�) which allows

to di¤erentiate the utility generated by the public good according to where itis produced. As in Besley and Coate (2003), we introduce �scal federalism byassuming that preferences for the impure public good are additive within eachlocal authority:

�i(:) = fi(Si) + gi (Sj) ; i 2 fa; bg :Functions f (�) and g (�) are assumed to be increasing and concave in their

argument (decreasing marginal utility at community level), hence the utility ofan additional unit depends on where it is produced2 . The level of publicness ofthe good depends on the functional form for f (�) and g (�). In particular:

1. for fi = gi, the good H is a public good;

2. for gi = 0, the good H is local public good;

3. for 0 < gi < fi, the good H is a local public good with spillovers.

1The coe¢ cient 12before the integral is due to the assumption that the population in each

region is 12since the total population has been assumed to be 1.

2For a distinction between global public goods and local public goods with spillovers seeLevaggi (2009).

4

Page 6: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

In this environment, the decision maker has to internalise the externalitycaused by the consumption of H via a subsidy that is �nanced through a linearincome tax, partly levied at national level (t) and partly at local level at rate� i.Here, we assume:

1. Ya > Yb, i.e. local authority a is richer than b;

2. the marginal cost to produce H is constant and there is no �xed cost;

3. the average cost of production is equal to v, and local authority a is moree¢ cient than b in the production process so that va < vb.

Given the double nature of private and public good, the bene�tter of thetwo characteristics may not coincide. The quantity demanded by residents ineach local authority (Qi) does not necessarily need to coincide with the quantityproduced in the same area (Si). This implies that to match supply and demand,lower tiers have to negotiate a transfer price which will not be equal to marginalcost, given the externality produced.In this context �scal federalism, i.e. the complete devolution of the pro-

duction of good H to a lower tier, produces a welfare loss because the positiveexternality produced by its supply of public good (spillover e¤ect) may not becorrectly evaluated. However, although total welfare is decreasing, �scal federal-ism may produce a welfare improvement for some local authorities (the richestones) because it may reduce the pressure for equalisation of resources. Thismeans that a cooperative solution to internalise such externalities may not befeasible and that Central Government�s intervention to correct for spillovers maynot be feasible if lower tiers have private information or play strategically.In this paper we concentrate on coordination problems, i.e. we assume that

the goods produced at central and local level produce the same level of utility.In a more general context the loss deriving from the problems presented in thispaper will have to be balanced with the gains outlined by the traditional theoryon �scal federalism.

3 Centralised solution (First Best)

The provision of impure public goods at local level may be granted by CentralGovernment directly or through an agency (centralisation), by an autonomouslower tier (�scal federalism) or by a lower tier with a speci�c intervention ofa higher tier aimed at reducing the problems arising from lack of coordination(decentralisation). The relative advantages of these solutions have long beendiscussed in the literature3 . Given that the aim of the paper is to study thecoordination problems that may arise in a decentralised system, we will �rstpresent the centralised solution which in our context corresponds to First Best.Central Government has to �nd the optimal mix between the central tax rate

3See, for example, Levaggi and Smith (2006), Oates (2005), Besley and Coate (2003).

5

Page 7: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

(t), the local one (� i) and the user charge (pi). As in Petretto (2000), thenational income tax is used to �nance a part of the provision of such good andto redistribute resources:

t =�Sva + �Svb +Ga +Gb

Ya + Yb;

where S is a �xed quantity of the service that Central Government wishes to�nance and 0 � � � 1 is the share of the cost the central Government is willingto �nance. Both S and � depend on the preferences of Central Government;we assume they are set outside the model and equal to zero. Gi representsthe equalisation grant which is distributed in a lump-sum form as suggested byDahlby and Wilson (1994) and Smart (1998):

Gi =1

2�m�Y � Yi

�;

�m =�aYa + � bYbYa + Yb

;

Y =Ya + Yb2

;

where �m and Y represent the national average surtax rate and the standardisedtax base. Both are invariant to each regional �scal decision, i.e. local authoritiesdo not perceive the e¤ects that their tax rate has on the equalisation grant.Impure public good are heterogeneous, varying from impure public goods in

its most traditional de�nition (Musgrave and Musgrave, 1973) to spurious meritgoods4 . In our model, such characteristic of the service is captured by the usercharge. For an impure public good, the usual form is a price subsidy, i.e. theconsumer is asked to pay a fraction of the price of the service produced. Whenthe impure public good is also a merit good, it is usually supplied for free, butnot necessarily to the entire population. The most representative example inthis category is health care which is supplied for free or through the paymentof a limited fee, but only if the treatment is cost e¤ective5 .The impure public good used by residents in one region but produced outside

has a price q. For this reason, the local tax rate can be written as:

� i =viSi � �piQi + q(Qi � Si)�Gi

Yi:

The problem for Central Government is to �nd the quantity of H to beproduced, the optimal �nancial mix, the transfer price and the best outputdistribution. In actual fact, the maximisation cannot be performed for q, the

4The basic di¤erence between a merit good and an impure public good is that the formeris in fact a private good that is used to improve income redistribution or to pivot consumers�preferences towards the use of goods which the planner thinks they should use. We de�neas spurious merit good a class of services that have this double characteristic, for examplehealth, education and cultural activities.

5 In this case, � may represent the e¤ectiveness of the treatment for that speci�c patient.

6

Page 8: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

transfer price. In a centralised system, q is used as an instrument to redistributeincome between the two local authorities; in our model, given the assumptionof linear utility as regards disposable income, distribution does not matter. Forthis reason, such parameter will have to be determined by Central Governmentusing other criteria.6 The problem for Central Government can be written as:

maxpa;pb;Sa;SbX

i 6=j=a;b

�Yi (1� t� � i) + 1

4�2�2�pi��p2i+2�p

2i

� + fi (Si) + gi (Sj)�

s.t.� i =

(vi�q)Si�(�pi�q)Qi�Gi

Yi;

t = Ga+Gb

Ya+Yb= 0;

Sa + Sb = Qa +Qb = Q:(1)

The FOC are derived in Appendix A and can be written as:

@fa(Sa)@Sa

+ @gb(Sa)@Sa

+ p = va;@fb(Sb)@Sb

+ @ga(Sb)@Sb

+ p = vb;

pa = pb = p;p2� =

q+�2� ;

p� =

�1� SDa � SDb

�:

(2)

The �rst two conditions can be written as

va �@fa (Sa)

@Sa� @gb (Sa)

@Sa= vb �

@fb (Sb)

@Sb� @ga (Sb)

@Sb;

which can be interpreted in the following way: the allocation of production be-tween the two local authorities should follow an e¢ ciency principle by balancingthe need to reduce the cost of public provision with the utility both communitiesderive from the location of the production of that speci�c good.The quantity of the impure public good in the two local authorities will be

the same in equilibrium. According to the value of �, p can be interpreted interms of a price or a demanded quantity. In both cases p� is chosen to equalizethe marginal rate of substitution between income and the impure public goodwith the price ratio. Although the e¤ect of q in aggregate cancels out, its valuea¤ects �, the Lagrange multiplier. This parameter is equal to zero when thetransfer price q is chosen to make supply and demand match. In a centralisedcontext where Central Government may choose the level of supply and demandin the two regions, q may be arbitrarily set. However, if such price does notclear the market, � will be positive, indicating the presence of an equilibriumwith rationing.The further discretion that Central Government has in this case may be used

to improve equalisation and the level of welfare in the two regions, but at thecost of severe controls to avoid overspending.

6An alternative may be to use the average cost: va+vb�

or the minimum production cost,vain our case.

7

Page 9: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

The optimal solution in terms of p�, S�a, S�b , Q

�a, and Q

�bcan be substituted

in the welfare function:

W � =1

2

�2 � 2�p�� � p�2 + 2�p�2�

(3)

+X

i 6=j=a;b

�Yi (1� t� ��i (q)) + fi (S�i ) + gi(S�j )

�;

��i (q) =S�i (vi � q)�Q�i (�p� � q)

Yi

��Y � Yi

�(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

(S�i (vi � q)�Q�i (�p� � q)) :

The value of ��i (q), the optimal local tax rate, depends on the net cost to pro-duce the optimal quantity S�i and on the equalisation grant. In aggregate theydo not have any e¤ect on welfare because they simply determine the allocationof income between the two jurisdictions.However, the welfare of each single jurisdiction depends on q. The lower

the q the better-o¤ the less e¢ cient local authority where residents to get theimpure public good at a very convenient price. In aggregate the two e¤ectscancel out and do not a¤ect the equalisation grant that is de�ned on an averagetax rate. However, as pointed out before, if q is not chosen to equalise supplyand demand, the Government will have to implement rationing on the demandfor the part of services bought outside each jurisdiction.

3.1 Special cases

The more traditional case studied by the literature on �scal federalism wherethe quantity demanded at local level is produced in the same jurisdiction (i.e.mobility is not allowed) is a special case of our model. In this case the lastconstraint in (1) becomes:

Sa = Qa;

Sb = Qb:

The FOC presented in Appendix A can be written as:

12�

�@fa(Qa)@Qa

+ @gb(Qa)@Qa

�+ pa

2� =va2� ;

12�

�@fb(Qb)@Qb

+ @ga(Qb)@Qb

�+ pb

2� =vb2� :

(4)

The interpretation is straightforward: the quantity to be produced in eachlocal authority is equal to the sum of the private marginal utility (p) and thepublic marginal utility, taking the externalities into due account. It is interestingto note that if the marginal cost in the two local authorities di¤ers, even in thepresence of a public good the quantity supplied in the two tiers will be di¤erent.This represents an important and interesting di¤erence from the model in which

8

Page 10: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

mobility is allowed, a result somehow similar to the literature on bene�ts arisingfrom international trade.Also in this case, the optimal values bp�i , bQ�aand bQ�b can be substituted in the

welfare function:

cW �i =

Xi=a;b

�Yi (1� t� b��i ) + 14 �2 � 2�bp�i � � bp�2i + 2�bp�2i

�(5)

+X

i 6=j=a;b

�fi

� bQ�i�+ gi � bQ�j�� ;b��i =

bQ�i (vi � �bp�i )Yi

��Y � Yi

�(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

bQ�i (vi � �bp�i ) :Welfare is certainly lower than in the previous example, unless mobility is

zero in equilibrium in (3). As per welfare distribution, Central Government maysimply use the equalisation grant, i.e. the margins for redistribution are morelimited.

"Global" public goods Another interesting case that may be consideredis represented by the assumption that the public good is produced throughdemand, not supply. In other words, the welfare function should be written as

W =Xi=a;b

�Yi (1� t� � i) +

1

4

�2 � 2�pi� � p2i + 2�p2i�

�+fa (Qa) + ga (Qb) + fb (Qa) + gb (Qb) :

In this case, the good should be produced in the most e¢ cient local author-ity. Although the functional form is rather di¤erent, the coordination problemsarising in this context are those studied by the literature on global public goods.7

4 Fiscal federalism

In this framework, each local authority sets its own level of taxation and serviceproduction according to its preferences and resources. It takes t and G as given,and perceives its budget constraint as hard. Central Government�s role is merelycon�ned to equalising resources through the lump-sum grant; this actor is thelast one to move, i.e. it sets the grant after local authorities have set their ownlevel of expenditure and taxation. Local authorities have the maximum degreeof autonomy and we denote it by �scal federalism.The �rst best solution outlined in Section 3 may not be the outcome of a

process of �scal federalism, even in a setting where there is symmetric informa-tion between Central Government and local authorities. This usually happensbecause the local authority does not fully take into account the consequences

7See Levaggi (2009) for a review of these issues.

9

Page 11: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

of its actions on welfare (Petretto, 2000). This behaviour usually leads to asub-optimal solution; in this section we show the classical problem arising fromlack of coordination: each local authority maximises its own utility functionwhereas in the centralized model the total welfare is maximized. The problemfaced by each local authority can be written as

maxpi;SiW = Yi (1� t� � i) + 14�2�2�pi��p2i+2�p

2i

� + fi (Si) + gi (Sj)

s.t.� i =

(vi�q)Si�(�pi�q)Qi�Gi

Yi

(6)

The FOC for the problem are derived in Appendix B and can be written as

pi = q;

�vi + q + @fi(Si)@Si

= 0:(7)

Each local authority does not take into account the spillover e¤ect that itsproduction creates on the neighbour jurisdiction. Furthermore, in their max-imisation process they take q as a given parameter, but in equilibrium only avalue will clear the market. To reconcile decentralisation with market clearingconditions, it is necessary to �nd the q that satis�es the optimal conditions (7)and the market clearing constraint. The problem can be solved using a Nashgame:

Si = f 0�1i (vi � q) ; (8)

Sa + Sb = Qa +Qb = 1�q

�:

After �nding the q that clears the market, it will be possible to obtain p, Saand Sb.The total quantity produced is lower than in �rst best because the local

authorities do not take the positive externality into account. Total welfare canbe written as

W =1

2

�2 � 2�p� � p2 + 2�p2�

+Xi=a;b

Yi (1� t� � i) (9)

+X

i 6=j=a;b

�fi�Si�+ gi

�Sj��;

� i =Si (vi � q)�Qi (�p� q)

Yi

��Y � Yi

�(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

�Si (vi � q)�Qi (�p� q)

�:

Total welfare will be lower than in the �rst best equilibrium, but this doesnot necessarily mean that both local authorities are worse o¤. To explain this,let�s compare (3) with (9. The quantity produced is lower than in the �rst best

10

Page 12: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

equilibrium. This means that the average local tax rate� is lower. In general,the �rst e¤ect o¤sets the second, but in this case the average tax rate is also usedto set the equalising grant Gi:This implies that less resources are �owing fromA to B in equilibrium and this income e¤ect may, for the richer local authority,more than o¤set the initial loss due to underproduction. The second elementthat determines � i is q, the price set for mobility. In First Best it may be set toany level, provided that Central Government is prepared to impose rationing.In this model it is the market that sets q; but the e¤ect on the distribution ofwelfare in this case is ambiguous: it depends on the initial level of q:In general,it is not however possible to conclude that both local authorities are losers.

4.1 No mobility

As for centralisation, we can examine the optimal conditions for the case wheremobility is not allowed. In this case it is possible to �nd a solution withouta coordination e¤ort between the two local authorities. In fact, each of themmaximises its own utility function and assumes that the quantity produced bythe other local authority is set. The F.O.C for the problem can be written as:

12�

�@fa(Qa)@Qa

�+ pa

2� =va2� ;

12�

�@fb(Qb)@Qb

�+ pb

2� =vb2� :

(10)

The quantity produced and demanded will clearly be lower than in the FirstBest equilibrium as in the case with mobility. Total welfare in this case can bewritten as

fW =1

2

�2 � ep2i � 2�epi� + 2�ep2i�

+Xi=a;b

Yi (1� t� e� i) (11)

+X

i 6=j=a;bfi

� eQi�+ gi � eQj� ;e� i =

eQi (vi � �epi)Yi

��Y � Yi

�(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

eQi (vi � �epi) :Also in this case total welfare is lower than in �rst best, but this does not

necessarily mean that both local authorities are worse o¤. In this case, therichest local authority is certainly paying less in terms of equalising grant andthis e¤ect may o¤set the loss in utility caused by the reduction in the quantityof impure public goods produced.To explain how this happens, let�s examine Figure 1 where the di¤erent

e¤ects are depicted.

The �rst best optimal allocation is represented by the combination� bQ�a; bQ�b�.

Given a speci�c level of expenditure, Central Government sets the lump sum

grant Gi so that the net income of each local authority is�bY �a ; bY �b � and total

welfare is cW �a +cW �

b . In the �scal federalism case, each local authority does not

11

Page 13: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

-�QaQb

a0

a

a0a

6

O

Yb

b0

b

b0b

cW �a

fWa

fWb

cW �b

Ya

eQa bQ�a

bY �aeYabY �b

eQbbQ�beYb

Wa

Wb

Figure 1: Centralisation vs �scal federalism: welfare analysis

perceive the positive externality its production creates and the optimal quantity

of impure public good is reduced to� eQa; eQb�. Expenditure and the average tax

rate decreases, there is less need for equalisation grant. This is the reason whythe budget constraint shifts from aa to a0a0. and from bb tob0b0 respectively. Bcertainly su¤ers a welfare loss, but A may be better o¤: the quantity of impurepublic good produced is lower than the optimal amount, but the income e¤ectbrought about by the reduction in the equalisation grant may compensate suchreduction. We can then conclude that while

cW �a +cW �

b > fWa +fWb;fW �b > fWb;

for A we have cW �a ? fWa:

This is the reason why, although a bargaining solution where the two localauthorities coordinate their e¤ort and pay for the reciprocal externalities shouldbe envisaged, such outcome may not be reached. If Central Government wishesto reach an optimal allocation, a form of reduced autonomy has to be used.

5 Decentralisation

Central Government may follow di¤erent strategies in a federal context. Its pri-mary objective is to �nd an optimal trade-o¤ between autonomy and control.

12

Page 14: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

For this reason, it may leave local authorities free to set their expenditure andtaxation strategies or it may try to induce them to choose a welfare improvingequilibrium. Central Government may use several instruments to reach thisobjective. In our analysis we will use a matching grant since it is the instru-ment suggested by the literature to correct for spillover. Given the assumptionof perfect information, Central Government may �nd the optimal level of thematching grant by �nding the subsidy that allows the externality to be inter-nalised. Tresh (1995) suggests using a unit subsidy equal to the marginal rate ofsubstitution between the public good produced in local authority i and incomein local authority j, i.e. the spillover created by each local authority:In our case (see Appendix C), the optimal rate of the matching grant will

be equal to:

r�i =@gj (Si)

@Si

1

vi;

and the F.O.C for each single local authority becomes:

pi = q;

�vi (1� r�i ) + q +@fi(Si)@Si

= 0:

The externality created by the supply of the impure public good is inter-nalised through a matching grant to the jurisdiction that produces the good.However, given that for an impure public good only the quantity actually soldproduces bene�ts to the community, supply has to match demand. In thismodel, given the assumption of mobility between the two regions, the marginalprice for demand is q. As in the previous section q will have to be set to clearthe market:

Si = f 0�1i (vi (1� ri)� q); (12)

Sa + Sb = 1� q

�:

In this case, given that q is chosen to clear the market, � will be equal tozero.The cost of the matching grant will be �nanced through the national tax t.Through decentralisation, Central Government may replicate the �rst best

optimal solution and reach the same level of total welfare, but the distributionwill be determined by the market. For a decentralised system, in fact, welfarewill be written as:

13

Page 15: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

WD =1

2

�2 � p�2 � 2�p�� + 2�p�2�

+Xi=a;b

Yi�1� td � �di

�(13)

+X

i 6=j=a;b

�fi (S

�i ) + gi

�S�j��;

�di =S�i�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��Q�i

��p� � qd

�Yi

��Y � Yi

�(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

�S�i�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��Q�i

��p� � qd

��;

td =

Pbi=a vir

�i S

�i

Ya + Yb:

In this case, total welfare is certainly equal to �rst best, given that thequantity produced is the same in both cases. The distribution of welfare betweenthe two local authorities depends on the initial value of q, the transfer price inFirst Best and on the relative importance of the spillover e¤ect the two localauthorities produce. Given that the quantity produced in both cases is thesame, the di¤erence in welfare may arise from a di¤erent distribution of the �scalburden. In other words, for each local authority the welfare gain (loss) from �rstbest to decentralisation depends on the sign of the following expression:

��i � �di � td: (14)

If it is positive, the local authority is the net gainer in the decentralisationprocess, if it is negative it will lose. To show how spillovers and transfer priceinteract, we can observe that 14 can be written as8 :

��i � �di � td =1

Yi

�S�i vi �

�qd � q

�(S�i �Q�i )�Qi�p�

�+S�i vir

�i � S�j vjr�j2Yi

:

The �rst part of the expression depends on the value of q. In particu-lar if Central Goverment chooses in equilibrium a transfer price to clear themarket(qd), the two expressions are equal. The second part depends on thespillover e¤ect. As shown in Appendix D, if the utility function derived fromthe public characteristic is logarithmic, the last part is zero if the spillover e¤ectis reciprocal.

5.1 No mobility

For the no mobility case Central Government has to �nd a grant that internalisesthe positive externality. Using the procedure described in Appendix B, the

8See appendix....

14

Page 16: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

matching grant will be written as:

bri = 2�

vi

@gj (Qi)

@Qi:

In this case demand has to be incentivated in order to increase productionand to internalise the externality. This is the basic reason why the matchinggrant is written in terms of marginal rate of substitution from the consumer�spoint of view.Total welfare in this case can be written as:

cW �a =

1

2

�2 � p�2i � 2�p�i � + 2�p�2i�

+Xi=a;b

Yi�1� btd � b� i�

+X

i 6=j=a;bfi

� bQ�i�+ gi � bQ�j�

b� i =bQ�i (vi(1� bri)� �p�i )

Yi��Y � Yi

�Pbi=a

bQ�i (vi(1� bri)� �p�i )(Ya + Yb)Yi

;

btd =

Pbi=a vibri bQ�iYa + Yb

:

Total welfare is equal to �rst best, but the distribution depends on therelative size of the spillover e¤ect the two local authorities produce as shown inAppendix D.

6 Discussion

The model presented in this paper shows that even in a context where �scalfederalism is second best, some local authorities may be better o¤. This is duethe sum of two countervailing e¤ects: a decrease in welfare brought about bythe lack of coordination which means that the total quantity of public goodproduced is not optimal; a reduction in the equalisation grant. Richer regionsmay well be better o¤ as a result, while poor regions will certainly be worseo¤. In this environment, some forms of decentralisation may be more e¢ cient,although they require an amount of information that in the real world CG maynot possess. We model a class of public goods that we think may represent moreclosely the actual supply by local authorities since we concentrate on impurepublic and merit goods. We show that in this environment the coordinationproblems characterizing �scal federalism are important and that it is usuallynot possible to reach a �rst best allocation without the intervention of a supra-national authority. Cooperative solutions would be welfare improving for thewhole community, but they may not be implemented because they may notbe bene�cial for all the actors. This result is caused by the equalisation of re-sources that usually characterizes federal systems. The reduction of expendituredue to misperception of the spillovers reduces the grant that richer regions have

15

Page 17: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

to pay to poorer ones.This e¤ect may well o¤set the initial welfare loss due tounderprovision of the impure public good.In the presence of an impure public good, allowing mobility increases wel-

fare, although it creates more problems as regards coordination. Furthermore,decentralisation in this case may allow the same level of welfare to be reached asin �rst best, but CG loses a redistributive tool. In the centralised solution CGmay use the equalisation grant and q, the transfer price to redistribute income.In the decentralised solution q is set by the market.

6.1 Example

In this section we present a numerical example to highlight the results of ourpaper As in Besley and Coate (2003) we assume a linear/log utility for eachlocal authority:

Wi = Yi (1� t� � i) +1

4

�2 � 2�pi� � p2i + 2�p2i�

+wi lnSi + (1� wi) lnSj ;

and we assume that the good produced is a merit good (� = 0). We haveevaluated the di¤erent solutions for the following initial parameters

Ya Yb wa wb S va vb �14 8 0.6 0.6 0 5 6 0

The results are presented in Table 1.

Welfare reaches its maximum in a system where mobility is allowed, as mightbe expected. In this case production is concentrated in region a, but the quan-tity demanded is the same in both local authorities. The tax rate and the grantdepends on q, the price for mobility as much as the welfare of the two localauthorities. The �scal federalism solution for the most general model is charac-terized by a relatively high price for mobility, which creates an increase in thequantity of good H produced in A, but a total reduction in demand (Qa+Qb).The increase in Sa and the contextual reduction in � and G may make local au-thority A better o¤ in this environment, much depends on the price for mobilityCG wishes to �x in a centralised system. The gain in welfare for A is, on theother hand, unquestionable for the model without mobility. In the latter case,a bargaining solution allowing to reach �rst best would be feasible in theory,but A would never accept it because it implies a lower utility. Finally, throughCG intervention using a matching grant, it is possible to reach �rst best in thiscontext. In this case, the price for mobility is lower than in �scal federalism,but the quantity o¤ered is higher because of the matching grant. It is alsointeresting to note that for q = 3:039 in the �rst best equations such solutionis perfectly replicated in terms of welfare distribution and the local tax rate isequal. It is however important to note that this result depends on the type of

16

Page 18: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

Table 1: Simulation results

First Best Fisc Fed Decentralisation

M NM M NM M NM

q policy option 3.86 3.039Sa 0.510 0.432 0.526 0.411 0.510 0.432Sb 0.337 0.410 0.280 0.388 0.337 0.410Qa 0.424 0.432 0.403 0.411 0.424 0.432Qb 0.424 0.410 0.403 0.388 0.424 0.410pa 3.039 2.689 3.86 3.541 3.039 2.689pb 3.039 3.566 3.86 4.456 3.039 3.566t 0 0 0 0.036 0.021�a 0.226-0.006q 0.199 0.196 0.189 0.171 0.163� b 0.175+0.01q 0.229 0.196 0.216 0.171 0.192Ga -0.624+1.36*10�7q -0.631 -0.588 -0.598 -0.515 -0.522Gb 0.624-1.36*10�7q 0.631 0.588 0.598 0.515 0.522ra 0.156 0.184rb 0.197 0.162Ua 14.871+0.086q 15.25 15.174 15.27 15.133 15.25Ub 10.561-0.086q 10.13 10.225 9.80 10.299 10.13UT 25.432 25.38 25.399 25.07 25.432 25.38

utility function used and the assumption of symmetric spillovers as shown inthe previous section.

7 Conclusions

The traditional literature on �scal federalism suggests that the allocation offunctions to local governments should follow e¢ ciency principles. The choice ofthe quantity to be produced should be left to the tier which knows local pref-erences best. However, in order to �nance the local provision, grants might beused for equity and e¢ ciency reasons. Indeed, the presence of grants balancingfor uneven distribution in both resources and needs is one of the main argumentsin favour of the application of strict budget balance rules. This means that anyexpenditure in excess of that �nanced by Central Government should be paidby local taxes. The traditional literature on �scal federalism is centred on theproduction of goods and services that have mainly the characteristic of localpublic goods. In the recent past the process of �scal federalism has extendedthe category of goods and services to be provided at local level to include alsoservices that are both impure public goods and merit goods, i.e. they are rivalin consumption and can be supplied to local residents also by providers locatedoutside the boundaries of the local authority.The use of �scal federalism in this case is problematic for the regulator which

17

Page 19: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

is left with very few options for making local government replicate the �rst bestsolution. This is a well-known result; what our model adds to the previousliterature is the e¤ect on coordination of impure public goods provision. Inthis context, we have shown that when mobility may be allowed, such solutionimproves welfare, but it creates more problems as regards coordination.In a context of full information such as the one we have presented in this

paper, local authorities do not play any strategic game and through decentralisa-tion total welfare may be maximised. However, in a more realistic context wherepreferences may be private information and rules concerning the settlement ofpayment for services produced to outside users may be di¢ cult to enforce, thecoordination problems and the lack of incentives to move from a suboptimalsolution may be the cause of the problems observed in federal states.

18

Page 20: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

References

[1] Akai, N. and Mikami, B. (2006) Fiscal decentralisation and centralisationunder majority rule: A normative analysis, Economic Systems, EconomicSystems, 30(1),41-55

[2] Besley, T. and S.Coate (2003) Centralized versus decentralised provisionof local public goods: a political economy approach, Journal of PublicEconomics, 87,2611-37

[3] Crivelli, E. and K. Staal (2006) Size and Soft Budget Con-straint, CESifo Working Paper Series No. 1858 Available at SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=949711

[4] Davenport

[5] Grazzini, L and A Petretto (2005) Regional �scal e¤ort with revenue shar-ing and equalisation, http://maceprha.unipv.it/websiep/default.asp

[6] King, D, (1984), Fiscal tiers: the economics of multi-level Government,Allen & Unwin, London

[7] Marton, J and D Wildasin (2007). "Medicaid Expenditures and State Bud-gets: Past, Present, and Future," Working Papers 2007-04, University ofKentucky, Institute for Federalism and Intergovernmental Relations.

[8] Maskin, E and C Xu (2001) �Soft Budget Constraint Theories,�Economicsof Transition, 9, 1-27.

[9] Kornai J, (1986), The Soft Budget Constraint, Kyklos, 39(1), 3-30.

[10] Kornai, J, E Maskin and G Roland (2003) �Understanding the Soft BudgetConstraint,�Journal of Economic Literature, XLI, 1095-1136.

[11] Levaggi, R (1991) Fiscal Federalism, and grants-in-aid: The problem ofasymmetrical information, Avebury, Gower, Aldershot

[12] Levaggi, R. and P.C.Smith (2004)Decentralization in health care: lessonsfrom public economics, in Smith, P., Ginnelly, L. and Sculpher, M. (eds),Health policy and economics: opportunities and challenges, London: OpenUniversity Press

[13] Levaggi, R. (2008)Decentralisation vs �scal federalism in the presence ofimpure public goods, available at SSRN http://ssrn.com/abstract=1140673

[14] Levaggi, R. (2009)From Local to Global Public Goods: HowShould We Write the Utility Function. Available at SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1328245

[15] Musgrave, R. and P.B. Musgrave (1973). Public Finance in Theory andPractice, pp. 80-81.

19

Page 21: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

[16] Oates, W (1972) Fiscal Federalism, Harcourt Brace Janovich, New York

[17] Oates, W (2005) Towards a second generation Theory of Fiscal Federalism,International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 349-374

[18] Petretto, A (2002) The impact of vertical �scal competitionon the tax structure of a federation with equalising grant,http://maceprha.unipv.it/websiep/default.asp

[19] Petretto, A (2000) On the cost and bene�t of the regionalisation of theNHS, Economics of Governance, 1, 213-232

[20] Tresh, R (2002) Public Finance: A normative view, 2nd Edition, AcademicPress, San Diego

[21] Smart, M. (1998) Taxation and deadweight loss in a system of Intergovern-menta Transfer, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 31(1), pp.- 189-206

[22] Snoddon, T. and J.F. Wen (2003) Grants structure in an intergovernmental�scal game, Economics of Governance, 4, 115-126

[23] Wildasin D.E. Ogawa, H. (2008) Think locally, Act locally: spillovers, spill-backs and E¢ cient Decentralized Policy Making, IFIR Working Paper Se-ries n. 2007-06, forthcoming American Economic Review

[24] Wildasin , DE (2004) The institutions of federalism: towards an analyticalframework, National Tax Journal, LVII, 247-272

[25] Wildasin, D.E. (1997) Externalities and bailouts, Hard and Soft budgetconstraints in Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations, mimeo

20

Page 22: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

A Solution to the Central Government problem

The more general problem can be written as:

maxpa;pb;Sa;SbX

i 6=j=a;b

�Yi (1� t� � i) + 1

4�2�2�pi��p2i+2�p

2i

� + fi (Si) + gi (Sj)�

s:t:

� i =(vi�q)Si�(�pi�q)Qi�Gi

Yi;

t = 0;(1� a)Sa + aSb = (1� a)Qa + aQb;(1� b)Sa + bSb = (1� b)Qa + bQb:

For a = b = 12 mobility is allowed, for a = 1 and b = 0mobility is not allowed.

The �rst two constraints can be substituted in the maximisation problem. TheLagrangean is

L = Ya

1�

(va � q)Sa � (�pa � q) 12� (� � pa)�Ga

Ya

!

+1

4

�2 � p2a � 2�pa� + 2�p2a�

+ fa (Sa) + ga (Sb) +

Yb

1�

(vb � q)Sb � (�pb � q) 12� (� � pb)�Gb

Yb

!

+1

4

�2 � p2b � 2�pb� + 2�p2b�

+ fb (Sb) + gb (Sa)

+�1

�(1� a)Sa + aSb � (1� a)

1

2�(� � pa)� a

1

2�(� � pb)

�+�2

�(1� b)Sa + bSb � (1� b)

1

2�(� � pa)� b

1

2�(� � pb)

�;

on which the �rst order conditions are

@L@pa

: 12q�pa+�1(1�a)+�2(1�b)

� = 0;@L@pb

: 12q�pb+�1a+�2b

� = 0;@L@Sa

: �va + q + @fa(Sa)@Sa

+ @gb(Sa)@Sa

+ �1(1� a) + �2(1� b) = 0;@L@Sb

: @ga(Sb)@Sb� vb + q + @fb(Sb)

@Sb+ �1a+ �2b = 0;

which can be rearranged to give the conditions presented in the text.

21

Page 23: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

B Solution to the �scal federalism problem

In this case, the problem has to be written for each authority:

maxpi;Si Yi (1� t� � i) + 14�2�2�pi��p2i+2�p

2i

� + fi (Si) + gi (Sj)

s:t:

� i =(vi�q)Si�(�pi�q)Qi�Gi

Yi;

t = 0;Si = Qi:

The last constraint is relevant only in the problem without mobility. The�rst two constraints can be substituted in the maximisation problem. TheLagrangean is

L = Yi

1�

(vi � q)Si � (�pi � q) 12� (� � pi)�Gi

Ya

!

+1

4

�2 � p2i � 2�pi� + 2�p2i�

+ fi (Si) + gi (Si) +

+�

�Si �

1

2�(� � pi)

�;

on which the �rst order conditions are

@L@pi

: 12q�pa��

� = 0;@L@Si

: �vi + q + @fa(Sa)@Sa

� � = 0:

Mobility allowed In this case, � = 0 and the conditions are the same asthose presented in the text. Both local authorites will have to agree at a laterstage on q in order to clear the market.

Mobility not allowed In this case � can be substitued back from the�rst equation into the second one to give the optimal conditions presented inthe text.

22

Page 24: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

C Optimal matching grant

In general, the optimal conditions for the supply of an impure public good withspillovers in a community made of ni individuals can be written as:

niXi=1

MRSY ii ;H

i +

njXj=1

MRSY jj ;H

j +MRSYi;Hi =MRTY;H :

In the �scal federalism case, each jurisdiction underestimates the marginalrate of substitution because it does not take account of the positive externalityand the FOC can be written as:

niXi=1

MRSY ii ;H

i +MRSYi;Hi =MRTY;H :

To internalise the externality it is su¢ cient to use a per unit subsidy equalto the aggregate gain of citizens in the other local authority:

si =

njXj=1

MRSY jj ;H

j ;

in the form of a conditional matching grant at rate ri = sivi.

Mobility In this case, the subsidy is supplied to the producer. From (2)we can write

si =

njXj=1

MRSY jj ;H

j =@fj (Si)

@Si:

No mobility In this case the subsidy has to be given in terms of demandprice reduction hence the marginal rate of substitution takes account of themarginal cost of taxation. The subsidy in this case will be equal to:

si =

njXj=1

MRSY jj ;H

j = 2�@fj (Qi)

@Qi:

23

Page 25: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

D Welfare comparison

Mobility In order to understand how welfare is distributed, it is necessaryto determine the sign of the following expression:

��i � �di � td;

which can be written as:

S�i (vi � q)�Q�i (�p� � q)Yi

� Y � Yi(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

(S�i (vi � q)�Q�i (�p� � q))

� 1

Ya + Yb

Xi=a;b

vir�i S

�i �

S�i�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��Q�i

��p� � qd

�Yi

+Y � Yi

(Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

�S�i�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��Q�i

��p� � qd

��:

Let�s �rst examine ��i . In equilibrium, S�a+S

�b = Q

�a+Q

�b . It is then possible

to write

��i =1

Yi(S�i vi � q (S�i �Q�i )�Qi�p�) +

Ya � Yb2 (Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

(S�i vi �Q�i �p�) :

The second expression can be written as

1

Ya + Yb

Xi=a;b

viS�i r�i +

1

Yi

�qdQ�i + S

�i

�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��� Y � YiYi (Ya + Yb)

Xi=a;b

�qdQ�i + S

�i

�vi (1� r�i )� qd

��;

or

1

Yi

�S�i vi � qd (S�i �Q�i )�Qi�p�

�+

Ya � Yb2 (Ya + Yb)Yi

Xi=a;b

(S�i vi �Q�i �p�)�S�i vir

�i � S�j vjr�j2Yi

;

and, �nally,

��i � �di � td =1

Yi

�S�i vi �

�qd � q

�(S�i �Q�i )�Qi�p�

�+S�i vir

�i � S�j vjr�j2Yi

:

For a lin-log utility function of the form:

Wi = Yi (1� t� � i) +1

4

�2 � 2�pi� � p2i + 2�p2i�

+wi lnSi + (1� wi) lnSj ;

24

Page 26: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

we have

��i � �di � td =1

Yi

�S�i vi �

�qd � q

�(S�i �Q�i )�Qi�p�

�+(1� wi)� (1� wj)

2Yi:

If the spillover is reciprocal, the last term is equal to zero and the distributionof welfare between First Best and decentralisation depends on q: In particular,if q = qd decentralisation exactly replicates �rst best.

No mobility In this case, given that Qi = Si the di¤erence in utility canbe written as b��i � b�di � btd = bQ�i vir�i � bQ�jvjr�j

2Yi;

and for a lin-log utility we get

b��i � b�di � btd = (1� wi)� (1� wj)2Yi

:

25

Page 27: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

Discussion Papers recentemente pubblicati Anno 2006 0601 – Francesco MENONCIN “The role of longevity bonds in optimal portfolios” (gennaio) 0602 – Carmine TRECROCI, Matilde VASSALLI “Monetary Policy Regime Shifts: New Evidence from Time-Varying Interest-Rate Rules” (gennaio) 0603 – Roberto CASARIN, Carmine TRECROCI “Business Cycle and Stock Market Volatility: A Particle Filter Approach” (febbraio) 0604 – Chiara DALLE NOGARE, Matilde VASSALLI “A Pressure-Augmented Taylor Rule for Italy” (marzo) 0605 – Alessandro BUCCIOL, Raffaele MINIACI “Optimal Asset Allocation Based on Utility Maximization in the Presence of Market Frictions” (marzo) 0606 – Paolo M. PANTEGHINI “The Capital Structure of Multinational Companies under Tax Competition” (marzo) 0607 – Enrico MINELLI, Salvatore MODICA “Credit Market Failures and Policy” (gennaio) 0608 – J.H. DRÈZE, E. MINELLI, M. TIRELLI “Production and Financial Policies Under Asymmetric Information” (febbraio) 0609 – Françoise FORGES, Enrico MINELLI “Afriat’s Theorem for General Budget Sets” (marzo) 0610 – Aviad HEIFETZ, Enrico MINELLI “Aspiration Traps” (marzo) 0611 – Michele MORETTO, Paolo M. PANTEGHINI, Carlo SCARPA “Profit Sharing and Investment by Regulated Utilities: a Welfare Analysis” (aprile) 0612 – Giulio PALERMO “Il potere come relazione sociale. Il caso dell’università baronale italiana” (giugno) 0613 – Sergio VERGALLI “Dynamics in Immigration Community” (luglio) 0614 – Franco SPINELLI, Carmine TRECROCI “Maastricht: New and Old Rules” (luglio) 0615 – Giulio PALERMO “La valutazione dei titoli scientifici dei docenti del Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche dell’Università di Brescia” (settembre) 0616 – Rosella LEVAGGI “Tax evasion and the cost of public sector activities” (settembre) 0617 – Federico BOFFA, Carlo SCARPA “Exporting Collusion under Capacity Constraints: an Anti-Competitive Effect of Market Integration” (ottobre) 0618 – Monica BILLIO, Roberto CASARIN “Stochastic Optimisation for Allocation Problems with Shortfall Risk Constraints” (ottobre) Anno 2007 0701 – Sergio VERGALLI “Entry and Exit Strategies in Migration Dynamics” (gennaio) 0702 – Rosella LEVAGGI, Francesco MENONCIN “A note on optimal tax evasion in the presence of merit goods” (marzo) 0703 – Roberto CASARIN, Jean-Michel MARIN “Online data processing: comparison of Bayesian regularized particle filters” (aprile) 0704 – Gianni AMISANO, Oreste TRISTANI “Euro area inflation persistence in an estimated nonlinear DSGE model” (maggio) 0705 – John GEWEKE, Gianni AMISANO “Hierarchical Markov Normal Mixture Models with Applications to Financial Asset Returns” (luglio) 0706 – Gianni AMISANO, Roberto SAVONA “Imperfect Predictability and Mutual Fund Dynamics: How Managers Use Predictors in Changing Systematic Risk” (settembre) 0707 – Laura LEVAGGI, Rosella LEVAGGI “Regulation strategies for public service provision” (ottobre)

Page 28: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

Anno 2008 0801 – Amedeo FOSSATI, Rosella LEVAGGI “Delay is not the answer: waiting time in health care & income redistribution” (gennaio) 0802 - Mauro GHINAMO, Paolo PANTEGHINI, Federico REVELLI " FDI determination and corporate tax competition in a volatile world" (aprile) 0803 – Vesa KANNIAINEN, Paolo PANTEGHINI “Tax neutrality: Illusion or reality? The case of Entrepreneurship” (maggio) 0804 – Paolo PANTEGHINI “Corporate Debt, Hybrid Securities and the Effective Tax Rate” (luglio) 0805 – Michele MORETTO, Sergio VERGALLI “Managing Migration Through Quotas: an Option-Theory perspective” (luglio) 0806 – Francesco MENONCIN, Paolo PANTEGHINI “The Johansson-Samuelson Theorem in General Equilibrium: A Rebuttal” (luglio) 0807 – Raffaele MINIACI – Sergio PASTORELLO “Mean-variance econometric analysis of household portfolios” (luglio) 0808 – Alessandro BUCCIOL – Raffaele MINIACI “Household portfolios and implicit risk aversion” (luglio) 0809 – Laura PODDI, Sergio VERGALLI “Does corporate social responsability affect firms performance?” (luglio) 0810 – Stefano CAPRI, Rosella LEVAGGI “Drug pricing and risk sarin agreements” (luglio) 0811 – Ola ANDERSSON, Matteo M. GALIZZI, Tim HOPPE, Sebastian KRANZ, Karen VAN DER WIEL, Erik WENGSTROM “Persuasion in Experimental Ultimatum Games” (luglio) 0812 – Rosella LEVAGGI “Decentralisation vs fiscal federalism in the presence of impure public goods” (agosto) 0813 – Federico BIAGI, Maria Laura PARISI, Lucia VERGANO “Organizational Innovations and Labor Productivity in a Panel of Italian Manufacturing Firms” (agosto) 0814 – Gianni AMISANO, Roberto CASARIN “Particle Filters for Markov-Switching Stochastic-Correlation Models” (agosto) 0815 – Monica BILLIO, Roberto CASARIN “Identifying Business Cycle Turning Points with Sequential Monte Carlo Methods” (agosto) 0816 – Roberto CASARIN, Domenico SARTORE “Matrix-State Particle Filter for Wishart Stochastic Volatility Processes” (agosto) 0817 – Roberto CASARIN, Loriana PELIZZON, Andrea PIVA “Italian Equity Funds: Efficiency and Performance Persistence” (settembre) 0818 – Chiara DALLE NOGARE, Matteo GALIZZI “The political economy of cultural spending: evidence from italian cities” (ottobre) Anno 2009 0901 – Alessandra DEL BOCA, Michele FRATIANNI, Franco SPINELLI, Carmine TRECROCI “Wage Bargaining Coordination and the Phillips curve in Italy” (gennaio) 0902 – Laura LEVAGGI, Rosella LEVAGGI “Welfare properties of restrictions to health care services based on cost effectiveness” (marzo) 0903 – Rosella LEVAGGI “From Local to global public goods: how should externalities be represented?” (marzo) 0904 – Paolo PANTEGHINI “On the Equivalence between Labor and Consumption Taxation” (aprile) 0905 – Sandye GLORIA-PALERMO “Les conséquences idéologiques de la crise des subprimes” (aprile) 0906 – Matteo M. GALIZZI "Bargaining and Networks in a Gas Bilateral Oligopoly” (aprile)

Page 29: DECENTRALISED PROVISION OF MERIT AND IMPURE PUBLIC … · a certain degree of mobility (either of the service or the service user) may be allowed. The main examples of goods falling

0907 – Chiara D’ALPAOS, Michele FRATIANNI, Paola VALBONESI, Sergio VERGALLI “It is never too late”: optimal penalty for investment delay in public procurement contracts (maggio) 0908 – Alessandra DEL BOCA, Michele FRATIANNI, Franco SPINELLI, Carmine TRECROCI “The Phillips Curve and the Italian Lira, 1861-1998” (giugno)