Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

158
Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Transcript of Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Page 1: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Copyright

by

Ekaterina Sokolova

2007

Page 2: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

The Dissertation Committee for Ekaterina Sokolovacertifies that this is the approved version of the following dissertation:

Indifference valuation in non-reduced incomplete

models with a stochastic risk factor

Committee:

Thaleia Zariphopoulou, Supervisor

Clint Dawson

Irene Gamba

Ehud Ronn

Stathis Tompaidis

Page 3: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Indifference valuation in non-reduced incomplete

models with a stochastic risk factor

by

Ekaterina Sokolova, B.S.; M.S.

Dissertation

Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of

The University of Texas at Austin

in Partial Fulfillment

of the Requirements

for the Degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

The University of Texas at Austin

December 2007

Page 4: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

To my parents, Sergey Sokolov and Inessa Sokolova

Page 5: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Acknowledgments

I wish to thank everyone who helped me along the lengthy and enlightening path of

finishing my dissertation.

First and foremost, I am most indebted to my research advisor, Professor

Thaleia Zariphopoulou. She introduced me to the word of mathematical finance

and guided me with eternal patience through the jungle of derivatives valuation

theory. It has been my distinct privilege to be her student.

I would also like to thank Professor Dawson, Professor Gamba, Professor

Ronn, and Professor Tompaidis for their service on my dissertation committee and

their questions and feedback on my dissertation. Their comments and suggestions

have greatly helped me at various stages of the doctoral program and undoubtedly

made this dissertation better.

My heartfelt gratitude also goes to my colleagues at Scicomp, Curt Randall

and Elane Kant, for being supportive while I was writing this dissertation.

I am eternally grateful for the friendship, and constant encouragement to

persevere with my research to my friend, Revathi Ananthakrishnan. Special thanks

also go to all my friends and fellow Ph.D. students at UT-Austin who made my

graduate school experience memorable and enjoyable.

Many people have contributed to this thesis through their love and encour-

agement. I owe many thanks to my parents, my husband, and the rest of my

family, for all the unconditional love and support they have given me throughout

v

Page 6: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

this endeavor. Without their support it would have been impossible to complete

this work.

Ekaterina Sokolova

The University of Texas at Austin

December 2007

vi

Page 7: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Indifference valuation in non-reduced incomplete

models with a stochastic risk factor

Publication No.

Ekaterina Sokolova, Ph.D.

The University of Texas at Austin, 2007

Supervisor: Thaleia Zariphopoulou

This work contributes to the methodology of valuation of financial derivative con-

tracts in an incomplete market. It focuses on a special type of incompleteness caused

by the presence of a non-traded stochastic risk factor, affecting the value of the con-

tract. The non-traded risk factor may only appear in the payoff of the contract or, in

addition, may enter the dynamics of the traded asset. We consider both cases. We

suggest a discrete time discrete space binomial model for the traded stock and the

non-traded risk factor. We work in the utility maximization framework with dynam-

ically changing agent’s preferences. We present a discrete time multi-period analog

of the forward and backward utility processes recently developed in continuous time.

We use methods of stochastic control and provide the indifference valuation algo-

vii

Page 8: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

rithm with both the forward and backward dynamic utilities. We compare the two

approaches and provide conditions under which they assign the same value to the

contract. We show that unlike the backward dynamic utility, the forward dynamic

utility yields prices that do not depend on the end of the investment horizon. We

pay attention to the choice of the equivalent martingale measure used for valuation

(i.e., the minimal martingale measure and the minimal entropy measure for the

forward and the backward utility processes correspondingly). We explicitly charac-

terize both measures and give conditions under which they coincide. We extend our

algorithm to the case of American and partial exercise contracts. We illustrate our

work with numerical examples, showing that in an incomplete market, a call option

on a non-traded risk factor may optimally be exercised early, and that it may be

optimal to exercise only a fraction of the total number of contracts held, if partial

exercise is allowed. In continuous time we extend the existing results to the case of

American contracts with both the backward and the forward utilities. We emphasize

the similarities between our discrete time valuation algorithm and the continuous

time valuation. The two approaches use the same pricing measures, yield prices

through nonlinear functionals of similar form, exhibit a similar relationship between

the backward and forward prices, and a similar structure for the aggregate minimal

entropy. We believe that our work makes a contribution by exposing the two above

mentioned ways of dependence on the non-traded risk factor, and by providing a

new dynamic indifference pricing algorithm that allows consistent valuation across

different investment horizons.

viii

Page 9: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Contents

Acknowledgments v

Abstract vii

List of Figures xi

Chapter 1 Introduction 1

Chapter 2 The discrete time model and existing results 8

2.1 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82.2 Existing results for European claims under simplifying assumptions . 11

Chapter 3 The minimal martingale and the minimal entropy mea-

sures in the discrete model 14

Chapter 4 Dynamic indifference valuation for European contracts in

the discrete model. 31

4.1 Dynamic indifference valuation with the forward utility. . . . . . . . 314.2 Dynamic indifference valuation with the backward utility. . . . . . . 464.3 The forward and the backward dynamic valuation in the reduced model 58

Chapter 5 Dynamic indifference valuation of American contracts in

the discrete model. 60

5.1 Dynamic indifference valuation with the forward utility. . . . . . . . 605.2 Dynamic indifference valuation with the backward utility. . . . . . . 745.3 Reduced model results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

ix

Page 10: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 6 The continuous time model and the dynamic indifference

valuation. 91

6.1 Market model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 936.2 Forward dynamic preferences and indifference price for European con-

tracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 936.3 Backward utility process and indifference price for European contracts 986.4 Forward indifference price for American contracts . . . . . . . . . . . 1006.5 Backward Indifference price for American contracts . . . . . . . . . . 103

Chapter 7 Extension of the discrete dynamic forward algorithm to

partial exercise contracts. 107

Chapter 8 Examples of numerical implementation. 115

Chapter 9 Conclusion and future work. 136

Bibliography 142

Vita 147

x

Page 11: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

List of Figures

8.1 Dependence of Indifference price on correlation and risk aversion . . 1198.2 Binomial and Continuous implementation for a basket call option . . 1208.3 Position of the early exercise boundary in a survey over correlation . 1228.4 European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on cor-

relation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1238.5 European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on cor-

relation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1248.6 European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on cor-

relation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1258.7 Backward and Forward prices for basket call option . . . . . . . . . . 1278.8 Backward and Forward prices vs time horizon . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1288.9 Partial exercise price for 50 put option on non-traded asset . . . . . 1308.10 Optimal number of options to hold . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1318.11 Optimal investment policy with partial exercise . . . . . . . . . . . . 1328.12 Forward indifference price for an American put . . . . . . . . . . . . 134

xi

Page 12: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 1

Introduction

This work contributes to the methods used for valuation of financial derivativecontracts. It considers the case where the value of the contract depends on boththe value of the underlying exchange-traded asset and the level of a non-tradedrisk factor. In a classical model, where neither the contract’s payoff nor the tradedasset’s dynamics depends on the risk factor, the well-known arbitrage-free valuationtheory suggests pricing the contract by calculating the risk-neutral expectation ofthe contract’s discounted stochastic payoff. Assuming that the traded asset followsa lognormal stochastic process, the famous Black-Scholes formula ([5], [37]) applies.The risk factor is usually assumed to follow a stochastic process, correlated to thetraded asset process. Not only the payoff of the contract, but also the dynamicsof the traded asset may depend explicitly on the past and current levels of thenon-traded risk factor. The non-traded factor carries extra exogenous risk, whichcannot be eliminated through trading with available market instruments. Thus, itbecomes impossible to replicate exactly the payoff of the contract. Without theperfect replication assumption, the classical no-arbitrage valuation does not give aunique answer for the value of such a contract since, in this case, more than one risk-neutral measure exists. The market is then termed incomplete and other methodsmust to be applied to value those contracts that are contingent on the non-tradedrisk factor.

One way to extend the classical no-arbitrage theory for an incomplete mar-ket settings is to assume that the agent, trading in the market and holding thecontingent contract, has pre-specified preferences regarding stochastic outcomes of

1

Page 13: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

his trading strategies and market dynamics. Depending on these preferences, eachagent will then have his own price, which may differ from the price of other agents.The agent’s preferences determine his attitude towards the risk carried by the non-traded stochastic factor. Specifying the agent’s preferences leads to pricing usingthe so-called utility maximization approach, originated by [36]. Utility maximizationcan usually be addressed using either duality methods or the methods of dynamicprogramming and stochastic control. Duality methods allow one to treat even verygeneral utility maximization problems, such those in which the Markovian propertydoes not hold. However the results usually are not as explicit as when using themethods of stochastic control and dynamic programming developed by [30] and [15].The latter are methods used in this work.

For utility maximization, an important question is which utility function (orpreferences) to choose. A number of different choices have been suggested, such asa utility function of a quadratic form, for example. The latter leads to methodsof local risk minimization and mean-variance pricing ([19] provide a summary andcomparison of the two approaches). Quadratic utility function is also used in the ε- arbitrage approach (see [4]). A more general choice of a power utility function isused in [48], [33] and [21]. Another common choice is to assume the agent’s utilityof an exponential form, as it is done in this work. In the simplest case, the utilityfunction can be static, i.e, it either has the same functional form at all times or isassigned and fixed at one particular time point only. In a more general setting, theagent’s preferences may be dynamically changing with the market, as it is in thiswork.

There is a growing community of researchers who support the idea that anagent’s preferences should be dynamic in order to capture changes in his attitudetowards the environment changes. One way to extend the traditional static expo-nential utility, prescribed at only one future point in time, is to roll it backwardrecursively from the terminal time to the current valuation time. A rich class ofutilities can be obtained in such a way. However, having a fixed utility at the end ofthe investment horizon is not a very desirable feature since it imposes the restrictionthat all the contracts valued must mature prior to the end of the investment hori-zon. If an additional contract is to be valued with a longer maturity, the end of theinvestment horizon needs to be changed and all the contracts re-evaluated accord-ingly. Doing so would create an artificial mispricing, a consequence of the utility

2

Page 14: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

function choice. In this work we present two different dynamic utility processes.One of these is derived backward in time, starting at the end of the investmenthorizon. The other progresses forward in time, and does not have the unattractivefeature described above.

In addition to choosing a specific form of the utility function, one mustalso choose functional form of the stochastic processes describing the evolution ofthe traded stock and the non-traded factor. As mentioned above, two types ofdependence are possible. With the first, the dynamics of the traded asset onlydepend on the traded asset itself, and the dependence on the non-traded risk factoronly enters through the payoff of the contract. This type of dependence usuallyyields more explicit results and is commonly used in the literature. Examples ofsuch models include [48], [20], and [18]. The other, more fundamental type ofdependence arises when the traded asset’s dynamics depend explicitly on the valueof the risk factor. In such models the valuation procedure is usually more complexand is the subject of this work.

Throughout this thesis we work with two dynamic utilities. Our work ismotivated by that of [42] in continuous time, which suggests two different dynamicutility processes, the backward and the forward. We construct the two similar utilityprocesses in discrete time. In the absence of any derivative contracts, both utilitiesare invariant with respect to the end of the investment horizon, as in [42]. That is,starting with the same initial wealth, the optimal investment in the interval [t;T1)yields the same expected utility of terminal wealth as the one in the interval [t;T2).The backward utility is normalized (fixed) at a future time point T , and turns out tocoincide with the plain investment value function V 0, considered in [41]. The forwardutility introduced by [42] in continuous time is fixed at a prior time, not a futuretime. Is shown in this work, the forward utility does not impose any time restrictionson the maturities of valued contracts, and yields prices that do not depend on theend of the investment horizon. We use the indifference valuation framework to derivethe corresponding prices and their properties first for European, then American, andlater partial exercise contracts. We compare the forward valuation algorithm to thebackward valuation algorithm for European and American contracts.

The holder can terminate (i.e., exercise) an American contract at any timewithin a pre-specified period, and receive the upon agreed cashflow, called the in-trinsic payoff. A partial exercise contract can be viewed as a bundle of identical

3

Page 15: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

American contracts, each of which can be exercised at a different time within thesame pre-specified horizon. At any time the holder has to decide how many (whatfraction) of all the American contracts held needs to be exercised. With contractsthat have either American or partial exercise features, it is common for cashflows toarrive at different times. The timing of these cashflows does not necessarily coincidewith the end of the investment horizon. Thus, the need for dynamic utility choicebecomes apparent.

Allowing for early exercise translates into solving the optimal stopping prob-lem. Pure optimal stopping problems have become a necessary component of thearbitrage-free valuation theory. A classical treatment in discrete time can be foundin [51]. For a more applied recent study see also [6], who consider applications toreal options in discrete time. In continuous time [1], studies the optimal stoppingproblem for a general jump diffusion process for a perpetual American option. Alsoin continuous time diffusion setting [55] studies the optimal stopping problem un-der the unhedgeable event risk affecting the contract’s payoff. In our setting, inaddition to holding the option, we allow the agent to trade in the market, whichmathematically leads to a mixed optimal stopping and utility maximization prob-lem. In complete markets, the mixed problems of optimal stopping and utilitymaximization have been studied by [29], who focused on the existence of optimalstrategies in continuous time. In the case of an incomplete market, [7], treats theproblem in the presence of transaction costs in discrete time, [9] do so continuoustime. Recently, in continuous time, [14] (with a power utility) and [20] (with astatic exponential utility) consider mixed optimal stopping and stochastic controlproblem with the non-traded assets. When a non-traded risk factor affects the con-tract’s valuation, the models assumed in the literature are usually either simplified,so that the dependence on the non-traded factor only enters through the contract’spayoff, or are very general semi-martingale models that do not allow for very explicitcharacterizations. Our discrete time model makes a contribution because it has thecomplexity to make visible the effect of the stochastic risk factor explicitly changingthe dynamics of the traded asset, and at the same time provides explicit results.

A common example of a contract with partial exercise and a non-tradedrisk factor would be employee stock option grants. An employee may be restrictedin trading his own company’s stock, but may trade another correlated asset. Inthis case the company’s stock can be viewed as a non-traded risk factor and the

4

Page 16: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

employee’s stock options viewed as options on the non-traded risk factor.When the market is complete and the options are written on the traded asset,

the timing of early exercise is independent of the number of options held. Moreover,all the options held should optimally be exercised at once. Starting with [47], it hasbeen pointed out that in an incomplete market, it may be optimal to exercise onlya fractional amount of the total number of options held. [47] introduce the marketincompleteness through the no-short-sales constraint, which causes the options tobe exercised in fractions. [33] study a particular case of employee stock options,the reload options, again under the no-short-sales of the company’s stock. Neitherof the above publications assume the agent can trade an asset correlated to thecompany’s stock. Allowing the executive to take a position in a correlated asset hasbecome the next step in the development of a methodology for valuation of employeestock options. The correlated asset available for trade is typically assumed to berepresented by a market index. This modeling approach was undertaken by [22] andlately by [34]. Both of these papers use the indifference valuation framework with aclassical static exponential utility function and demonstrate important insights intohow the risk aversion and vesting affect the value of employee stock options. Inboth of the above papers the authors choose to work with a simplified model wherethe payoff of the contract is the only part affected by the non-traded risk factor. Indiscrete time, [18] adopts the setting of [41] and builds on their results for Europeancontracts, to value employee stock options. The setting of [41], as will be shown inthis work, uses a reduced model, where the traded and the non-traded componentsare only related through the contract’s payoff. In addition, the utility function usedin [41] and in [18] is the traditional static exponential utility.

We present our main results in a discrete time and discrete space binomialframework, that extends the results of [41], and consequently those of [18]. Weconstruct the backward and the forward dynamic utility processes, as [42] in con-tinuous time. We discuss the properties of the dynamic utilities constructed, andpresent the algorithm that recursively computes indifference values for both dy-namic utilities. We demonstrate that in both cases the prices are obtained throughthe recursive application of the nonlinear pricing functionals, similar to the onesintroduced by [41]. We demonstrate that the prices satisfy the natural properties ofbeing monotone with respect to risk aversion, and investigate the limiting cases asrisk aversion becomes zero or infinity. We pay attention to the choice of equivalent

5

Page 17: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

martingale measures used for valuation with the forward and backward utilities. Weprovide explicit characterization of the two measures, the minimal martingale mea-sure and the minimal entropy measure, by looking at the conditional probabilitiesthey assign to a non-traded risk factor, given the value of the traded asset. [49] and[35] characterize the minimal martingale measure in discrete time using martingalerepresentation properties. Our characterization of the minimal martingale measuremay be less general, but is more intuitive, and we show that it satisfies the conditionof [49] as well. [16] characterizes the minimal entropy measure in a discrete timediscrete state model slightly different from ours. The author does not make explicitassumptions about the presence of the non-traded risk factor. He suggests thatthe density of the minimal entropy measure is of the exponential form, and thatthe minimal entropy measure assigns larger probabilities to extreme values of thetraded asset. Again, our model assumptions are different and our characterizationcomes from a different perspective. We characterize and compare both measuresand provide conditions for them to coincide. Results of chapter 3 discussing therelation between the measures have also been presented in [53].

On the pricing side, we provide an explicit formula that relates the backwardand the forward prices for European contracts, and the conditions under whichthe two prices coincide. Since the market is incomplete, the operators involved inpricing are nonlinear with respect to the contract’s payoff. For European claims weinvestigate the additive and multiplicative properties of those nonlinear operatorswith respect to the payoffs. We compare our discrete time results for Europeancontracts to the ones of [42] in terms of the structural form of the prices, the measuresused, and the characterization of the aggregate minimal entropy, and find manysimilarities. Chapter 4 of this work discusses European contracts, and is mostlyformed of results presented in [38] and [39]. For American claims we derive thepricing algorithm, the optimal stopping policy and the hedging strategy. We alsoprovide an alternative characterization of the American price as the supremum ofEuropean prices. With forward utility, we extend our discrete time framework tocontracts with partial exercise. We also extend the continuous time results of [42]to the case of American claims, and compare the discrete and continuous Americanprices as well. We provide numerical examples when the backward and the forwardprices are different in discrete time. We illustrate our American algorithm with adiscrete time numerical example that shows the position of the free boundary. We

6

Page 18: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

also show a discrete time numerical example that demonstrates that the optimalexercise may indeed be partial.

As our analysis shows, with the forward utility, the prices do not depend onthe end of the investment horizon. The measure used in forward valuation is com-pletely horizon independent as well. We value American contracts of finite maturityand impose a condition that at maturity the contracts must be exercised if theyhave not been exercise before. This is the only reference to any kind of future timehorizon. This indicates the forward utility may be a promising concept for valu-ing perpetual American contracts. The problem of valuating perpetual Americanoptions using utility maximization remains a question of interest in the literature.One of the difficulties is that most of the utility functions or processes used so farcarry a reference to some future end of the investment horizon. Thus it has notbeen clear how that dependence would reflect in the valuation of perpetual con-tracts. Recently [21] have formulated a concept of so-called horizon-unbiased utilityfunctions with the prospect of valuating infinite horizon real options, which is sim-ilar to the forward utility function we use. There, the authors again work with areduced model. They suggest to adjusting the traditional static power type utilityfunction by a multiplicative time-dependent exponential factor to make the utilitydynamic. The authors also show that their dynamic utility satisfies the propertyof time-consistency, which is similar to the concept of self-generation developed in[42], and is the one we use in our work. Compared to [21], the forward dynamicutility suggested in [42] and developed herein is formulated in a richer, non-reducedmodel. In our work, instead of imposing a particular form of the utility, the latter isnaturally constructed from the self-generation property and the normalization con-dition. As a result, the functional form of the utility is financially intuitive: the localentropy terms used to describe the forward and the backward dynamic utilities arefundamental model quantities that reflect the market incompleteness. In this workwe provide the valuation algorithm and pricing examples with the forward utility,extending the scope of applications of this new concept.

7

Page 19: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 2

The discrete time model and

existing results

2.1 The Model

In our model, financial instruments available for trade include a risky asset St and ariskless bond. Interest rate, for simplicity, is assumed to be zero. Incompleteness isintroduced in the form of a non-traded risky stochastic factor Yt. Our model adoptsthe setting of [41] with the two risky assets satisfying, respectively, for 0 ≤ t ≤ T−1,such that:

St+1St

= ξt+1, with ξt+1 = ξut+1, ξdt+1, 0 < ξdt+1 < 1 < ξut+1,

Yt+1Yt

= ηt+1, with ηt+1 = ηut+1, ηdt+1, 0 < ηdt+1 < ηut+1,

(2.1)

Time T represents the end of the investment horizon. The two-dimensional stochas-tic process St, Yt, t = 0, 1, ..., T is defined on the probability space (Ω,F ,P) withfiltration Ft generated by Ss, Ys, s = 1, ..., t and F = FT . FSt denotes the filtra-tion generated by Ss, s = 1, ..., t. P represents the historical measure. In general,ξt+1 and ηt+1 are allowed to depend on S0, ..., St and Y0, ..., Yt, but neither on St+1

or Yt+1.We consider a single investor with initial wealth X0 = x. He allocates wealth

between the traded asset S and the risk-free bond (with zero interest, for simplicity).The initial capital and the self-financing trading strategy α = (α1, ..., αt) generate

8

Page 20: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

the time t wealth of the investor of the form:

Xt = x+T∑i=1

αi(Si − Si−1), (2.2)

where αs stands for the number of shares of the traded security the investor holdsover the period [s− 1, s). We take αs to be Fs−1 measurable so that anticipation offuture stock movements is not allowed.

The investor is offered an opportunity to purchase a contract with an earlyexercise or, in later chapters, partial exercise feature. Intrinsic payoff of the contractis specified as Ct = C(St, Yt) for a bounded function C. The maturity of the contractmust not coincide with the end of the trading horizon. The former will be denoted byT , assuming T ≤ T . A stopping time τ with respect to the filtration Ft, 0 ≤ t ≤ T ,represents the exercise time chosen by the investor, and is assumed to satisfy a.s.τ ≤ T . Listed below are common simplifying assumptions used in the literature tovalue contracts that depend on a non-traded risky stochastic factor in an incompletemarket with a utility framework. We will be referring to these assumptions in thiswork, gradually eliminating them.

Assumption 2.1 (Simplified model) ξut and ξdt , t = 0, ..., T are a set of con-stants, and the historical distribution of the traded asset is independent of previousand current values of the non-traded risk factor, namely:

P(ξt+1/Ft) = P(ξt+1/FSt ), t = 0, 1, ..., T . (2.3)

Assumption 2.2 (European claim) The contract pays amount CT = C(ST , YT )at time T .

Assumption 2.3 (Static exponential preferences) The agent has static expo-nential preferences, i.e., utility function of the form U(x) = −e−γx, fixed at T thatcoincides with T .

We start by providing the necessary definitions for stating existing results,which have been derived under assumptions listed above for a simplified model, withthe static exponential preferences and European contracts. Note that we use T asmaturity of the contract because under assumption 2.3, T = T .

9

Page 21: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Definition 2.1 The value function of the buyer holding a claim CT , V C(x, t) is themaximal expected utility of his time T wealth, conditioned on the currently availableinformation. That is,

V C(x, t) = supαt+1,...,αT

E[−e−γ(XT+CT )/Ft

]. (2.4)

If CT = 0 a.s. then (2.4) becomes the so-called plain investment value functionfor an investor who just optimizes his expected terminal wealth with no derivativecontracts involved. The corresponding value function will be denoted by V 0(x, t)and is equal to:

V 0(Xt, t) = supαt+1,...,αT

E[−e−γXT /Ft

]. (2.5)

Definition 2.2 The time t buyer’s indifference price of the European claim CT isdefined as the amount νt for which the two value functions V C and V 0 coincide.Namely, νt is the amount which satisfies:

V C(Xt − νt(CT ), Yt, t) = V 0(Xt, t). (2.6)

In a similar fashion, one could define the value function of the writer. Since un-derwriting the European liability CT is equivalent to buying the European claim−CT , the writer’s value function equals the right hand side of definition (2.4), withCT replaced by −CT . By analogy, the writer’s indifference price is defined as theamount that, if added to the writer’s time t wealth, makes his value function asgood as V 0. It’s not difficult to see that, as those definitions imply, the buyer’s andwriter’s indifference prices are related by the formula:

νt(CT ) = −νt(−CT ), (2.7)

with νt(CT ) denoting the writer’s indifference price for the liability CT .[41] established results for the writer’s indifference price process of a Eu-

ropean derivative in a discrete time setting of a simplified model. Relation (2.7)allows us to reformulate their results from the buyer’s perspective, as necessary forour work. The next section explains the above mentioned results.

10

Page 22: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

2.2 Existing results for European claims under simpli-

fying assumptions

In this section we define a family of nonlinear operators to be used to character-ize the buyer’s indifference price. Equations (2.8) and (2.9) contain the necessarydefinitions. Then, Theorem 1 presents the main result of [41] for European claims,which lays the foundation for this study.

Definition 2.3 Let Zs, 0 ≤ s ≤ T be an Fs-adapted process and Q be a martingalemeasure. For t ≤ s define the iterative pricing operator E t,sQ (Zs) as follows:

E t,sQ (Zs) = E t,s−1

Q

(Es−1,sQ (Zs)

), t ≤ s− 1

Es,sQ (Zs) = Zs,(2.8)

whereEs−1,sQ (Zs) = −EQ

[1γ

lnEQ[e−γZs/Fs−1 ∨ FSs

]/Fs−1

]. (2.9)

Theorem 1 Let Q be a martingale measure satisfying, for t = 0, 1, ..., T ,

Q(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

)= P

(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

). (2.10)

(i) The indifference price νt(CT ) satisfiesνt(CT ) = E t,t+1

Q (et+1(CT )) , t < T

νT (CT ) = CT ,(2.11)

with E t,t+1Q defined in equation (2.9) for Q = Q.

(ii) The indifference price process is given by

et(CT ) = E t,TQ (CT ), (2.12)

with E t,TQ defined in equations (2.8) and (2.9) for Q = Q.(iii) The pricing algorithm is consistent across time in that, for 0 ≤ t ≤ s ≤ T , thesemigroup property

νt(CT ) = E t,sQ

(Es,TQ (CT )

)= E t,sQ (es(CT )) = νt

(Es,TQ (CT )

)(2.13)

11

Page 23: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

holds.(iv) A martingale measure Q has property (2.10) if and only if it has the minimalrelative to P entropy.(v) At any time 0 < t < T , the value function of the buyer is of the form

V C(Xt, Yt, t) = −e−γ(Xt+νt(CT ))−Hmet,T , (2.14)

where Hmet,T is the minimal, conditional on Ft entropy commonly defined as

Hmet,T = minQ∈Qe

EQ

[lnQ(·/Ft)P(·/Ft)

/Ft], (2.15)

where Qe denotes the set of all martingale measures equivalent to P, Q(·/Ft) andP(·/Ft) denote restrictions of Q and P on Ft.(vi) The minimal entropy Hmet,T has an explicit representation as:

Hmet,T = EQ

[T−1∑k=t

hk/Ft

], (2.16)

wherehk = qk+1 ln

qk+1

P(ξuk+1/Fk)+ (1− qk+1) ln

(1− qk+1)1− P(ξuk+1/Fk)

, (2.17)

are referred to as local entropy terms and

qk =1− ξdkξuk − ξdk

. (2.18)

Again, we would like to caution the reader that the above theorem has been de-rived under the assumption of simplified model; the characterization of the minimalentropy measure(2.9), as the one that preserves the conditional distribution of thenon-traded risk factor (given the next period’s value of the traded stock) does nothold if Assumption (2.1) of the simplified model is violated. In the next chapter wedrop Assumption (2.1) and present a new characterization of the minimal entropymartingale measure. We also show which equivalent martingale measure has prop-erty (2.9) of preserving the conditional distribution of the non-traded risk factor,given the next period’s value of the traded asset. Also, the result above shows thatthe minimal entropy, conditional on the available to the current time information ,

12

Page 24: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

accumulates linearly by taking the expectation under the minimal entropy measureof the sum of the local entropy terms. As we show in the next chapter, in a moregeneral model the entropy accumulates in a nonlinear way.

13

Page 25: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 3

The minimal martingale and the

minimal entropy measures in

the discrete model

Let Q be the set of martingale measures on F and consider, for t = 0, 1, ..., T, thequantities

HmmT (Q (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) = EP

(− ln

Q (· |Ft )P (· |Ft )

|Ft)

andHmeT (Q (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) = EQ

(lnQ (· |Ft )P (· |Ft )

|Ft),

where Q ∈ Q and Q (· |Ft ) and P (· |Ft ) denote the restrictions of Q and P on Ft.The minimal martingale measure Qmm (· |Ft ) is defined as the minimizer of

HmmT , i.e.,

HmmT (Qmm (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) = minQ∈Q

HmmT (Q (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) . (3.1)

Respectively, the minimal entropy measure Qme (· |Ft ) is the minimizer of HmeT , i.e.,

HmeT (Qme (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) = minQ∈Q

HmeT (Q (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) . (3.2)

Most of the analysis below will involve the latter entropy. To simplify the

14

Page 26: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

presentation we will be using the condensed notation

Hmet,T = HmeT (Qme (· |Ft ) | P (· |Ft )) (3.3)

and the terminology aggregate entropy.The next several results provide explicit characterization of the correspond-

ing measures. In continuous time both of these measures have been characterizedin a number of different ways. In the discrete time, very few results for the twomeasures are available. The most closely related characterizations are in the formof predictable martingale representations, such as [49] and [35]. To the best of ourknowledge, the characterization of the minimal entropy martingale measure pre-sented below is new. It is discussed in more detail in [53]. Our characterizations forboth measures are very explicit.

We introduce, for t = 0, 1, ..., T, the sets

At = ω : ξt (ω) = ξut and Bt = ω : ηt (ω) = ηut (3.4)

Note that for all Q,Q′ ∈ Q,

Q (At |Ft−1 ) = Q′(At |Ft−1 ) =

1− ξdtξut − ξdt

.= qt. (3.5)

We recall the process ht, which will be referred to as the local entropy processfrom here on. Let ht, t = 1, ... be given by

ht.= qt ln

qtP (At |Ft−1 )

+ (1− qt) ln1− qt

1− P (At |Ft−1 )(3.6)

where At is defined in (3.4), P is the historical probability measure and Ft thefiltration generated by the random variables Si and Yi, for i = 0, 1, ..., t.

Lemma 2 For t = 1, ..., T, ht ∈ Ft−1. Moreover, for all Q ∈ Q,

ht = Q (At |Ft−1 ) lnQ (At |Ft−1 )P (At |Ft−1 )

+ (1−Q (At |Ft−1 )) ln1−Q (At |Ft−1 )1− P (At |Ft−1 )

. (3.7)

The next proposition provides the characterization of the minimal martingale mea-sure. This result has already appeared in [41]. There, the authors work under

15

Page 27: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

the assumption (2.1) that the historical probability distribution of the traded asset,given the information available up to the current time, does not depend on the pathof the stochastic factor, and that the values of ξt and ηt are constant and do notdepend on values of either traded stock or the non-traded stochastic factor. Theauthors characterize the minimal entropy measure using the condition presentedbelow. Later we will show that under the assumption of a so-called reduced modelthe two measures coincide. The model of [41] satisfies the reduced model condi-tion, implying that the characterization of the minimal entropy measure using thecondition 3.8 is indeed appropriate. In the non-reduced model though, conditionbelow characterizes the minimal martingale measure, and not the minimal entropymeasure.

Proposition 3 The minimal martingale measure Qmm ( ·| Ft) satisfies, for t =1, ..., T,

Qmm(Yt| Ft−1 ∨ FSt

)= P

(Yt| Ft−1 ∨ FSt

). (3.8)

Proof. We need to show that for t = 1, ..., T,

Qmm (AtBt| Ft−1)Qmm (At| Ft−1)

=P (AtBt| Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

,Qmm (AtBc

t | Ft−1)Qmm (At| Ft−1)

=P (AtBc

t | Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

Qmm (ActBt| Ft−1)Qmm (Act | Ft−1)

=P (ActBt| Ft−1)P (Act | Ft−1)

,Qmm (ActB

ct | Ft−1)

Qmm (Act | Ft−1)=

P (ActBct | Ft−1)

P (Act | Ft−1).

Since the rest of the proof follows by similar arguments, we only show, the firstequality, namely,

Qmm (AtBt| Ft−1)Qmm (At| Ft−1)

=P (AtBt| Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

, (3.9)

where sets At, Bt are defined as in (3.4). We use induction. At t = T,

EP

(− ln

Q (ξT , ηT |FT−1 )P (ξT , ηT |FT−1 )

|FT−1

)= −P (ATBT | FT−1) ln

Q (ATBT | FT−1)P (ATBT | FT−1)

−P (AcTBT | FT−1) lnQ (AcTBT | FT−1)P(AcTBT

∣∣FT−1

)−P (ATBc

T | FT−1) lnQ (AT | FT−1)−Q (ATBT | FT−1)

P(ATBc

T

∣∣FT−1

)

16

Page 28: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

−P (AcTBcT | FT−1) ln

Q (AcT | FT−1)−Q (AcTBT | FT−1)P(AcTB

cT

∣∣FT−1

) ,

and direct differentiation yields the claimed equality. Next, we assume that (3.9)holds for t+ 1 and show its validity at t. We have

EP

(− ln

Q ( ·| Ft)P ( ·| Ft)

∣∣∣∣Ft)

= −EP

(ln

(T−1∏i=t+1

Q(ξi+1ηi+1

∣∣Fi)P(ξi+1ηi+1

∣∣Fi))∣∣∣∣∣Ft

)− EP

(lnQ(ξt+1ηt+1

∣∣Ft)P(ξt+1ηt+1

∣∣Ft)∣∣∣∣∣Ft).

Because we use the single-period arguments used to establish (3.9) for t = T andbecause the second term above depends only onQ

(ξt+1ηt+1

∣∣Ft), we easily conclude.

As we have mentioned before, the distribution of the next period’s value ofthe traded asses, conditional on the information available up to the current time, isthe same among all equivalent to P martingale measures. What differs among themis how the non-traded stochastic factor is distributed, given the known next period’svalue of the traded asset. The minimal martingale measure is characterized by avery natural and very simple assumption that the non-traded risk factor, given theknown next period’s value of the traded asset, has the same distribution as under thehistorical measure P. The minimal martingale measure has been studied by [50] incontext of continuous time in the context of quadratic hedging, and [54] have done soin the context of indifference pricing. [49] provides an explicit characterization of theminimal martingale measure in discrete time (denoted as P ) , using the Doob-Mayerdecomposition of the traded stock process as follows:

dPdP =

T∏t=1

1− λt∆St1− λt∆At

, (3.10)

where λt = ∆AtEP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]

and ∆At = EP[∆St/Ft−1]. The process At with

A0 = 0 and At − At−1 = ∆At defined above is the compensator in the uniqueDoob-Mayer decomposition of St, i.e. St − S0 −At is the martingale part of St.

More recently, [35], in a discrete time model similar to ours, show that the

17

Page 29: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

minimal martingale measure exists, is unique and is characterized by the density

dP

dP=

T∏t=1

(1 + ∆Lt), (3.11)

where the process Lt, 0 ≤ t ≤ T has a predictable representation with respect to themartingale part Mt of the discounted traded asset process St of the following form:

Lt = 1 +n∑k=1

αk∆Mk, (3.12)

and

α1 = (1 + r1)2EP[S1]S2

0V ar (R1), R1 = S1

S0− 1

αn = (1 + rn)(rn − EP [Rn])Sn−1V ar (Rn) , Rn = Sn

Sn−1− 1.

(3.13)

In the next proposition we show that the measure Qmm characterized by(3.8) does have the Radon-Nikodym derivative of the form specified above by [49].The characterizations of [49] and of [35] are both somewhat technical, while thecharacterization derived in this work seems to be very simple, explicit, and intuitive.

Proposition 3.1 The measure Qmm characterized by (3.8), solves equation (3.10)shown above.

Proof.dQmm

dP=

T∏i=1

Qmm (ξiηi| Fi−1)P (ξiηi| Fi−1)

. (3.14)

Under condition (3.8) the above simplifies to

dQmm

dP=

T∏i=1

Qmm (ξi| Fi−1)P (ξi| Fi−1)

. (3.15)

Qmm (ξi| Fi−1)P (ξi| Fi−1)

=

1− ξdi

P (ξi = ξui | Fi−1)(ξui − ξdi

) , for ξi = ξui ,

ξui − 1(1− P (ξi = ξui | Fi−1))

(ξui − ξdi

) , for ξi = ξdi .(3.16)

18

Page 30: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Thus it only remains to show that 1− λt∆St1− λt∆At

equals the right side of (3.16). Direct

calculation yields that

1− λt∆St1− λt∆At

==EP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]− λt∆StEP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]− λt∆At

(3.17)

Also calculating directly,

EP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]− λt∆At = p(1− p)(ξut − ξdt )2, (3.18)

EP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]− λt∆St = (1− p)(ξdt − ξut )(ξdt − 1), forw : St = Sut , (3.19)

and

EP[(∆St)2/Ft−1]− λt∆St = p(ξut − ξdt )(ξut − 1), forw : St = Sdt , (3.20)

where p = P(ξt = ξut /Ft−1), and the proof follows.Next we provide an explicit representation of the minimal entropy measure.

However, the characterization of the minimal entropy measure turns out not to be asmuch intuitive as the one for the minimal martingale measure. a number of authorshave studied the minimal entropy measure in continuous time, including [17] usingduality methods, [3] using PDE methods.

In the discrete time, [16] studied the characterization of the minimal entropymeasure in a finite-state traded asset process model. Some of their results wereobtained for a single-period model; others for a multi-period model. In their setup,the model is only implicitly incomplete, and no explicit assumptions about thepresence or the form of the non-traded factor dynamics is made. Their most explicitminimal entropy measure characterization is given for one risk-free asset and onerisky asset taking n different values in a one-period model. They characterize theminimal entropy measure in terms of the probabilities it assigns to the risky asset.They state that under the minimal martingale measure, the risky asset process ismore likely to take extreme values (i.e. the smallest or the largest) rather thenthe values in the middle. We characterize the minimal martingale measure and theminimal entropy measure from a different perspective, by looking at the probabilitiesthey assign to a non-traded factor. As mentioned earlier, in our model all theequivalent martingale measures assign the same probabilities to the values of the

19

Page 31: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

traded asset and the latter does not carry any specific information about eitherminimal entropy or minimal martingale measures. However, like [16], we do find thatin one period the minimal entropy measure and the minimal martingale measureconcide.

The characterization below uses the aggregate entropy Hmet,T , which was de-fined above in 3.2. An explicit form of the aggregate entropy is an independentresult and will be shown later. Therefore, we may assume that the explicit formof the entropy is known to us and we can characterize the conditional minimal en-tropy probabilities in terms of the known historical probabilities and the aggregateentropy. To the best of our knowledge, the characterization below is a new result.It is discussed in more detail in [53].

Proposition 4 The minimal entropy measure satisfies, for t = 1, ..., T,

Qme (AtBt| Ft−1)Qme (At| Ft−1)

=

P (AtBt| Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

e−Huut,T

P (AtBt| Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

e−Huut,T +

P (AtBct | Ft−1)

P (At| Ft−1)e−H

udt,T

, (3.21)

Qme (AtBct | Ft−1)

Qme (At| Ft−1)=

P (AtBct | Ft−1)

P (At| Ft−1)e−H

udt,T

P (AtBt| Ft−1)P (At| Ft−1)

e−Huut,T +

P (AtBct | Ft−1)

P (At| Ft−1)e−H

udt,T

, (3.22)

Qme (ActBt| Ft−1)Qme (Act | Ft−1)

=

P (ActBt| Ft−1)P (Act | Ft−1)

e−Hdut,T

P (ActBt| Ft−1)P (Act | Ft−1)

e−Hdut,T +

P (ActBct | Ft−1)

P (Act | Ft−1)e−H

ddt,T

, (3.23)

Qme (ActBct | Ft−1)

Qme (Act | Ft−1)=

P (ActBct | Ft−1)

P (Act | Ft−1)e−H

ddt,T

P (ActBt| Ft−1)P (Act | Ft−1)

e−Hdut,T +

P (ActBct | Ft−1)

P (Act | Ft−1)e−H

ddt,T

, (3.24)

where the events At, Act , Bt, Bct are as in (3.4) and Huut,T , Hudt,T , Hdut,T , and Hddt,T are

the values of the Ft−measurable random variable Hmet,T , (defined in (3.2)), condi-

20

Page 32: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

tional on Ft−1.

Proof. We only show that

Qme (AtBt| Ft−1)Qme (At| Ft−1)

=P (AtBt| Ft−1) e−H

uut,T

P (AtBt| Ft−1) e−Huut,T + P (AtBc

t | Ft−1) e−Hudt,T

(3.25)

since the rest of equalities can be proved along similar arguments. We recall thedefinition of the minimal entropy measure (3.2) and observe that

EQ

(lnQ (· |Ft−1 )P (· |Ft−1 )

|Ft−1

)= EQ

(lnQ (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )P (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )

|Ft−1

)

+EQ

(EQ

(ln

(T∏

i=t+1

Q (ξi, ηi |Fi−1 )P (ξi, ηi |Fi−1 )

)∣∣∣∣∣Ft)∣∣∣∣∣Ft−1

).

Therefore, one needs to minimize the first term over Q (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 ) and the sec-ond term in two steps: first minimize the nested conditional expectation overQ (ξi, ηi |Fi−1 ) , i = t + 1, ..., T and, in turn, over Q (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 ). Therefore itsuffices to calculate

minQ(ξtηt|Ft−1 )

(EQ

(lnQ (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )P (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )

|Ft−1

)+ EQ

(Hmet,T

∣∣Ft−1

))where we used (3.2). Expanding yields

EQ

(lnQ (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )P (ξt, ηt |Ft−1 )

|Ft−1

)+ EQ

(Hmet,T

∣∣Ft−1

)= Q (AtBt| Ft−1) ln

Q (AtBt| Ft−1)P (AtBt| Ft−1)

+Q (ActBt| FT−1) lnQ (ActBt| Ft−1)P (ActBc

t | Ft−1)

+ (Q (At| Ft−1)−Q (AtBt| Ft−1)) ln(Q (At| Ft−1)−Q (AtBt| Ft−1))

P (AtBct | Ft−1)

+ (Q (Act | Ft−1)−Q (ActBt| Ft−1)) ln(Q (Act | Ft−1)−Q (ActBt| Ft−1))

P (ActBct | Ft−1)

+Q (AtBt| Ft−1)Huut,T + (Q (At| Ft−1)−Q (AtBt| Ft−1))Hudt,T

+Q(AdtBt

∣∣∣Ft−1

)Hdut,T + (Q (Act | Ft−1)−Q (ActBt| Ft−1))Hddt,T .

21

Page 33: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Differentiating with respect to Q (AtBt| Ft−1) and rearranging terms yields at theoptimum

lnQme (AtBt| Ft−1)

P (AtBt| Ft−1)− ln

Qme (At| Ft−1)−Qme (AtBt| Ft−1)P (AtBc

t | Ft−1)

+Huut,T −Hudt,T = 0

and we conclude.

Corollary 5 The measures Qmm,Qme coincide at T − 1,

Qmm (ATBT | FT−1) = Qme (ATBT | FT−1) (3.26)

with similar equalities for the events ATBT , AcTBT and ATBcT .

The corollary implies that to see the difference between the minimal entropy andminimal martingale measure, one would need to consider a model of several periods.Then, for t < T − 1 the differences emerge as formulae (3.21) and (3.8) indicate.The same result has been obtained by [16] in a single-period finite state traded assetprocess model. At the end of this chapter we expand on the question of when thetwo measures are the same.

Definition 1 Let Z be a random variable on (Ω,F ,P). For t = 0, 1, ..., T, s =t+ 1, ..., T and Q ∈ Q define the nonlinear functional J

(t,t+1)Q (Z) = EQ

(lnEQ

(eZ∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)|Ft),

J (t,s)Q (Z) = J (t,t+1)

Q

(J (t+1,t+2)Q

(...J (s−1,s)

Q (Z))) (3.27)

where Ft and FSt are the filtrations generated, respectively, by (Si, Yi) and Si fori = 1, ..., t.

As one can see, the operator J (t,t+1)Q (·) is the same as the operator E(t,t+1)

Q (·)) for

γ = −1. Operators J (t,t+1)Q (·)) will be used next to characterize the aggregate

entropy. We emphasize that J (t,t+1)Q (·)) are independent of the risk aversion level

γ. Also, one could easily see that

J (t,t+1)Q (Z) = −γE(t,t+1)

Q (−1γZ), t < T . (3.28)

22

Page 34: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Next we proceed with the characterization of the aggregate minimal entropy. Thelatter has been characterized in, for example, [16] in a multi-period finite-statetraded-asset process model. Their characterization suggests that the minimal rela-tive entropy is the supremum over certainty equivalents of a certain class of payoffs,having non-positive expectations under the minimal entropy measure. This relatesthe model-specific quantity of the entropy to expectations of a somewhat artificialclass of payoffs that have no connection to the model chosen. Our characterizationof the entropy does not involve any additional artificial payoffs and is independentof the risk aversion and of any characteristics of the contract to be to be valued.

Proposition 6 The aggregate minimal entropy is given by the iterative scheme

HmeT,T = 0 and HmeT−1,T = hT , (3.29)

andHmet,T = ht+1 − J (t,t+1)

Qmm(−Hmet+1,T

), t = 0, 1, ..., T − 2, (3.30)

with J (t,t+1) and h defined in (3.27) and (3.6), respectively. Moreover,

Hmet,T = −J (t,T )Qmm

(−

T∑i=t+1

hi

)

The above proposition shows that the aggregate entropy under the minimal mar-tingale measure accumulates in a non-linear way, using nonlinear functionals, verysimilar to the ones that are used for pricing European contracts. I signifies that thenonlinear functionals J (t,t+1)

Q (·) and E(t,t+1)Q (·) are universal and used not only for

pricing but also to express fundamental model quantities like the aggregate entropy.The above formula has a direct analog in the continuous time setting, which weconsider in later chapters, and which draws a lot of similarity between the localentropy terms and the Sharpe ratio of the traded asset in continuous time.Proof. The first equality in (3.29) is immediate while the second part followseasily from the definitions of HmeT−1,T and hT and equalities (3.9) and (3.26). We,next, establish (3.34) for t = T − 2, i.e., that

HmeT−2,T = hT−1 − EQme(

lnEQme(e−H

meT−1,T

∣∣FT−2 ∨ FST−1

)|FT−2

). (3.31)

23

Page 35: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We have

HmeT−2,T = EQme

(ln

Qme(ξT−1, ηT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(ξT−1, ηT−1 |FT−2

) |FT−2

)

+EQme

(EQme

(ln

Qme (ξT , ηT | FT−1)P (ξT , ηT |FT−1 )

∣∣∣∣FT−1

)|FT−2

)

= EQme

(ln

Qme(ξT−1, ηT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(ξT−1, ηT−1 |FT−2

) ∣∣∣∣∣FT−2

)+ EQme (hT |FT−2 ) ,

where we used (3.29). Next, we introduce the random variables

ZuT−2 =P (AT−1BT−1| FT−2)

P (AT−1 |FT−2 )e−H

me,uut−1,T +

P(AT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P (AT−1 |FT−2 )

e−Hme,udt−1,T

and

ZdT−2 =P(AcT−1BT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(AcT−1 |FT−2

) e−Hme,dut−1,T +

P(AcT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(AcT−1 |FT−2

) e−Hme,ddt−1,T

where Hme,uut−1,T ,Hme,udt−1,T ,H

me,dut−1,T and Hme,ddt−1,T are the values of Hmet−1,T ∈ Ft−1 condi-

tional on Ft−2.

Expanding the above formula for HmeT−2,T gives:

HmeT−2,T = Qme (AT−1BT−1| FT−2) ln

(Qme (AT−1| FT−2)

P (AT−1| FT−2)e−H

me,uut−1,T

ZuT−2

)

+Qme(AT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)ln

(Qme (AT−1| FT−2)

P (AT−1| FT−2)e−H

me,udt−1,T

ZuT−2

)

+Qme(AcT−1BT−1

∣∣FT−2

)ln

(Qme

(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

) e−Hme,dut−1,T

ZdT−2

)

+Qme(AcT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)ln

(Qme

(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

) e−Hme,ddt−1,T

ZdT−2

)+ EQme (hT | FT−2) .

Further simplification and rearrangement of terms yield

HmeT−2,T = −Hme,uut−1,T Qme (AT−1BT−1| FT−2)−Hme,udt−1,T Qme(AT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)

24

Page 36: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

−Hme,dut−1,T Qme(AcT−1BT−1

∣∣FT−2

)−Hme,ddt−1,TQme

(AcT−1B

cT−1

∣∣FT−2

)+Qme (AT−1| FT−2)

(ln

Qme (AT−1| FT−2)P (AT−1| FT−2)

− lnZuT−2

)

+Qme(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)(ln

Qme(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)P(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

) − lnZdT−2

)+ EQme (hT | FT−2)

= Qme (AT−1| FT−2) lnQme (AT−1| FT−2)

P (AT−1| FT−2)

+ (1−Qme (AT−1| FT−2)) ln1−Qme (AT−1| FT−2)

1− P (AT−1| FT−2)

−Qme (AT−1| FT−2) lnZuT−2 −Qme(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)lnZdT−2.

Using (3.6) we obtain

HmeT−2,T = hT−1 −Qme (AT−1| FT−2) lnZuT−2 −Qme(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)lnZdT−2. (3.32)

Observe, however, that because of (3.8),

ZuT−2 = EQmm(e−H

meT−1,T

∣∣∣FT−2 ∨AT−1

)and ZdT−2 = EQmm

(e−H

meT−1,T

∣∣∣FT−2 ∨AcT−1

).

The above, together with (3.5), yield

Qme (AT−1| FT−2) lnZuT−2 + Qme(AcT−1

∣∣FT−2

)lnZdT−2

= EQmm(

lnEQmm(e−hT

∣∣∣FT−2 ∨ FST−1

)∣∣∣FT−2

).

Combining the above and using hT−1 ∈ FT−2 we obtain (3.21).To establish (3.21) for t < T −2 we work along similar arguments which have

been omitted.The next result highlights an important connection between J

(t,t+1)Qmm and

J(t,t+1)Qme . It plays an important role in relating the backward and the forward prices

developed in subsequent chapters. To our knowledge the result is new.

Proposition 7 Let Z be an Ft+1−measurable random variable and Hmet+1,T ,J(t,t+1)Qmm

25

Page 37: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

as in (3.30) and (3.27), respectively. Then

J (t,t+1)Qmm (Z) = J (t,t+1)

Qme(Z +Hmet+1,T

)+ J (t,t+1)

Qmm(−Hmet+1,T

).

Proof. By the definition of J (t,t+1)Qmm we have

J (t,t+1)Qmm (Z)

= Qmm (At+1| Ft) ln

(Qmm (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

Qmm (At+1| Ft)eZ

uu+

Qmm(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qmm (At+1| Ft)

eZud

)

+Qmm(Act+1

∣∣Ft) ln

(Qmm

(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)Qmm

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdu

+Qmm

(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qmm

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdd

)

= Qme (At+1| Ft) ln

(P (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

P (At+1| Ft)eZ

uu+

P(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P (At+1| Ft)

eZud

)

+Qme(Act+1

∣∣Ft) ln

(P(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdu

+P(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdd

)where we used (3.9) and (3.5) applied to Qmm and Qme. Using the above proposition(representation of the minimal entropy measure) yields

J (t,t+1)Qmm (Z)

= Qme (At+1| Ft) ln(

Qme (At+1Bt+1| Ft)Qme (At+1| Ft)

eZuu+Hme,ut+1,T ×

×

(P (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

P (At+1| Ft)e−H

me,ut+1,T +

P(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P (At+1| Ft)

e−Hme,udt+1,T

)

+Qme

(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qme (At+1| Ft)

eZud+Hme,udt+1 ×

×

(P (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

P (At+1| Ft)e−H

me,ut+1,T +

P(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P (At+1| Ft)

e−Hme,udt+1,T

)

+Qme(Act+1

∣∣Ft) ln

(Qme

(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)Qme

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdu+Hme,dut+1,T ×

26

Page 38: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

×

(P(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,dut+1,T +

P(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,ddt+1,T

)

+Qme

(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qme

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdd+Hme,ddt+1,T×

×

(P(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,dut+1,T +

P(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,ddt+1,T

).

Further simplification yields

J (t,t+1)Qmm (Z) = Qme (At+1| Ft) ln

(Qme (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

Qme (At+1| Ft)eZ

uu+Huut+1,T

+Qme

(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qme (At+1| Ft)

eZud+Hme,udt+1,T

)

+Qme(Act+1

∣∣Ft) ln

(Qme

(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)Qme

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdu+Hme,dut+1,T

+Qme

(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)Qme

(Act+1

∣∣Ft) eZdd+Hme,ddt+1,T

).

+Qme (At+1| Ft) ln

(P (At+1Bt+1| Ft)

P (At+1| Ft)e−H

me,ut+1,T +

P(At+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P (At+1| Ft)

e−Hme,udt+1,T

)

+Qme(Act+1

∣∣Ft) ln

(P(Act+1Bt+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,dut+1,T +

P(Act+1B

ct+1

∣∣Ft)P(Act+1

∣∣Ft) e−Hme,ddt+1,T

)and the claim follows.

Corollary 8 Let Hmet,T be the aggregate entropy. Then

J (t,t+1)Qme

(Hmet+1,T

)= −J (t,t+1)

Qmm(−Hmet+1,T

). (3.33)

We next obtain the representation of the aggregate entropy Hmet,T in termsof the minimal entropy measure. The proof follows from Proposition 8 and themeasurability properties of h.

27

Page 39: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Proposition 9 The aggregate minimal entropy is given by the iterative scheme

HmeT,T = 0 and HmeT−1,T = hT ,

andHmet,T = ht+1 + J (t,t+1)

Qme(Hmet,T

), t = 0, 1, ..., T − 2, (3.34)

with J (t,t+1) and h defined in (3.27) and (3.6), respectively. Moreover,

Hmet,T = J (t,T )Qme

(T∑

i=t+1

hi

). (3.35)

A natural question one should ask is when the minimal entropy measure is the sameas the minimal martingale measure. This question has been investigated by severalauthors in continuous time, including [25] in the context of a stochastic volatilitymodel. They concluded that the two measures coincide when the Sharpe ratio iseither constant or FS - measurable (i.e., a function of the traded asset only, andnot of its non-traded volatility). [45] call this latter case a complete model. Ina more general model, [56] provide sufficient conditions for Qmm = Qme, also incontinuous time, using predictable representations with respect to the martingalepart of the traded asset process. The condition we derived in our discrete time modelis simple and is similar to the Sharpe ratio condition of [45]. It implies that the localentropy terms are FS-measurable (i.e., they do not depend on the non-traded riskfactor). The condition of the next corollary impacts considerably the representationof the minimal entropy, of the value function and the indifference prices that willbe developed in later chapters. Throughout this work, the condition below will bereferred to as the reduced model in discrete time.

Corollary 10 (Reduced model) If the historical distribution of the traded assetis independent of the past and current values of the non-traded risk factor, namely

P(ξt+1/Ft) = P(ξt+1/FSt ), t = 0, 1, ..., T , (3.36)

and neither are ξut+1 and ξdt+1 (i.e., ξut+1 and ξdt+1 are FSt -measurable), then(i) the local entropy terms hu are FSu -measurable, u = 0, 1, ..., T

28

Page 40: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

(ii) the representation of the aggregate entropy Hmet,T simplifies to

Hmet,T = EQmm

[T∑

i=t+1

hi/Ft

], (3.37)

(ii) the minimal martingale measure Qmm coincides with the minimal entropy mea-sure Qme.

Note that FSt -measurability of ξut+1 and ξdt+1 does not make St+1 FSt -measurable.

Proof. (i) follows easily from the definition of the local entropy terms hu (equa-tion (3.6)). (ii) As easily seen from the explicit formula for JQme (equation (3.27))and from the aggregate entropy representation above (equation (3.35)), under thealready established condition (i),

J (t,T )Qme (hu) = EQme [hu/Ft], u=0,1,...,T, (3.38)

and the first part of the corollary is obvious. Since hu is Fu-measurable, so is Hmet,T .With the last property, the quantities Huut,T and Hudt,T in equation (3.21) are the sameand this equation (3.21) becomes:

Qme (AtBt/Ft−1)Qme (At/Ft−1)

=P (AtBt/Ft−1)P (At/Ft−1)

, (3.39)

with the corresponding equations for other combinations of sets A, Ac, B and Bc.Using the characterization (3.8) of the minimal martingale measure, it become ob-vious that the measures coincide.

We finish with a representation result for the value function. This is theclassical value function, with the classical static exponential utility, studied in con-tinuous time, among others, by [46], and [10], [28] and [2]. In [13] have obtaineda representation of V 0 in discrete time using duality methods for a general staticstrictly increasing, concave, continuous, and continuously differentiable utility func-tion, fixed at the terminal time horizon. Their results were derived in a model withM traded assets and L non-tradable risk factors, but with only one trading period,which starts at t = 0 and ends at t = 1. Because it is a one-period model, the latterhas the minimal martingale measure equal to the minimal entropy measure. The

29

Page 41: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

result presented below is, in the above mentioned sense, more general than that of[13], and represents the value function in a different form.

Proposition 11 The value function satisfies, for x ∈ R and t = 0, 1, ..., T,

V 0 (x, t) = − exp(−γx−Hmet,T

).

Thus,

V 0 (x, t) = − exp

(−γx− J (t,T )

Qme

(T∑

i=t+1

hi

))

= − exp

(−γx+ J (t,T )

Qmm

(−

T∑i=t+1

hi

))with h and J as in (3.6) and (3.27) respectively.

30

Page 42: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 4

Dynamic indifference valuation

for European contracts in the

discrete model.

4.1 Dynamic indifference valuation with the forward

utility.

A common assumption in the classical utility maximization approach to valuation ofderivative contracts in incomplete markets is that the investor optimizes his expectedwealth, generated by the contract held and through the choice of trading strategyover a certain time period. The end of that time period is often referred to asan investment horizon. The utility function is traditionally specified at the end ofthe investment horizon. In this framework, even in the absence of any liabilities,the optimal expected terminal wealth depends on the end of the investment horizon.The above indicates that the classical utility maximization approach with the utilityfunction fixed at the end of the investment horizon might create mispricing andmisalignment in investment decisions. Such problems may be avoided if one choosesto work with dynamic utility processes. The dynamic utility process, as shown in[42], can be constructed to solve the inconsistency problem caused by the choice ofinvestment horizon necessary for the model.

The choice for the dynamic exponential utility that yields the same expected

31

Page 43: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

wealth levels across different investment horizons is not unique. Such a utility pro-cess could propagate forward in time and be pre-specified at some initial time point(called the normalization point), thus generating a forward utility, or it could bepre-specified at a future time (again, called the normalization point) and propagatebackward, generating a backward utility. In this section we present a discrete timeforward utility. Following the ideas of [42], we construct the corresponding forwardutility process. The process generates the same wealth levels for different investmenthorizons. It also satisfies the so-called self-generation property that the maximal ex-pected wealth, generated with the given utility process and starting with the currentwealth level in the absence of any derivative contacts) is the same as the utility ofthe current wealth level. We explain how European contracts can be priced withsuch a utility process. We derive the recursive pricing algorithm, and study howthe prices are effected by risk aversion. We show that the prices are only sub-linearwith respect to payoffs, unlike the pricing by expectation in complete market. Moreimportantly, we emphasize that not only the forward utility process, but also theprices, are independent of the investment horizon. Even though the forward utilityprocess is dependent on the initial normalization point, the prices generated by thealgorithm are not. We believe the last two properties make the forward dynamicutility an attractive candidate for use in the valuation of derivative contracts.

We start by presenting a small lemma that is a technical intermediate result,and will used later to derive the desired properties for the forward utility. Theproof of the lemma follows easily from formula (11) presented in chapter 3. Werecall that (11) is the discrete time analog for the classical result of [10] whichcharacterizes the functional form of the so-called pain investment value function inutility maximization problems with static exponential utility.

As mentioned earlier, our model is general enough to value contracts forwhich maturity does not necessarily coincide with the end of the investment horizon.From now on, we denote by T the end of the investment horizon and by T thecontract’s maturity, and assume T ≤ T .

Lemma 12 For t ≥ 0 and i = t, t + 1, ..., T , consider the aggregate entropy HTand the local entropies hi, given, respectively, in (2.17) in Chapter 2 and recalled in

32

Page 44: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

(3.6) in Chapter 3. Then HT ∈ Ft while hi ∈ Fi−1. Moreover,

supαi+1

EP

(−e−γαi+1∆Si+1+hi+1

∣∣∣Fi) = −1. (4.1)

We are now ready to introduce the forward dynamic utility in a multi-period setting.For this, we fix the forward normalization point denoted by s ≥ 0. The forwarddynamic utility, denoted by UFt (x; s) is defined for t ≥ s below.

Definition 4.1 Let s ≥ 0 be the forward normalization point. For t = s, s+1, ...,, anFt-measurable stochastic process UFt (x; s) is called a forward dynamic exponentialutility, normalized at s, if, for all t, T, with T = t + 1, t + 2, ..., it satisfies thestochastic optimization criterion

UFt (x; s) =

−e−γx, t = s

supAEP(UFT (XT ; s)

∣∣Ft) , s ≤ t ≤ T(4.2)

with XT as in (2.2) and Xt = x.

Several things to notice are that by construction, there is no constraint onthe length of the trading horizon and that the investor receives the same expectedutility of terminal wealth, independently of the length of the trading horizon. Thelatter property will be referred to as the time consistency of the dynamic utility.Also, the forward dynamic utility is self-generating (the value function) is definedtraditionally as the expected utility of the terminal wealth, and coincides with theutility function itself.

Note that the forward dynamic utility might not be unique. Questions aboutuniqueness and robustness are currently under investigation and are not the sub-ject of this presentation. We will be working with one specific solution of (4.2),introduced below.

Proposition 13 For s = 0, 1, ..., the processUFt (x; s) : t = s, s+ 1, ...

defined,

for x ∈ R, by

UFt (x; s) =

−e−γx, t = s

−e−γx+∑tu=s+1 hu , t ≥ s+ 1

(4.3)

33

Page 45: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

h-variables with the local entropy terms, hi, i = 1, 2, ..., given by (3.6), is a forwarddynamic exponential utility.

Proof. The fact that UF is normalized at time s is a direct consequence of itsdefinition. To show (4.3), it suffices to establish it for T = t+ 1 since the rest of theproof would follow by direct induction arguments. To this end, we recall

UFt (x; s) = supαt+1

EP(UFt+1 (Xt+1; s) |Ft

)(4.4)

= supαt+1

EP

(−e−γXt+1+Σt+1

i=s+1hi |Ft)

(4.5)

= e−γx+Σti=s+1hi supαt+1

EP

(−e−γαt+1∆St+1+ht+1 |FT

)(4.6)

and using (4.1) we conclude.In this section, we discuss the notion of forward indifference price and we

provide an iterative algorithm for its construction. This new concept of price wasrecently introduced by the authors in [42] in continuous time. In discrete time theissue has been considered in [38], and this section follows closely that paper, withthe only exception that all the results are formulated from the buyer’s point of view.

Definition 4.2 Let s ≥ 0 be the forward normalization point and consider theforward dynamic exponential utility UF introduced in (4.3). Let s ≤ t0 ≤ T andconsider a claim, written at t0, yielding payoff CT ∈ FT . For t ∈ [s, T ], the forwardindifference price is defined as the amount νFt (CT ; s) for which

UFt(x+ νFt (CT ; s); s

)= supAEP(UFT (XT + CT ; s)

∣∣Ft) (4.7)

for all initial wealth levels x ∈ R.

The notation we use suggests that there is a dependency of the forward dynamicutility and, consequently, the price on the normalization point s. As will becomeclear after the explicit formula for the price is derived, the normalization point doesnot affect the price, but for now we keep the normalization point in the notation.

Next, we construct the forward indifference valuation algorithm. In the def-inition of the forward price functionals, the forward dynamic utility and its in-

34

Page 46: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

verse, with respect to the wealth argument, appear. This functional is denoted by(UF)−1

t(x; s) and is given, for t ≥ s, by

(UF)−1

t(x; s) = −1

γlog (−x) +

t∑i=s+1

hi, (4.8)

for x ∈ R− and hi as in (3.6). We recall that Ft and FSt are the filtrations generated,respectively, by the random variables (Si, Yi), and Si, for i = 1, 2, ..., t.

Definition 4.3 Let Z be a random variable on (Ω,F , P). Let s be the forwardnormalization point and UFt (x) and

(UF)−1

t(x) the forward dynamic utility and its

inverse (given in (4.3) and (4.8)). We define:· the forward pricing measure Qmm to be the minimal martingale measure,

characterized by:

Qmm(ηt+1

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)= P

(ηt+1

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

), t = 0, 1, ..., T . (4.9)

· the single step forward price functional

E(t,t+1)Qmm (Z; s) = EQmm

((UF)−1

t+1

(EQmm

(UFt+1 (Z; s)

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

); s)), (4.10)

· the multi step forward price functional

E(t,t′)Qmm(Z; s) = E(t,t+1)

Qmm (E(t+1,t+2)Qmm (...(E(t′−1,t′)

Qmm (Z; s); s); s); s), (4.11)

across the time interval (t, t′).

Theorem 14 Let CT ∈ FT be the claim, introduced at t0 and to be priced underthe forward dynamic utility UFt (x; s). The following statements hold:

(i) The forward indifference price νFt (CT ; s), defined in (4.7), is given, fort0 ≤ t ≤ T , by the backward induction algorithm

νFt (CT ; s) = E(t,t+1)Qmm (νFt+1(CT ; s); s), t < T ,

νFT

(CT ; s) = CT ,(4.12)

with Qmm defined in (4.9).

35

Page 47: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

(ii) The forward indifference price process νFt (CT ; s) ∈ Ft and satisfies, fort ≥ t0,

νFt (CT ; s) = E(t,T )Qmm(CT ; s), (4.13)

with the iterative forward price functional defined in (4.11).(iii) The forward indifference price algorithm is consistent across time in

that, for s ≤ t ≤ t′ ≤ T , the semigroup property

νFt (CT ; s) = E(t,t′)Qmm(E(t′,T )

Qmm (CT ; s) ; s) = E(t,t′)Qmm(νF

t′(CT ; s); s) = νFt (E(t,T )

Qmm(CT ; s); s).(4.14)

holds.

Before we prove the theorem, we present a proposition below. The followingresult emphasizes two important properties of the single-step forward price func-tional, namely, its independence of the forward normalization point and its staticnature. The first property is the one that mainly differentiates the forward and thebackward pricing schemes. Note that the forward price functional E(t,T )

Qmm(·) emergesfrom the pricing condition (4.7) in which the involved forward dynamic utility doesdepend on s and, also changes dynamically in time. Nevertheless, these two featuresdissipate in the price. In addition, the proposition re-formulates equation (4.12).This is the form in which theorem 14 will be proved.

Proposition 15 Let Z be a random variable on the probability space (Ω,F ,P). IfE(t,t+1)

Qmm (·)is the single-step forward price functional, introduced in (4.10), then fort = s, s+ 1, ..., T − 1,

E(t,t+1)Qmm (Z; s) = −EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γZ

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)|Ft). (4.15)

Proof. We first observe that

EQmm(UFt+1 (Z; s)

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)= EQmm

(−e−γZ+ΣTi=s+1hi

∣∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)(4.16)

= −eΣTi=s+1hiEQmm(−e−γZ

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

). (4.17)

Therefore, (UF)−1

t′

(EQmm

(UFt′ (Z; s)

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt′ ) ; s)

(4.18)

36

Page 48: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= −1γ

log(eΣTi=s+1hiEQmm

(−e−γZ

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

))+

t∑i=s+1

hi (4.19)

= −1γ

logEQmm(−e−γZ

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)(4.20)

and the assertion follows.We are now ready to prove theorem 14. Proof. We prove (i) in the view of

propostion 15 above. (ii) and (iii) follow from the definition of operators E t,uQmm(·),t ≤ u ≤ T . At time T − 1,

supAEP(UFT

(XT + CT ; s)∣∣FT−1

)= supAEP(−e−γ(XT+CT )+hT

∣∣FT−1

)=

ehT supAEP(−e−γ(XT+CT )

∣∣FT−1

)= ehT

(−e−γ(XT−1+E(T−1,T )

Qmm (CT ))−hT),

(4.21)

as follows using theorem 1, Chapter 2, Part (v).At time T − 2,

supAEP(UFT

(XT + CT ; s)∣∣FT−2

)= sup

αT−1,αT

EP

(−e−γ(XT+CT )+hT+hT−1

∣∣∣FT−2

)=

ehT−1 supαT−1

EP

(ehT sup

αT

EP(−e−γ(XT+CT )

∣∣FT−1

)|FT−2

)=

ehT−1 supαT−1

EP

(ehT − e−γ(XT−1+νF

T−1(CT ;s))−hT |FT−1

)=

−e−γ(XT−2+E(T−2,T−1)Qmm (νF

T−1(CT ;s)))

.

(4.22)For other t < T − 2, the argument is similar and is omitted. Taking into accountproposition 15 presented above, the proof of 14 is complete.

The forward indifference price is calculated via the iterative pricing scheme(4.12), applied backwards in time. The scheme has local and dynamic properties.Dynamically, at each time interval, say [t; t + 1), the price νFt (CT ; s) is computedvia the single-step forward price functional E(t,t+1)

Qmm (·), applied to the claim’s value atthe end of period [t; t+ 1). The latter turns out to be the forward indifference price,νFt+1(CT ; s), yielding forward prices consistent across times. Locally, the valuationrole of E(t,t+1)

Qmm is similar to its static counterpart, as developed in [41], it is nonlinearand produces the prices in two sub-steps. In the first sub-step, the end of the periodvalue, νFt+1(CT ; s), is altered using forward risk preferences and the conditioning

37

Page 49: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

on the information generated by Ft ∨ FSt+1. The new payoff, called the forwardconditional certainty equivalent

νFt+1(CT ; s) =(UF)−1

t+1

(EQmm

(UFt+1

(νFt+1(CT ; s)

) ∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

); s)

(4.23)

= −1γ

logEQmm(e−γν

Ft+1(CT ;s)

∣∣Ft ∨ FSt+1

)(4.24)

emerges. Once this step is executed, the remaining risks are priced linearly. Theforward indifference price is then provided as

νFt (CT ; s) = EQmm(νFt+1(CT ; s) |Ft ). (4.25)

The price functional E(t,t+1)Qmm (·) is affected by the forward dynamic risk preferences

(and their inverse) only at its first sub-step. Note, however, that E(t,t+1)Qmm (·) is in-

dependent of the specific payoff and uses the same pricing measure throughout. Itis also independent of the forward normalization point, a property that is, in turn,inherited by the forward prices. To remind ourselves of this, we therefore eliminatethe s−notation.

The reader familiar with existing indifference algorithmic results for multi-period binomial models (see, among others, [52], [2] and [41]) might find the form of(4.12) very similar to the one appearing in these references. However, the results inthe latter works and the ones herein differ considerably. First, the pricing measureused is neither the minimal entropy measure, nor the historical measure, but theminimal martingale measure. Second, earlier results refer to entirely different riskpreference structures and are derived for simplified market conditions, where thenext period’s distribution of the traded asset is not affected by the value of thenon-traded stochastic factor.

The algorithm presented above for the indifference valuation with the forwarddynamic utility may be extended to contracts that yield a series of clash flows. Thisis not a subject of this work. Instead, in later chapters, we develop the correspondingalgorithm for early exercise and partial exercise claims.

We study the behavior of the forward indifference prices in terms of the modelparameters. We start by presenting how the indifference is affected by changes inrisk aversion . We occasionally adopt the notation νFt (CT ; γ) and E(t,T )

Qmm(· ; γ) torefer to a specific level of risk aversion.

38

Page 50: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Proposition 16 For a fixed contract CT , the function

γ → νFt (CT ; γ) (4.26)

from R+ into R is decreasing and continuous.

Proof. Continuity follows from formula (4.12) and the continuity properties ofthe single-step price functional E(t,t+1)

Qmm (·), for t = s, s+ 1, ..., T − 1.To establish the claimed monotonicity, we take γ1 ≤ γ2 and use backward

induction. We first show that

νFT−1(CT ; γ1) ≥ νFT−1(CT ; γ2) (4.27)

or, equivalently, that

−EQmm

(1γ1

logEQmm(e−γ1CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.28)

≥ −EQmm

(1γ2

logEQmm(e−γ2CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

). (4.29)

To this end, using Holder’s inequality yields

EQmm(e−γ1CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST)≤(EQmm

(e−γ2CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST))γ1/γ2 (4.30)

and, in turn,

− 1γ1

logEQmm(e−γ1CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST)≥ − 1

γ2

logEQmm(e−γ2CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST).

(4.31)Taking conditional expectation with respect to FT−1 and under Qmm, we conclude.We next assume that

νFt+1(CT ; γ1) ≥ νFt+1(CT ; γ2) (4.32)

and we are going to establish

νFt (CT ; γ1) ≥ νFt (CT ; γ2). (4.33)

Using (4.12), the monotonicity of E(t,t+1)Qmm with respect to the payoff and Holder’s

39

Page 51: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

inequality, we obtain

νFt (CT ; γ1) = E(t,t+1)Qmm (νFt+1(CT ; γ1); γ1) ≥ E(t,t+1)

Qmm (νFt+1(CT ; γ2); γ1) (4.34)

≥ E(t,t+1)Qmm (νFt+1(CT ; γ2); γ2) = νFt (CT ; γ2), (4.35)

which completes the proof.

Proposition 17 The following limiting relations hold

limγ↓0

νFt (CT ; γ) = EQmm (CT |Ft ) (4.36)

andlimγ↑∞

νFt (CT ; γ) = νF,Inft (C), (4.37)

with νF,Inft (C) defined recursively as: νF,InfT

(C) = CT ,

νF,Inft (C) = EQmm( infYt+1

νF,Inft+1 (C)), t < T .(4.38)

Proof. We recall that

νFt (CT ) = E(t,t+1)Qmm

(E(t+1,t+2)

Qmm(...(E(T−1,T )

Qmm (CT ))))

(4.39)

withE(i,i+1)

Qmm (Z) = −EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γZ

∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)|Fi), (4.40)

for i = t, t+ 1, ..., T − 1 and Z a random variable on (Ω,F ,P). For convenience, wedenote by tj the generic intermediate point of [t, T ], i.e. t = t1 ≤ t2 ≤ ... ≤ tn−1 ≤T = tn, and we define, for j = 1, ..., n− 1,

E(tj ,tj+1)Qmm (Z; γj+1) = −EQmm

(1

γj+1

logEQmm(e−γj+1Z

∣∣∣Ftj ∨ FStj+1

) ∣∣Ftj ) .(4.41)

The forward indifference price can then be written as

νFt (CT ; γ1, ..., γn) (4.42)

40

Page 52: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= E(t1,t2)Qmm

(E(t2,t3)

Qmm((...E(T−1,T )

Qmm (CT ; γn))

; γ2

); γ1

)(4.43)

with γj = γ for j = 1, ..., n. Using the continuity and monotonicity properties ofthe forward single-step price functional, we deduce that

limγ→γ

νFt (CT ; γ) = limγ1→γ

(...

(limγn→γ

νFt (CT ; γ1, ..., γn)))

(4.44)

= limγ1→γ

E(t1,t2)Qmm

(limγ2→γ

E(t2,t3)Qmm

((... limγn→γ

E(tn,tn+1)Qmm (CT ; γn)

); γ2

); γ1

). (4.45)

The limits in (4.36) and (4.37) then correspond to the choices γ = 0 and γ

=∞.We start with the case γ = 0. Clearly, the analysis reduces to the specification

of the individual limits, as γm ↓ 0 of the nested single forward price functionals. Weobserve

limγn↓0E(tn−1,tn)

Qmm (CT ; γn) (4.46)

= limγn↓0−EQmm

(1γn

logEQmm(e−γnCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.47)

where we remind the reader that tn−1 = T − 1 and tn = T . The above termexpands as:

νFT−1

(CT ; γn) = E T−1,TQmm (CT ) = −

Qmm(AT /FT−1)γn

log(

Qmm(ATBT /FT−1)Qmm(AT /FT−1) e−γnC

uuT +

Qmm(ATBcT /FT−1)

Qmm(AT /FT−1) e−γnCudT

)−

Qmm(AcT /FT−1)γn

log(

Qmm(AcTBT /FT−1)Qmm(AcT /FT−1) e−γnC

duT +

Qmm(AcTBcT /FT−1)

Qmm(AcT /FT−1) e−γnCddT

),

(4.48)where events AT , Ac

T, BT and Bc

Tare defined in equation (3.4) of Chapter 3.

41

Page 53: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Sending γn ↓ 0 yields

limγn↓0 E(tn−1,tn)Qmm (CT ; γn) = Qmm(ATBT /FT−1)Cuu

T

+Qmm(ATBCT/FT−1)Cud

T+ Qmm(Ac

TBT /FT−1)Cdu

T+ Qmm(Ac

TBcT/FT−1)Cdd

T.

(4.49)Combining the above yields

limγn↓0E(tn−1,tn)

Qmm (CT ; γn) = limγn↓0E(T−1,T )

Qmm (CT ; γn) = EQmm(CT∣∣FT−1 ). (4.50)

Repeating the arguments as γn−1 ↓ 0, ..., γ1 ↓ 0, we deduce that

limγ↓0

νFT (CT ; γ) = EQmm((...EQmm

(EQmm(CT

∣∣FT−1 )∣∣FT−2

))... |Ft

), (4.51)

and using the properties of conditional expectation we obtain (4.36).Next, we look at the case γ = ∞ and we follow along the lines of the

above arguments. We start by calculating limγ↑∞ E(tn−1,tn)Qmm (CT ; γn) . Using (4.48)

and passing to the limit as γn ↑ ∞, we observe

limγn↑∞

E(tn−1,tn)Qmm (CT ; γn) (4.52)

= limγn↑∞

−EQmm

(1γn

logEQmm(e−γnCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.53)

= Qmm(AT /FT−1) min(CuuT, Cdu

T

)+(1−Qmm(AT /FT−1)

)min

(CduT, Cdd

T

)= EQmm(inf

YTCT /FT−1)

(4.54)Using the continuity of the involved single-step forward price functionals, we deduce

limγn−1↑∞

E(tn−2,tn−1)Qmm

(limγn↑∞

E(tn−1,tn)Qmm (CT ; γn) ; γn−1

)(4.55)

= limγn−1↑∞

E(tn−2,tn−1)Qmm

(EQmm(inf

YTCT /FT−1); γn−1

). (4.56)

As γn−1 ↑ ∞,νFtn−2

(CT ; γ) ↓ νF,Inftn−2(C). (4.57)

Working similarly for the rest of the nested limits we obtain (4.37).

42

Page 54: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We note that results of the above two Propositions have been established forindifference prices under the traditional sense (backward) and for general marketenvironments by several authors (see, among others, [46], [10]).

We explore the monotonicity, convexity, and scaling properties of the forwardindifference prices. We note that in the next two propositions, all inequalities amongpayoffs and their prices hold both under the historical measure P and the pricingmeasure Qmm. Since these two measures are equivalent, we skip, for the ease of thepresentation, any measure-specific notation.

Proposition 18 The forward indifference price is a non-decreasing function of theclaim’s payoff, namely, for t = t0, t0 + 1, ..., T ,

if C1T ≤ C

2T then νFt

(C1T

)≤ νFt

(C2T

), . (4.58)

In addition, if α ∈ (0, 1), and C ≥ 0 then

νFt(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)≥ ανFt

(C1T

)+ (1− α)νFt

(C2T

). (4.59)

Proof. Monotonicity follows from elementary backward induction arguments, thevaluation algorithm (4.12) and the monotonicity of E(t,t+1)

Qmm (·) with respect its payoffargument.

The induction arguments needed for the convexity property are more in-volved, and for these we present the key steps only. We first establish (4.59) fort = T − 1, i.e. that

νFT−1

(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)≤ ανFT−1

(C1T

)+ (1− α)νFT−1

(C2T

). (4.60)

To this end, we use (4.12) and Holder’s inequality to deduce

νFT−1

(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)(4.61)

43

Page 55: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= −EQmm(

1γ logEQmm

(e−γ(αC

1T

+(1−α)C2T ) ∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST

) ∣∣FT−1

)≥ −EQmm

(1γ log

((EQmm

(e−γC

1T

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST))α

×(EQmm

(e−γC

2T

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST))1−α

) ∣∣FT−1

)= −αEQmm

(1γ logEQmm

(e−γC

1T

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)− (1− α)EQmm

(1γ logEQmm

(e−γC

2T

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

).

(4.62)

We now assume that

νFi+1

(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)≥ ανFi+1

(C1T

)+ (1− α)νFi+1

(C2T

)(4.63)

and we will establish

νFi(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)≥ ανFi

(C1T

)+ (1− α)νF

(C2T

). (4.64)

Using (4.12) and the above assumption, we observe that

νFi(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)(4.65)

= EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(eγν

Fi+1(αC1

T+(1−α)C2

T ) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)|Fi)

(4.66)

≥ EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(eγ(αν

Fi+1(C1

T )+(1−α)νFi+1(C2T )) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)|Fi). (4.67)

Applying Holder’s inequality to the last expectation yields

νFi(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T

)(4.68)

≥ −EQmm

(1γ

log(EQmm

(e−γν

Fi+1(C1

T ) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)α(4.69)

× EQmm(e−γν

Fi+1(C2

T ) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)1−α)|Fi)

(4.70)

= −αEQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γν

Fi+1(C1

T ) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)|Fi)

(4.71)

−(1− α)EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γν

Fi+1(C2

T ) ∣∣Fi ∨ FSi+1

)|Fi)

(4.72)

44

Page 56: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= ανFi(C1T

)+ (1− α)νFi

(C2T

), (4.73)

and we easily conclude.

Next, we investigate additivity properties of the forward indifference pricewith respect to the claims’ payoffs. As expected, multiples of the same payoff arenot priced by forward indifference in a linear manner. This is a direct consequence ofthe market incompleteness and the nonlinear character of forward valuation. Also,for two different claims, the forward price fails to act additively. Nothing, however,can be further said about the emerging non-linearities, since they strongly dependon the specific model and payoff structure. A concise characterization of the familyof claims that are priced additively under forward indifference valuation remains, tothe best of our knowledge, an open question.

Proposition 19 The forward indifference price satisfies, for C ≥ 0 and t = t0, t0 +1, ..., T ,

νFt (αCT ) ≥ ανFt (CT ) for α ∈ (0, 1) (4.74)

andνFt (αCT ) ≤ ανFt (CT ) for α ≥ 1. (4.75)

Proof. We only show (4.74) since (4.75) follows along similar arguments. We firstestablish that

νFT−1 (αCT ) ≥ αE(T−1,T )Qmm (CT ). (4.76)

Indeed, from Proposition 15 we easily see that

νFT−1 (αCT ) = −EQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γαCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.77)

= −αEQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.78)

≥ −αEQmm

(1γ

logEQmm(e−γCT /FT−1 ∨ FST

)/FT−1

), (4.79)

where we used monotonicity of the price with respect to the risk aversion coefficient(see Proposition 16) for α ∈ (0, 1) and γ = αγ < γ. Dividing by α > 0, yields thedesired inequality.

45

Page 57: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Working with backward induction, we next assume that

νFi+1 (αCT ) ≥ ανFi+1 (CT ) . (4.80)

The forward valuation algorithm, together with the induction assumption above,yield

νFi (αCT ) = E(i,i+1)Qmm (νFi+1 (αCT )) (4.81)

≥ E(i,i+1)Qmm (ανFi+1 (CT )). (4.82)

Using arguments similar to the above, we obtain

E(i,i+1)Qmm (ανFi+1 (CT )) ≥ αE(i,i+1)

Qmm (νFi+1 (CT )) (4.83)

and conclude the proof.We finish this section by showing that the process νFt (CT ) is a submartingale

with respect to Ft, under the pricing measure Qmm. The proof is simple and followstheorem 14 (the main pricing result) and Jensen’s inequality, as thus the proof isomitted.

Proposition 20 The forward indifference price process is a submartingale with re-spect to Ft and under Qmm, namely, for t = t0, t0 + 1, ...T ,

EQmm(νFt+1 (CT ) |Ft

)≥ νFt (CT ) . (4.84)

4.2 Dynamic indifference valuation with the backward

utility.

In this section we consider a European contract initiated at time t0 and expires attime T , yielding payoff CT ∈ FT . The utility of the agent is fixed at time T > T ,the time T is referred to as the end of the investment horizon. Making utility fixedat a future time point is a characteristic feature of the traditional static exponentialutility and backward utility developed herein as well. Again, herein we considervaluation form the buyer’s prospective, so the relevant formulas from [39] are allre-stated to reflect the buyer’s point of view.

46

Page 58: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Definition 4.4 A stochastic processUBt (x;T ) : t = 0, 1, ..., T

is called a back-

ward exponential utility, normalized at time T , if it satisfies the following properties

• at the normalization point it coincides with the utility datum,

UBT (x;T ) = −e−γx (4.85)

• for all admissible self-financing investment policies α, the process UBt (Xαt ;T )

is an Ft− supermartingale under P,

EP(UBs (Xα

s ;T )∣∣Ft) ≤ UBt (Xα

t ;T ) s = t, t+ 1, ..., T (4.86)

• there exists a policy, α∗, for which the process UBt(Xα∗t ;T

)is a Ft− martingale

under P,

EP(UBs (Xα

s ;T )∣∣Ft) = UBt (Xα

t ;T ) s = t, t+ 1, ..., T . (4.87)

The last two properties in the above definition can be rewritten as

UBt (Xt;T ) = supAEP(UBT (XT ; s)

∣∣Ft) , s ≤ t ≤ T (4.88)

We used property (4.88) when formulating the forward utility, and as one can see, itis equivalent to (4.86) and (4.87). One might wonder if the backward utility processexists and, moreover, if it is unique. The answer is affirmative as the next resultstates. The proof follows directly from the Dynamic Programming Principle.

Proposition 4.1 The exponential backward utility process is unique and is givenby the ”plain investment” value function V 0(Xt, t), defined in 2.4 of Chapter 2 andrecalled in proposition 11 of Chapter 3.

V 0 (x, t) = UBt (x;T ) = −e−γx−Hmet,T (4.89)

where Hmet,T

is the aggregate entropy.

Next, we define the indifference price process.

47

Page 59: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Definition 4.5 Let UBt (x;T ) , t = 0, 1, ..., T be the exponential backward utilityprocess given in (4.89). The indifference price of the claim CT = C (ST , YT ) , CT ∈FT , is defined as the amount νBt (CT ;T ) , t = 0, 1, ..., T , for which equality

UBt(Xt + νBt (CT ;T ) ;T

)= sup

αt+1,...,αT

EP(UBT (XT + CT ;T )

∣∣Ft) (4.90)

is satisfied for all initial wealth levels x ∈ R.

Below we provide two alternative variations of the indifference pricing algo-rithm, one under the minimal martingale measure, the other one under the minimalentropy measure. First we first present the algorithm under the minimal martingalemeasure, and make a comment about the difference in the algorithms for back-ward and forward utilities. We note that expressions of the first algorithm can besimplified if one works under the minimal entropy measure instead.

Thus we provide another version of the algorithm, this one under the minimalentropy measure. We mention that the second version of the algorithm is very muchin line with the continuous time indifference valuation with backward utility, asshown by [54]. Next, we investigate the properties of the prices obtained throughour algorithm. At the end of the section we compare and contrast the backwardand forward valuation algorithms.

The following functionals will be used in the sequel.

Definition 4.6 Let Z be a random variable on (Ω,F , P). For t = 0, 1, ..., T , s =t+ 1, ..., T and Q ∈ Q define

P(t,t+1)Qmm (Z) = E(t,t+1)

Qmm

(Z +

1γHmet+1,T

)− E(t,t+1)

Qmm

(1γHmet+1,T

)(4.91)

andP(s,t)

Qmm (Z) = P(s,s+1)Qmm

(...P(t−1,t)

Qmm (Z)). (4.92)

Theorem 21 Let CT ∈ FT be the claim to be priced. Let Qmm be the minimalmartingale measure and Hme

t,Tthe aggregate entropy. The following statements are

true:(i) The indifference price νBt (CT ;T ), defined in (4.90), is given by the algo-

rithmνBT (CT ;T ) = CT , (4.93)

48

Page 60: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

νBt (CT ;T ) = P(t,t+1)Qmm

(νBt+1 (CT ;T )

), (4.94)

where P(t,t+1)Qmm is the single-step pricing functional given in (4.91).

(ii) The indifference price process is given by

νBt (CT ;T ) = P(t,T)Qmm (CT ) , t = 0, 1, ..., T , (4.95)

with the multi-step price functional P(t,T)Qmm defined in (4.92).

In particular,

νBt (CT ;T ) = E(t,T )Qmm

(CT +

T∑i=t+2

hi

)− E(t,T )

Qmm

(+

T∑i=t+2

hi

), t = 0, 1, ..., T − 1.

(4.96)(iii) The pricing algorithm is consistent across time in that for 0 ≤ t ≤ s ≤

T , the semigroup property

νBt (CT ;T ) = P(t,s)Qmm(P(s,T )

Qmm (CT )) = P(t,s)Qmm((νBs (CT ;T )) = νBt (P(s,T )

Qmm(CT ;T ))(4.97)

holds.(iv) The value function V CT , defined in (2.4), can be written in the form

V CT (x, t) = − exp

(−γ(x− νBt (CT ;T )

)+ J (t,T )

Qmm

(−

T∑i=t+1

hi

)), (4.98)

with h given in (3.6) and J (t,T)Qmm as in (3.27) with Q = Qmm.

Proof. Equality (4.93) is immediate. We establish (4.94) for t = T − 1. Using thesingle-period arguments employed in [41], and recalled in 2.14

V CT(x, T − 1

)= sup

αT

EP(UB

(x+ αT

(ST − ST−1

)− CT

)∣∣FT−1

)(4.99)

= −e−γ(x−E(T−1,T)

Qmm (CT )

)−hT

. (4.100)

49

Page 61: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Using V 0(x, T − 1

)= −e−γx−hT , we deduce

νBT−1 (CT ;T ) = E(T−1,T)Qmm (CT ) . (4.101)

For t = T − 2, we have

V CT(x, T − 2

)=

supαT−1,αTEP

(−e−γ(x+αT−1(ST−1−ST−2)+αT (ST−ST−1)−CT )

∣∣∣FT−2

) (4.102)

= supαT−1EP

(e−γ(x+αT−1(ST−1−ST−2))

supαT EP

(−e−γ(αT (ST−ST−1)−CT )

∣∣∣FT−1

)∣∣∣FT−2

) (4.103)

= supαT−1EP

(−e−γ

(x+αT−1(ST−1−ST−2)−

(νBT−1

(CT ;T )− 1γhT

))∣∣∣∣FT−2

)= −e

−γ(x−E(T−2,T−1)

Qmm(νBT−1

(CT ;T )− 1γhT

))−hT−1

(4.104)

where we used (4.101) and (3.28). Proposition 11 in Chapter 3 together with (3.28)and the measurability properties of h yields

V 0(x, T − 2

)= −e−γx+J (T−2,,T)

Qmm (−(hT−1+hT )) = −e−γx−hT−1+E(T−2,,T)Qmm

(−hT

γ

).

(4.105)Combining the above we obtain

νBT−2 (CT ;T ) = E(T−2,T−1)Qmm

(νBT−1 (CT ;T )− 1

γhT

)−E(T−2,T−1)

Qmm

(−1γhT

)(4.106)

= E(T−2,T−1)Qmm

(νT−1 (CT )− 1

γHmeT−1,T

)− E(T−2,T−1)

Qmm

(−1γHmeT−1,T

). (4.107)

Next, we assume that

νBt+1 (CT ;T ) = E(t+1,t+2)Qmm

(νBt+2 (CT ;T )− 1

γHmet+1,T

)− E(t,t+1)

Qmm

(−1γHmet+1,T

)(4.108)

and we are going to show (4.94).

50

Page 62: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We have

V CT (x, t) = supαt+1,...,αT

EP

(− exp

(−γ(x+ ΣT−1

i=t αi+1 (Si+1 − Si)− CT))∣∣∣Ft)

(4.109)= supαt+1

EP(e−γ(x+αt+1(St+1−St))

supαt+2,...,αTEP

(−e−γ

(ΣT−1i=t+1αi+1(Si+1−Si)−CT

)∣∣∣∣Ft+1

)∣∣∣∣Ft) (4.110)

= supαt+1

EP

(e−γ(x+αt+1(St+1−St))UBt+1

(−νBt+1 (CT ;T )

)∣∣∣Ft) (4.111)

= supαt+1

EP

(− exp

(−γ(x+ αt+1 (St+1 − St)− νBt+1 (CT ;T )

)−Hmet+1,T

)∣∣∣Ft)(4.112)

= supαt+1EP (− exp (−γ (x+ αt+1 (St+1 − St)

−(νBt+1 (CT ;T )− 1

γHmet+1,T

)))∣∣∣Ft) (4.113)

= − exp(−γ(x− E(t,t+1)

Qmm

(νBt+1 (CT ;T )− 1

γHmet+1,T

))− ht+1

), (4.114)

where we used the appropriate single-period arguments. Using once again proposi-tion 11 of chapter 3 and (3.28), we have

V 0 (x, t) = − exp(−γx−

(−γE(t,t+1)

Qmm

(−1γHmet+1,T

)+ ht+1

))(4.115)

and using (4.90) we conclude.

Next we produce the pricing algorithm in terms of the minimal entropymeasure.

Theorem 22 Let CT ∈ FT be the claim to be priced. Let Qme be the minimalentropy measure and Hme

t,Tbe the aggregate entropy. The following statements are

true:(i) The indifference price νBt (CT ;T ), defined in (4.90), is given by the algo-

rithmνBT (CT ;T ) = CT , (4.116)

νBt (CT ;T ) = E(t,t+1)Qme

(νBt+1 (CT ;T )

), (4.117)

51

Page 63: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

where E(t,t+1)Qme is the single-step price functional defined in (2.9).(ii) The indifference price process is given by

νBt (CT ;T ) = E(t,T)Qme (νt+1 (CT ;T )) , t = 0, 1, ...T , (4.118)

with the multi-step price functional E(t,T)Qme defined in (2.8).

(iii) The pricing algorithm is consistent across time in that, for 0 ≤ t ≤ s ≤T , the semigroup property

νBt (CT ;T ) = E(t,s)Qme(E

(s,T )Qme (CT )) = E(t,s)

Qme((νBs (CT ;T )) = νBt (E(s,T )

Qme (CT ;T )) (4.119)

holds.(iv) The value function V CT , defined in (2.4), can be written in the form

V CT (x, t) = − exp

−γ (x− νBt (CT ;T ))− J (t,T)

Qme

T∑i=t+1

hi

, (4.120)

with J (t,T)Qme as in (3.27).

Proof. Using Z = γνBt+1 (CT ;T )−Hmet+1,T

in (3.28) yields

J (t,t+1)Qmm

(γνt+1 (CT )−Hme

t+1,T

)= J (t,t+1)

Qme(γνBt+1 (CT ;T )

)+

J (t,t+1)Qmm

(−Hme

t+1,T

) (4.121)

and, in turn,

1γJ

(t,t+1)Qmm

(γνBt+1 (CT ;T )−Hme

t+1,T

)= 1

γJ(t,t+1)Qme

(γνBt+1 (CT ;T )

)+

1γJ

(t,t+1)Qmm

(−Hme

t+1,T

).

(4.122)

Thus

E(t,t+1)Qmm

(νBt+1 (CT ;T )−

Hmet+1,T

γ

)= E(t,t+1)

Qme(νBt+1 (CT ;T )

)+ E(t,t+1)

Qmm

(−Hmet+1,T

γ

)(4.123)

and we easily conclude.

52

Page 64: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Next we focus on properties of the indifference prices in terms of their payoffsand risk aversion parameter. When stating results regarding the risk aversion, weoccasionally use the modified notation E t,uQ (·; γ) instead of E t,uQ (·;T ) to reference aspecific level of γ. The backward normalization point T is fixed and is the same forall results considered in this section.

Proposition 4.2 The function γ → νBt (CT ;T ) from R+ into R is decreasing andcontinuous.

Proof. We will use the price representation (4.118). Continuity follows directlyfrom the formula (4.117) and the continuity of the single-step functionals E t,t+1

Qme (·).To establish monotonicity, let us assume that 0 < γ1 < γ2. We first show that

νBT−1(CT ; γ1) > νBT−1(CT ; γ2). (4.124)

Holder’s inequality yields

EQme(e−γ1CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST)≤(EQ(e−γ2CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST))γ1/γ2 (4.125)

and, in turn,

− 1γ1

lnEQme(e−γ1CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST)≥ − 1

γ2

lnEQme(e−γ2CT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST). (4.126)

Taking the expectation with respect to Qme, we deduce (4.124). The rest of theproof follows by straightforward induction arguments.

Proposition 4.3 The following limiting relations hold

limγ→0+

νBt (CT ; γ) = EQme (CT |Ft ) , (4.127)

andlimγ→∞

νBt (CT ; γ) = νB,Inft (C), (4.128)

with νB,InfT

(C) = CT ,

νB,Inft (C) = EQme

(infYt+1

νB,Inft+1 (C)), t < T .

(4.129)

53

Page 65: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Proof. We recall that

νBt (CT ; γ) = E(t,t+1)Qme

(E(t+1,t+2)

Qme((...E(T−1,T )

Qme (CT ))))

, (4.130)

with

E(s,s+1)Qme (·) = −EQme

(1γ

logEQme(e−γ(·) ∣∣Fs ∨ FSs+1

)|Fs)

(4.131)

for s = t, t + 1, .., T . For convenience, we denote by ti the intermediate points of[t, T ], t = t0 ≤ ... ≤ tn−1 ≤ T = tn. We define

E(ti,ti+1)Qme (· ; γi+1) (4.132)

= −EQme

(1

γi+1

logEQme(e−γi+1(·)

∣∣∣Fti ∨ FSti+1

) ∣∣Fti+1

)(4.133)

for i = 0, 1, ..., n− 1. Thus, the indifference price can be written as

νBt (CT ; γ1, ...γn) (4.134)

= E(t0,t1)Qme

(E(t1,t2)

Qme((...E(tn−1,tn)

Qme (CT ; γn))

; γ2

); γ1

)(4.135)

with γi = γ for i = 1, .., n. Using a classical diagonalization argument, we deducethat

limγ→γ

νBt (CT ; γ) = limγ1→γ

(...

(limγn→γ

νBt (CT ; γ1, ...γn)))

(4.136)

= limγ1→γ

E(t0,t1)Qme

(limγ2→γ

E(t1,t2)Qme

((... limγn→γ

E(tn−1,tn)Qme (CT ; γn)

); γ2

); γ1

)(4.137)

The limits in (4.127) and (4.128) then correspond to the cases γ = 0 and γ

=∞.We start with the case γ = 0. Clearly, the analysis reduces to the specification

of the individual limits as γm+1 → 0 of the nested single-step price functionalsE(tm,tm+1)

Qme(·; γm+1

), for m = 0, 1, .., n− 1. We first look at

limγn→0

E(tn−1,tn)Qme (CT ; γn) (4.138)

54

Page 66: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= limγn→0

−EQme

(1γn

logEQme(e−γnCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST)|FT

)(4.139)

where we remind the reader that T − 1 = tn−1 and T = tn. Recall that thelast term coincides with the indifference price νT−1(CT ; γn) and it can be computedexplicitly. The expression above expands as

νBT−1

(CT ; γn) = E T−1,TQme (CT ) = −

Qme(AT /FT−1)γn

log(

Qme(ATBT /FT−1)Qme(AT /FT−1) e−γnC

uuT +

Qme(ATBcT /FT−1)

Qme(AT /FT−1) e−γnCudT

)−

Qme(AcT /FT−1)γn

log(

Qme(AcTBT /FT−1)Qme(AcT /FT−1) e−γnC

duT +

Qme(AcTBcT /FT−1)

Qme(AcT /FT−1) e−γnCddT

),

(4.140)where events AT , Ac

T, BT , and Bc

Twere defined in equation (3.4) of Chapter 3 and

represent the four possible outcomes for the time T state space, as seen from timeT − 1.

Taking γn → 0 yields

limγn↓0 E(tn−1,tn)Qme (CT ; γn) = Qme(ATBT /FT−1)Cuu

T

+Qme(ATBCT/FT−1)Cud

T+ Qme(Ac

TBT /FT−1)Cdu

T+ Qme(Ac

TBcT/FT−1)Cdd

T.

(4.141)Combining the above yields

limγn→0

E(tn−1,tn)Qme (CT ; γn) = EQme(CT

∣∣FT−1 ). (4.142)

Repeating the arguments as γn−1 → 0, ..., γ1 → 0, we deduce that

limγ→0

νBt (CT ; γ) = EQme((...EQme

(EQme(CT

∣∣FT−1 )∣∣FT−2

))|Ft)

(4.143)

and using the law of iterative expectations we obtain (4.127).Next, we consider the case γ = ∞ and proceed in a manner similar to the

above arguments. We start with the last limit, namely, limγ→∞ E(tn−1,tn)Qme (CT ; γn)

for which we observelim

γn→∞E(tn−1,tn)

Qme (CT ; γn) (4.144)

55

Page 67: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

= limγn→∞

−EQme

(1γn

logEQme(e−γnCT

∣∣FT−1 ∨ FST) ∣∣FT−1

)(4.145)

= qT min(C(SuT , Y

uT

), C(SuT , Y

dT

))+ (1− qT ) min

(C(SuT , Y

uT

), C(SdT , Y

dT

))(4.146)

Using the continuity of the involved single-step pricing functionals,

limγn−1→∞

E(tn−2,tn−1)Qme

(lim

γn→∞E(tn−1,tn)

Q (CT ; γn) ; γn−1

)(4.147)

= limγn−1→∞

E(tn−2,tn−1)Qme

(EQme(inf

YTCT /FT−1); γn−1

)(4.148)

As γn−1 → ∞, νBt (CT ; γ) ↓ νB,Inft (C). Working similarly with the rest of single-period limits, we obtain 4.128

Next, we explore monotonicity, convexity, and scaling behavior of the indif-ference prices. We note that all inequalities below hold almost surely under thehistorical and minimal entropy measures. Since these measures are equivalent, weskip any measure-specific notation.

Proposition 4.4 The following statements hold:(i) The indifference price is a non-decreasing function of the claim’s payoff,

namely,if C1

T ≤ C2T then νBt

(C1T ;T

)≤ νBt

(C2T ;T

). (4.149)

In addition, for α ∈ (0, 1) and C ≥ 0,

νBt(αC1

T + (1− α)C2T ;T

)≥ ανBt

(C1T ;T

)+ (1− α)νBt

(C2T ;T

), (4.150)

(ii) Let ti, i = 0, 1, .., n with t = t0 ≤ t1 ≤ ... ≤ tn = T . Then, for C ≥ 0,the indifference price satisfies

νBt (αCT ;T ) ≥ αnνBt (CT ;T ) for α ∈ (0, 1) (4.151)

andνBt (αCT ;T ) ≤ αnνBt (CT ;T ) for α ≥ 1. (4.152)

Proof. Monotonicity (4.149) follows directly from elementary backward inductionarguments and monotonicity of the single-period functionals E t,t+1

Qme (·) To establish

56

Page 68: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

(4.150), we show it first for t = T − 1. Applying Holder’s inequality to obtain

−EQme(

1γ lnEQme

(e−γ(αC

1T

+(1−α)C2T ) |ST

))=

≥ −EQme

(1γ ln

((EQme

(e−γC

1T |ST

))α (EQme

(e−γC

2T |ST

))1−α))

= −αEQme(

1γ lnEQme

(e−γC

1T |ST

))− (1− α)EQme

(1γ lnEQme

(e−γC

2T |ST

)).

(4.153)

To show (4.150) for t < T−1, we use induction and (4.117). Inequalities (4.151) and(4.152) follow using induction, the appropriate single-period arguments and (4.117).

So far we have presented the indifference valuation algorithms for both thebackward and forward prices. The forward indifference valuation involves the min-imal martingale measure Qmm and the nonlinear pricing functionals E t,t+1

Qmm (·). Thebackward indifference valuation shares some of the forward valuation features. Bothof the algorithms are recursive, proceed backwards in time, and structurally are writ-ten in terms of the same nonlinear pricing functionals E t,t+1

Q (·). However, there aresome differences. Theorem 22 states that the backward valuation uses the mini-mal entropy measure Qme, and not the Qmm. The valuation with backward utilitycould be done using the minimal martingale measure Qmm (see Theorem 21), butwould then use the nonlinear functionals Pt,t+1

Q (·) (defined in equation (4.91)) whosestructure is different from E t,t+1

Q (·) (defined in Chapter 2 equation (2.9)). Thenonlinear functionals E t,t+1

Q (·) do not carry any dependence on either the forwardnormalization time point s, or the backward normalization point T , and neitherdoes the minimal martingale measure Qmm. The minimal entropy measure Qme

does depend on the backward normalization point T , which also represents the endof the investment horizon. The minimal entropy measure transfers its T -dependenceonto the backward indifference prices it generates. Dependence on the end of theinvestment horizon T is another important difference between the backward andforward prices.

57

Page 69: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

4.3 The forward and the backward dynamic valuation

in the reduced model

In this section we address two important issues. First, we provide conditions underwhich the two dynamic utilities yield identical indifference prices. Clearly, they doso when the market is complete, but this is not the only case. Second, we addressthe reduced model properties of the forward and backward prices with respect tohedgeable risks.

The concept of a reduced model was introduced in chapter 3. In such a modelthe historical distribution of the next period’s traded asset value does not dependof the path of the non-traded risk factor Y up to the current time t, and neitherdo the variables ξut+1 and ξdt+1, for all 0 ≤ t ≤ T − 1. We have shown in corollary10 of chapter 3 that in a reduced model, the minimal martingale measure and theminimal entropy measure are the same. A natural consequence of that corollary isthat, in the reduced model, the backward and forward indifference prices are thesame as well.

Theorem 23 In the reduced binomial model, i.e. when

P(ξt+1/Ft) = P(ξt+1/FSt ), t = 0, 1, ..., T − 1. (4.154)

and ξut+1, ξdt+1 are FSt -measurable, the forward and backward indifference prices ofthe European contract C written at t0 and maturing at T , coincide:

νFt (CT ) = νBt (CT ;T ) (4.155)

for t0 ≤ t ≤ T ≤ T .

The proof of the above result follows easily from corollary 10 of Chapter 3, thealgorithms are derived for the forward and the backward prices (Theorems 14 and21, correspondingly).

The next result assumes the reduced model and considers the payoff depend-ing on the traded asset only. In this case both the backward and forward pricescoincide with the complete market price. The proof uses FS

T-measurability of the

payoff, the independence of ξut+1 and ξdt+1 of the stochastic factor Y , and followseasily from the valuation algorithms of Theorems 21 and 14.

58

Page 70: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Proposition 4.5 Under the reduced model assumption of corollary 10, Chapter 3(also shown in Theorem 23 above), if the payoff C(ST , YT ) does not depend on YT ,then

νFt (CT ) = νBt (CT ;T ) = EQ(C(ST )/FSt ), (4.156)

for any martingale measure Q equivalent to P and any t0 ≤ t ≤ T .

One example of a reduced form model would be when ξu+1t and ξdt+1 are

constants and the property (4.154) holds. The above assumptions are the ones usedby [41], and are very common in the literature.

59

Page 71: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 5

Dynamic indifference valuation

of American contracts in the

discrete model.

5.1 Dynamic indifference valuation with the forward

utility.

In this section we show how liabilities with early exercise can be valued in thediscrete time framework using the forward dynamic utility. We formulate the corre-sponding value functions for the agent as stochastic control problems incorporatingboth the agent’s investment policy and the exercise time of the claim. We defineand derive closed-form formulas for the indifference price. We investigate propertiesof the indifference price with respect to risk aversion, in particular its monotonicityand limiting values as risk aversion becomes infinitely small or infinitely large. Weprovide a characterization of the optimal exercise time and the optimal hedgingpolicy, and derive a new representation for the early exercise indifference price. Thenew representation relates the price of the American contract to prices of Europeanclaims of maturities within the allowed exercise horizon. We extend the algorithmto partial exercise in subsequent chapters. We remind the reader that the name”forward” is not being used in the traditional way of referring to wealth being ex-pressed in forward units. Herein, the name ”forward” refers to the way the dynamic

60

Page 72: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

utility propagates, from initial point s, at which it is fixed, forward in time.Let t be the current valuation time, α = (αt+1, ..., αT ) be a trading strategy

and τ be a stopping time (to exercise the claim) chosen by the investor. Here weconsider the early exercise only on a finite horizon and thus we require t ≤ τ ≤ T

a.s. We also require that the claim be exercised at T if it has not been exercisedbefore that time. The early exercise liability yields intrinsic payoff Cτ , if exercised attime τ . The total wealth of the investor time τ combines proceeds Xτ accumulatedthrough trading with the payoff upon exercise Cτ . At time τ the agent measureshis total wealth through the forward dynamic utility UF (Xτ +Cτ , τ ; s), normalizedat s, s ≤ t. Investor’s time t value function is defined accordingly:

Definition 5.1 The time t value function of the buyer of the American claim C,written at t0 and maturing at ¯T , is defined as the expected utility of his total wealthupon exercise, optimized through the choice of the trading strategy α and of thestopping time τ . Namely,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) = supαt+1,...,αT

supt≤τ≤T

EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft]. (5.1)

Given the notion of the buyer’s value function, we define the indifference price as:

Definition 5.2 Let s be the forward normalization point. The buyer’s indifferenceprice of the American claim C, written at t0 and maturing at ¯T , is the amountat(C; s) to be payed for the claim, which makes the value functions V C equal to UF .Namely, at(C; s) is the amount satisfying:

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) = UFt (Xt + at(C; s); s). (5.2)

The two definitions above, in analogy with the way we defined the indifference pricefor European contracts, can easily be combined into just one pricing condition:

UFt (Xt + at(C; s); s) = supαt+1,...,αT

supt≤τ≤T

EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft]. (5.3)

This way, the concept of value function will no longer be needed anymore, as is thecase with European claims. For convenience, we choose to keep the definition of thevalue function for convenience, so that the relevant results regarding the righthandside of (5.3) can be formulated more simply.

61

Page 73: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We are aiming at constructing the recursive algorithm that would relate thetime t indifference price to the one of time t+ 1. Indifference prices are obtained bystudying the corresponding value functions. Thus, one should proceed by relatingthe buyer’s value function of time t to that one of time t + 1. In the discrete timemodel, the claim can either be exercised immediately, or the investor will have towait till the next period to be able to exercise the claim. Using this observation wearrive at a simplified expression for the value function.

Theorem 24 If the optimal τ?u and α?u+1, ..., α?T

solving 5.1 exists for all t ≤ u ≤ T ,then V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) has the following recursive representation:

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) =

maxUFt (Xt + Ct; s), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft],

V C(XT , ST , YT , T ; s) = UFT

(XT + CT ; s).

(5.4)

Proof. If optimizers τ?u and α? exist for all t ≤ u ≤ T ,

V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s) = EP[UFτ?t+1(Xτ?t+1

+ Cτ?t+1; s)/Ft+1]. (5.5)

τ?t+1 and α?t+2, ..., α?T

may not be optimal solutions of (5.1) at time t, implying forany choice of αt+1 that V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) ≥ EP[UFτ?t+1

(Xτ?t+1+ Cτ?t+1

; s)/Ft], for

Xτ?t+1= Xt +αt+1(St+1 − St) +

τ?t+1∑u=t+2

α?u(Su − Su−1). Conditioning on Ft+1, we get

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) ≥ EP[EP[UFτ?t+1(Xτ?t+1

+ Cτ?t+1; s)/Ft+1]/Ft] =

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft],(5.6)

for Xt+1 = Xt + αt+1(St+1 − St). Since αt+1 is arbitrary,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) ≥ supαt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft]. (5.7)

Clearly, V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) ≥ UFt (Xt + Ct; s) and thus V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) is at least

62

Page 74: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

as big as the righthand side of (5.4). On the other hand, for any τ and α,

EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft] =1τ=tU

Ft (Xt + Ct; s) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft] =

1τ=tUFt (Xt + Ct; s) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft+1]/Ft] ≤

1τ=tUFt (Xt + Ct; s) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft] ≤

1τ=tUFt (Xt + Ct; s) + (1− 1τ=t) sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft] ≤

1τ=tmaxUFt (Xt + Ct; s), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft]

+

(1− 1τ=t) maxUFt (Xt + Ct; s), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft]

=

maxUFt (Xt + Ct; s), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft]

(5.8)

To characterize the buyer’s indifference price of the American claim C, weintroduce another family of operators At,uQ (Z) for t ≤ u ≤ T . We let Z be an Fu -measurable random variable and Q be a martingale measure equivalent to P. DefineAt,uQ (Z) as

At,uQ (Z) = At,u−1Q

(Au−1,uQ (Z)

),

At,tQ (Z) = Z,(5.9)

whereAu−1,uQ (Z) = max

Cu−1, Eu−1,u

Q (Z). (5.10)

with Eu−1,uQ (Z) defined earlier in equation (2.9) of chapter 2.The theorem below presents the multi-period pricing algorithm, the main

result of this section.

Theorem 25 Let Qmm be a martingale measure equivalent to P satisfying, for t =0, 1, ..., T ,

Qmm(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

)= P

(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

). (5.11)

(i) The indifference price at (C; s) as in definition (5.2) satisfiesat (C; s) = max

Ct, E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1 (C; s)), t < T

aT (C; s) = CT ,(5.12)

63

Page 75: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

with E t,t+1Qmm defined in equation (2.9) of chapter 2 for Q = Qmm.

(ii) The indifference price process is given by

at (C) = At,TQmm (CT ) , (5.13)

with At,TQmm defined in equations (5.9)-(5.10) for Q = Qmm.(iii) The pricing algorithm is consistent across time, in that, for 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T , thesemi-group property

at (C; s) = At,uQmm(Au,TQmm (CT )

)= At,uQmm (au (C; s)) = at

(Au,TQmm (CT ) ; s

)(5.14)

holds.

Formula (5.12) has an intuitive interpretation: Ct equals the amount the buyer gainsif he exercises the claim immediately; E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1 (C; s)) represents the amount thebuyer gains if he continues to hold the claim till the next possible exercise time.at (C; s) is then the maximum of the two available alternatives. Formula (5.12)inherits the remarkable nested structure of the discrete time complete market no-arbitrage prices, rolling backwards from the terminal time T to the current timet. As in the complete market case, the price is the maximum of two values, oneof which is the intrinsic value of the option, the other the value of the alternative”to continue”. However, in our pricing scheme market incompleteness shows itselfin a number of ways. One is in the choice of the pricing measure, which is differentfrom the complete market case. The measure Qmm used throughout is the minimalmartingale measure, the same measure used in indifference pricing of Europeanclaims with forward preferences. Another consequence of market incompletenessis that the value of the alternative ”to continue” is now characterized using the(nonlinear) one-period European buyer’s indifference functionals, and not the risk-neutral expectations. Also, the prices depend on the level of the absolute riskaversion. Operators At,t+1

Qmm are in general nonlinear but, as will be shown, thenonlinearities go away if the two risky stocks are ”perfectly correlated” or in thelimiting case where risk aversion approaches zero.

Although the forward dynamic utility process depends on the normalizationpoint, this dependency does not appear anywhere in the formula (5.9) for the non-linear indifference pricing operator At,uQme(·). The normalization point s does not

64

Page 76: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

affect the measure Qmm in any way, as discussed in section 4.1. Under the forwarddynamic utility, the indifference prices do not depend on the normalization points either. For early exercise contracts, the prices depend on the expiration date ofthe contract, but unlike with the backward dynamic utility, the expiration date ofthe contract does not need to be bounded in time by any artificially chosen ”end ofinvestment horizon”.Proof. (i) At time T − 1,

V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1; s) =

max

UFT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1; s), supαT

E[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ; s)/FT−1

]=

max

UFT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1; s), supαT

E[UFT

(XT + CT ; s)/FT−1

].

(5.15)

supαT

E[UFT

(XT + CT ; s)/FT−1

]can be viewed as time T − 1 value function of an

investor with forward preferences holding a claim CT expiring at T . Consideringthe results already obtained for European claims,

supαT

E[UFT

(XT + CT ; s)/FT−1

]= UF

T(XT + E T−1,T

Qmm (CT ) ; s), (5.16)

and

V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1; s) =

maxUFT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1; s), UFT

(XT − ET−1,TQmm (CT ) ; s)

=

UFT−1

(XT−1 + max

CT−1, E

T−1,TQmm (CT )

; s),

(5.17)

implying the corresponding relation for the indifference price.Following a typical induction argument, assume that the formula holds for timest + 1 through T . Now one needs to prove that the formula also holds at time t.

65

Page 77: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

From definition 5.2 of the indifference price,

supαt+1

E[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1; s)/Ft

]=

supαt+1

E[UF (Xt+1 + at+1(C; s), t+ 1; s)/Ft

]=

supαt+1

E

[− exp

(−γ(Xt+1 + at+1(C; s)) +

t+1∑k=s+1

hk

)/Ft

]=

exp

(t∑

k=s+1

hk

)supαt+1

E [− exp(−γ(Xt+1 + at+1(C; s)) + ht+1)/Ft] ,

(5.18)

sincet∑

k=s+1

hk is Ft-measurable. The last expression can be viewed as the time t

one-period value function of an investor with forward utility function who holdsEuropean claim paying amount at+1(C; s) at time t + 1. Based on the obtainedresults for the European claims in section 4.1 theorem 14,

exp

(t+1∑

k=s+1

hk

)supαt+1

E [− exp (−γ(Xt+1 + at+1(C; s))) /Ft] =

exp

(t+1∑

k=s+1

hk

)(− exp

(−γ(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s)))− ht+1

))=

− exp

(−γ(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s)))

+t∑

k=s+1

hk

)=

UFt

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s)) ; s).

(5.19)

Therefore, using formula (5.4) for the buyer’s value function,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) = maxUFt (Xt + Ct; s), UFt

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s)) ; s)

=

UFt

(Xt + max

Ct, E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s))

; s).

(5.20)From the definition of the buyer’s indifference price and the calculation above,

at (C; s) = maxCt, E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1 (C; s)), (5.21)

and the proof of Part (i) is complete.Parts (ii) and (iii) of theorem 25 follow from (i) together with the definition of theoperators At,uQmm introduced above in equations (5.9) and (5.10)

66

Page 78: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We further consider properties of the buyer’s indifference price. The nexttheorem (theorem 26) shows how the price is affected by changes in the absoluterisk aversion. Part (i) of the theorem shows that a more risk averse buyer assignsa smaller value to the claim bearing unhedgeable risk. In the next theorem we usea slightly different notation at (C ; γ) and E t,t+1

Qmm (Zt+1 ; γ). The ”extra argument” γspecifies a particular level of risk aversion to which the indifference price corresponds.Part (ii) of the theorem characterizes asymptotic behavior as γ → 0. Also, itprovides an upper bound for at (C ; γ) for all values of γ, obtained as the indifferenceprice for a buyer with infinitesimally small risk aversion. The limiting value showssignificant structural similarity to the no-arbitrage price of the American claim ina complete market. However it uses a different measure Qmm, and not the classicalrisk-neutral measure. The result of Part (ii) is consistent with familiar asymptoticresults for European derivatives in discrete and continuous time. Part (iii) describesasymptotic behavior of the price as γ →∞ and provides a lower bound for at(C; γ)in the form of the buyer’s indifference price for an agent with infinitely large riskaversion.

Theorem 26 (Monotonicity and asymptotic bounds) (i) For γ1 ≥ γ2

at (C; γ1) ≤ at (C; γ2) , t ≤ T a.s. (5.22)

(ii) Define the sequence of Ft-measurable random variables ν0t (C) as

ν0T (C) = CT ,

ν0t (C) = max

Ct, EQmm

[ν0t+1(C)/Ft

], t < T .

(5.23)

Then for any t ≤ T ,at (C; γ) ν0

t (C) , as γ → 0. (5.24)

(iii) Define the sequence of Ft-measurable random variables νinft (C) as νinfT (C) = CT ,

νinft (C) = maxCt, EQmm [min

Yt+1

νinft+1/Ft], t < T .

(5.25)

Thenat(C; γ) νinft (C), as γ →∞. (5.26)

67

Page 79: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

In (5.25), the expectation can be taken under any equivalent to P martingale measureQ.

Proof. (i) For t = T , aT (C; γ1) = aT (C; γ2) = CT and inequality (5.22) holds.For t < T , one only needs to show that for every Ft+1-measurable random variableZt+1,

E t,t+1Qmm (Zt+1; γ1) ≤ E t,t+1

Qmm (Zt+1; γ2) . (5.27)

Let γ = −γ,

E t,t+1Qmm (Zt+1; γ) = EQmm

[ln(EQmm

[(eZt+1

)γ/Ft ∨ FSt+1

]) 1γ/Ft]

=

EQmm

[ln(EQmm

[(Ht+1)γ /Ft ∨ FSt+1

]) 1γ/Ft] (5.28)

where Ht+1 = eZt+1 > 0. Due to monotonicity of conditional expectation andlogarithmic function it only remains to show that for γ1 ≤ γ2 < 0

EQmm[(Ht+1)γ1 /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ1 ≤ EQmm

[(Ht+1)γ2 /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ2 (5.29)

With Hγ1t+1 = Gt+1 and 0 < γ = γ2

γ1≤ 1 inequality (5.29) can be rewritten (note

that the sign of the new inequality is different because 1γ1

is negative):

EQmm[Gt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

]≥ EQmm

[(Gt+1)γ /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ (5.30)

The last inequality follows from concavity of the function xγ for x > 0, 0 < γ ≤ 1,and the Jensen’s inequality.(ii) We first show that the formula holds for time T − 1. For any t ≤ T , includingt = T − 1, E t,t+1

Qmm (CT ) could be written explicitly as

68

Page 80: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

E t,t+1Qmm (at+1) = −

Qmm(At+1/Ft)γ log

(Qmm(At+1Bt+1/Ft)

Qmm(At+1/Ft)e−γa

uu+

Qmm(At+1Bct+1/Ft)

Qmm(At+1/Ft)e−γa

udt+1

)−

Qmm(Act+1/Ft)γ log

(Qmm(Act+1Bt+1/Ft)

Qmm(Act+1/Ft)e−γa

dut+1 +

Qmm(Act+1Bct+1/Ft)

Qmm(Act+1/Ft)e−γa

ddt+1

),

(5.31)with

Qmm(At+1/Ft) = Qmm(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft

),

Qmm(Act+1/Ft) = Qmm(St+1 = Sdt+1/Ft

),

Qmm(At+1Bt+1/Ft) = Qmm(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

Qmm(Act+1Bt+1/Ft) = Qmm(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

Qmm(At+1Bct+1/Ft) = Qmm

(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

Qmm(Act+1Bct+1/Ft) = Qmm

(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

(5.32)

with auu, audt+1, adut+1 and addt+1 denoting the four possible values of at+1(C; s), asviewed form time t. For t = T − 1,

aijt+1 = Cij = C(SiT, Y j

T), for i, j = ’u’ and ’d’ . (5.33)

Using L’Hopital’s rule and equation (5.31), the limit of E T−1,TQmm (CT ) as γ → 0 is

Qmm(AT /FT−1)(

Qmm(ATBT /FT−1)Qmm(AT /FT−1) Cuu +

Qmm(ATBcT /FT−1)

Qmm(AT /FT−1) Cud)

+Qmm(AcT/FT−1)

(Qmm(AcTBT /FT−1)

Qmm(AcT /FT−1) Cdu +Qmm(AcTB

cT /FT−1)

Qmm(AcT /FT−1) Cdd)

= EQmm[CT /FT−1

].

(5.34)

The calculation above shows that E T−1,TQmm (CT ) converges to EQmm

[CT /FT−1

]. Con-

sequently, since CT−1 is independent of γ,

aT−1(C; γ)→ maxCT−1, EQmm[CT /FT−1

],

69

Page 81: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

as γ → 0.To confirm the formula for t ≤ T − 2, one would proceed by induction and

assume that the limit of au(C; γ) as γ → 0 equals ν0u(C) for all u ≥ t+1. at(C; γ) is

the maximum of Ct and E t,t+1Qmm (at+1(C; γ)). The latter has an explicit representation

of equation (5.31). Since, by induction assumption, at+1(C; γ) converges to ν0t+1(C)

as γ → 0, applying the same argument as before yields:

limγ→0E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; γ)) =

Qmm(At+1/Ft)(

Qmm(At+1Bt+1/Ft)Qmm(At+1/Ft)

auut+1 +Qmm(At+1B

ct+1/Ft)

Qmm(At+1/Ft)audt+1

)+

Qmm(Act+1/Ft)(

Qmm(Act+1Bt+1/Ft)Qmm(Act+1/Ft)

adut+1 +Qmm(Act+1B

ct+1/Ft)

Qmm(Act+1/Ft)addt+1

)=

EQmm[ν0t+1(C)/Ft

].

(5.35)Thus at(C; γ) converges to maxCt, EQmm [ν0

t+1(C)/Ft].(iii) As before we show that formula for t = T − 1. For other values of t ≤ T − 2one can use induction and repeat the argument. The limit of E T−1,T

Qmm (CT ) as γ →∞is given by

limγ→∞

[ −Qmm(AT /FT−1)·

CuuQmm(ATBT /FT−1)e−γCuu

+ CudQmm(ATBcT /FT−1)e−γC

ud

Qmm(ATBT /FT−1)e−γCuu

+ Qmm(ATBcT /FT−1)e−γC

ud −

Qmm(AcT/FT−1)

CduQmm(AcTBT /FT−1)e−γCdu

+ CddQmm(AcTBcT /FT−1)e−γC

dd

Qmm(AcTBT /FT−1)e−γCdu

+ Qmm(AcTBcT /FT−1)e−γC

dd ]

= Qmm(AT /FT−1) minCuu, Cud+ Qmm(AcT/FT−1) minCdu, Cdd

= EQmm [minYT

CT /FT−1].

(5.36)In fact, Q(AT /FT−1) is the same among all martingale measures Q equivalent

70

Page 82: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

to P. Therefore, the expectation in (5.25) could be taken under any equivalentmartingale measure Q

The theorem above shows that asymptotically as γ → 0 and γ → ∞ therecursive structure of the indifference price is preserved. To evaluate the benefits ofcontinuing to hold the claim, an investor with an infinitesimally small risk aversionwould price the next date’s indifference value using expectation under the minimalmartingale measure, while a very risk averse buyer would use the ”lower hedgingprice” for European claims. Both investors will exercise if the value of ”alternativeto continue” falls below the payoff from immediate exercise Ct.

The next theorem provides another condition under which the indifferenceprice with forward utility at(C; s) accumulates by taking expectations under theminimal martingale measure, that is the nonlinearity in At,uQmm goes away.

Theorem 27 (Perfect correlation result) If the historical measure P is suchthat, for all t ≤ T ,

P(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

),∈ 0, 1, (5.37)

then the forward indifference price at(C; s) coincides with ν0t (C) defined by equation

(5.23) above.

Proof. Under condition (5.37) Qmm(Yt/Ft−1 ∨ FSt ) ∈ 0, 1. Writing the expres-sion for the indifference price explicitly as in (5.31), one could see that equation(5.31) for E t,t+1

Qmm (at+1(C; s)) simplifies to EQmm [at+1(C; s)/Ft], and the statement ofthe theorem follows

Condition (5.37) indicates that given all the information up to time t and aparticular time t+ 1 realization of St+1, the value of Yt+1 is known for sure and wecan say the movements of stock S and risk-factor Y are ”perfectly correlated”. Inthat case there is only one (defined on Ft) martingale measure equivalent to P, thenonlinearity in at(C; s) goes away, and at(C; s) becomes the same as ν0

t (C).The next result defines an early exercise time that later will be shown to be

the optimal exercise time. It is an intermediate result that provide an additionalcharacterization for the indifference price used in other theorems.

Proposition 5.1 Let at(C; s) be defined as in equation (5.12). Define a stoppingtime τ?t as

τ?t = inft≤u≤T

u : au(C; s) = Cu. (5.38)

71

Page 83: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

at(C; s) = supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQmm(aτ (C)) = E t,TQmm(aτ?t (C)). (5.39)

Proof. Since the operators E t,t+1Qmm (·) are monotone, for any u ≥ t,

at(C; s) ≥ E t,t+1Qmm (at+1(C; s)) ≥ E t,uQmm(au(C; s)) = E t,TQmm(au(C; s)). (5.40)

Thus, for any stopping time t ≤ τ ≤ T , at(C; s) ≥ E t,T (aτ (C; s)). Also the processau∧τ?t (C; s), t ≤ u ≤ T satisfies

Eu,u+1Qmm (au+1∧τ?t (C; s)) = au∧τ?t (C; s). (5.41)

Indeed, if τ?t < u + 1 then au+1∧τ?t (C; s) = aτ?t (C; s) is Fu-measurable and theleft-hand side of (5.41) equals aτ?t (C; s). If τ?t ≥ u + 1 then the righthand side of(5.41) becomes Eu,u+1

Qmm (au+1(C; s)), which is equal to au(C; s) by definition of τ?t(see equation (5.38)). Repeated application of (5.41) for s = t, t + 1, ..., T yieldsat(C; s) = E t,T (aT∧τ?t (C; s)) = E t,TQmm(aτ?t (C; s))

The next result provides an alternative characterization of the indifferenceprice. It is consistent with the Snell envelope representation in complete market. Inaddition, it confirms that the indifference price at(C; s) is greater than any of theprices E t,sQmm(Cu), t ≤ u ≤ T , of corresponding European claims.

Theorem 28 Define a sequence of Ft-measurable variables νt as follows:

νt = supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQmm(Cτ ). (5.42)

The indifference price process at(C; s) and the process νt coincide.

Proof. For any stopping time τ , aτ (C) ≥ Cτ . The operators E t,t+1Qmm (·) are mono-

tone and Proposition 5.1 yields at(C; s) ≥ E t,TQmm(aτ (C)) ≥ E t,TQmm(Cτ ). On the

other hand, aτ?t (C; s) = Cτ?t . Therefore, at(C; s) = E t,TQmm(aτ?t (C)) = E t,TQmm(Cτ?) =

supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQmm(Cτ )

Theorem 29 (Optimal stopping time) Optimal stopping time defined in equa-tion (5.38) and αt+1, ...αT shown in equation (5.45) are a solution of stochastic

72

Page 84: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

optimization problem (5.1), that is

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t; s) = EP[UFτ?t(Xτ?t

+ Cτ?t , τ?t

); s)/Ft], (5.43)

with

Xτ?t=

τ?t∑u=t

(Su+1 − Su)α?u+1, (5.44)

α?t = 1γSt−1(ξu − ξd)

log(

(ξu − 1)P(At/Ft−1)(1− ξd)P(Act/Ft−1)

)+ 1γSt−1(ξu − ξd)

·

log

((eγ−a

uut+1P(At, Bt/Ft−1) + eγ−a

udt+1P(At, Bc

t /Ft−1))P(Act/Ft−1)(eγ−a

dut+1P(Act , Bt/Ft−1) + eγ−a

ddt+1P(Act , B

ct /Ft−1))P(At/Ft−1)

),

(5.45)

P(At+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft

),

P(Act+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sdt+1/Ft

),

P(At+1Bt+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

P(Act+1Bt+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

P(At+1Bct+1/Ft) = P

(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

P(Act+1Bct+1/Ft) = P

(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

(5.46)

and auut+1, audt+1, adut+1 and addt+1 denoting the four possible values of at+1(C; s), asviewed from time t.Proof. We first check the result for t = T − 1.

EP[UFT−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

; s)/FT−1] =

EP[1τ?T−1

=T−1UFτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

; s)+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)UFτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

; s)/FT−1] =

1τ?T−1

=T−1UFT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1; s)+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[UFT

(XT + CT ; s)/FT−1] =

1τ?T−1

=T−1UFT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1; s)+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ; s)/FT−1].

(5.47)

73

Page 85: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

By definition of τ?T−1

,

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ; s)/FT−1] =

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)VC(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1; s)

(5.48)

for α?T

defined as in (5.45). Therefore

EP[UFτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

; s)/FT−1] =

V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1; s).(5.49)

Now assume that (5.43) holds for t = u+ 1, ...T . To show that (5.43) also holds fort = u, write

EP[UFτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)/Fu] = EP[1τ?u=uUFτ?u

(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)+(1− 1τ?u=u)UFτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)/Fu] = 1τ?u=uU

Fu (Xu + Cu; s)+

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[UFτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)/Fu].

(5.50)

For w : τ?u(w) > u, τ?u = τ?u+1 and

EP[UFτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)/Fu] = 1τ?u=uVC(Xu, Su, Yu, u; s)+

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[UF (Xτ?u+1+ Cτ?u+1

, τ?u+1, u+ 1; s)/Fu] =

1τ?u=uVC(Xu, Su, Yu, u; s) + (1− 1τ?u=u)EP[V C(Xu+1, u+ 1, u+ 1; s)/Fu]

(5.51)by induction assumption. By definition of τ?u,

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[V C(Xu+1, Su+1, Yu+1, u+ 1, u+ 1; s)/Fu] =(1− 1τ?u=u)V C(Xu, Su, Yu, u; s)

(5.52)

for α?u+1 defined as in (5.45).Therefore, EP[UFτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ; s)/Fu] = V C(Xu, Su, Yu, u; s)

5.2 Dynamic indifference valuation with the backward

utility.

In this section we show how liabilities with early exercise CAN be valued in the dis-crete indifference framework using the backward dynamic utility. While the forward

74

Page 86: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

dynamic utility introduced in the previous section is a new concept, the backwarddynamic utility is closer to the classical static exponential utility. In fact, the back-ward utility is the unique self-generating dynamic extension of the classical staticexponential utility. We have already presented the valuation for forward and back-ward utilities for European claims. The forward valuation approach has a numberof advantages, such as independence of the investment horizon and simpler char-acterization of the measure, but the backward utility approach possesses all othernatural properties of the forward one.

We formulate the corresponding value functions for the agent as stochasticcontrol problems incorporating both the agent’s investment policy and the exercisetime of the claim. We define and derive closed form formulas for the indifferenceprice. We investigate properties of the indifference price with respect to risk aversion,in particular its monotonicity and limiting values as risk aversion becomes infinitelysmall or infinitely large. We provide a characterization of optimal exercise timeand optimal hedging policy, and derive a new representation for the early exerciseindifference price that relates it to the indifference prices of European claims ofmaturities within the allowed exercise horizon. We comment on how the resultsfor the backward dynamic utility compare to tse for the forward utility. Numericalexamples for both forward and backward utilities are provided in chapter 8. In thischapter we discuss valuation exclusively from the buyer’s perspective, and all thenonlinear operators and functions used to characterize the indifference price refer tothe buyer’s point of view.

Let t be the current valuation time, α = (αt+1, ..., αT ) be a trading strategyand τ be a stopping time (to exercise the claim) chosen by the investor. Here weonly consider early exercise on a finite horizon and thus we require t ≤ τ ≤ T a.s.We also require that the claim in exercised at T if it has not been exercise beforethat time. The early exercise liability yields intrinsic payoff Cτ if exercised at timeτ . The total wealth at time τ of the investor combines proceeds Xτ accumulatedthrough trading with the payoff upon exercise Cτ . At time τ , the agent measureshis total wealth through the backward utility function UBτ (Xτ +Cτ ;T ), normalizedat T , t ≤ T . The backward utility process UBt is the same one used in [39] forEuropean contracts. Investor’s time t value function is defined accordingly:

Definition 5.3 Let T be the backward normalization point. The time t value func-tion of the buyer of the American claim C, written at t0 and expiring at T , is defined

75

Page 87: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

as the expected utility of his total wealth upon exercise, optimized through the choiceof a trading strategy α and of a stopping time τ . Namely,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) = supαt+1,...,αT

supt≤τ≤T

EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft]. (5.53)

Given the notion of the buyer’s value function, we define the indifference price as:

Definition 5.4 The buyer’s indifference price of the American claim C, writtenat t0 and expiring at T ≤ T , is the amount at(C;T ), to be payed for the claim,which makes the value function V C equal to UB. Namely, at(C;T ) is the amountsatisfying:

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) = UBt (Xt + at(C;T ), T ). (5.54)

We aim to constructing the recursive algorithm that would relate the time t indif-ference price to the one of time t + 1. Indifference prices are obtained by studyingthe corresponding value functions. Thus, one should proceed by relating the time tbuyer’s value function to that of time t+1. In the discrete time model, the claim caneither be exercised immediately, or the investor will have to wait till the next periodto be able to exercise the claim. Using this observation we arrive at a simplifiedexpression for the value function.

Theorem 30 If the optimal τ?u and α?u+1, ..., α?T

solving stochastic control problem(5.53) exist for all t ≤ u ≤ T , then V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) has the following recursiverepresentation:

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) =

maxUBt (Xt + Ct;T ), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft],

V C(XT , ST , YT , T ;T ) = UBT

(XT + CT ;T ).

(5.55)

Proof. If optimizers τ?u and α? exist for all t ≤ u ≤ T , then

V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T ) = EP[UBτ?t+1(Xτ?t+1

+ Cτ?t+1;T )/Ft+1]. (5.56)

τ?t+1 and α?t+2, ..., α?T

may not be optimal solutions of (5.53) at time t, implyingfor any choice of αt+1 that V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) ≥ EP[UBτ?t+1

(Xτ?t+1+Cτ?t+1

;T )/Ft] for

76

Page 88: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Xτ?t+1= Xt +αt+1(St+1 − St) +

τ?t+1∑u=t+2

α?u(Su − Su−1). Conditioning on Ft+1, we get

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) ≥ EP[EP[UBτ?t+1(Xτ?t+1

+ Cτ?t+1;T )/Ft+1]/Ft] =

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft],(5.57)

for Xt+1 = Xt + αt+1(St+1 − St). Since αt+1 is arbitrary,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) ≥ supαt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft]. (5.58)

Defintion 5.3 clearly implies V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) ≥ UBt (Xt +Ct;T ). Taking this intoaccount together with (5.58), we conclude V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) is at least as big asthe righthand side of (5.55). On the other hand, for any τ and α,

EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft] =1τ=tU

Bt (Xt + Ct;T ) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft] =

1τ=tUBt (Xt + Ct;T ) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft+1]/Ft] ≤

1τ=tUBt (Xt + Ct;T ) + (1− 1τ=t)EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft] ≤

1τ=tUBt (Xt + Ct;T ) + (1− 1τ=t) sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft] ≤

1τ=tmaxUBt (Xt + Ct;T ), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft]

+

(1− 1τ=t) maxUBt (Xt + Ct;T ), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft]

=

maxUBt (Xt + Ct;T ), sup

αt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft]

(5.59)To characterize the buyer’s indifference price of the American claim C, we use a

family of operators At,uQ (Z) for t ≤ u ≤ T . We let Z be an Fu - measurable randomvariable and Q be a martingale measure equivalent to P. We define At,uQ (Z) as

At,uQ (Z) = At,u−1

Q

(Au−1,uQ (Z)

),

At,tQ (Z) = Z,(5.60)

whereAu−1,uQ (Z) = max

Cu−1, Eu−1,u

Q (Z). (5.61)

77

Page 89: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

with Eu−1,uQ (Z) is the one-period European buyer’s operator, defined in chapter

2 equation (2.9). The structural form of nonlinear operators defined above is thesame we used for the forward indifference price in equation (5.9). The theorem belowindicates the measure that should be used in connection with the above operators tovalue American contracts. The theorem below is the multi-period pricing algorithm,the main result of this section.

Theorem 31 Let Qme be the minimal entropy martingale measure, defined in chap-ter 3.(i) The indifference price at (C;T ) as in definition (5.4) satisfies

at (C;T ) = maxCt, E t,t+1

Qme (at+1 (C;T )), t < T

aT (C;T ) = CT ,(5.62)

with E t,t+1Qme defined in equation (2.9) of chapter 2 for Q = Qme.

(ii) The indifference price process is given by

at (C;T ) = At,TQme (CT ) , (5.63)

with At,uQme defined in equations (5.60)-(5.61) for Q = Qme and t ≤ u ≤ T .(iii) The pricing algorithm is consistent across time, in that, for 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T , thesemi-group property

at (C;T ) = At,uQme(Au,TQme (CT )

)= At,uQme (au (C;T )) = at

(Au,TQme (CT ) ;T

)(5.64)

holds.

Formula (5.62) has an intuitive interpretation: Ct equals the amount the buyer gainsif he exercises the claim immediately; E t,t+1

Qme (at+1 (C;T )) represents the amountthe buyer gains if he continues to hold the claim till the next possible exercisetime. at (C;T ) is then the maximum of the two available alternatives. Formula(5.62) inherits the nested structure of the discrete time complete market no-arbitrageprices, rolling backwards from the terminal time T to the current time t. As in thecomplete market case, the price is the maximum of two values, one of which isthe intrinsic value of the option, and the other is the value of the alternative ”tocontinue”.

78

Page 90: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Although it is similar in the structural form to the complete market price,our pricing scheme reflects market incompleteness in a number of ways. One is inthe choice of the pricing measure, which differs from the complete market case. Themeasure Qme used throughout is the minimal entropy martingale measure, the samemeasure as used in indifference pricing of European claims with backward prefer-ences. Another consequence of market incompleteness is that the value of alternative”to continue” is now characterized using the nonlinear one-period European buyer’sindifference prices, and not the risk-neutral expectations. The nonlinearity entersthough the level of the absolute risk aversion. As we see further, the nonlinearitygoes away in the limiting cases of risk aversion approaching zero, or in the case of”perfect correlation” discussed below.

Remarkably, the backward early exercise price only differs from the forwardearly exercise price in the choice of the pricing measure (the minimal entropy one andnot the minimal martingale). The definition of operators At,uQ (·) does not containany dependence on the backward normalization point T . One may wrongly concludethat the prices may be independent on the normalization point as well. This is, infact, not the case since the characterization of the martingale measure Qme itselfincludes dependence of the backward normalization point T . Through the measureQme, the prices become dependent on the backward normalization point T .Proof. (i) At time T − 1,

V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1;T ) =

max

UBT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1;T ), supαT

EP[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ;T )/FT−1

]=

max

UBT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1;T ), supαT

EP[UBT

(XT + CT ;T )/FT−1

].

(5.65)

supαT

EP[UBT

(XT + CT ;T )/FT−1

]can be viewed as time T − 1 value function of an

investor with forward preferences holding a claim CT expiring at T . Consideringthe results already obtained for European claims,

supαT

EP[UBT

(XT + CT ;T )/FT−1

]= UB

T(XT + E T−1,T

Qme (CT ) ;T ), (5.66)

79

Page 91: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

and

V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1;T ) =

maxUBT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1;T ), UBT−1

(XT − ET−1,TQme (CT ) ;T )

=

UBT−1

(XT−1 + max

CT−1, E

T−1,TQme (CT )

;T).

(5.67)

This implies the corresponding relation for the indifference price. Following a typicalinduction argument, assume that the formula holds for times t+ 1 through T . Nowwe need to prove that the formula also holds at time t. From definition 5.4 of theindifference price,

supαt+1

EP[V C(Xt+1, St+1, Yt+1, t+ 1;T )/Ft

]=

supαt+1

EP[UBt+1(Xt+1 + at+1(C;T );T )/Ft

]=

supαt+1

E[− exp

(−γ(Xt+1 + at+1(C;T ) + 1

γH(t+ 1;T )))/Ft]

=

− exp(−γ(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm(at+1(C;T ) + 1

γH(t+ 1;T )))− ht+1

)=

UBt

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm(at+1(C;T ) + 1

γH(t+ 1;T ))

+ 1γ ht+1 − 1

γH(t;T );T)

=

UBt

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qmm(at+1(C;T ) + 1

γH(t+ 1;T ))

+ 1γ ht+1 −

(1γ ht+1 + E t,TQmm

(1γH(t+ 1;T )

));T)

=

UBt

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qme (at+1(C;T )) ;T).

(5.68)

Therefore, using formula (5.55) for the buyer’s value function,

V C(Xt, St, Yt, t;T ) = maxUBt (Xt + Ct;T ), UBt ]

(Xt + E t,t+1

Qme (at+1(C;T )) ;T)

=

UBt

(Xt + max

Ct, E t,t+1

Qme (at+1(C;T ))

;T).

(5.69)From the definition of the buyer’s indifference price and the calculation above,

at (C;T ) = maxCt, E t,t+1

Qme (at+1 (C;T )), (5.70)

and the proof of Part (i) is complete.Parts (ii) and (iii) of theorem 31 follow from (i) together with the definition ofthe operators At,uQme introduced above in equations (5.60) and (5.61) We furtherconsider properties of the buyer’s indifference price. The next theorem (32) shows

80

Page 92: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

how the price is affected by changes in the absolute risk aversion. Part (i) of thetheorem shows that a more risk averse buyer assigns a smaller value to the claimbearing unhedgeable risk. There, we use a slightly different notation at (C ; γ) andE t,t+1

Qme (Zt+1 ; γ). The ”extra argument” γ specifies a particular level of risk aversionto which the indifference price corresponds. Part (ii) of the theorem characterizesasymptotic behavior as γ → 0. Also, it provides an upper bound for at (C ; γ) forall values of γ, obtained as the indifference price of a buyer with infinitesimallysmall risk aversion. The limiting value shows significant structural similarity to theno-arbitrage price of an American claim in a complete market. However it usesa different measure Qme, and not the classical risk-neutral measure. Results ofPart (ii) are consistent with familiar asymptotic results for European derivatives indiscrete and continuous time. Part (iii) describes the asymptotic behavior of theprice as γ →∞ and provides a lower bound for at(C;T ) in the form of the buyer’sindifference price for an agent with infinitely large risk aversion.

Theorem 32 (Monotonicity and asymptotic bounds) (i) For γ1 ≥ γ2

at (C; γ1) ≤ at (C; γ2) , t ≤ T a.s. (5.71)

(ii) Define the sequence of Ft-measurable random variables ν0t (C) as

ν0T

(C) = CT ,

ν0t (C) = max

Ct, EQme

[ν0t+1(C)/Ft

], t < T .

(5.72)

Then for any t ≤ T ,at (C; γ) ν0

t (C) , as γ → 0. (5.73)

(iii) Define the sequence of Ft-measurable random variables νinft (C) as νinfT

(C) = CT ,

νinft (C; γ) = maxCt, EQme [min

Yt+1

νinft+1/Ft], t < T.

(5.74)

Thenat(C;T ) νinft (C), as γ →∞. (5.75)

In (5.74), the expectation can be taken under any equivalent to P martingale measure

81

Page 93: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Q.

Proof. (i) For t = T , aT (C; γ1) = aT (C; γ2) = CT and inequality (5.71) holds.For t < T , one only needs to show that, for every Ft+1-measurable random variableZt+1,

E t,t+1Qme (Zt+1; γ1) ≤ E t,t+1

Qme (Zt+1; γ2) . (5.76)

Let γ = −γ,

E t,t+1Qme (Zt+1; γ) = EQme

[ln(EQme

[(eZt+1

)γ/Ft ∨ FSt+1

]) 1γ/Ft]

=

EQme

[ln(EQme

[(Z1t+1)γ /Ft ∨ FSt+1

]) 1γ/Ft] (5.77)

where Z1t+1 = eZt+1 > 0. Due to the monotonicity of the conditional expectationand logarithmic function it only remains to show that for γ1 ≤ γ2 < 0

EQme[(Z1t+1)γ1 /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ1 ≤ EQme

[(Z1t+1)γ2 /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ2 (5.78)

With Z1γ1t+1 = Gt+1 and 0 < γ = γ2

γ1≤ 1, inequality (5.78) can be rewritten (note

that the sign of the new inequality is different because 1γ1

is negative):

EQme[Gt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

]≥ EQme

[(Gt+1)γ /Ft ∨ FSt+1

] 1γ (5.79)

The last inequality follows from concavity of the function xγ for x > 0, 0 < γ ≤ 1,and the Jensen’s inequality.(ii) We first show that the formula holds for time T − 1. For any t, includingt = T − 1, E t,t+1

Qme (CT ) can be written explicitly as

E t,t+1Qme (at+1) = −

Qme(At+1/Ft)γ log

(Qme(At+1Bt+1/Ft)

Qme(At+1/Ft)e−γa

uut+1 +

Qme(At+1Bct+1/Ft)

Qme(At+1/Ft)e−γa

udt+1

)−

Qme(Act+1/Ft)γ log

(Qme(Act+1Bt+1/Ft)

Qme(Act+1/Ft)e−γa

dut+1 +

Qme(Act+1Bct+1/Ft)

Qme(Act+1/Ft)e−γa

ddt+1

),

(5.80)

82

Page 94: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

with

Qme(At+1/Ft) = Qme(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft

),

Qme(Act+1/Ft) = Qme(St+1 = Sdt+1/Ft

),

Qme(At+1Bt+1/Ft) = Qme(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

Qme(Act+1Bt+1/Ft) = Qme(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

Qme(At+1Bct+1/Ft) = Qme

(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

Qme(Act+1Bct+1/Ft) = Qme

(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

(5.81)

with auut+1, audt+1, adut+1 and addt+1 denoting the four possible values of at+1(C; γ), asviewed from time t. For t = T − 1 in particular,

aijT

= Cij = C(SiT , YjT

), for i, j = ’u’ and ’d’ . (5.82)

Using L’Hopital’s rule and equation (5.80), the limit of E T−1,TQme (CT ) as γ → 0 is

Qme(AT /FT−1)(

Qme(ATBT /FT−1)Qme(AT /FT−1) Cuu +

Qme(ATBcT /FT−1)

Qme(AT /FT−1) Cud)

+Qme(AcT/FT−1)

(Qme(AcTBT /FT−1)

Qme(AcT /FT−1) Cdu +Qme(AcTB

cT /FT−1)

Qme(AcT /FT−1) Cdd)

= EQme[CT /FT−1

].

(5.83)

The calculation above shows that E T−1,TQme (CT ) converges to EQme

[CT /FT−1

]. Con-

sequently, since CT−1 is independent of γ,

aT−1(C; γ)→ maxCT−1, EQme[CT /FT−1

],

as γ → 0.To confirm the formula for t ≤ T − 2, one would proceed by induction and

assume that the limit of au(C; γ) as γ → 0 equals ν0u(C) for all u ≥ t+1. at(C; γ) is

the maximum of Ct and E t,t+1Qme (at+1(C; γ)). The latter has an explicit representation

provided in equation (5.80). Since, by induction assumption, at+1(C; γ) converges

83

Page 95: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

to ν0t+1(C) as γ → 0, applying the same argument as before yields

limγ→0E t,t+1

Qme (at+1(C; γ)) =

Qme(At+1/Ft)(

Qme(At+1Bt+1/Ft)Qme(At+1/Ft)

auut+1 +Qme(At+1B

ct+1/Ft)

Qme(At+1/Ft)audt+1

)+

Qme(Act+1/Ft)(

Qme(Act+1Bt+1/Ft)Qme(Act+1/Ft)

adut+1 +Qme(Act+1B

ct+1/Ft)

Qme(Act+1/Ft)addt+1

)=

EQme[ν0t+1(C)/Ft

].

(5.84)

Thus at(C; γ) converges to maxCt, EQme [ν0t+1(C)/Ft].

(iii) As before we show that formula for t = T −1. For other values of t ≤ T −2 onecould use induction and repeat the argument. The limit of E T−1,T

Qme (CT ) as γ → ∞is given by

limγ→∞

[ −Qme(AT /FT−1)·

CuuQme(ATBT /FT−1)e−γCuu

+ CudQme(ATBcT /FT−1)e−γC

ud

Qme(ATBT /FT−1)e−γCuu

+ Qme(ATBcT /FT−1)e−γC

ud −

Qme(AcT/FT−1)

CduQme(AcTBT /FT−1)e−γCdu

+ CddQme(AcTBcT /FT−1)e−γC

dd

Qme(AcTBT /FT−1)e−γCdu

+ Qme(AcTBcT /FT−1)e−γC

dd ]

= Qme(AT /FT−1) minCuu, Cud+ Qme(AcT/FT−1) minCdu, Cdd

= EQme [minYT

CT /FT−1].

(5.85)In fact, Qme(AT /FT−1) is the same among all martingale measures Q equiv-

alent to P. Therefore, the expectation in (5.74) could be taken under any martingalemeasure Q

The theorem above shows that asymptotically as γ → 0 and γ → ∞ therecursive structure of the indifference price is preserved. To evaluate the benefits ofcontinuing to hold the claim, an investor with an infinitesimally small risk aversion

84

Page 96: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

would price the next date’s indifference value using expectation under the minimalmartingale measure, while a very risk averse buyer would use the ”lower hedgingprice” for European claims. Both investors will exercise if the value of ”alternativeto continue” falls below the payoff from immediate exercise Ct.

Next we present another condition, under which the backward early exerciseprice coincides with ν0

t .

Theorem 33 (Perfect correlation result) If the historical measure P is suchthat, for all t ≤ T ,

P(ηt+1/Ft ∨ FSt+1

)∈ 0, 1, (5.86)

then early exercise indifference price at(C;T ) coincides with ν0t defined by equation

(5.72).

Proof. Writing the expression for the indifference price explicitly as in (5.81) andtaking into account the characterization of the minimal entropy martingale measureQme, given in chapter 3 proposition 4, one can immediately see that under condi-tion (5.86), Qme(Yt/Ft−1 ∨ FSt ) ∈ 0, 1. Thus, equation (5.80) for E t,t+1

Qme (at+1(C))simplifies to EQme [at+1(C)/Ft], and the statement of the theorem follows

Condition (5.86) indicates that, given all the information up to time t and aparticular time t+ 1 realization of St+1, the value of Yt+1 is known for sure and wecan say the movements of stock S and risk-factor Y are ”perfectly correlated”.

The next result defines an early exercise time that later will be shown to bethe optimal exercise time. It is an intermediate result that provide an additionalcharacterization for the indifference price used in other theorems.

Proposition 5.2 Let at(C;T ) be defined as in equation (5.62). Define a stoppingtime τ?t as

τ?t = inft≤s≤T

s : as(C;T ) = Cs. (5.87)

at(C;T ) = supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQme(aτ (C;T )) = E t,TQme(aτ?t (C;T )). (5.88)

Proof. Since the operators E t,t+1Qme (·) are monotone, for any s ≥ t,

at(C;T ) ≥ E t,t+1Qme (at+1(C)) ≥ E t,sQme(as(C;T )) = E t,TQme(as(C;T )). (5.89)

85

Page 97: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Thus, for any stopping time t ≤ τ ≤ T , at(C;T ) ≥ E t,T (aτ (C)). Also the processas∧τ?t (C), t ≤ s ≤ T satisfies

Es,s+1Qme (as+1∧τ?t (C)) = as∧τ?t (C). (5.90)

Indeed, if τ?t < s + 1 then as+1∧τ?t (C) = aτ?t (C) is Fs-measurable and the left-hand side of (5.90) equals aτ?t (C). If τ?t ≥ s + 1 then the righthand side of(5.90) becomes Es,s+1

Qme (as+1(C)), which is equal to as(C;T ) by definition of τ?t(see equation (5.87)). Repeated application of (5.90) for s = t, t + 1, ..., T yieldsat(C;T ) = E t,T (aT∧τ?t (C)) = E t,TQme(aτ?t (C))

The next result provides an alternative characterization of the indifferenceprice. It is consistent with the Snell envelope representation in a complete market.In addition, it confirms that the indifference price at(C;T ) is greater than any ofthe prices E t,sQme(Cs) of the corresponding European claims.

Theorem 34 Define a sequence of Ft-measurable variables νt as follows:

νt = supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQme(Cτ ). (5.91)

The indifference price process at(C;T ) and the process νt coincide.

Proof. For any stopping time τ , aτ (C;T ) ≥ Cτ . The operators E t,t+1Qme (·) are

monotone and Proposition 5.2 yields at(C;T ) ≥ E t,TQme(aτ (C)) ≥ E t,TQme(Cτ ). On the

other hand, aτ?t (C) = Cτ?t . Therefore, at(C;T ) = E t,TQme(aτ?t (C)) = E t,TQme(Cτ?) =

supt≤τ≤T

E t,TQme(Cτ )

Theorem 35 (Optimal stopping time) Optimal stopping time defined in equa-tion (5.87) and αt+1, ...αT shown in equation (5.94) are a solution of stochasticoptimization problem (5.53), that is

V C(Xt, St, Yt, s;T ) = EP[UBt(Xτ?t

+ Cτ?t , τ?t

);T )/Ft], (5.92)

with

Xτ? =τ?t∑u=t

(Su+1 − Su)α?u+1, (5.93)

86

Page 98: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

α?t = 1γSt−1(ξut − ξdt )

log(

(ξut − 1)P(At/Ft−1)(1− ξdt )P(Act/Ft−1)

)+ 1γSt−1(ξut − ξdt )

·

log

((eγ−a

uut+1P(At, Bt/Ft−1) + eγ−a

udt+1P(At, Bc

t /Ft−1))P(Act/Ft−1)(eγ−a

dut+1P(Act , Bt/Ft−1) + eγ−a

ddt+1P(Act , B

ct /Ft−1))P(At/Ft−1)

),

(5.94)

P(At+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft

),

P(Act+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sdt+1/Ft

),

P(At+1Bt+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

P(Act+1Bt+1/Ft) = P(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y u

t+1/Ft),

P(At+1Bct+1/Ft) = P

(St+1 = Sut+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

P(Act+1Bct+1/Ft) = P

(St+1 = Sdt+1, Yt+1 = Y d

t+1/Ft),

(5.95)

and auut+1, audt+1, adut+1 and addt+1 denoting the four possible values of at+1(C;T ), asviewed from time t.

Proof. We first check the result for t = T − 1.

EP[UBT−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

;T )/FT−1] =

EP[1τ?T−1

=T−1UBτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

;T )+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)UBτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

;T )/FT−1] =

1τ?T−1

=T−1UBT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1;T )+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[UBT

(XT + CT ;T )/FT−1] =

1τ?T−1

=T−1UBT−1

(XT−1 + CT−1;T )+

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ;T )/FT−1].

(5.96)

By definition of τ?T−1

,

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)EP[V C(XT , ST , YT , T ;T )/FT−1] =

(1− 1τ?T−1

=T−1)VC(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1, T − 1;T )

(5.97)

for α?T

defined as in (5.94). Therefore

EP[UBτ?T−1

(Xτ?T−1

+ Cτ?T−1

;T )/FT−1] = V C(XT−1, ST−1, YT−1T − 1;T ). (5.98)

Assuming that (5.92) hold for t = u+1, ..., T , we need to show that (5.92) also holds

87

Page 99: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

for t = u. Expand EP[UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu] as:

EP[UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu] = EP[1τ?u=uUBτ?u

(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )+(1− 1τ?u=u)UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu] = 1τ?u=uU

Bu (Xu + Cu;T )+

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu].

(5.99)

For w : τ?u(w) > u, τ?u = τ?u+1 and

EP[UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu] = 1τ?u=uVC(Xu, Su, Yu, u;T )+

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[UBτ?u+1(Xτ?u+1

+ Cτ?u+1;T )/Fu] =

1τ?u=uVC(Xu, Su, Yu, u;T ) + (1− 1τ?u=u)EP[V C(Xu+1, Su+1, Yu+1, u+ 1;T )/Fu]

(5.100)by induction assumption. By definition of τ?u,

(1− 1τ?u=u)EP[V C(Xu+1, Su+1, Yu+1, u+ 1;T )/Fu] =(1− 1τ?u=u)V C(Xu, Su, Yu, u;T )

(5.101)

for α?u+1 defined as in (5.94).Therefore, EP[UBτ?u(Xτ?u + Cτ?u ;T )/Fu] = V C(Xu, Su, Yu, u;T )

We have presented the two indifference pricing algorithms with different dy-namic utilities. Both algorithms are recursive, have s structure similar to the com-plete market price of an American contract, and use the same nonlinear pricingfunctionals E t,uQ (·). However, there are some differences, such as the measures usedfor valuation and dependence on the normalization point. As with European con-tracts, the forward early exercise price does not depend on the forward normalizationpoint s, nor does it depend on the end of the investment horizon T . Not so for thebackward early exercise price, which uses the minimal martingale measure Qme,which depends on the backward normalization point T (also the end of the invest-ment horizon). The next and final section of this chapter works under the reducedmodel assumption of corollary 10 in chapter 3, and shows how the two early exerciseprices are related.

[18] recently suggested a valuation method similar to ours. This method usesthe traditional static preferences of the form −e−γx to price an early exercise liabil-ity generating cashflows on [0;T ]. In [18] the agents preferences are fixed at time T ,as they are for our backward utility process in our work. [18] works with a reduced

88

Page 100: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

model, for which the minimal entropy measure and the martingale measure coin-cide. In addition to using dynamic preferences and having a more general model,our results are fully formulated even in the multi-period setting in terms of the cor-responding theorems, and have been rigorously confirmed. We address properties ofthe indifference prices in a rigorous way and provide an alternative characterizationof the early exercise price, as the supremum of the European prices.

5.3 Reduced model results

The concept of a reduced model was introduced in chapter 3, corollary 10. In sucha model the historical distribution of the next period’s traded asset value does notdepend of the path of the non-traded stochastic risk factor Y , and neither do thevariables ξut+1 and ξdt+1, for all 0 ≤ t ≤ T − 1. We have shown in corollary 10 ofchapter 3 that in a reduced model, the minimal martingale measure and the minimalentropy measure are the same. In addition, theorem 23 of section 4.3 states that thebackward and the forward European prices are the same. Naturally, the Americanbackward and forward prices are the same as well. The results are stated withouta proof since the latter is obvious once the American pricing algorithms 31 and 25have been established.

Theorem 36 In the reduced binomial model, i.e. when

P(ξt+1/Ft) = P(ξt+1/FSt ), t = 0, 1, ..., T − 1, (5.102)

and ξut+1, ξdt+1 are FSt -measurable, the forward and backward indifference prices ofthe American contract C written at t0 and maturing at T , coincide:

aFt (C) = aBt (C;T ) (5.103)

for t0 ≤ t ≤ T ≤ T .

The next result assumes the reduced model and considers the payoff depend-ing on the traded asset only. In that case both the backward and the forward pricescoincide, and the call option on the traded asset S should never be exercised. Inthe non-reduced model, ξut+1 and ξdt+1 may be dependent on the non-traded risk

89

Page 101: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

factor values. Then, under any equivalent to P martingale measure Q, the distribu-tion of the next period’s traded asset value St+1 would depend on Y . In that case,even if the payoff only depends on the traded asset S, the pricing algorithm cannotbe simplified to pricing using expectations. Then, the call option on the tradedasset may have to be exercised early. The proof of the next result follows easilyfrom proposition 4.5 of section 4.3, theorems 31 and 25, and Jensen’s inequality forconvex functions, and therefore is omitted.

Proposition 5.3 Under the reduced model assumption of corollary 10, chapter 3(also shown in theorem 36 above), if the intrinsic payoff C(St, Yt) does not dependon Yt for all t0 ≤ t ≤ T , then

aFt (C) = aBt (C;T ) (5.104)

In addition, if C(St) = (St −K)+, then

aFt (C) = aBt (C;T ) = EQmm [(ST −K)+/FSt ] = EQme [(ST −K)+/FSt ], (5.105)

for any t0 ≤ t ≤ T .

90

Page 102: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 6

The continuous time model and

the dynamic indifference

valuation.

In this chapter we focus our study on valuation of early exercise contracts in con-tinuous time. The binomial model and results presented above provide an explicitalgorithm for valuation of early exercise and partial exercise claims with either back-ward of forward utility, including the cases when dynamics of the traded asset areaffected by the non-traded factor. Unfortunately for certain models, the associatedbinomial tree would not recombine, making the practical implementation compu-tationally intractable, as discussed in more detail in the concluding chapter. Forthose models, the more straight forward way to value early exercise contracts withnon-traded assets would be in the PDE framework, developed herein.

In modeling the traded asset and the non-traded stochastic factor, a typicalsetting would be the one with the two SDEs governing the dynamics of the instru-ments, respectively. The dependence of the stock dynamics on the non-traded factorcan show itself in two distinct ways: through the correlation coefficient between therespective Brownian motions and through explicit functional dependence of stock’sSDE coefficients. If only the first type is present, then the Sharpe ratio of the tradedasset does not depend on the value of a stochastic factor. Such a model was calledan almost complete model by [45]. When both types of dependence are present, thevaluation becomes more involved, as we see further.

91

Page 103: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Several studies have already been initiated to value early exercise claimswith non-traded assets in continuous time. For us, the closest related are the onesthat apply indifference pricing methodology. Among those are a number of studiesthat used the traditional, static exponential utility U(x) = −e−γx and the constantSharpe ratio. Among the ones are [20], [14], [22], [44], [34].

In [20], perpetual options are considered. In [22] and [34], the partial exercisefeature is brought in. In our study we assume that that early exercise option isexpiring at a certain time and, at that time, it has to be exercised if not exercised sofar. Partial exercise has been addressed in our work in discrete time. In continuoustime, we do not address the partial exercise feature. Intead, we focus on working withmore general model dynamics, and are going to derive the value for the Americancontract with finite-horizon under two different dynamic utilities. Extending ourcontinuous time results even more, to partial exercise or to infinite horizon, is afuture research topic.

With more general models, valuation of early exercise claims with non-tradable assets in continuous time is represented by the works of, for example,[32] and [31]. There, the authors suggest to work with price processes given as semi-martingales and deploy game-theoretic arguments to deduce the price, but thoseresults again either use a static exponential utility or are not as explicit as the oneswe present below.

In what follows, our goal is to derive the price of the early exercise claimwith non-traded stochastic factor, for the forward and the backward preferences,as solutions of their respective variational inequalities. We start by presenting thecorresponding continuous time results for European contracts, first for the forwardutility, then for the backward. [42] work with writer’s value. We are pricing Ameri-can claims from the buyer’s prospective. All the concepts and results derived belowwill be stated from the buyer’s point of view. We use classical stochastic controlarguments together with existing results about the Backward and the Forward util-ity processes and the associated measures. We comment on the similarities andthe differences in the representations for the Backward and Forward prices. Wepresent the alternative characterizations for the Backward and Forward prices, us-ing the nonlinear functionals under the minimal entropy and minimal martingalemeasures correspondingly. We comment on the similarities between the alternativerepresentations and results obtained in our binomial model.

92

Page 104: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

6.1 Market model

We use a market model consisting of a riskless bond, a risky traded stock and a risky(non-traded) stochastic factor. The interest rate is assumed to be zero. Therefore,the bond price Bs is identically 1 at all times. The stock price process, Ss is adiffusion process. Its drift and volatility are dependent on the level of the non-traded factor Ys. The non-traded risk factor itself, Ys, is also a diffusion. Ss and Yssatisfy the corresponding pair of stochastic differential equations:

dSs = µ(Ys, s)Ssds+ σ(Ys, s)SsdW 1s ,

dYs = b(Ys, s)ds+ a(Ys, s)dW 2s .

(6.1)

The processes W 1s and W 2

s are standard Brownian motions defined on the probabilityspace (Ω,F ,Fs,P). Fs is the augmented σ-algebra generated by (W 1

u ,W2u , 0 ≤ u ≤

s). The Brownian motions are correlated with a correlation coefficient ρ ∈ (−1, 1).µ,σ, a and b are such that (6.1) has unique strong solution. A claim C is written ona both assets, and could not be perfectly replicated through trading. As for now,the claim is assumed to be European.

An investor is endowed with the time t wealth of x dollars, and uses a self-financing trading strategy πs, t ≤ s ≤ T . Assuming zero interest rate, it is notdifficult to see that the wealth of the investor evolves according to the SDE shownbelow:

dXs = πsµ(Ys, s)ds+ πsσ(Ys, s)dW 1s ,

Xt = x.(6.2)

The trading strategy πs is assumed be such that ET∫0

σ2sπ

2sds < ∞. The set of all

such trading strategies forms the set A of admissible controls. The sopping time τ ,taking values in [t0; T ], represents the exercise time chosen by the investor. T is theexpiration date of the claim.

6.2 Forward dynamic preferences and indifference price

for European contracts

In this section we state results of [42] obtained for the forward utility process forEuropean claims. Those results are necessary for comparison with our discrete time

93

Page 105: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

formulas obtained in section 4.1, and set the modelling framework and create afoundation for valuation of American contracts with forward dynamic utility, thatare presented in subsequent sections.

The agent’s preferences are specified by the forward dynamic utility of theform:

UFt (x; s) = −e−γx+h(s,t), (6.3)

withh(s, t) =

s∫t

12λ

2(Yu)du (6.4)

and λ being the Sharpe ratio:

λu = λ(Yu) = µ(Yu)σ(Yu) . (6.5)

The time point s is referred to as the normalization point, that is at t = s,

UFs (x; s) = −e−γx. (6.6)

An important property of the forward dynamic utility that it is self-generating, thatis

UFt (x; s) = supAEP[UFT (XT ; s)/Ft], t ≥ s. (6.7)

The properties of self-generation (6.7) and the normalization (6.6) are satisfied byseveral different processes, one of them being the forward utility process (6.3). An-other process, as [42] point out, would be, for example of the form:

UFt (x; s) = −e−γx−Z(s,t),

Z(s, t) =t∫s

12λ

2(Yu)du+t∫sλ(Yu)dW 1

u .(6.8)

The characterization of the class of processes that satisfy the the self-generationcondition and the normalization condition together, remains an open question, aswell as what are the conditions under which (6.7) and (6.6) yield unique solution.We are not addressing this question herein.

The self generation properly implies that the value function (defined tra-ditionally, as the expectation of the agent’s terminal wealth) coincides with theforward dynamic utility process itself. Another attractive property of the forward

94

Page 106: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

utility process (6.3), is that is is independent of the end-point T of investment hori-zon. As will be seen later, the prices generated with the forward dynamic utilityprocess (6.3) are independent of T as well. Below we continue with a summaryof the relevant results obtained by [42] regarding the indifference prices generatedby forward dynamic utility and the relevant measures, the minimal entropy andthe minimal martingale measure, defined correspondingly the minimizers of the twoentropic functionals:

Definition 6.1 (Minimal Entropy measure)

H (Qme/P) = minQ∈Qe

EP

[dQ

dPlog

dQ

dP

]. (6.9)

Definition 6.2 (Minimal Martingale measure)

H (Qmm/P) = minQ∈Qe

EP

[− log

dQ

dP

]. (6.10)

The Minimal Entropy measure and the Minimal Martingale measure defined abovepossess the following Radon-Nikodym densities:

dQmm

dP = exp

(−

T∫0

λudW1u −

T∫0

12λ

2udu

)(6.11)

and

dQme

dP = exp

(−

T∫0

λudW1u −

T∫0

λudW1,⊥u −

T∫0

12(λ2

u + λ2

u)du

), (6.12)

with dW 2u = ρdW 1

u +√

1− ρ2dW 1,⊥u . dW 1

u and dW 1,⊥u are the two orthogonal

Brownian motions.The minimal aggregate relative conditional (on time t) entropy H(Qme/P) equals

H(Qme/P) = −JQmm

(−

T∫t

12λ

2udu

)(6.13)

with JQ(·) being the conditional nonlinear expectation of a generic random variable

95

Page 107: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Z ∈ FT , defined with respect to any equivalent martingale measure Q as

JQ(Z) = 11− ρ2 lnEQ[e(1−ρ2)Z/Ft]. (6.14)

We point out that JQ(·) is independent of γ. We also define another nonlinearfunctional, EQ(·) as

EQ(Z) = − 1γ(1− ρ2)

lnEQ[e−γ(1−ρ2)Z/Ft]. (6.15)

Clearly, JQ(Z) = −γEQ(−1γZ), or JQ(Z) is the same as EQ(Z) with γ = −1. The

functional E(·) does depend on the level of the absolute risk aversion.The relative aggregate conditional (on time t) entropy of the minimal mar-

tingale measure H(Qmm/P) equals:

H(Qmm/P) = EQmm

[T∫t

12λ

2uds

]. (6.16)

As shown in [42], the minimal aggregate relative entropy process is given by

H(Qme/P) = EQme

[T∫t

12

(λ2(Ys) + λ

2(Ys, s;T )

)ds/Ft

], (6.17)

with λ being the Sharpe ratio as in (6.5), λ: R× [0;T ]→ R+ defined as

λ(y, s;T ) = − 1√1− ρ2

a(y)fy(y, t;T )f(y, t;T ) , (6.18)

and with f solving ft + 12a

2(y)∂2f∂y2 + (b(y)− ρλ(y)a(y))∂f

∂y= 1

2(1− ρ2)λ2(y)f,

f(y, T ) = 1.(6.19)

So far we have provided two different representations for the minimal aggregateentropy process H(Qme/P), that is equations (6.13) and (6.17). Both of those rep-resentations could be written equivalently in the PDE form, as the next propositionshows.

96

Page 108: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Proposition 6.1 The minimal aggregate entropy process equals

H(Qme/P) = H(Yt, t;T ) (6.20)

with the function H(y, t;T ) : R× [0;T ]→ R solves either of the two PDEs below:Ht + LmmH − 1

2(1− ρ2)a2(y)H2y + 1

2λ2(y) = 0,

H(y, T ;T ) = 0.(6.21)

or Ht + LmeH + 1

2

(λ2(y) + λ

2(y))

= 0,

H(y, T ;T ) = 0.(6.22)

The operators Lmm and Lme are defined below in equations (6.23) and (6.24) cor-respondingly:

Lmm = 12σ

2(y)S2 ∂2

∂S2 + ρσ(y)Sa(y) ∂2

∂S∂y+ 1

2a2(y) ∂

2

∂y2

+ (b(y)− ρλ(y)a(y)) ∂∂y,

(6.23)

LY,me = 12σ

2(y)S2 ∂2

∂S2 + ρσ(y)Sa(y) ∂2

∂S∂y+ 1

2a2(y) ∂

2

∂y2

+(b(y)− ρλ(y)a(y) + a2(y)fy(y, t;T )

f(y, t;T )

)∂∂y

(6.24)

and f solves equation (6.19).

We are now ready to define the indifference price and state its corresponding PDE.

Definition 6.3 (Forward European indifference price) Let s ≥ 0 be the for-ward normalization point and consider a claim CT ∈ FT , written at t0 ≥ s andmaturing at T < T . For t ∈ [t0; T ], the forward indifference value process νFt (CT ; s)satisfies the pricing equation:

UFt (x+ νFt (CT ; s); s) = supAE[UFT

(XT + CT ; s)/Ft], (6.25)

for all x ∈ R, Xt = x.

Proposition 6.2 The forward indifference price νFt (CT ; s) equals:

νFt (CT ; s) = pF (St, Yt, t), (6.26)

97

Page 109: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

with function pF (S, y, t) : R+ ×R× [t0; T ]→ R solving the PDE:pFt + LmmpF − 1

2γ(1− ρ2)a(y)2(pFy )2 = 0,pF (S, y, T ) = C(S, y),

(6.27)

and the operator Lmm defined as in (6.23) above.

6.3 Backward utility process and indifference price for

European contracts

This section introduces the backward utility process, following closely the work of[42], and re-stating their results to reflect the buyer’s point of view. Those resultslay the foundation for valuing American claim that we attempt in the next twosections.

As the with the forward utility, the backward utility process is createdthrough the introduction of the two necessary condition, the self-generation andthe normalization. Unlike the forward utility, that is normalized at a time point inthe past, the backward utility is normalized at the future time point T , so that

UBT (x;T ) = −e−γx. (6.28)

The self-generation condition for the backward utility is as follows:

UBt (x;T ) = supAEP[UBT (XT ;T )/Ft], t ≥ s. (6.29)

The normalization (6.28) and the self-generation (6.29) imply the unique backwarddynamic utility process of the form:

UBt (x;T ) = −e−γx−H(y,t;T ), t ≤ T (6.30)

As one can see, the backward utility process is actually the same as what is tra-ditionally called ”the plain investment value function” of an agent maximizing hisexpected utility of the terminal wealth, when the agent is endowed with static expo-nential utility. We next state the definition of the backward indifference price andthe corresponding PDE it solves.

98

Page 110: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Definition 6.4 (Backward European indifference price) Let T < T be thematurity of the European contract CT , written at time t0. For t ∈ [t0; T ], thebackward indifference price process νBt (CT ;T )) satisfies the pricing condition:

UBt (x+ νBt (CT ;T )) = supAE[UBT

(XT + CT ;T )/Ft], (6.31)

for all x ∈ R, Xt = x.

Proposition 6.3 The backward indifference price process νBt (CT ;T ) is given by:

νBt (CT ;T ) = pB(St, Yt, t), (6.32)

where function pB : R+ ×R× [t0; T ]→ R satisfies:pBt + LmepB − 1

2γ(1− ρ2)a(y)2(pBy )2 = 0,pB(S, y, T ) = C(S, y).

(6.33)

The operator Lme is the one defined in (6.24) above.

Comparing results of propositions 6.3 and 6.2, one could easily see that the two pric-ing PDE equations have the same terminal conditions, the same structure, but dif-ferent operators, Lmm and Lme. The two operators differ only in the drift term, the

latter having the same drift as Lmm, but with an extra added factor a2(y)fy(y, t;T )f(y, t;T ) .

In our model, when the Sharpe ratio λ(y) is independent of y, the Sharpe ratio isconstant, i.e., the model becomes almost complete when the Sharpe ratio is con-stant. The PDE for function f has a unique solution. One could see that, having aconstant λ, implies that f is identically 1, and that the operators Lmm and Lme thenbecome the same, as become the forward and the backward prices. The differencebetween the backward and the forward price could only be seen when λ has somedependence on y.

We provide another representation of the backward and forward prices, inthe form of the nonlinear functionals.

Proposition 6.4 The Backward and the Forward buyer’s indifference prices of the

99

Page 111: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

European contract CT equal

νBt (CT ;T ) = EQme (CT ) ,νFt (CT ; s) = EQmm (CT ) ,

(6.34)

with the nonlinear functional EQ(·) defined in equation (6.15) of the previous sectionfor any martingale measure Q.

6.4 Forward indifference price for American contracts

Traditionally, in continuous time the indifference price is represented with PDEs. Inthis section we first extend the work of [42] by deriving the forward indifference valueof an American contracts as the solution of the corresponding variational inequality.Motivated by our discrete time results in earlier chapters( see 28 in section 5.1), weprovide an alternative representation using nonlinear functionals EQ(·), in the spiritof proposition 6.4 of the previous section. This alternative representation providesa convenient way for comparison to the discrete time pricing fomulas.

The buyer is now allowed to exercise his contract at any time within theinterval [t0; T ], and a stopping time τ represents the exercise time of the contract,chosen by the buyer. Upon exercise, the buyer receives the payoff Xτ + Cτ . Weformulate the indifference pricing condition similarly to the way [42] formulated itfor the European contracts, but with the stopping time τ taken into account.

Definition 6.5 (Forward early exercise indifference price) Let T be the ex-piration date of the American contract with intrinsic payoff Ct, written at time t0,t0 ≤ t ≤ T . For t ∈ [t0; T ], the forward early exercise indifference price processνa,Ft (C; s) satisfies the pricing condition:

UFt (x+ νa,Ft (C; s); s) = supA,τ

EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft

]. (6.35)

for all x ∈ R, Xt = x.

Below we present the main result of this section.

Theorem 37 The forward early exercise indifference price νa,Ft (C; s) satisfies:

νa,Ft (C; s) = νa,F (S, y, t), (6.36)

100

Page 112: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

with function νa,F (S, y, t) : R+×R× [t0; T ]→ R being the unique bounded viscositysolution of the quasilinear variational inequality shown below:

min−νa,Ft − Lmmνa,F + 12γ(1− ρ2)a(y)2(νa,Fy )2, νa,F − C(S, y) = 0,

νa,F (S, y, T ) = C(S, y).(6.37)

Proof. We assume that indifference prices and other functions we define and usein this proof are sufficiently differentiable. The formal arguments presented hereincould be made rigorous in the viscosity sense. First note that, using measurabilityproperty of h(s, t),

supA,τ

EP[UFτ (Xτ + Cτ ; s)/Ft

]= e

t∫s

12λ2(Yu)du

supA,τ

EP[−e−γ(Xτ+Cτ )+

τ∫t

12λ2(Yu)du

/Ft] =

e

t∫s

12λ2(Yu)du

uc(Xt, St, Yt, t).(6.38)

Using the classical stochastic stochastic control arguments for problems with optimalstopping, one could see that function uc(x, S, y, t) : R×R+×R×[t0; T ]→ R satisfiesthe following equation:

min−uct −maxπ

(12σ

2(y)π2ucxx + π(σ2(y)SucxS + ρσ(y)a(y)ucxy + µ(y)ucx)

−L(S,y)uc − 12λ

2(y)u, uc + e−γ(x+C(S,y)) = 0,uc(x, S, y, T ) = −e−γ(x+C(S,y)),

(6.39)with the operator L(S,y) defined as:

L(S,y) = 12σ

2(y)S2 ∂2

∂S2 + ρa(y)σ(y)S ∂2

∂S∂y+ 1

2a2(y) ∂

2

∂y2

+µ(y)S ∂∂S

+ b(y) ∂∂y.

(6.40)

For the forward utility process, using the self-generation condition,

UFt (x; s) = supAEP[UF

T(XT ; s)/Ft] =

= e

t∫s

12λ2(Yu)du

supAEP

−e−γXT+T∫t

12λ2(Yu)du

/Ft

= e

t∫s

12λ2(Yu)du

u0(Xs, Ys, t).

(6.41)

101

Page 113: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Again, using classical stochastic control arguments, u0(x, y, t) : R×R× [t0; T ]→ Rsatisfies the following HJB equation:

u0t + max

π(12σ

2(y)π2u0xx + π(σ2(y)Su0

xS + ρσ(y)a(y)u0xy + µ(y)u0

x)

+L(y)u0 + 12λ

2(y)u0 = 0,u0(x, y, T ) = −e−γx,

(6.42)

with L(y) as in:L(y) = 1

2a2(y) ∂

2

∂y2 + b(y) ∂∂y. (6.43)

In order for the pricing condition to hold, we must have

uc(Xt, St, Yt, t) = u0(Xt + νa,F (St, Yt, t), Yt, t). (6.44)

Let νa,F : R+×R× [t0; T ]→ R be an arbitrary (sufficiently differentiable) functionof S, y and t. Condition (6.44) then translates into:

uc(x, S, y, t) = u0(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t). (6.45)

Following the arguments in [40], plugging the right-hand side of (6.45) into equation(6.39), and taking (6.42) into account, we deduce that νa,F solves:

minu0x(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t)

(−νa,Ft − Lmmνa,F

)−u0

xy(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t)a2(y)(1− ρ2)νa,Fy−u0

xx(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t)12a

2(y)(1− ρ2)(νa,Fy )2,

u0(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t) + e−γ(x+C(S,y)) = 0.

(6.46)

[42] show that equation (6.42) has unique solution, which equals u0(x, S, y, t) =−e−γx. Therefore,

u0x(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t) = γe−γ(x+νa,F (S,y,t)),

u0xx(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t) = −γ2e−γ(x+νa,F (S,y,t)),

u0xy(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t) = 0,u0(x+ νa,F (S, y, t), y, t) = −e−γ(x+νa,F (S,y,t)).

(6.47)

102

Page 114: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Using equation (6.47) in (6.46), we get:

minγe−γ(x+νa,F (S,y,t))(−νa,Ft − Lmmνa,F + 1

2γa2(y)(1− ρ2)(νa,Fy )2

),

e−γ(x+νa,F (S,y,t))(−1 + e−γ(C(S,y)−νa,F (S,y,t))

) = 0.

(6.48)

Equation 6.48 above is equivalent to (6.37)The next theorem provides another representation of the indifference price, in

the form of non-linear functionals EQ(·) defined in (6.15). The proof follows closelyProposition 11 in [40] and is omitted.

νa,Ft (C; s) = supt0≤τ≤T

(EQmm(C(Sτ , Yτ ))) . (6.49)

The result shown above exists in a similar form in our binomial setting, see section5.1 theorem 28. In both cases, the continuous and the binomial, the functionalscharacterizing the indifference value are nonlinear, become linear as risk aversionapproaches 0, use the same (minimal) martingale measure, and incorporate thestopping time in the same way, by taking the supremum of all possible buyer’s pricesobtained for different exercise times. A small difference is that in continuous timethe instantaneous correlation coefficient is incorporated into the formula explicitly,but in the discrete time it enter the formula implicitly through the joint distributionof the traded asset and the non-traded factor.

6.5 Backward Indifference price for American contracts

In this section we derive the formulas for the backward indifference price. We startin the same way as with previous section, by introducing the pricing condition inthe traditional way, but with the new backward utility process.

Definition 6.6 (Backward early exercise indifference price) Let T < T bethe expiration date of the American contract with intrinsic payoff Ct, written attime t0, t0 ≤ t ≤ T . For t ∈ [t0; T ], the backward early exercise indifference priceprocess νa,Bt (C;T ) satisfies the pricing condition:

UBt (x+ νa,Bt (C;T );T ) = supA,τ

EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft], (6.50)

103

Page 115: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

for all x ∈ R, Xt = x.

Theorem 38 The backward early exercise indifference price νa,Bt (C;T ) satisfies:

νa,Bt (C;T ) = νa,B(St, Yt, t), (6.51)

with function νa,B(S, y, t) : R+×R× [t0; T ]→ R being the unique bounded viscositysolution of the following variational inequality:

min−νa,Bt − Lmeνa,B + 12γ(1− ρ2)a(y)2(νa,By )2, νa,B − C(S, y) = 0,

νa,B(S, y, T ) = C(S, y).(6.52)

with Lme defined earlier in (6.24).

Proof. We assume that indifference prices and other functions we define and use inthis are sufficiently differentiable. The formal arguments presented herein could bemade rigorous in the viscosity sense. As shown in [42], the backward utility processsatisfies:

UBt (Xt;T ) = v0(Xt, Yt, t), (6.53)

where function v0(x, y, t) : R×R× [0;T ]→ R equals:

v0(x, y, t) = −e−γx+H(y,t;T ), (6.54)

where the process H(Yt, t;T ) represents the aggregate minimal entropy and thefunction H(y, t;T ) solves either of equations (6.21) or (6.22) defined above. Onthe other hand, following the classical control arguments, v0(x, y, t) satisfies thefollowing HJB equation on [t0; T ]:

v0t + max

π(12σ

2(y)π2v0xx + π(σ2(y)Sv0

xS + ρσ(y)a(y)v0xy + µ(y)v0

x)

+L(y)v0 = 0,v0(x, S, y, T ) = −e−γx−H(y,T ;T )

(6.55)

with Ly defined in (6.43). Using the classical stochastic control arguments, wededuce that the right hand side of (6.50) equals:

supA,τ

EP[UBτ (Xτ + Cτ ;T )/Ft] = v(Xt, St, Yt, t), (6.56)

104

Page 116: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

where function v(x, S, y, t) : R × R+ × R × [t0; T ] → R is the unique boundedviscosity solution of the following variational inequality:

min−vt −maxπ

(12σ

2(y)π2vxx + π(σ2(y)SvxS + ρσ(y)a(y)vxy + µ(y)vx)

−L(S,y)v, v − v0(x+ C(S, y), y, t) = 0,v(x, S, y, T ) = v0(x+ C(S, y), y, T ),

(6.57)In order for the pricing condition (6.50) to hold, we have to have that

v(x, S, y, t) = v0(x+ νa,B(S, y, t), y, t), t ∈ [t0; T ]. (6.58)

Plugging the right hand side of equation (6.58) into the HJB equation (6.57), andtaking (6.55) into account we get:

minv0x(x+ νa,B(S, y, t), S, y, t)

(−νa,Bt − Lmmνa,B

)−v0

xy(x+ νa,B(S, y, t), S, y, t)a2(y)(1− ρ2)νa,By−v0

xx(x+ νa,B(S, y, t), S, y, t)12a

2(y)(1− ρ2)(νa,By )2,

v0(x+ νa,B(S, y, t))− v0(x+ C(S, y), y, t) = 0.

(6.59)

Knowing the exact formula for v0(x, y, t), we differentiate it to get:

v0x(x+ νa,B(S, y, t)) = γe−γ(x+νa,B(S,y,t))−H(y,t;T ),

v0xx(x+ νa,B(S, y, t)) = −γ2e−γ(x+νa,B(S,y,t))−H(y,t;T ),

v0xy(x+ νa,B(S, y, t)) = γeγ(x+νa,B(S,y,t))−H(y,t;T )

(−Hy(y, t;T )

).

(6.60)

Equations (6.21), (6.22) and (6.19) together, imply that

Hy(y, t;T )(1− ρ2) +fy(y, t;T )f(y, t;T )

= 0, (6.61)

and thus

v0xy(x+ νa,B(S, y, t))(1− ρ2) = γeγ(x+νa,B(S,y,t))−H(y,t;T ) fy(y, t;T )

f(y, t;T ). (6.62)

Combining (6.59), (6.60) and (6.62) yields the result of the theorem

105

Page 117: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

The next theorem provides another representation of the indifference price, inthe form of non-linear functionals EQ(·) defined in (6.15). The proof follows closelyProposition 11 in [40] and is omitted here.

νa,Bt (C;T ) = supt0≤τ≤T

(EQme(C(Sτ , Yτ ))) . (6.63)

The result shown above exists in a similar form in our binomial setting, see sec-tion 5.2 theorem 34. In both cases, the continuous and the discrete binomial, thefunctionals characterizing the indifference value are nonlinear, become linear as riskaversion approaches 0, use the same (minimal entropy) martingale measure, andincorporate the stopping time in the same way, by taking the supremum of all pos-sible buyer’s prices obtained for different exercise times. A small difference is thatin continuous time the instantaneous correlation coefficient is incorporated into theformula explicitly, but in the discrete time it enter the formula implicitly throughthe joint distribution of the traded asset and the non-traded factor.

Our results show that the difference between the early exercise indifferenceprices with Backward and Forward preferences is inherited form their Europeancounterparts. Again, if the Sharpe ratio of the traded asset is constant, then thetwo variational inequalities (6.52) and (6.37) become the same, as is the case withtheir European counterparts.

106

Page 118: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 7

Extension of the discrete

dynamic forward algorithm to

partial exercise contracts.

This chapter is devoted to the discussion of the optimal early exercise strategy andthe price for situations when an agent us granted several American claims that hecould exercise several at a time. In a complete market, the classical no-arbitragepricing theory suggests that all of the available options have to be exercised at once.When the market is not complete, the additional unhedgeable risk carried by thecontract may cause the optimal exercise policy to be partial, even in the absenceof transaction costs or trading constraints. For example, [47] use expected utilityframework to show that the optimal number of options to be exercised could beonly a fraction of the total number held. In incomplete market this problem hasbeen studied extensively in recent years, especially in the context of employee stockoptions. Among the ones are [11] and [27], who use certainty-equivalent approach tovalue partial exercise contracts with non-traded assets. There, the opportunity toinvest in the market is not taken into consideration when the contracts are being val-ued. The next step in the development has become including in investor’s portfolioa correlated traded asset, to partially hedge the risk, as in [22] or [18]. [22] assumethat the Sharpe ratio is constant in continuous time; in discrete time [18] assumesthe probability distribution of the traded asset does not depend of the non-tradedrisk factor, and ξut , ξdt are constant. We take the analysis even further, by valuing

107

Page 119: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

the partially exercised contracts with the non-traded risk factor in a more general,non-reduced model with a dynamically changing agent’s utility function.

We assume at any time 0 ≤ t ≤ T −1, the buyer would exercise some numberof options, add the resulting cash amount to his wealth and then make an investmentdecision of how many shares of the traded asset to hold over the next period. Attime T the buyer only needs to make an exercise decision. As with early exercise,we assume the forward dynamic utility function specified in section 4.1, and that bythe terminal time all of the options must be exercised. We also assume the interestrate is zero. We denote the relevant variables as follows:N - total number of options to be exercised on [0, T ],nt - number of options to be exercised up to and including time t,βt - number of options to be exercised at time t,αt - number of shares of traded asset to hold on [t− 1, t),Xt - total wealth of the option holder at time t (before exercise takes place at timet)x - investor’s initial wealth at time 0,Ct - time t intrinsic payoff of each exercised option, Ct = C(St, Yt).With the assumptions above, investor’s wealth accumulates according to

Xt = x+t−1∑i=0

Ciβi +t∑i=1

αt(Si − Si−1), (7.1)

and

Xt+1 = Xt + βtCt + αt(St − St−1). (7.2)

Non-negative option exercise strategy β = (β0, ..., βT ) has to satisfyT∑t=0

βi = N .

Definition 7.1 We define the value function of the options holder as his maximalexpected terminal wealth conditioned on the currently available market information,i.e.

V C(Xt, nt−1, t; s) = supβt,...,βT

supαt+1,...,αT

E[UFT

(XT + βTCT ; s)/Ft] (7.3)

Throughout this chapter V C denotes the partial exercise value function (before V C

was used to denote the early exercise value function). The number of state variableshas increased by one compared to the early exercise case, taking into account thenumber of options exercised before time t.

108

Page 120: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

The definition above in the form of stochastic optimization problem is rathergeneral and we propose a simplified form of the value function, convenient for thederivation of the indifference price.

Theorem 39 (Value function with partial exercise) If the optimal strategiesαt+1, .., αT and βt, .., βT in stochastic control problem (7.3) exist for all t < T V C(Xt, nt−1, t; s) = sup

0≤βt≤N−nt−1

supαt+1

E[V C(Xt+1, nt−1 + βt, t+ 1; s)],

V C(XT , nT−1, T ; s) = UFT

(XT +N − nT−1; s).(7.4)

Proof. We prove the statement in two parts, by first showing that the left-handside of (7.3) is at least as big as its right-hand side and then by taking care of theopposite inequality.

We start with arbitrary βt and αt+1 to obtain Xt+1 = Xt+βtCt+αt+1(St+1−St). We then use β = (βt+1, ..., βT ) and α = (αt+2, ..., αT ) that are optimal in thesense of (7.3) for V C(Xt+1, nt−1 + βt, t+ 1). With the above choice of strategies,

EP[UFT

(XT + CTβT ; s)/Ft] = EP[EP[UFT

(XT + CTβt; s)/Ft+1]/Ft]] =EP[V C(Xt+1, nt−1 + βt, t+ 1)/Ft].

(7.5)

Clearly, α = (αt, α) and β = (βt, β) are not necessarily optimal for stochastic controlproblem (7.3), thus using (7.5)

V C(Xt, nt−1, t; s) ≥ EP[V C(Xt+1, nt−1 + βt, t+ 1; s)/Ft] (7.6)

for any Xt+1 = Xt + βtCt + αt+1(St+1 − St). Since the choice of βt and αt+1 wasarbitrary, the left-hand side of (7.3) is at least as big as its right-hand side. Toprove the opposite inequality, assume that α? and β? (and the corresponding X?

s ,t ≤ s ≤ T , constructed via (7.1)) solve (7.3) starting at time t with a wealth levelXt and and a remaining number of options to exercise N − nt−1. Then

V C(Xt, nt−1, t; s) = EP[EP[UFT

(X?T

+ CTβT ; s)/Ft+1]/Ft]] =

EP[EP[UFT

(X?t+1 +

T−1∑i=0

Ciβ?i +

T∑i=1

α?t (Si − Si−1) + β?TCT ; s)/Ft+1]/Ft]] =

≤ EP[V C(X?t+1, nt−1 + β?t , t+ 1; s)/Ft]

≤ sup0≤βt≤N−nt−1

supαt+1

EP[V C(X?t+1, nt−1 + β?t , t+ 1; s)/Ft]

(7.7)

109

Page 121: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

The next step is to define a family of pricing operators for the case of partialexercise. We start with a one-period operator.

Definition 7.2 Let Z = (Z0, ..., ZN ) be a vector of Ft+1-measurable random vari-ables and Q be the minimal martingale measure defined earlier in chapter 3. Thepartial exercise one-period pricing operator Pt,t+1(·) maps Z into a vector of Ft-measurable random variables Z = (Z0, ...,ZN ) so that the m-th component of Z

Zm = max0≤n≤N−m

Ctn+ E t,t+1Q (Zm+n), 0 ≤ m ≤ N. (7.8)

Note that m-th component of the image vector Z only depends on Zm, ..., ZN (anddoes not depend on the first m components of Z). Using the definition above werecursively construct the multi-period operator Pt,sQme(·), s > t.

Definition 7.3 The multi-period pricing operator maps a vector of Fs-measurablerandom variables Z = (Z0, ..., ZN ) into a vector of Ft-measurable random variablesZ = (Z0, ...,ZN ) so that

Zm = Pt,t+1Qme

(Pt+1,t+2

Qme(...Ps−2,s−1

Qme(Ps−1,s

Qme(Z))...))

. (7.9)

In other words, the multi-period pricing operator is a composit appropriate numberof one-period pricing operators.

Definition 7.4 We define the buyer’s indifference price pt(nt−1;C) of a partialexercise claim C initiated at t0 and expiring at T as the amount the that satisfiesthe pricing equation below:

V C(Xt, nt−1, t; s) = UFt (Xt + pt(nt−1;C); s), (7.10)

for all 0 ≤ nt−1 ≤ N .

Clearly, the indifference price at time t would depend on nt−1, the number of optionsexercised before time t. The pricing condition above defines an N + 1 - dimensionalvector of indifference prices pt(C) = (pt(0;C), ..., pt(N ;C)). In what follows we useboth, the vector notation and component-wise notation for the indifference price.We are now ready to present the main results of this chapter, analogous to the onesthat have already been shown for American claims.

110

Page 122: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Theorem 40 (Indifference price with partial exercise) (i) The buyer’s indif-ference price with partial exercise satisfies the recursive formula:

pT (C) = CT · N , N = (N,N − 1, ..., 0),pt(C) = Pt,t+1

Qme (pt+1(C)), t < T .(7.11)

(ii) The time t buyer’s indifference price is given by:pT (C) = CT · N ,pt(C) = Pt,TQme(CT · N), N = (N,N − 1, ..., 0), t < T .

(7.12)

(iii) Buyer’s indifference price is time-consistent, i.e.

pt(C) = Pt,sQme(Ps,TQme

(CT · N

))= Pt,sQme (ps(C)) = pt(Ps,TQme(CT · N)). (7.13)

Proof. (i) We confirm the statement for t = T , T − 1 and T − 2. The rest couldbe carried out via induction arguments. At time T ,

V C(XT , nT−1, T ) = UFT

(XT + CT ·m; s),m = 0, ..., N, (7.14)

and the statement follows easily using the definition 7.4.At time T − 1,

V C(XT−1, nT−2, T − 1; s) =sup

0≤βT−1≤N−nT−2

supαT

EP[V C(XT , nT−2 + βT−1, T ; s)/FT−1] =

sup0≤βT−1≤N−nT−2

supαT

EP[UFT

(XT + CT · (N − nT−2 − βT−1); s)/FT−1].

(7.15)

Expression supαT

EP[U(XT + CT · (N − nT−2 − βT−1), T ; s)/FT−1] can be viewed as

the one-period value function of an investor who holds a European derivative CT ·(N −nT−2− βT−1) expiring at time T . Therefore, based on the previous results for

111

Page 123: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

European claims,

V C(XT−1, nT−2, T − 1; s) =

sup0≤βT−1≤N−nT−2

UFT−1

(XT−1 + E T−1,TQ (CT · (N − nT−2 − βT−1)); s) =

UFT−1

(XT−1 + sup0≤βT−1≤N−nT−2

E T−1,TQ (CT · (N − nT−2 − βT−1)); s),

(7.16)

Since the forward utility function is monotone in wealth. Comparison of (7.16)evaluated at XT−1 − pT−1(nT−2;C) to UF

T−1(XT−1; s) yields

pT−1(nT−2;C) = sup0≤βT−1≤N−nT−2

E T−1,TQ (CT · (N − nT−2 − βT−1)) =

sup0≤n≤N−m

E T−1,TQ (CT · (N − (m+ n)) = sup

0≤n≤N−mE T−1,T

Q (pT (m+ n;C))).

(7.17)At time T − 2, using the simplified form (7.4) of the partial exercise value function,

V C(XT−2, nT−3, T − 2; s) =sup

0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

supαT−1

EP[V C(XT−1, nT−3 + βT−2, T − 1; s)]. (7.18)

Using the definition of pT−1(n;C),

V C(XT−1, nT−3 + βT−2, T − 1) =UFT−1

(XT−1 + pT−1(nT−3 + βT−2;C); s).(7.19)

Then,

V C(XT−2, nT−3, T − 2; s) =sup

0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

supαT−1

EP[UFT−1

(XT−1 + pT−1(nT−3 + βT−2;C); s)/FT−2]. (7.20)

The inner supremum in the expression above can be viewed as the time T − 2 one-period value function of an investor who holds the European claim pT−1(nT−3 +βT−2;C) expiring at T − 1. Then, using results for European payoffs of theorem 14of section 4.1 again and the definition of the forward dynamic utility UF of equation

112

Page 124: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

4.2 in section 4.1,

V C(XT−2, nT−3, T − 2; s) =

sup0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

UFT−1

(XT−2 + E T−2,T−1Q (pT−1(nT−3 + βT−2;C); s) =

UFT−1

(XT−2 + sup0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

E T−2,T−1Q (pT−1(nT−3 + βT−2;C)); s),

(7.21)

and (i) is confirmed for t = T − 2.(ii) For t = T and t = T − 1, statements (i) and (ii) coincide, so it only remains toshow (ii) for t = T − 2. We start as in (i) and arrive to (7.18) and (7.20). As shownbefore,

pT−1(nT−3 + βT−2;C) =

sup0≤n≤N−nT−3−βT−2

E T−1,TQ (pT (nT−3 + βT−2 + n;C))). (7.22)

Therefore,

V C(XT−2, nT−3, T − 2; s) = sup0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

supαT−1

EP[UFT−1

(XT−1+

sup0≤n≤N−nT−3−βT−2

E T−1,TQ (pT (nT−3 + βT−2 + n;C)); s)]

= sup0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

UFT−1

(XT−2+

E T−2,T−1Q ( sup

0≤n≤N−nT−3−βT−2

E T−1,TQ (pT (nT−3 + βT−2 + n;C))); s)

= UFT−2

(XT−2 + sup0≤βT−2≤N−nT−3

E T−2,T−1Q ( sup

0≤n≤N−nT−3−βT−2

E T−1,TQ (pT (nT−3 + βT−2 + n;C)))); s)

= UFT−2

(XT−2 + ZnT−3; s),

(7.23)

where ZnT−3is the nT−3-th component of P T−2,T

Qme (pT (C)).V C(XT−2 + pT−2(nT−3;C), nT−3, T − 2; s) can be computed similarly and,

compared to UFT−2

(XT−2; s), yields

pT−2(C) = P T−2,TQme (pT (C)). (7.24)

(iii) The proof of the last part follows from part (ii) and the definition of operatorsPt,sQme(·)

113

Page 125: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

The formula for the partial exercise operator (7.8) translates into choosing thenumber of options to be exercised this period in such a way that indifference valueof the next periods partial exercise price is maximized. If the investor holds only oneunit of the American contract, and the only two alternatives available for the investoreach period are to exercise one unit of options or none, then the maximum in formula(7.8) reduces to the maximum over C(St, Yt) and the next periods indifference valueof one American contract. That exactly the early exercise algorithm we derived forAmerican claims earlier, meaning that the current algorithm is an extension of theone developed herein for American contracts.

The one-period pricing operators, defined in chapter 2 equation (2.9) underthe minimal martingale measure, create a foundation for the early exercise andpartial exercise pricing algorithms. As a result, all of the natural properties of theEuropean indifference prices are transferred onto pricing of contracts with partialexercise. One could rigorously show that the partial exercise algorithm yields pricesthat are monotone in risk aversion(i.e., the more risk averse investor would agreepay a lower price). Also, as before, the nonlinearities in the pricing would go awayif the risk aversion level becomes very small, or if the non-traded risk factor is in”perfect correlation” with the traded stock.

114

Page 126: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 8

Examples of numerical

implementation.

This chapter is devoted to numerical implementation of the derived algorithm forEuropean and American derivatives. We consider several examples with non-tradedassets that show dependence of the indifference price on correlation between thetraded and the non-traded asset, dependence on risk aversion, demonstrate the dif-ference between the prices for the American and European contracts of the samelength, and show the difference between prices with backward and forward prefer-ences.

Our first model example is the discrete time analog of the continuous timemodel consisting of the traded asset S and non-traded stochastic factor Y , satisfyingtheir corresponding SDEs as:

dSt = µStdt+ σStdW1t ,

dYt = bYtdt+ aYtdW2t ,

(8.1)

with dW 1t and dW 2

t being the two Brownian motions correlated with a coefficient ρ.In this example, µ, σ, b, a and ρ are constant. According to the chosen framework

115

Page 127: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

we construct a binomial tree with the following parameters:

ξut = 1 + µdt+ σ√dt,

ξdt = 1 + µdt− σ√dt,

ηut = 1 + bdt+ a√dt,

ηdt = 1 + bdt− a√dt

(8.2)

with −σ < µ√dt < σ, −a < b

√dt < a and dt = T/N . Also, for all 0 <= t <= T ,

P (St = Sut /Ft−1) = 0.5,

P (Yt = Y ut /Ft−1 ∨ FSt ) =

1 + ρ2 , St = Sut ,

1− ρ2 , St = Sdt .

(8.3)

Note that with such a set of parameters

EP [ξt/Ft−1] = 1 + µ,

EP [ηt/Ft−1] = 1 + b+ a√dt · (2P (Yt = Y u

t /Ft−1)− 1) =1 + b+ a

√dt · (2 · (P (Yt = Y u

t /Ft−1 ∨ St = Sut ) · P (St = Sut /Ft−1)+P (Yt = Y u

t /Ft−1 ∨ St = Sdt ) · P (St = Sdt /Ft−1))− 1) =

1 + b+ a√dt · (2 · (1 + ρ

2 · P (St = Sut /Ft−1)+1− ρ

2 · (1− P (St = Sut /Ft−1)))− 1) =1 + b+ a

√dtρ(2P (St = Sut /Ft−1)− 1) = 1 + b.

(8.4)

Thus,EP [∆St/Ft−1] = St−1µdt,

EP [∆Yt/Ft−1] = Yt−1bdt,

V ar[∆St/Ft−1] = S2t−1σ

2dt,

V ar[∆Yt/Ft−1] = Y 2t−1a

2dt.

(8.5)

Note also that

Cov[∆St,∆Yt/Ft−1] = St−1Yt−1aσdt

(P (St = Sut , Yt = Y ut /Ft−1) + P (St = Sdt , Yt = Y d

t /Ft−1)−P (St = Sut , Yt = Y d

t /Ft−1)− P (St = Sdt , Yt = Y ut /Ft−1)) =

St−1Yt−1aσdt(1 + ρ

2 · 0.5 +(

1− 1− ρ2

)· 0.5−(

1− 1 + ρ2

)· 0.5− 1− ρ

2 · 0.5)

= St−1Yt−1aσdtρ,

(8.6)

116

Page 128: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

and therefore

Cor[∆St,∆Yt/Ft−1] = ρ. (8.7)

In this example, the historical probability distribution of the next period’s increasein the level of the traded asset S, given the currently available market information,is constant throughout time and equals 0.5. As confirmed by the theoretical resultsof the previous chapters, the minimal martingale measure and the minimal entropymeasure then coincide. In this example we will be referring to that measure as theminimal martingale measure Qmm, that satisfies:

Qmm(St = Sut /Ft−1) = 1− ξdtξut − ξdt

= 12 −

µ√dt

2σ . (8.8)

For the non-traded risk factor

Qmm(Yt = Y ut /Ft−1) =

Qmm(Yt = Y ut /Ft−1 ∨ S = Sut ) ·Qmm(St = Sut /Ft−1)+

Qmm(Yt = Y ut /Ft−1 ∨ S = Sdt ) ·Qmm(St = Sdt /Ft−1) =

P (Yt = Y ut /Ft−1 ∨ S = Sut ) ·Qmm(St = Sut /Ft−1)+

P (Yt = Y ut /Ft−1 ∨ S = Sdt ) ·Qmm(St = Sdt /Ft−1) =

1 + ρ2 ·

(12 −

µ√dt

)+ 1− ρ

2 ·(

1−(

12 −

µ√dt

))=

12 − ρ

µ√dt

2σ .

(8.9)

The graphs shown in Figure 8.1 is a plot of the indifference price of the Europeanbasket call option. We used µ = b = 0, σ = 0.2, a = 0.4, γ = 0.5 and 0.2, ρ varyingfrom −1 to 1 with a step size of 0.2. The call matures in 1 month and we used100 time steps to make the graph. The graph shows both, the writer’s price curves,the buyer’s price curves for two different risk aversion values, and the ”risk-neutral”price(i.e., the expectation of the contracts payoff under the minimal martingalemeasure). The highest curve on the graph corresponds to the writer’s price when γequals to 0.5. The lowest curve is the buyer’s price for γ = 0.5. The middle curve isthe ”risk-neutral” price, and the two curves immediately above and below the ”risk-neutral” curve are the writer’s and buyer’s prices for γ = 0.2. The graph shows thatprices are monotone with respect to risk aversion, and show a dependence on thecorrelation between the asset and the non-traded factor. The dependence on the

117

Page 129: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

correlation is non-linear, and not always monotone, as for example with γ = 0.5. Asconfirmed theoretically, the dependence on γ is monotone, and the price is higherfor a more risk averse writer, the opposite being true for the buyer. Also note thatindependently γ, the prices coincide when ρ = 1 or ρ = −1. In the case of perfectcorrelation or perfect anti-correlation, the distribution of the non-traded factor giventhe value of the traded stock is known with certainty. For those values of correlation,the nonlinearity of the indifference goes away independently of what the level of riskaversion is. Thus, as confirmed in Figure 8.1, at ρ = 1 or ρ = −1, indifference pricesare the same for all values of γ.

Figure 8.2 confirms results computed with binomial model by comparingthem against results obtained for the original continuous model (8.1). The green(upper) curve represents the output obtained with our binomial algorithm for thesame parameters as in Figure 8.1 with γ = 0.5 for the writer’s price. The blue(lower) curve represents the indifference value of the same contract computed as asolution of the nonlinear indifference price PDE, using the method developed by[44]. The method uses an explicit finite difference scheme, with the spacial stepsize of 0.1 in both S and Y , and time step size of 0.0002. For more details on theimplementation of indifference priced via solutions of PDEs we refer the reader to[44]. As seen from the graph, the two outputs are the same at least up to twosignificant digits. Thus the two methods could be used to cross-check each other’sresults.

The graph in Figure 8.3 shows a family of curves that represent prices ofAmerican put option on a non-traded risk factor, maturing at T with a strike priceK, shown as a function of initial risk factor value Y0. We used the following datato make the graph: µ = σ = 1, a = b = 1, T = 1, N = 100, K = 1, γ = 0.1.The parameters used are the same as in [44]. The upper most curve on the graphcorresponds to ρ = 1 and the lower most curve to ρ = −1. Clearly, the value of theput option decreases in Y0, as expected. Also, the price of a put option is monotonein the correlation between the traded stock and the risk factor. As ρ increases from−1 to 1, the conditional on time t probability of Y going up (under the minimalentropy measure Qmm) decreases, as computed via equation (8.9):

Qmm(Yt = Y ut /Ft−1) = 1

2 − ρµ√dt

2σ . (8.10)

118

Page 130: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

−1 −0.8 −0.6 −0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75Basket option price vs correlation

Correlation

Indi

ffere

nce

pric

e

Figure 8.1: Dependence of Indifference price on correlation and risk aversion

119

Page 131: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

−1 −0.8 −0.6 −0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7Indifference price of a basket call option

Correlation

Price

continuous time solution

Discrete time solution

Figure 8.2: Binomial and Continuous implementation for a basket call option

120

Page 132: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Thus, when ρ increases, the put option on the non-traded risk factor gains value,which is what we see in the graph of Figure 8.3. In addition, shown in the same graphis initial intrinsic value (Y0−K)+ of the put, as a function of Y0 (solid black line). Asit should be with an American option, the price of the option is always greater thanits intrinsic value. Figure 8.3 indicates position of the free boundary. According tothe graph, in-the-money put may be exercised if the correlation between the stockand the factor is small enough, especially if negative.

Figures 8.4-8.6 shows selected curves for both European and American op-tions together for direct comparison. The graph of Figure 8.4 corresponds to ρ = 1.In that case the probability of Y going up reaches its maximum value and there isno incentive for the buyer to exercise the option early. Thus, the prices of Euro-pean and American options coincide. The graph in Figure 8.5 shows European andAmerican options for ρ = 0. The probability of Y going up is now smaller thanin the upper graph of the Figure 8.4 and thus there are more incentives to exercisethe option early, which results in a bigger difference in between the European andthe American prices. For the graph in Figure 8.6, the correlation is set to −1 andthe difference between the American and the European option prices becomes evenmore pronounced.

In the previous model example (as given by 8.2 and 8.3), dynamics of thetraded asses were such that the probability distribution of the next period’s valueof the asset is not affected by the path of the non-traded factor, and constant ξut ,ξdt , that is the assumption 10 of chapter 3 holds. As a result, there is no differencebetween the indifference prices obtained with either forward or backward dynamicpreferences. To provide an example where the two are in fact different, we slightlymodify the previous reduced model example by re-defining the historical probabilityof the upward traded asset movement to be

P(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft) = 0.5 exp((Yt − Y0)dt). (8.11)

That way, if Yt > Y0, the probability of S going up would be slightly bigger then 0.5,and slightly smaller then 0.5 otherwise. This example may not have the continuoustime limit as dt approaches 0, but it is well suited for our purpose of demonstratingthe difference between the Forward and the Backward prices. With this example, weconfirm that our algorithm produces forward price that is greater then the backward.

121

Page 133: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 20

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Indifference price of the American contract

Initial value of risk factor Y0 in dollars

Pric

e in

dol

lars

ρ = 1

ρ = −1

ρ changes from −1 to 1

with a stepsize of 0.5

Figure 8.3: Position of the early exercise boundary in a survey over correlation

122

Page 134: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 20

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Initial value of risk factor Y0 in dollars

Price

in

do

llars

Perfect agreement for the European and American contracts, rho=1

European contract

American contract

Intrinsic value

Figure 8.4: European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on corre-lation

123

Page 135: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 20

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Initial value of risk factor Y0 in dollars

Price

in

do

llars

Price difference for the European and American contracts, rho=0

European contract

American contract

Intrinsic value

Figure 8.5: European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on corre-lation

124

Page 136: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 20

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Initial value of risk factor Y0 in dollars

Price

in

do

llars

Price difference for the European and American contracts, rho=−1

European contract

American contract

Intrinsic value

Figure 8.6: European vs American equal maturity put prices, dependence on corre-lation

125

Page 137: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

We again use basket call option with a = 0.4, γ = 0.75, µ = 0.05, S0 = Y0 = 10,K = 20, σ = 0.2, ρ = 0.5. Maturity of the call option is fixed at 1 month and thetime step is 1

12 · 60. We used the same discretization for ξt and ηt as in equation8.2, the same P(Yt = Y u

t /Ft−1) = 0.5, but P(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft) is not 0.5 but insteadgiven by equation (8.11).

Figure 8.7 shows the forward and the backward priced for the buyer(lowertwo curves) and the writer(upper two curves) of the fixed, 1 month maturity basketcall option with parameters as described above and investment horizon of 3 month.We plot the prices as functions of parameter ρ. The forward price turned out to begreater then the backward, for both the buyer and the writer, but we believe thismight not be generally the case. Also, in this case the difference is more pronouncedfor the buyer rather then for the writer.

To make Figure 8.8, we kept maturity of the call option fixed at 1 month,but let the trading horizon (that is, the normalization point for the backward pref-erences) vary form 1 month to 2 month. As a result, the calculated forward pricedid not show any changes, unlike the ”horizon-dependent” backward price, that wasdecreasing, the difference between the two getting bigger as the investment horizonincreased. Our numerical surveys indicate that the difference between the backwardand the forward price is small for shorter maturity contracts; it gets larger whenthe maturity of the option and the end of investment horizon become more apart.Whether for the writer, then the opposite would hold for the buyer, but it does notseem to necessarily be the case.

The next example presented here illustrates the partial exercise algorithmdeveloped in the earlier chapters. Investor holds a total of 50 put options on a non-traded risk factor. He should exercise all of the options by the maturity date of thecontract, which is a quarter of a year away from now. Before the maturity date, thereare 20 available equally spaced exercise periods, during which the investor couldexercise from 0 to 50 options. This example mostly uses the same discretizationas described above with the following parameters: a = 0.2, b = 0.05, γ = 0.5,µ = 0.05, S0 = 10, σ = 0.2, ρ = 0.5, K = 10. The discretization of the historicalprobability distribution is slightly different compared to the previous example. Here,

126

Page 138: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

−1 −0.9 −0.8 −0.7 −0.6 −0.5 −0.4 −0.3 −0.2 −0.1 00.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7Forward and Backward price of a basket call

parameter ρ

Indi

ffere

nce

price

Figure 8.7: Backward and Forward prices for basket call option

127

Page 139: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

0.08 0.09 0.1 0.11 0.12 0.13 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.170.7604

0.7606

0.7608

0.761

0.7612

0.7614

0.7616

0.7618

0.762

0.7622

0.7624The Forward and the Backward basket call prices vs time horizon

Time horizon

Indi

ffere

nce

price

Forward priceBackward price

Figure 8.8: Backward and Forward prices vs time horizon

128

Page 140: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

the conditional distribution of Yt+1 given St+1 is homogeneous in time and such that

P(Yt+1 = Y ut+1/Ft ∨ St+1) =

(1− ρ)

2 , for St+1 > St,(1 + ρ)

2 , for St+1 ≤ St(8.12)

and

P(St+1 = Sut+1/Ft) =

0.55, for Yt+1 > Y0,

0.45, for Yt+1 ≤ Y0

(8.13)

With such choice of the historical distribution, the distribution of the traded assetis affected by the non-traded factor. Therefore, the backward and forward priceswould not coincide.

Figures 8.9, 8.10 and 8.11 present the forward partial exercise price, theoptimal number of options to hold and the optimal investment policy, all as functionsof the initial value of the non-traded risk factor Y 0 and the number of time periodsleft until maturity of the contract. Y0 changes from 9.9 to 10.1. The graphs showthat the price decreases with the current non-traded factor value Y0 and increaseswith time to maturity.

In a complete market, all of the contracts held should be exercised at once.In this example, contract’s payoff depends on the non-traded risk factor. As aresult, the optimal exercise policy is indeed partial, as shown in figure 8.10. Theoptimal number of options to hold increases with Y0, since a higher initial value of Y0

reduces the payoff of put option units exercised immediately. The optimal number ofoptions to hold also decreases with time to maturity. The optional investment policyindicates holding less shares of traded stock for a higher level of the non-traded riskfactor, and also less shares of the traded asset for longer contract’s maturity.

One of the applications for non-reduced discrete binomial model developedin the earlier chapters would be to the models stochastic volatility, such as Hestonmodel, originated in [23], in which the traded asset and the non-traded stochasticprocess satisfy:

dSt = µStdt+ St√YtdW

1t ,

dYt = κ(σ − Yt)dt+√YtdW

2t ,

(8.14)

where dW 1t and dW 2

t are the two Brownian motions correlated with an instantaneouscorrelation coefficient ρ. One could discretize SDEs for S and Y in a way similar tothe earlier examples, but in that case parameters ξut and ξdt would depend on the

129

Page 141: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

9.9

9.95

10

10.05

10.1

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.251

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Current value of non−traded factor

Partial exercise indifference price

Time till maturity

Indi

ffere

nce

price

Figure 8.9: Partial exercise price for 50 put option on non-traded asset

130

Page 142: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

9.9 9.92 9.94 9.96 9.98 10 10.02 10.04 10.06 10.08 10.1

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.2510

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Current value of non−traded factor

Optimal number of options to keep

Time till maturity

Num

ber o

f opt

ions

Figure 8.10: Optimal number of options to hold

131

Page 143: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

9.9

9.95

10

10.05

10.1

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.255.4

5.5

5.6

5.7

5.8

5.9

6

6.1

6.2

Current value of non−traded factor

Optimal investment policy

Time till maturity

Trad

ed s

tock

sha

res

quan

tity

Figure 8.11: Optimal investment policy with partial exercise

132

Page 144: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

whole path from time 0 up to time t of the stochastic factor and the correspondingbinomial tree would not recombine. Working with non-recombining binomial treesrequires substantial computational resources and is not effective. A number of wayshave been suggested in the literature to reduce the problem to constructing binomialtrees that would recombine. A classical approach is to transform the stochasticequation above into a simpler one, using a different pair of stochastic variables, asin [24] for example. The transformation maps the variable St into St = f(St, Yt).Since function f in general, depends on the value of the non-traded factor, the newvariable St may not be perfectly replicable. With the transformation approach, ouralgorithm could not be applied to the new state variable S, implying that an efficientnumerical application of the algorithm to stochastic volatility models is yet to bedeveloped.

In continuous time, a stochastic volatility model is numerically implementedusing finite difference techniques for partial differential equations. Below we providean example of implementation of the early exercise indifference price with forwardpreferences in Heston stochastic volatility model shown above. We have used thefollowing parameters: K = 10, Y0 = 0.25, σ = 0.25, µ = 0.05, a = 0.5, κ = 1.0,γ = 0.5, ρ = −0.5, T = T = 1.2 years. The graph in figure 8.12 shows the earlyexercise indifference price for the buyer of the put option on the traded asset S witha strike K, as a function of the initial traded asset value S0 varying from 8 to 12with a step size of 1. the early exercise price is greater than the intrinsic payoff,and in decreasing in the initial traded asset value S0. Figure 8.12 also shows theoption’s intrinsic payoff, as a function of the initial traded asset value S0.

The partial differential equation that the indifference price with the forwardpreferences, νa,F satisfies has been derived in chapter (Reference) equation 6.37:

min−νa,Ft − Lmmνa,F + 12γ(1− ρ2)a(y)2(νa,Fy )2, νa,F − C(S, y) = 0,

νa,F (T ) = max(S −K, 0).(8.15)

with

Lmm =12S2y

∂2

∂S2 + ρSay∂2

∂S∂y+

12a2y

∂2

∂y2 + (κ(θ − y)− ρµa)∂

∂y(8.16)

We have made a change of variables S = S0 · eu, y = Y0 · ez , with u and z varyingfrom −3 to 3 with a step size of 0.05.

133

Page 145: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 120

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5American indifference price with Forward preferences

Initial traded asset value

Price

Figure 8.12: Forward indifference price for an American put

134

Page 146: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

With the above parameter values we have been able to see that the earlyexercise price almost coincides with the price of the corresponding European optionwith maturity at T . Therefore, with the model chosen and the parameters chosen,the call on the traded asset should never be exercised. We have discussed in section5.3, that in the non-reduced model, as the stochastic volatility model consideredabove, there may be situations when a call on the traded asset S would be exercisedearly, but with the above model parameters that is not the case. That may be anindiaction that the particular example used is numerically very close to satisfying areduced model condition. We also confirmed the above by computing the backwardand the forward prices directly. We have obtained, for example, the differenceon order of 0.1 and 0.2 percent for maturities of 0.9 and 1.2 years correspondingly.Those differences between the backward and the forward prices were not sufficient tobe above the error of the numerical implementation. However, there is a trend of thedifference between the two becoming larger as the length of the contract increases.The finite difference method we used is an explicit finite difference method of [44]. Ithas been specifically developed for early exercise contracts and satisfies the necessaryconditions for convergence. As for any explicit scheme, the time step size has tobe restricted in order for the numerical scheme to converge. To compute the pricefor a 1.2 year contract we had to use 6 · 103 steps with a time step of 2 · 10−4.Clearly, in order to have the contract length of a few years, too many time steps areneeded. We conclude that, to see a significant difference between the backward andthe forward price of a call option in a stochastic volatility model, a longer contractshould be considered, possibly with another finite difference scheme. To avoid timestep size restrictions, an implicit finite difference scheme may be chosen, togetherwith a penalty method to incorporate the early exercise feature.

135

Page 147: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Chapter 9

Conclusion and future work.

This thesis contributes to the vast literature on the valuation of derivative contractsin incomplete markets. We work with a special type of market incompleteness, inwhich the contract’s value is affected by the non-traded risk factor. The latter canaffect the value of the contract in two distinct ways, the first of which is throughthe functional form of the payoff; the second way is that the non-traded factor mayexplicitly enter the the dynamics of the traded asset. The first way is subtle andusually yields a simpler valuation procedure. The second way is more fundamentaland yields more involved pricing. The majority of explicit pricing results derived sofar have are for the first type of dependency. In this work we focused on the second,more fundamental type of dependence, and yet were able to preserve the explicitcharacter and tractability of our results.

The discrete time model project presented here was started shortly after theresults of [2] and [41] became available. The discrete model suggested in the latterreference served as a starting point for our work. We extended the model so that wecould separate the two types of dependence on the non-traded risk factor describedabove. Our model is also attractive in that its computational implementation uses awell-known and easily implementable method of computing the value of the optionon a binomial tree, originated in [8].

The original model of [41] is a reduced model. As a result, in that modelthe minimal entropy measure and the minimal martingale measure are the same,and the minimal entropy measure has a simpler characterization. In that modelthe local entropy terms (that are the discrete time analog of the Sharpe ratio)

136

Page 148: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

are not affected by the non-traded risk factor and the aggregate minimal entropyaccumulates using the linear operator (the expectation under the minimal entropymeasure). In our work, the reduced model assumption has been forfeited, openingthe way for the new characterization of the minimal entropy martingale measureand the new representation for the aggregate entropy. It turns out that in the non-reduced model, the minimal entropy measure has a more complex representationand the aggregate entropy is a nonlinear functional of the sum of the local entropyterms. Also, the two measures, the minimal martingale and the minimal entropy,are different. Explicit characterization of two measures has helped us to draw a cleardifference between them, and has had a significant impact on the pricing results.The new characterizations have also helped to reconcile our discrete time modelwith the continuous time model developed in [42] and [54].

Another common assumption in the literature considering the valuation ofcontracts in an incomplete market using utility maximization is the classical staticexponential utility function, which is usually fixed at contract’s expiration date.This is a somewhat restrictive assumption since it imposes a time constraint onthe maturities of contracts being priced. Also, it creates an artificial mispricing,since the two differently chosen investment horizons yield different prices for thesame contract. In an attempt to avoid the above difficulty, [42] introduced thenew concept of the forward dynamic utility in continuous time. The forward utilityallows the investment horizon and contract’s expiration to be different, and does notimpose any time constraints on the maturities of contracts. Motivated by the newconcept, we developed the multi-period pricing algorithm with the forward dynamicutility in discrete time. The indifference valuation has long been associated withthe minimal entropy measure, and the construction of [42] has made an unexpectedturn by showing that one can construct the utility process in such a way that theassociated pricing measure is the minimal martingale measure, and not the minimalentropy one. That is also the case with our discrete time model, i.e., one can usethe minimal martingale measure as the pricing measure and the indifference pricingframework combined, with all their attractive properties.

Another way to extend the classical static exponential utility to a dynamicone is to use the so-called plain investment value function discussed in chapter2. As [42] suggest and as we confirmed in the discrete time model, the dynamicutility chosen in the above way satisfies the self-generation property and thus is

137

Page 149: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

consistent across different investment horizons. The above utility has been termedthe backward dynamic utility process. In this work we constructed its discreteversion in a more general, non-reduced model.

Working with both forward and backward dynamic utilities, we developed adiscrete time algorithm for valuing, first European, and then American, and partialexercise contracts. The forward and backward valuation algorithms are similar inthat both are iterative and compute the prices backward in time, starting at thecontract’s expiration. They have the same structure, in that at each valuation stepthere are two sub-steps: the first one that prices the non-hedgeable risk with condi-tional certainty equivalents and the second prices linearly the remaining hedgeablerisk. When the market becomes complete, the first sub-step does not come into ef-fect and both forward and backward prices reduce to the arbitrage-free price. Withboth utilities, the form of the nonlinear pricing functional is time-invariant, anddependence on the normalization points or the end of the investment horizon canonly enter through the measure used for pricing.

There are, however, some important differences. The most immediate differ-ence is that the algorithms use different pricing measures, the minimal martingalemeasure for the forward and the minimal entropy measure for the backward. Inthis work we provided explicit characterization for both of these measures. We haveshown that the property of preserving the historical probability distribution of thenon-traded risk factor, given the next period’s value of the traded stock, belongsto the minimal martingale measure, and not to the minimal entropy measure, aswas originally derived in the reduced model of [41]. The above characterization ofthe minimal martingale measure is time-invariant. Since both the minimal mar-tingale measure characterization and the form of the forward valuation algorithmare time-invariant, the forward indifference prices are independent of the forwardnormalization point, even though the forward dynamic utility itself is dependent onit. For the minimal entropy measure, the story is quite different. As our explicitcharacterization shows, the minimal entropy measure is dependent on the end ofthe investment horizon, at which time point the backward utility is normalized.As a result, even though the backward algorithm structure itself is time-invariant,the backward indifference prices are not. In addition, the characterization of theminimal martingale measure is simpler and more natural, rather than the minimalentropy one. Altogether, these factors make the forward dynamic utility a better

138

Page 150: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

candidate for valuing contracts affected by the non-traded risk factor.We provided an explicit formula that shows how the backward and forward

prices for European claims are related. We have shown that the backward priceequals the difference of the two forward prices. The first is the price of an adjustedpayoff, equal to contract’s payoff less the entropy. The second is the price of a payoffequal to the entropy. Clearly, in a complete market the backward and forward pricesare the same. We have shown that in the reduced model the two prices are the sameas well. Also, in the reduced model the two measures, the minimal entropy measureand the minimal martingale measure coincide. Therefore both the backward andthe forward utility pricing schemes are the direct extensions of the reduced modelto a more general one.

We found that a number of continuous time results of [42] have their analogsin our binomial model. In particular, there is a clear analogy between the Sharperatio of the traded asset in continuous time and the local entropy terms in discretetime. This analogy starts with the structural similarity of the forward and backwardutilities, and continues in the formulas for the aggregate entropy, and the reducedmodel condition. The continuous time model suggests that the entropy accumulatesas a nonlinear functional of the integrated squared Sharpe ratio under the minimalmartingale measure. This is similar to our discrete time model where the aggregateentropy is the nonlinear functional of the sum of local entropy terms. In the contin-uous model, if the Sharpe ratio is constant, then the backward and forward pricesare the same. In discrete time, if the local entropy terms are constant, the twoprices are the same as well. In addition, the continuous time model suggests pricingwith forward utility via the nonlinear PDE associated with the minimal martingalemeasure, and the discrete time model suggests using the nonlinear pricing functionalunder same measure. We have also shown the above analogy between the discreteand continuous models for the backward utility and the minimal entropy measure.

The above similarities concern not only the European contracts, but alsothe early exercise contracts. We have shown that with both the backward andforward utilities in continuous time, there are values of the traded stock and thenon-traded factor, for which the American price equals the intrinsic payoff of thecontract. For other values of the traded stock and the non-traded risk factor, theEuropean nonlinear PDE for the corresponding (backward or forward) indifferenceprice holds. Similarly, in the discrete time model, for some values of S and Y ,

139

Page 151: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

the price equals C(S, Y ). For others, the current indifference value is computed asthe nonlinear functional of the next period’s price. Another similarity we found isthat the continuous time price of an American security is the supremum over allpossible exercise times times of European prices of contracts with the maturity thatcorresponds to a particular stopping time. We have been able to derive the aboveresult with both the forward and backward utility in discrete and continuous time.

For American contracts, in addition to the indifference value, we derived theoptimal stopping time an the exercise policy. We have shown that it is optimalto exercise the American contract when the indifference value of alternative ”tocontinue” crosses the level of the intrinsic payoff. The optimal hedging policy isthe one that maximizes the next period’s indifference value of the contract held,provided the contract will not be exercised immediately. With the forward utility,we have extended our algorithm to allow for partial exercise. Unlike in the completemarket, since the non-traded stochastic factor affects the traded stock dynamics,partial exercise may be optimal. We provided a numerical example where indeed,only a fraction of all the contracts held is optimal to exercise.

In the non-reduced version of our binomial model, ξut+1 and ξdt+1 are allowedto depend on the path of the stochastic factor up to time t. Conditional on timet, the time t + 1 probability distribution of the traded asset is allowed to dependon the path of the non-traded risk factor up to time t as well. This makes ourmodel a suitable application to stochastic volatility models, like Hull-White ([26]),Heston model ([23]), and other models. Our binomial model requires to discretizethe original continuous time dynamics. For a simple continuous model, where thetraded stock and the non-traded factor are both lognormal processes, the discretizedversion of the model has parameters ξt an ηt that ate constant, and the binomial treeimplementation is straight forward, as examples of chapter 8 confirm. In a stochasticvolatility model, the non-traded factor Yt affects the value of ξt+1. As a result, thebinomial tree built in a straight-forward way would not recombine. In this casethe direct application of the binomial model to the state variables S and Y wouldlead to computationally intractable numerical procedure. A number of specializedways for building recombining binomial trees for stochastic volatility models havebeen developed in the literature, including the works of [24], [43], and recently in[12]. The idea behind those papers in to transform existing state variables S andY into new ones, and to generate paths of two new Brownian motions so that the

140

Page 152: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

binomial tree in the new variables recombines. The original state variables are thenapproximated via the inverse transformation of the new ones. The new, transformedvariables may both depend on the non-traded risk factor, and our framework ofone traded asset and one non-traded factor may not be applicable directly. Theabove indicates that more research is needed to be able to implement indifferencepricing with stochastic volatility models in the discrete time model like the onewe considered herein. The implementation using binomial trees is very intuitiveand thus attractive, and has been used by industry practitioners for decades. Ourdiscrete time algorithm definitely allows for an easy numerical implementation ina reduced model, as confirmed by examples provided herein. For the non-reducedmodel we have made the next necessary step of extending the theoretical derivations,creating a foundation for pricing via utility indifference in a more general class ofmodels with binomial trees.

141

Page 153: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Bibliography

[1] K. Aase. The perpetual american put option for jump-diffusions with applica-tions. Working paper, 2005.

[2] D. Becherer. Rational hedging and valuation of integrated risks under constantabsolute risk aversion. Insurance : Mathematics and Economics, 33(1):1–28,2003.

[3] F. Benth and K. Karlsen. A pde representation of the density of the minimalentropy martingale measure in stochastic volatility markets. Stochastics andStochastics Reports, 77(2):109–137, 2005.

[4] D. Bertsimas, L. Kogan, and A. Lo. Pricing derivative securities in incompletemarkets: an ε-arbitrage approach. Operations Research, 50(2):358–374, 2002.

[5] F. Black and M. Scholes. Pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journalof Political Economy, 81:637–654, 1973.

[6] S. Boyarchenko and S. Levendorkii. Practical guide to real options in discretetime. To appear in International Economic Review, 2007.

[7] P. Chalasani. Randomized stopping times and american option pricing withtransaction costs. Mathematical Finance, 1(1):33–77, 2001.

[8] J. Cox, S. Ross, and M. Rubinstein. Option pricing: a simplified aproach.Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 1979.

[9] M. Davis and T. Zariphopoulou. American options and transaction fees. InMathematical Finance, IMA Volumes in Mathematics and Its applications.Springer-Verlag, 1995.

142

Page 154: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

[10] F. Delbaen, T. Rheinlander, D. Samperi, M. Schweizer, C. Stricker, andP. Grandits. Exponential hedging and entropic penalties. Mathematical Fi-nance, 12(2):99–123, 2002.

[11] J. Detemple and S. Sundaresan. Nontraded asset valuation with portfolio con-strains: a binomial approach. Review of Financial Studies, 12(3):835872, 1999.

[12] Moretto E., S. Pasquali, and Trivellato B. Derivative evaluation using recom-bining trees under stochastic volatility. Working paper, 2006.

[13] R. Elliott and J. van der Hoek. Pricing claims on non-tradable assets. Con-temporary Mathematics, 351:103–114, 2004.

[14] J. Evans, V. Henderson, and Hobson D. Optimal timing for an indivisible assetsale. To appear in Mathematical Finance, 2007.

[15] W. Fleming and Soner M. Controlled Markov processes and viscosity solutions.Springer-Verlag, 1993.

[16] M. Fritelli. The minimal entropy martingale measure and the valuation problemin incomplete markets. Mathematical Finance, 10(1):39–52, 2000.

[17] P. Grandits and T. Rheinlander. On the minimal entropy martingale measure.The Annals of Probability, 30(3):1003–1038, 2002.

[18] M. Grasselli. Nonlinearity, correlation and the valuation of employee stockoptions. In preparation, 2006.

[19] D. Heath and E. Platen. A comparison of two quadratic aproaches to hedgingin incomplete markets. Mathematical Finance, 11(4):385–413, 2001.

[20] V. Henderson. Valuing the option to invest in an incomplete market. To appearin Mathematics and Financial Economics, 2007.

[21] V. Henderson and D. Hobson. Horizon unbiased utility functions. StochasticProcesses and Applications, 117(11):1621–1641, 2007.

[22] V. Henderson and D. Hobson. Risk aversion, effort and block exercise of exec-utive stock options. Working paper, 2007.

143

Page 155: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

[23] S. Heston. A closed-form solution for options with atochastiv volatilities withapplication to bond and currency options. The Review of Financial Studies,6:281–300, 1993.

[24] J. Hillard and Shwartz A. Binomial option pricing under stochastic volatilityand correlated state variables. Journal of Derivatives, Fall:23–39, 1996.

[25] D. Hobson. Stochastic volatility models, correlation and the q-optimal measure.Mathematical Finance, 14(4):537–556, 2004.

[26] J. Hull and A. White. The pricing of options with stochastic volatilities. TheJournal of Finance, 42:281–300, 1987.

[27] A. Jain and A. Subramanian. The intertemporal exercise and valuation ofemployee options. The Accounting Review, 79(3):705743, 2004.

[28] Y. Kabanov and Stricker C. On the optimal portfolio for the exponential util-ity, maximization: remarks to the six-author paper. Mathematical Finance,12(2):125–134, 2002.

[29] I. Karatzas and H. Wang. Utility maximization with discretionary stopping.SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 39(1):306–329, 2000.

[30] N. Krylov. Controlled diffusion processes. Springer-Verlag, 1980.

[31] C. Kuhn, A. Kyprianou, and K. van Schaik. Pricing israeli options: a pathwiseapproach. Stochastics An International Journal of Probability and StochasticProcesses, 79(1 and 2):117–137, 2007.

[32] C. Kunh. Pricing contingent claims in incomplete markets, when the holdercan choose among different payoffs. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics,31:251–233, 2002.

[33] K. Lau and Y. Kwok. Valuation of employee reload options using utility max-imization aproach. Internationa Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance,8(5):659 – 674, 2005.

[34] T. Leung and R. Sircar. Accounting for risk aversion, vesting, job terminationrisk and multiple exercises in valuation of employee stock options. To appearin Mathematical Finance, 2007.

144

Page 156: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

[35] P. Li and J. Xia. Minimal martingale measure for discrete-time incompletemarkets. Acta Matimaticae Applicatae Sinica, English Series, 18(2):349–352,2002.

[36] R. Merton. Lifetime portfolio selection uder uncertainty: the continuous timemodel. Review of Economic Studies, 51:247–257, 1969.

[37] R. Merton. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica,41:867–887, 1973.

[38] M. Musiela, E. Sokolova, and Zariphopoulou T. Indifference pricing underforward valuation criteria: the case study of the binomial model. In preparation,2007.

[39] M. Musiela, E. Sokolova, and Zariphopoulou T. Indifference valuation in in-complete binomial models. In preparation, 2007.

[40] M. Musiela and T. Zariphopoulou. Indifference prices of early exercse claims.Contemporary Mathematics, 351:259–272, 2003.

[41] M. Musiela and T. Zariphopoulou. A valuation algorithm for indifference pricesin incomplete markets. Finance and Stochastics, 8(3):399–414, 2004.

[42] M. Musiela and T. Zariphopoulou. Investment and valuation under backwardand forward dynamic exponential utilities in a stochastic factor model. Ad-vances in Mathematical Finance, pages 303–334, 2007.

[43] D. Nelson and K. Ramaswamy. Simple binomial processes as diffusion approx-imations in financial models. The Review of Financial Studies, 3(3):393430,1990.

[44] A. Oberman and T. Zariphopoulou. Pricing early exercise contracts in incom-plete markets. Computational Management Science, 1(1):75–107, 2003.

[45] H. Pham, T. Rheinlander, and M. Schweizer. Mean-variance hedging for contin-uous processes: new proofs and examples. Finance and Stochastics, 2:173–198,1998.

[46] R. Rouge and El Karoui N. Pricing via utility maximization and entropy.Mathematical Finance, 10(2):259–276, 2000.

145

Page 157: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

[47] J. Scheinkman and L.C.G. Rogers. Optimal exercise of executive stock options.Finance and Stochastics, 11(3):357–372, 2007.

[48] E. Schwartz and C. Tebaldi. Illiquid assets and optimal portfolio choice. NBERWorking paper, 2007.

[49] M. Schweizer. Variance-optimal hedging in discrete time. Mathematics of Op-erations Research, 20:1–32, 1993.

[50] M. Schweizer. On the minimal martingale measure and the fllmer-schweizerdecomposition. Stochastic Analysis and Aplications, 13:573–599, 1995b.

[51] S. Shreve. Stochastic Calculus for Finance I: The Binomial Asset PricingModel. Springer-Verlag, 2004.

[52] J. Smith and R. Nau. Valuing risky projects: option pricing theorey and deci-sion analysis. Management Science, 41(5):795–816, 1995.

[53] E. Sokolova and Zariphopoulou T. A note on the minimal martingale and theminimal entropy measures in incomplete binomial models. In preparation, 2007.

[54] S. Stoikov and T. Zariphopoulou. Optimal investments in the presence of un-hedgeable risks and uder cara preferences. Submitted for publication, 2005.

[55] A. Szimayer. Valuation of american optionsin the presence of event risk. Financeand Stochastics, 9:89–107, 2005.

[56] A. Takuji. The relation between the minimal martingale measure and theminimal entropy measure. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, 8:167–177, 2001.

146

Page 158: Copyright by Ekaterina Sokolova 2007

Vita

Ekaterina Sokolova was born in Ivanovo, Russia on March 2 1978, the daughter of

Sergey Sokolov and Inessa Sokolova. After graduating from high school number 548

of Moscow she entered Moscow State Institute of Electronics and Mathematics in

Moscow, Russia in 1995. After receiving her undergraduate degree in mathematical

modeling and operations research she entered Computational and Applied Mathe-

matics program at the University of Texas at Austin, in August 1999. She received

her M.S. degree in Computational and Applied Mathematics in December 2003. She

was admitted to Ph.D. candidacy in May 2005. She joined SciComp Inc., Austin

Texas as a Senior Quantitative Analyst in May, 2004.

Permanent Address: 6325 Yaupon Dr., Austin TX, 78759

This dissertation was typeset with LATEX 2ε1 by the author.

1LATEX2ε is an extension of LATEX. LATEX is a collection of macros for TEX. TEX is a trademark ofthe American Mathematical Society. The macros used in formatting this dissertation were writtenby Dinesh Das, Department of Computer Sciences, The University of Texas at Austin, and extendedby Bert Kay, James A. Bednar, and Ayman El-Khashab.

147