Cooperation, Trust and Performance

download Cooperation, Trust and Performance

of 15

Transcript of Cooperation, Trust and Performance

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    1/15

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance – Empirical Results from Three Countries

    Matthias Fink1 and Alexander Kessler1,21Institute for Small Business Management and Entrepreneurship, WU Vienna University of Economics and

    Business, Augasse 2-6, 1090 Wien, Austria, and   2Institute for Management and Entrepreneurship, FHWien

    University of Applied Sciences of WKW, Waehringer Guertel 97, 1180 Wien, Austria

    Email:  [email protected]; [email protected]

    Reverting to the resource-based view of strategic management and cooperation theory,we provide argumentation for the value of two critical resources to cooperating firms:cooperation experience and maxim-based trust. The results of a large-scale surveyin three European countries (Austria, Slovenia and the Czech Republic) reveal an

    important fact: although cooperation experience contributes to business performance,the contribution of maxim-based trust to success is significantly higher. As a result,corporate success depends not only on the quantity of cooperation experience, butalso – and to an even greater extent – on the quality of cooperation with regard to theform of coordinative power established within the cooperation arrangement. Given thatmaxim-based trust has been identified as a feasible coordination mechanism incooperation relationships, it might therefore be freed from its frequent characterizationas utopian and out of touch with reality.

    Introduction

    The dynamization of markets in the context of 

    globalization has intensified the need for businessesto develop the ability to create unique sets of 

    resources in order to ensure sustainable corporate

    success. For this purpose, one promising means of 

    ensuring access to these critical resources – 

    especially for small and medium-sized enterprises(SMEs), which normally do not have extensive and

    manifold resource configurations at their disposal

     – is entering into cooperation relationships. By

    establishing a cooperation relationship, the part-

    ners can bundle (parts of) their resources and may

    thereby create a new and unique set of resources

    which can hardly be imitated. This is especially thecase when the partners succeed in identifying and

    capitalizing on the synergetic potential of the

    cooperation arrangement. Under these circum-

    stances, such an arrangement has the power to

    enhance the performance of both partners. Thecontribution of cooperation relationships to busi-

    ness performance can be short term or long term in

    nature (e.g. Macneil, 1980; Williamson, 1991).However, entering into cooperative relationships

    becomes a risky venture if the exchange relation-

    ship involves forgoing one’s own short-term profits

    in order to realize long-term gains together with a

    cooperation partner (Roessl, 1996). In suchtransaction relationships – which are the focus of 

    our research – cooperating companies make their

    own business performance dependent on their

    cooperation partner’s future behaviour. The ability

    to establish and maintain successful cooperation

    relationships is a critical resource in its own right,

    and it is built up in particular through practicalexperience in inter-firm cooperation relationships

    (e.g. Brulhart, 2007).

    However, it is not only the practical coopera-

    tion experience of the partners which makes (the

    partners in) a cooperation relationship successful,

    but also – and to an even greater extent – the

    coordination mechanism within these relation-The authors would like to thank the two anonymousreviewers for their constructive and helpful comments.

    British Journal of Management, Vol. 21, 469–483 (2010)

    DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2009.00647.x

    r 2009 British Academy of Management. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, OxfordOX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA, 02148, USA.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    2/15

    ships. We focus on long-term dyadic cooperation

    relationships between SMEs. These relationships

    represent contexts that are highly demanding

    with regard to behavioural coordination and areoften characterized by simultaneous market and

    organizational failure. In such contexts, e.g. joint

    R&D or cooperative internationalization, inter-organizational relationships can only be explained

    through trust-based behavioural coordination.

    These situations call for mutual trust as a

    coordination mechanism between the cooperation

    partners, as such trust plays a significant role inensuring the success of the cooperation and – as

    a consequence – the individual performance of 

    each cooperation partner. In order to fully under-

    stand the coordinative power of trust, we have to

    differentiate between instrumental (extrinsically

    motivated) trust and maxim-based (intrinsically

    motivated) trust (Osterloh and Weibel, 2000). Weargue that maxim-based trust represents a valu-

    able and particularly inimitable resource for the

    success of the cooperation and the performance of 

    the cooperation partners.

    This paper contributes to the field of coopera-

    tion research on several levels. We not only provide

    theoretical justification for the special value of (1)

    cooperation experience and (2) maxim-based trust

    as critical resources for business performance and

    develop a measurement model for cooperation

    experience, maxim-based trust and performance

    (which contributes to sharpening the measurementof trust, as called for by Moellering, Bachmann

    and Lee (2004), to name one example), but we also

    demonstrate the value of these two critical

    resources empirically. To this end, we use data

    from a large-scale questionnaire survey (n5303)

    in three European countries (Austria, Slovenia and

    Czech Republic) and employ hierarchical linear

    regression analysis to test three hypotheses.

    The results show that although cooperation

    experience contributes positively to business

    performance, maxim-based trust makes a signifi-

    cantly larger contribution to performance incooperation arrangements. Therefore, corporate

    success depends not only on the cooperation

    experience (quantitative aspect), but also – and

    to an even greater extent – on the form of 

    coordinative power within the cooperation

    arrangement (qualitative aspect).

    The paper is organized as follows. In the next

    section we develop three hypotheses against the

    backdrop of a focused literature review. We then

    discuss the sampling and operationalization of 

    the variables. Next, we present the empirical

    results, which are discussed and converted into

    implications linked to previous results in the twoensuing sections. We conclude by stating the

    limitations of this study and pointing out several

    directions for future research.

    Theoretical background anddevelopment of hypotheses

    Cooperation, opportunistic behaviour and success

    In order to generate profits, each company needs

    to have a certain set of resources at its disposal.

    For sustainable corporate success, it is crucial to

    secure access to such resources. Companies can

    employ three different   modi operandi   in order to

    ensure this access (Pfeffer and Salancik, 2003): (1)They can either internalize the source or (2) build

    up the competence and structures necessary togenerate the resource themselves. (3) Alterna-

    tively, companies may enter into a cooperative

    arrangement with a company that has access

    to the resource in question. As regards the third

    alternative, companies need to reach several

    decisions: they need to decide which resources

    are critical for achieving their value proposition

    and which of them they lack; which companies

    have those capabilities; and, based on cost, quality

    and speed considerations, whether the firm shouldpartner with or acquire those companies (Kim and

    Mauborgne, 2000).

    It is easy to see that there is less risk of losing

    access in the case of internalization or in-house

    production. Thus, in this context inter-firm co-

    operation might appear to be a less attractive

    alternative. However, the resources’ future value

    might not be predictable due to dynamic contextual

    conditions such as rapid technological change,

    modification of legal regulations or shifts in

    demand. In such cases, the risk of sunk costs

    impedes the development of capacities for in-houseproduction. This issue is also relevant in coopera-

    tion relationships, as changing partners gives rise to

    switching costs (Lipman and Wang, 2000). If the

    internalization of resources is also complicated, e.g.

    due to time or legal constraints or relatively high

    investment requirements, cooperative inter-firm

    arrangements become the most favourable means

    of gaining access to resources which are critical to

    the focal firm’s business performance.

    470   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    3/15

    In particular, SMEs often face situations in

    which both in-house production and internaliza-

    tion are unattainable. Manoeuvring within a

    limited number of rather specific and narrowbusiness areas with a comparatively small ‘war

    chest’, SMEs typically perceive unacceptably high

    risks when they consider obtaining control overcritical resources single-handedly. Consequently,

    cooperative arrangements represent an attractive

    option in the strategic portfolio of these firms.

    At the same time, inter-firm cooperation provides

    a vehicle for transactions which would otherwiseoverburden the focal SME (e.g. joint R&D or

    internationalization projects). By widening the

    behavioural portfolio, cooperative arrange-

    ments allow SMEs to exploit opportunities which

    they would have to forgo as isolated firms, and

    these arrangements hold the potential to create

    a synergetic, critical and hardly imitable combi-nation of the cooperation partners’ individual

    resources. In this way, inter-firm cooperation may

    make a positive contribution to the business

    performance of both cooperation partners.

    However, SMEs in cooperation arrangements

    often find themselves in a rather paradoxical

    situation. By entering into a cooperative arrange-

    ment with another company, they agree to

    coordinate their behaviour with the cooperation

    partner, thus restricting their own autonomy. As

    the elements of performance and reward are

    temporally separated in a cooperative exchangerelationship and a partner can always deviate from

    the agreement (Macneil (1980), from a contracting

    perspective; Emerson (1962), from a power-depen-

    dence perspective), cooperating companies make

    their own business performance dependent on their

    partner’s future behaviour. Therefore, cooperative

    strategies bring about a high level of risk: by

    frustrating the partner’s expectations, a cooperator

    may skim all of the short-term profits alone at the

    expense of joint long-term profits, thus defecting

    from the cooperation relationship. The possibility

    of such opportunistic behaviour makes cooperativearrangements a risky venture (e.g. Elango and

    Fried, 1997; Wathne and Heide, 2000). The ability

    of a firm to build up a sophisticated and effective

    instrument to handle this room for opportunistic

    behaviour determines the benefit it can generate

    from cooperative arrangements.

    In order to build up such an ability to

    coordinate cooperation relationships, the firm

    may resort to two critical resources: the firm can

    (1) tap its cooperation experience and (2) estab-

    lish maxim-based trust. In the following, the

    different bases, functional mechanisms and their

    (relative) impact on business performance will bediscussed and condensed into three hypotheses.

    Cooperation experience as a critical resource for

    business performance

    Organizational learning theory argues that

    companies may develop the capacity to handle

    complex transaction relationships by gaining

    experience in similar settings. In an iterative

    process, the firm extracts inferences from experi-

    ence gained in past cooperation relationships and

    extrapolates them to future situations in order toimprove its behaviour (Argyris und Schoen, 1978;

    Fiol and Lyles, 1985; Levitt and March, 1988).

    This argument is also supported by evolutionarytheory (Kale, Dyer and Singh, 2002), which

    claims that a firm’s competences evolve through

    incremental adaptation and progressive learning.

    In the context of cooperation relationships, these

    competences grow along with experience on two

    levels: first on the level of the experience gained in a

    cooperation relationship with a specific partner,

    and second on the level of general experience in

    cooperation management (Brulhart, 2007), which

    can be gained in the context of either domestic or

    international cooperation relationships (Nadolska

    and Barkema, 2007). Based on the argumentation

    above, we propose the following hypothesis:

    H1:   A cooperating company’s cooperation

    experience (measured in terms of the number,

    duration and internationality of cooperation

    relationships a company has participated in)

    has a positive effect on the focal firm’s business

    performance.

    Maxim-based trust within the cooperationrelationship as a critical resource for business

     performance

    It is not only cooperation experience (quantitative

    aspect), but also – as we argue even to a greater

    extent – the coordination mechanism within the

    cooperation relationship (qualitative aspect) that

    makes a cooperation relationship and its partners

    successful. When talking about the coordination

    mechanism, a major issue is the kind of power

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   471

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    4/15

    applied in order to coordinate the participants’

    behaviour within the field of cooperation.

    Consequently, the following question arises:

    how can cooperators ensure that their partnersbehave according to the rules stipulated  ex ante?

    There are three ideal-type coordination powers

    for the purpose of reducing the latitude foropportunistic behaviour. They apply to each real

    inter-firm transaction relationship in a certain

    combination (Adler, 2001; Bradach and Eccles,

    1989). (1) The market mechanism (which is based

    on isolated actors who pursue short-term advan-tages) cannot be the dominant coordination

    mechanism in a transaction relationship which

    strives for joint long-term profit (e.g. Ouchi, 1979).

    Following the logic of the ideal-type market,

    economic actors would opt for short-term profits,

    making long-term arrangements impossible in the

    first place. (2) Behavioural determination byhierarchical governance (e.g. Wathne and Heide,

    2000) is equally limited: credible sanction threats

    (Buckley and Casson, 1988) on an actor’s part

    require sufficient sanctioning power (Backhaus,

    1992; Kaas, 1992a, 1992b),   ex ante   knowledge

    (Eberl, 2004; Shane 1994) and   ex post   percept-

    ibility (Dwyer, Schurr and Oh, 1987) of the

    behaviour a cooperation partner is expected to

    show. The coordinative power of hierarchical

    governance is limited especially in those areas of 

    inter-firm cooperation where objectives cannot be

    programmed at all, or only at prohibitively hightransaction costs (Ring and Van de Ven, 1992).

    Thus, in transaction relationships which are

    complex and pursue long-term goals, neither

    market and hierarchy nor hybrids of these two

    coordination powers (Borys and Jemison, 1989)

    can govern the actors’ behaviour. Transaction

    cost economics ignore the fact that, beyond a

    certain level of complexity, market and organiza-

    tion failure impede exchange relations (Furubotn,

    2001; Roessl, 1996). In direct contrast to Baucus,

    Baucus and Human (1996), we argue that this

    deficit cannot be remedied by mixing elements of those two ideal-type coordination mechanisms or

    by delimiting contractual and relational obliga-

    tions as proposed by Williamson (1991). From

    a transaction cost perspective, trust cannot be

    accepted as an alternative because of its neo-

    institutional roots, which preclude non-rational

    behaviour and with it the acceptance of uncer-

    tainty and trust. However, highly complex transac-

    tion relationships obviously arise in real business

    life (Roessl, 1996) and form the focus of our

    investigation. This insight opens up the view to a

    third coordination mechanism which has slowly

    but steadily made its way into economic thinking.This third ideal-type coordination mechanism is

    particularly well suited in situations of both market

    and organizational failure. It is referred to as‘relational contracting’ (Carson, Madhok and Wu,

    2006), ‘trust’ (Eberl, 2004), ‘self-commitment’

    (Frey and Osterloh, 2002) or ‘Selbstverpflichtung ’

    (Fink, 2005; Sydow and Windeler, 2000).

    In society, trust was identified as a strongcoordinative power long ago. In the early twen-

    tieth century, the Austrian writer Egon Friedell

    postulated: ‘The most reliable way to make people

    decent is to take them for decent’ (Friedell, 1983).

    However, research on the coordinative role of trust

    within economic transactions did not become a

    serious issue for economists until the 1960s, whenresearchers such as Bator (1958), Ouchi (1979),

    Dwyer, Schurr and Oh (1987), Rotter (1971) and

    Wurche (1994) highlighted the shortcomings of the

    two classic coordinative powers of market and

    hierarchy, and pointed to the catalytic effect of 

    trust. After that first in-depth introduction to the

    phenomenon of ‘trust’ in economic theory, trans-

    action cost economics gained the upper hand,

    especially in the Anglo-Saxon world, widely

    ignoring the crucial role of trust in economic

    transactions. The subsequent debate focused on

    hybrids between market and hierarchy. Whereasauthors such as Zenger and Hesterly (1997) as well

    as Holland and Lockett (1997) detected the rising

    importance of these hybrid coordination mechan-

    isms, Williamson (1991) asserted their infeasibility

    and ineffectiveness. Again, these obviously incon-

    sistent standpoints opened up the field for trust to

    be viewed as a key to the controversy. Meanwhile,

    European economists in particular pressed ahead,

    theorizing on the role of trust in the economic

    context (e.g. Osterloh and Weibel, 2000; Roessl,

    1994, 1996) and providing a profound basis for a

    new global research effort on the unresolved issueof coordination. In his integrative work, Adler

    (2001) reintroduces trust as ‘a third increasingly

    significant coordination mechanism’.

    How can trust effectively coordinate the

    cooperation partners’ behaviour? Following Ring

    and Van de Ven (1992), Osterloh and Weibel

    (2000) or Adler (2001), we define trust as the

    response of an actor (an individual, not an

    organization) to subjective uncertainty regarding

    472   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    5/15

    the interaction partner’s behaviour. In order to

    understand the coordinative power of trust, it is

    necessary to differentiate between instrumental

    trust and maxim-based trust. Instrumentaltrust refers to the exogenous conformity of the

    cooperation partner’s behaviour with the explicit

    and implicit rules of cooperation. This kind of trust draws its coordinative power from sanction

    and control. The awareness that the cooperation

    partner may face disadvantages in the case of 

    defective behaviour motivates the actor to place

    instrumental trust in him.By contrast, maxim-based trust is intrinsically

    motivated, drawing its coordinative power

    from the actor’s self-commitment to a maxim

    (Kant, 1998).

    How does a maxim-based trust relationship

    evolve? The evolution of maxim-based trust

    can be described as a reciprocal, self-reinforcingprocess. It starts with the actors mutually

    conceding self-commitment to their cooperation

    partners, which is based on socialized informa-

    tion on the cooperation partner (e.g. reputation

    and perceived behavioural history). In this

    situation, the actors feel compelled to provide

    risky advance performance (irreversible commit-

    ments such as specific investments). In this way,

    they communicate their own self-commitment in

    a credible manner. Based on congruent expecta-

    tions, both sides perform acts of maxim-based

    trust, which in turn reinforce the initial expecta-tions and justify additional acts of maxim-based

    trust (Fink, 2005). They forgo individual short-

    term profits in favour of common long-term

    profits. As a result, a maxim-based trust relation-

    ship evolves. Although latitude for opportunistic

    behaviour still exists in such transaction relation-

    ships, restricting the participants’ inclination to-

    ward opportunistic behaviour reduces behavioural

    uncertainty. Therefore, the complexity of the

    transaction relationship and the risk of betrayal

    can be partly absorbed. Thus, maxim-based trust

    provides a key to double contingency and preventsthe development of social dilemmas such as the

    prisoner’s dilemma from the very outset. In this

    way, maxim-based trust enables transaction rela-

    tionships which would otherwise not take place

    due to high behavioural uncertainty.

    The prototypical transaction relationship,

    which can only be realized by interaction partners

    who place maxim-based trust in one other, is

    heterarchic cooperation. Heterarchic cooperation

    relationships can be defined as voluntary and

    organized relationships between autonomous and

    equal partners who mutually adapt their behaviour

    to each other, thus bringing about the possibilityof one-sided defection. Thus, if two actors who

    are ready to commit to each other enter into a

    heterarchic cooperation relationship, we can as-sume that a maxim-based trust relationship has

    been established between them (Fink, 2005).

    The competence necessary to build up and

    maintain such complex cooperation relationships

    enables the cooperators to handle behaviouraluncertainty. Consequently, they are able to capi-

    talize on additional opportunities which their

    competitors have to go without. Profits will rise

    in cases where only few firms are capable of 

    carrying out a transaction due to their control

    over rare, inimitable resources (e.g. Barney, 1986,

    1991). In fact, firms will then be able to apply thishighly sophisticated and efficient coordination

    power to realize profitable transaction relation-

    ships in risky contexts. The competitive advan-

    tage of being able to develop and manage

    cooperation relationships coordinated by max-

    im-based trust has a positive effect on the focal

    firm’s business performance. Therefore, the

    following hypothesis can be postulated:

    H2:  The more behavioural coordination relies

    on maxim-based trust in a cooperation rela-

    tionship, the better the performance of the

    focal participating company will be.

    The superiority of maxim-based trust as a

    contributor to business performance

    Both cooperation experience and the ability to

    establish and maintain a cooperation relationship

    coordinated by maxim-based trust can be seen as a

    firm’s resources. From this perspective, cooperation

    experience can be expected to have a weaker effect

    on the firm’s business performance, as it is easier to

    acquire and less bound to the socio-psychosocialprofile of the actors in charge of cooperation

    management. As a result, the competitive advan-

    tage of cooperation experience is easier to imitate

    and therefore of less value to the company.

    Accordingly, we propose the following hypothesis:

    H3: Maxim-based trust within a cooperation

    relationship has a stronger effect on the

    business performance of the focal firm than

    cooperation experience.

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   473

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    6/15

    Methods

    Sampling frame and response rates

    The quantitative part of this paper is based on a

    survey carried out in Austria, the Czech Republic

    and Slovenia between March and July 2006. A

    total of 10,000 (Austria, 2000; Czech Republicand Slovenia, 4000 each) SMEs (i.e. up to 249

    employees) was selected from national databases

    (Austria, AURELIA; Czech Republic, ALBER-

    TINA; Slovenia, IPIS) as a stratified random

    sample. The region (province) and size of each

    business (number of employees) were employed ascriteria for stratification. Stratification by region

    (total number of SMEs of a region     2000 or

    4000 divided by the total number of SMEs in the

    country) was employed in order to avoid over- or

    under-representing certain regions in the sample.

    Stratification by the ‘size of business’ ratio – 1:3:1for micro businesses (up to nine employees), small

    businesses (10–49 employees) and medium-sizedbusinesses (50–249 employees), respectively – was

    employed in order to avoid over-representing

    micro businesses, which show a low propensity

    to cooperate.

    The questionnaire was addressed to the owner/

    manager of each SME, as – in view of the topic of 

    the survey – knowledgeable informants were not

    available below that hierarchical level.

    The survey yielded a total of 458 (4.6%)

    returned questionnaires: 119 from Austria (re-sponse rate 6.0%), 199 from Slovenia (response

    rate 5.0%) and 140 from the Czech Republic

    (response rate 3.5%). A check based on telephone

    interviews with a random sample of 45 non-

    respondents from each country as well as a test

    comparing early, middle and late responders

    showed no systematic bias. Of these 458 SMEs,

    303 (91 Austrian, 150 Slovenian and 62 Czech)

    indicated that they participate in cooperation

    activities. Therefore, these 303 businesses serve

    as the basis for our analyses in this paper. The

    breakdown of the sample into cooperatingand non-cooperating businesses showed that the

    propensity to cooperate was significantly lower in

    the Czech sample (44.3%) than in the Slovenian

    (75.4%) and Austrian (76.5%) samples (w2543.12;

    p50.000).

    The sample for analysis consists of 49 (16.2%)

    micro, 153 (50.5%) small and 101 (33.0%)

    medium-sized enterprises across a broad range of 

    industries. Approximately 43% of the businesses in

    the sample belong to the service sector, some 37%

    belong to the production sector, and the remaining

    20% can be attributed to the trade sector.

    Variables and measures

    We used four-point scales (‘completely agree’,

    ‘inclined to agree’, ‘inclined to disagree’ and‘completely disagree’) to measure all items.

    Cooperation experience.   Cooperation experi-

    ence was measured using the number of coopera-tion relationships the business had had at the

    time of the survey (1, one; 2, two; 3, more than

    two), the duration of the cooperation arrange-

    ment with the firm’s main partner (1, up to one

    year; 2, one to three years; 3, three to five years; 4,

    five to ten years; 5, ten to 20 years; 6, more than

    20 years), and participation in an internationalcooperation arrangement (0, no international

    cooperation; 1, international cooperation).

    Maxim-based trust.   As outlined above, mutual

    trust can only evolve if both interaction partners

    are willing to make a commitment to each other.

    Therefore it is necessary to measure the level of 

    maxim-based trust on both actors’ sides. As the

    questionnaire survey was kept anonymous in

    order to increase the return rate, we could not

    match up the partners in cooperation systems. As

    a result, we had to apply a combination of direct

    and indirect measurements.

    On the side of the cooperation partner surveyed,

    we measured the level of self-commitment to the

    cooperation relationship as a manifest expression

    of the maxim-based trust placed in his/her

    cooperation partner (direct measurement). On

    the side of the cooperation partner  not   surveyed,

    maxim-based trust could be observed by identify-

    ing whether a heterarchic cooperation relationship

    had been established. Based on the argumentation

    outlined above, the existence of a heterarchiccooperation relationship allows for interference in

    the second cooperation partner’s level of maxim-

    based trust (indirect measure).

    As the individual items in maxim-based trust

    were considered independent from one another,

    we calculated a formative index.

    Self-commitment.   Our conceptualization of the

    self-commitment phenomenon is based on the

    474   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    7/15

    work of Roessl (1994, 1996) and comprises

    several dimensions. The present cooperation

    partner’s  reputation  provides information on the

    extent to which he/she has met the expectationsof his/her interaction partners in the past (Roessl,

    2001), thus affecting an actor’s decision to

    commit to the relationship.  Familiarity   is basedon personal impressions and provides informa-

    tion about the specific cooperation partner in the

    ongoing relationship (Roessl, 1994). Another

    indicator is the cooperation partner’s   perceived 

    behavioural history. In particular, the stability of the maxims underlying perceived behaviour is

    crucial here. Self-commitment requires observa-

    ble behavioural norms which remain stable

    over time and therefore allow a prognosis of 

    the cooperation partner’s future behaviour

    (Luhmann, 1989; Roessl, 1994). As perceived

    behavioural history is not based on personalimpressions, it has to be obtained actively. The

    source of this information is socialized impres-

    sions of others. If the cooperation partners build

    up a personal relationship, the relationship will be

    enriched by personal connotations, taking the

    relationship to a higher level. Such personal

    relationships between self-committed cooperators

    have   no short-term perspective   (Becaerra and

    Gupta, 2003; Kanter, 1995; Roessl, 1994).

    A further dimension of self-commitment is the

    actor’s self-restriction; the actor confines himself/

    herself to cooperative behaviour. He/she takesthe risk that his/her expectations concerning the

    cooperation partner’s behaviour might be

    frustrated. Therefore, the   willingness to take a

    risk   is another dimension of self-commitment.

    Self-commitment also requires   frustration toler-ance, i.e. the actor’s belief in his/her ability to

    cope with situations resulting from a frustration

    of expectations (Roessl, 1994). An actor’s self-

    commitment represents   self-exposure. Further-

    more, self-commitment calls for a   leap of faith

    (e.g. advance performance) which the interaction

    partner might capitalize on by defecting from therelationship unexpectedly.

    Heterarchic cooperation relationship.   We mea-

    sure heterarchic cooperation based on (1) structural

    characteristics and (2) interpersonal characteristics,

    which are a suitable means of delimiting this

    specific form of cooperation relationship from

    other forms of inter-firm cooperation relationships.

    Structural characteristics delimit from ‘informal

    relationship’: whereas informal relationships are

    characterized by a minimum share of elements

    typical of organizations, heterarchic cooperationrelationships are   organized relationships   and can

    therefore be characterized as systems (Plassmann,

    1974).Structural characteristics also delimit from ‘hier-

    archical cooperation’ and ‘concentration’: the

    essential difference here lies in the form of 

    coordination in the transaction relationship.

    Coordination based on mutually adjusted behaviouron the part of   autonomous and  equal  elements in a

    heterarchic cooperation relationship (Strohmayer,

    1996) is delineated from coordination based on

    power, control and sanction in a hierarchy system

    (Pleitner and Roessl, 1995). Consequently, each

    cooperator has the  possibility of one-sided defection

    in the heterarchic cooperation relationship at anytime (Plassmann, 1974). Hierarchical systems have

    a rigid structure of competences with a portfolio of 

    sanctions attached, whereas heterarchic relation-

    ships are characterized by   voluntary  participation

    and inputs (Strohmayer, 1996).

    The  interpersonal characteristics typical of heter-

    archic cooperation arrangements are captured

    using four indicators. The measure   communication

    quality describes how the cooperators communicate

    with each other. Communication quality is crucial

    for exchanging opinions and thoughts between the

    subsystems of the cooperation relationship. Onlyhigh-quality communication ensures that all parti-

    cipants have the opportunity to contribute their

    ideas and safeguard their interests. In this way,

    high communication quality contributes to high

    relationship quality (e.g. Becaerra and Gupta,

    2003; Kanter, 1995).

    The measure  resilience  captures those aspects of 

    the cooperation relationship which only move to

    the centre of attention in times of crisis. How

    robust the cooperation relationship is in times of 

    crisis and how elaborated problem-solving compe-

    tences are determine the relationship quality to agreat extent (De Búrca, Fynes and Roche, 2004).

    The measure transparency captures the coopera-

    tion partners’ openness concerning the internal

    processes of their firms. To what extent do the

    cooperation partners provide such insight, and how

    well and accurately informed do they feel? Trust

    can only evolve if the cooperation partners deal

    with each other openly and honestly. The more the

    actor knows about his/her interaction partner, the

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   475

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    8/15

    less risk he/she will perceive in the trust relation-

    ship, and the more likely a heterarchic cooperation

    relationship will evolve (De Búrca, Fynes and

    Roche, 2004).

    Once a heterarchic cooperation relationship

    has been established and the self-reinforcing

    process has started,   relationship intensity   rises

    automatically.

    For the purpose of measuring the components of 

    maxim-based trust, we used four-point scales

    (‘completely agree’, ‘inclined to agree’, ‘inclined to

    disagree’ and ‘completely disagree’). Table 1 shows

    Table1. Measurement of maxim-based trust

    Maxim-based

    trust

    Variables Sources Items

    Self-commitment Reputation Roessl, 2001 Before establishing the cooperation relationship, I

    had heard good things about my cooperation partner

    Familiarity Roessl, 2001 I have cooperated with my present cooperation

    partner in the pastPerceived

    behavioural history

    Roessl, 2001 Before establishing the cooperation relationship, I

    gathered information about my cooperation partner

    Personal relationship Becaerra and Gupta, 2003;

    Kanter, 1995

    I also meet my cooperation partner in my private life

    No short-term

    perspective

    De Búrca, Fynes and Roche,

    2004; Rusbult, Martz

    and Agnew, 1998

    With the cooperation relationship, I aim to realize

    noticeable success as fast as possiblea

    Self-restriction Osterloh and Weibel, 2000;

    Roessl, 1994

    I attune my behaviour to the aims of the cooperation

    relationship

    Willingness to

    take a risk

    McLain and Hackman, 1999 I am willing to take a risk

    Frustration

    tolerance

    Luhmann, 1989;

    Roessl, 1994

    I am convinced that I am able to cope with setbacks

    Self-exposure Roessl, 1994 The cooperation has a strong influence on the successof my company

    Leap of faith Luhmann, 1989 In order to make cooperation work, one has to take

    a leap of faith with one’s cooperation partner, even

    though this involves risk

    Heterarchic cooperation relationship

    Structural

    characteristics

    Organized

    relationship

    Plassmann, 1974;

    Roessl, 1994

    My cooperation partners and I talk about the

    cooperation

    Mutually adjusted

    behaviour

    Roessl, 1994 My cooperation partner and I take joint action in the

    area of cooperation

    Autonomy Troendle, 1987 I have remained legally independent within the

    cooperation arrangement

    Equality Ruehl, 1980 In decisions regarding the cooperation relationship,

    the opinion of each cooperation partner is equally

    important

    Possibility of 

    one-sided defection

    Plassmann, 1974 By behaving opportunistically, I could damage the

    cooperation relationship

    Voluntariness Strohmayer, 1996 I can terminate the cooperation relationship

    unilaterally at any time

    Interpersonal

    characteristics

    Communication

    quality

    Becaerra and Gupta, 2003;

    De Búrca, Fynes and

    Roche, 2004;

    Kanter, 1995

    I can get right to the point when speaking with my

    cooperation partner

    Resilience De Búr ca, Fynes and

    Roche, 2004

    Discussions with my cooperation partner always

    result in a solution

    Transparency De Búrca, Fynes and

    Roche, 2004

    I know the internal processes in my cooperation

    partner’s company

    Relationship intensity Lorenz, 1999 Since its establishment, the cooperation relationship

    has gained intensity

    aReverse item.

    476   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    9/15

    the measurement of maxim-based trust and its

    components.

    Performance.   Our measurement of entrepreneur-

    ial performance is based on an adapted formal

    structure of the balanced scorecard (Kaplan

    and Norton, 1996). In this way, we can ensure

    integrated coverage of the latent variable ‘perfor-

    mance’ within the framework of our empirical

    investigation.

    As the individual performance items were

    considered to be independent from one another,

    we calculated a formative index. Table 2 shows

    the variables employed along with their sources

    and the items used. As in the case of maxim-

    based trust, we used four-point scales (‘com-

    pletely agree’, ‘inclined to agree’, ‘inclined to

    disagree’ and ‘completely disagree’) to measureall items.

    Control variables.   We used firm size (number of 

    employees), firm age (years of existence) and

    country of origin (0, Austria as a traditional

    market economy; 1, Czech Republic and Slovenia

    as emerging market economies) as control vari-

    ables, as these characteristics can also have an

    impact on performance.

    Analysis

    We employed hierarchical linear regression anal-

    ysis to test our hypotheses. In the first step of 

    the analysis, the control variables were inserted

    into the model, using business performance as

    the dependent variable. In the next two steps,

    the variables   cooperation experience   and  maxim-based trust   were added to the model, and

    incremental R2 and F tests of statistical signifi-

    cance were evaluated.

    Results

    The means, standard deviations and correlations

    of the variables are displayed in Table 3. First, it

    is striking that (with the possible exception of the

    duration of cooperation and maxim-based trust)the correlations between the independent vari-

    ables are relatively low, ranging from –0.185 to

    0.177. However, the positive correlation between

    the duration of cooperation and maxim-based

    trust meets our expectations, as it supports the

    argument that trust can normally only evolve and

    increase with time (e.g. Jones and George, 1998;

    Lafontaine and Kaufmann, 1994). With regard to

    the correlations between the independent vari-

    Table2. Measurement of performance

    Performance Variables Sources Items

    Endogenous

    perspective

    Employee qualifications Kaplan and Norton, 1996 Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, the qualifications of my

    employees have improved

    Employee turnover Gomes, Yasin and Lisboa,

    2006; Hatch and Dyer, 2004

    Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, fewer employees have leftmy company

    Exogenous

    perspective

    Customer satisfaction

    Share of regular

    customers

    Anderson and Sullivan, 1993;

    Anderson, Fornell and

    Lehmann, 1994

    Bruhn, 1996; Horovitz

    and Panak, 1993;

    Quartapelle and Larsen, 1996

    My customers are always satisfied with

    my products and services

    Most of my customers are regular customers

    Market development Kaplan and Norton, 1996 Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, I have enlarged my market share

    Share of regular suppliers Riffner and Weidelich, 2001 Most of my suppliers are regular suppliers

    Financial

    perspective

    Cash flow development Kaplan and Norton, 1996 Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, I have boosted my cash flow

    Sales development Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, I have boosted my salesDevelopment of 

    investment activity

    Since the establishment of the cooperation

    relationship, I have boosted my investments

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   477

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    10/15

    ables and the dependent variable, maxim-based

    trust shows by far the highest positive correlation

    with performance, followed by the duration

    of the cooperation. The negative correlation

    between firm age and performance is also notice-

    able. This negative correlation may result from

    the fact that our performance measure, which is

    based on dynamic indicators, tends to favour

    younger, more flexible businesses in dynamicmarkets in comparison to more established,

    experienced businesses in stable environments.

    In order to check for multicollinearity in the

    regression analysis, the variance inflation factor

    was calculated for the individual predictors. All

    of the values are just over 1 and thus far below

    critical levels. In order to test the hypotheses,

    we first added the control variables (see Table 4,

    column 2, for results), then the cooperation

    experience variables (column 3) and finally the

    maxim-based trust variable (column 4).

    The control variables (firm size, firm age and

    country) explain 3.6% of the variation in per-

    formance, and the model only attains statistical

    significance at the 90% level in this step (p50.057).

    Nevertheless, while firm size and country do not

    show a significant impact on performance,

    firm age turns out to be a significant predictor(p50.034) for firm performance. As pointed out

    above in the discussion of correlations, the

    relationship between firm age and performance

    is negative. Once again, we repeat our assump-

    tion that this outcome is partly caused by the fact

    that we measured performance using dynamic

    performance indicators.

    In the next step of the regression analysis, the

    cooperation experience variables (number of 

    Table3. Means, standard deviations and correlations

    Mean Standard deviation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    (1) Performance 34.11 4.90 1

    (2) Firm size 2.31 0.92 0.079 1

    (3) Firm age 2.52 0.81   0.147**   0.150***   1

    (4) Country

    (Austria versus CZ/SI)

    0.70 0.46 0.090 0.004   0.185***   1

    (5) Number of cooperation

    relationships

    1.90 0.90 0.100 0.112*   0.018   0.158***   1

    (6) Duration of cooperation 3.20 1.35 0.204***   0.017 0.114*   0.008 0.177***   1

    (7) International cooperation

    (yes/no)

    0.48 0.50 0.161***   0.039   0.106*   0.127**   0.080 0.028 1

    (8) Maxim-based trust 61.92 6.16 0.421***   0.062 0.019   0.050 0.107*   0.128* 0.008 1

    *p40.1;  **po0.05;  ***po0.01.

    Table 4. Performance: control variables, cooperation experience and maxim-based trust (n5303)

    1 2 3 4

    Control

    variables

    Cooperation experience,

    control variables

    Maxim-based trust, cooperation

    experience, control variables

    b   SE   b   SE   b   SE

    Firm size 0.101 0.370 0.097 0.363 0.074 0.332

    Firm age   0.151**   0.429   0.162**   0.423   0.159**   0.386

    Country (Austria versus CZ/SI) 0.062 0.744 0.050 0.740 0.066 0.675

    Number of cooperation relationships 0.046 0.379 0.017 0.346

    Duration of cooperation 0.212***   0.248 0.165***   0.228

    International cooperation (yes/no) 0.124*   0.662 0.124**   0.604

    Maxim-based trust 0.398***   0.049

    R2 0.036*   0.104***   0.258***

    Adjusted R2 0.022*   0.077***   0.232***

    DR2 0.036*   0.068***   0.154***

    Standardized regression coefficients are displayed in the table.*p40.1;  **po0.05;  ***po0.

    478   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    11/15

    cooperation relationships, duration of coopera-

    tion, and existence of international cooperation)

    are reviewed beyond the base model. These three

    variables account for an additional 6.8% of the variation in performance (p50.002) and

    increase the statistical significance of the model

    (p5

    0.001). Explained variance thus attains avalue of 10.4%. Aside from the negative relation-

    ship between firm age and performance already

    discovered in the control variables block, the

    existence of international cooperation (p50.068)

    and particularly the duration of cooperation(p50.002) show significant positive relationships

    with business performance.

    This means that Hypothesis 1 can partially be

    supported. Cooperation experience in the form of 

    the duration of cooperation and – with some

    limitations due to lower significance – also the

    existence of international cooperation make apositive contribution to business performance.

    In the final step of our analysis, we added

    maxim-based trust to the regression model. The

    integration of this variable increases the explained

    variance considerably by 15.4% (p50.000) to

    25.8% (p50.000). Maxim-based trust shows a

    highly significant positive relationship with busi-

    ness performance (p50.000). In combination,

    these outcomes support Hypotheses 2 and 3:

    maxim-based trust has a positive influence on

    business performance (Hypothesis 2) and has a

    stronger effect on business performance thancooperation experience (Hypothesis 3). In fact,

    maxim-based trust explains a higher percentage of 

    the variance in performance (15.4%) than all the

    other variables in the final model combined.

    Discussion

    Empirical analysis shows that cooperating

    firms with more cooperation experience are more

    successful. The longer these firms manage to

    maintain their cooperative relationships, thebetter the firms perform. Moreover, the inter-

    nationality of cooperation relationships contri-

    butes to firm performance. Interestingly enough,

    the data do not indicate that the firms’ number of 

    cooperation relationships has a significant impact

    on performance. This can be interpreted as a first

    indication of the greater success contribution

    of continuous, systematic and focused investment

    in the development of an ongoing cooperation

    relationship which lies within the core of one’s

    business and widens the firm’s strategic portfolio.

    In contrast, the development of cooperation

    relationships with ever-changing partners doesnot contribute to firm performance. From this

    perspective, the firm’s number of cooperation

    relationships alone is not a decisive factor. More-over, the number of cooperation relationships

    maintained seems to be influenced by firm size,

    as increasing company size automatically leads to

    an increasing number of external contacts. At the

    same time, a larger number of external contactsincreases the probability that cooperatively co-

    ordinated transaction relationships will evolve.

    Although the results show that cooperation

    experience makes a positive contribution to the

    performance of cooperating firms, we were also

    able to identify a far stronger success factor

    for cooperators: maxim-based trust. Inter-firmcooperation relationships are characterized by

    double contingency and are therefore a suitable

    context for empirical research into the effect of 

    maxim-based trust on cooperators’ performance.

    In this context, we showed that maxim-based trust

    is a resource that substantially contributes to the

    cooperating firms’ performance. We interpret this

    trust based on maxims as a critical resource which

    is especially difficult to imitate and may thus

    serve as a possible key to developing competitive

    advantages. Firms that manage to evolve maxim-

    based trust possess a capability which enablesthem to manage cooperation relationships which

    could not be coordinated otherwise. They can

    seize and capitalize on opportunities which their

    competitors have to forgo due to the high com-

    plexity and uncertainty involved.

    We can sum up our findings as follows. It is not

    so much the quantity of cooperation experience,

    but the quality of the cooperation relationship

    that accounts for its value to the company. These

    findings concur with those of Lavie (2006), who

    highlights the special value of the nature of inter-

    firm relationships.

    Implications

    As cooperation experience has proved to be a

    success factor for cooperating firms, it seems

    beneficial to build up the appropriate management

    capacities in due time. From our results, we have

    learned that it is not the number of cooperation

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   479

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    12/15

    relationships a firm has experienced but the

    intensity of these relationships that contributes to

    future success. The management capacities relevant

    to coordinating cooperative relationships and theresulting firm performance obviously grow along

    with the challenge. This idea leads to the assump-

    tion that, in order to boost business performance,entrepreneurs have to venture into increasingly

    demanding transaction relationships. We argue

    that with rising cooperation experience firms build

    up a sophisticated and effective instrument for

    handling behavioural uncertainty within coopera-tion relationships. The challenge of coordinating

    cooperation relationships grows with longer time

    horizons and higher internationality, as these

    factors increase complexity and uncertainty. More

    demanding settings force cooperating firms to

    improve their coordination instruments, thus creat-

    ing a more valuable resource. Those who invest inthe development of their cooperation relationship

    and push the limits within this relationship will

    outperform those who only dare to act within the

    secure, familiar territory of the past.

    Our results show that the more a cooperation

    arrangement relies on maxim-based trust, the more

    successful it is. However, a firm cannot establish a

    maxim-based trust cooperation relationship over-

    night in order to boost its performance. First, the

    firm needs to find a like-minded partner who is

    willing to commit to the relationship to the same

    extent as itself. This is not an easy task, as self-commitment can only be communicated by leaps

    of faith and mutual-based trust can only evolve if 

    the interaction partner does not capitalize on this

    self-exposure. The tricky thing is the fact that

    self-exposure is only legitimated by its result. Thus,

    one can never be sure to succeed with this kind

    of advance. On the one hand, this dilemma is

    unpleasant for the actor who is willing to develop a

    maxim-based trust relationship with a cooperation

    partner, as it forces the actor to take a risk that

    cannot be legitimated beforehand. On the other

    hand, it also serves as a safety mechanism as itavoids instrumentalizing maxim-based trust: once

    you fake it, you break it.

    Second, such relationships typically grow over

    time. The evolution process of maxim-based

    trust cannot be accelerated by force. It rests on

    a long-term strategy aimed at building up a

    good reputation and ensuring a positive per-

    ceived history. Additionally, it requires a long-

    lasting personal relationship with the cooperation

    partner in the course of which one has credibly

    communicated a willingness to take risks, a

    sufficient level of frustration tolerance and readi-

    ness for self-restriction and self-exposure.It is easy to see that, although maxim-based

    trust is a possible key to boosting firm perfor-

    mance, it is not a management tool suitable forshort-term intervention. As the word maxim

    implies, it is more a constant socio-psychological

    predisposition underlying the entrepreneurs’

    decisions and actions.

    However, as our results identify maxim-basedtrust as a possible key to competitive advantage

    and enhanced business performance in the long

    run, researchers as well as practitioners may

    regard it as an important phenomenon in the

    cooperation context. Our findings may contribute

    to freeing this social phenomenon from its

    frequent characterization as utopian and out of touch with reality. In this respect, our results

    challenge theoretical concepts that adhere to the

    concept of   homo oeconomicus. This may provide

    support for those who have appropriate resources

    at their disposal and are willing to develop a

    maxim-based trust relationship. The more max-

    im-based trust cooperation relationships are

    realized in highly uncertain and complex con-

    texts, the less society suffers from the conse-

    quences of market and organization failure.

    In the field of SME cooperation, our results

    challenge arguments based on transaction costeconomics alone, such as those put forth

    by Williamson (1991), as well as explanations

    of exchange transactions based on rational

    choice theory (as argued by Axelrod (1984), for

    example). The results also provide empirical

    support for more holistic concepts of inter-firm

    transactions as proposed by Roessl (1994),

    Osterloh and Weibel (2000), Adler (2001) and

    Carson, Madhok and Wu (2006), to name just a

    few examples.

    In light of our empirical results, further

    research in this field is certainly worthwhile,both from a scientific as well as a practical point

    of view.

    Limitations and directions for futureresearch

    First, the moderate response rate has to be qualified

    in light of the fact that surveys on SMEs (especially

    480   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    13/15

    in transition economies) typically show low response

    rates. This difficulty is exacerbated when surveys

    address sensitive issues such as trust in cooperation

    partners. However, our check for non-response biasas well as a test comparing early, middle and late

    responders showed no systematic bias, thus indicat-

    ing robustness of the results presented.Second, although the survey instrument was

    tested in a 2004 survey of over 600 Austrian

    SMEs and the consistency of the results with

    those of the study at hand indicates reliability,

    further use in other contexts would be required inorder to legitimate the claim of reliability. This

    could likewise demonstrate whether our findings

    are valid in other geographical and cultural

    contexts as well as in a sample of large companies.

    Third, our one-sided measurement of maxim-

    based trust is justified by theoretical arguments and

    therefore does not compromise the empirical results.However, the measure should be subjected to

    further validation in qualitative as well as quanti-

    tative studies using pairs of cooperators. Pairing

    would further increase the reliability of the data, but

    at the same time represents a major challenge with

    regard to the anonymity of the respondents and,

    consequently, the resulting response rate.

    Fourth, as we employed a cross-sectional design,

    we cannot rule out reverse causality. In order to

    enhance clarity in this regard, a longitudinal

    study would have to be conducted. Such a design

    would also yield even higher explained variance inperformance.

    However, we are convinced that by presenting

    innovative lines of argumentation and current

    empirical results, we have been able to enhance

    our understanding of how SME cooperation

    arrangements generally contribute to business

    performance, and to add another piece to the

    puzzle regarding the special value of maxim-

    based trust relationships.

    References

    Adler, P. (2001). ‘Market, hierarchy, and trust: the knowledge

    economy and the future of capitalism’,  Organization Science,

    12, pp. 215–234.

    Anderson, E. and M. Sullivan (1993). ‘The antecedents and

    consequences of customer satisfaction for firms’,  Marketing

    Science,  12, pp. 125–142.

    Anderson, E., C. Fornell and D. Lehmann (1994). ‘Customer

    satisfaction, productivity, and profitability: differences between

    goods and services’,  Marketing Science,  16, pp. 129–145.

    Argyris, C. and D. Schoen (1978).   Organizational Learning: A

    Theory of Action Perspective. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.

    Axelrod, R. (1984).  The Evolution of Cooperation. New York:

    Basic Books.

    Backhaus, K. (1992). ‘Investitionsgueter-Marketing – Theorie-

    loses Konzept mit Allgemeingueltigkeitsanspruch?’,   Zeits-

    chrift fuer betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung,  44, pp. 771–791.

    Barney, J. (1986). ‘Organizational culture: can it be a source of 

    sustained competitive advantage?’,  Academy of Management

    Review,  11, pp. 656–665.

    Barney, J. (1991). ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive

    advantage’, Journal of Management,  17, pp. 99–120.

    Bator, F. (1958). ‘The anatomy of market failure’,   Quarterly

    Journal of Economics,  72, pp. 351–379.

    Baucus, D., M. Baucus and S. E. Human (1996). ‘Consensus

    in franchise organizations: a cooperative arrangement

    among entrepreneurs’,   Journal of Business Venturing,   11,

    pp. 358–378.

    Becaerra, M. and A. K. Gupta (2003). ‘Perceived trustworthi-

    ness within the organization: the moderating impact of 

    communication frequency on trustor and trustee effects’,

    Organization Science,  14, pp. 32–44.

    Borys, B. and D. B. Jemison (1989). ‘Hybrid arrangementsas strategic alliance: theoretical issues in organizational

    combinations’,   Academy of Management Review,   14, pp.

    234–249.

    Bradach, J. L. and R. G. Eccles (1989). ‘Price, authority and

    trust: from ideal types to plural forms’,   Annual Review of 

    Sociology,  15, pp. 97–118.

    Bruhn, M. (1996).  Qualitaetsmanagement fuer Dienstleistungen.

    Berlin: Springer.

    Brulhart, F. (2007). ‘Experience of partnership, experience with

    a partner, interpersonal complicity: what impact on success

    in a logistic partnership?’, The Business Review, Cambridge, 7,

    pp. 199–206.

    Buckley, P. and M. Casson (1988). ‘A theory of cooperation in

    international business’. In F. Contractor and P. Lorange(eds), Cooperative Strategies in International Business, pp. 31– 

    53. Toronto: Lexington.

    Carson, S. J., A. Madhok and T. Wu (2006). ‘Uncertainty,

    opportunism, and governance: the effects of volatility and

    ambiguity on formal and relational contracting’,  Academy of 

    Management Journal ,  49, pp. 1058–1077.

    De Búrca, S., B. Fynes and E. Roche (2004). ‘Evaluating

    relationship quality in a business-to-business context’,  Irish

    Journal of Management,  25, pp. 61–75.

    Dwyer, F. R., H. P. Schurr and S. Oh (1987). ‘Developing

    buyer–seller relationships’,   Journal of Marketing,   51,

    pp. 11–27.

    Eberl, P. (2004). ‘The development of trust and implications

    for organizational design: a game- and attribution-theoreticalframework’,  Schmalenbachs Business Review, 56, pp. 258–273.

    Elango, B. and V. H. Fried (1997). ‘Franchising research: a

    literature review and synthesis’,   Journal of Small Business

    Management,  35, pp. 68–81.

    Emerson, R. M. (1962). ‘Power–dependence relations’,   Amer-

    ican Sociological Review,  27, pp. 31–41.

    Fink, M. J. (2005).   Selbstverpflichtung als Erfolgsfaktor bei 

    langfristigen, komplexen Transaktionsbeziehungen. Mit einem

    empirischen Befund . Frankfurt: Peter Lang.

    Fiol, C. M. and M. A. Lyles (1985). ‘Organizational learning’,

    Academy of Management Review,  10, pp. 803–813.

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   481

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    14/15

    Frey, B. S. and M. Osterloh (2002).   Successful Management

    by Motivation: Balancing Intrinsic and Extrinsic Incentives.

    Berlin: Springer.

    Friedell, E. (1983). Selbstanzeige. Essays ab 1919. Wien: Loecker.

    Furubotn, E. G. (2001). ‘The new institutional economics and

    the theory of the firm’,  Journal of Economic Behaviour and 

    Organization,  45, pp. 133–153.

    Gomes, C. F., M. M. Yasin and J. V. Lisboa (2006). ‘Key

    performance factors of manufacturing effective performance.

    The impact of customers and employees’,   The TQM Maga-

    zine,  18, pp. 323–340.

    Hatch, N. W. and J. H. Dyer (2004). ‘Human capital and

    learning as a source of sustainable competitive advantage’,

    Strategic Management Journal ,  25, pp. 1155–1178.

    Holland, C. P. and G. A. Lockett (1997). ‘Mixed mode network

    structures: the strategic use of electronic communication by

    organizations’, Organization Science,  8, pp. 475–488.

    Horovitz, J. and M. J. Panak (1993).   Marktfuehrer durch

    Service. Lehren aus 50 hervorragenden europaeischen Unter-

    nehmen. Frankfurt: Campus.

    Jones, G. R. and J. M. George (1998). ‘The experience and

    evolution of trust: implications for cooperation and team-

    work’,   Academy of Management Review,  23, pp. 531–546.Kaas, K. P. (1992a). ‘Kontraktguetermarketing als Koopera-

    tion zwischen Prinzipalen und Agenten’,   Zeitschrift fuer

    betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung,  44, pp. 884–901.

    Kaas, K. P. (1992b).   Marketing und Neue Institutionenlehre.

    Working Paper 1 aus dem Forschungsprojekt Marketing und

    oekonomische Theorie, Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaf-

    ten, Lehrstuhl fuer Betriebswirtschaftslehre, insbesondere

    Marketing, Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universitaet, Frank-

    furt am Main.

    Kale, P., J. H. Dyer and H. Singh (2002). ‘Alliance capability,

    stock market response, and long term alliance success: the

    role of alliance function’,  Strategic Management Journal ,  23,

    pp. 747–767.

    Kant, I. (1998). Groundwork of the Metaphysics of Morals. NewYork: Cambridge University Press.

    Kanter, R. M. (1995). ‘Unternehmenspartnerschaften: Langsam

    zueinander finden’,   Harvard Business Manager,   17, pp.

    33–44.

    Kaplan, R. P. and D. P. Norton (1996).   The Balanced 

    Scorecard: Translating Strategy into Action. Boston, MA:

    Harvard Business School Press.

    Kim, W. C. and R. Mauborgne (2000). ‘Knowing a winning

    business idea when you see one’,   Harward Business Review,

    78, pp. 129–138.

    Lafontaine, F. and P. J. Kaufmann (1994). ‘The evolution of 

    ownership patterns in franchise systems’, Journal of Retailing,

    70, pp. 97–113.

    Lavie, D. (2006). ‘The competitive advantage of interconnectedfirms: an extension of the resource-based view’,   Academy of 

    Management Review,  31, pp. 638–658.

    Levitt, B. and J. G. March (1988). ‘Organizational learning’,

    Annual Review of Sociology,  14, pp. 319–340.

    Lipman, B. L. and R. Wang (2000). ‘Switching costs in

    frequently repeated games’,   Journal of Economic Theory,

    93, pp. 149–190.

    Lorenz, E. (1999). ‘Trust, contract and economic cooperation’,

    Cambridge Journal of Economics,  23, pp. 301–315.

    Luhmann, N. (1989).   Vertrauen. Ein Mechanismus der Reduk-

    tion sozialer Komplexitaet. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.

    Macneil, I. R. (1980). ‘Power, contract, and the economic

    model’, Journal of Economic Issues,  11, pp. 909–923.

    McLain, D. L. and K. Hackman (1999). ‘Trust, risk and

    decision-making in organizational change’,   Public Adminis-

    tration Quarterly,  23, pp. 152–176.

    Moellering, G., R. Bachmann and S. H. Lee (2004). ‘Introduc-

    tion: Understanding organizational trust – foundations,

    constellations, and issues of operationalisation’,   Journal of 

    Managerial Psychology,  19, pp. 556–570.

    Nadolska, A. and H. G. Barkema (2007). ‘Learning to

    internationalise: the pace and success of foreign acquisitions’,

    Journal of International Business Studies,  38, pp. 1170–1187.

    Osterloh, M. and A. Weibel (2000). ‘Ressourcensteuerung in

    Netzwerken: Eine Tragoedie der Allmende?’. In J. Sydow and

    A. Windeler (eds),  Steuerung von Netzwerken – Konzepte und 

    Praktiken, pp. 88–106. Wiesbaden: Opladen.

    Ouchi, W. (1979). ‘A conceptual framework for the design of 

    organizational control mechanisms’,   Management Science,

    25, pp. 833–848.

    Pfeffer, J. and G. R. Salancik (2003).  The External Control of 

    Organizations. A Resource Dependence Perspective. Stanford,

    CA: Stanford University Press.

    Plassmann, M. (1974). ‘Die Kooperationsentscheidung desUnternehmers’. Dissertation, Universita ¨ t Muenster.

    Pleitner, H. J. and D. Roessl (1995). ‘Wirtschaftsfoerderung

    unterhalb der Wirtschaftspolitik – der Beitrag zwischenbe-

    trieblicher Kooperation’. In A. Brandendberg (ed.),   Stand-

     punkte zwischen Theorie und Praxis – handlungsorientierte

    Problemloesungen in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, pp. 671– 

    689. Bern: Haupt.

    Quartapelle, A. Q. and G. Larsen (1996).  Kundenzufriedenheit.

    Wie Kundentreue im Dienstleistungsbereich die Rentabilitaet

    steigert. Berlin: Springer.

    Riffner, B. and R. Weidelich (2001).   Professionelles Lieferan-

    tenmanagement – so arbeitet man erfolgreich zusammen.

    Koeln: Deutscher Wirtschaftsdienst.

    Ring, P. S. and A. Van de Ven (1992). ‘Structuring cooperativerelationships between organizations’,   Strategic Management

    Journal ,  13, pp. 483–498.

    Roessl, D. (1994).   Gestaltung komplexer Austauschbeziehungen – 

    Analyse zwischenbetrieblicher Kooperation. Wiesbaden: Gabler.

    Roessl, D. (1996). ‘Selbstverpflichtung als alternative Koordi-

    nationsform von komplexen Austauschbeziehungen’,

    Zeitschrift fuer betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung,   48, pp.

    311–334.

    Roessl, D. (2001). ‘Entwicklungspfade asymmetrischer Koo-

    perationen’,  Journal fu ¨ r Betriebswirtschaft,  51, pp. 22–26.

    Rotter, J. B. (1971). ‘Generalized expectancies for interpersonal

    trust’, Journal of Personality,  35, pp. 651–665.

    Ruehl, G. (1980). ‘Aspekte optimaler zwischenbetrieblicher

    Zusammenarbeit im Zulieferwesen’,   Internationales Gewer-bearchiv,  28, pp. 80–91.

    Rusbult, C. E., J. Martz and C. R. Agnew (1998). ‘The

    investment model scale: measuring commitment level, satis-

    faction level, quality of alternatives, and investment size’,

    Personal Relationships,  5, pp. 357–391.

    Shane, S. (1994). ‘The effect of national culture on the choice

    between licensing and direct foreign investment’,   Strategic

    Management Journal ,  15, pp. 627–642.

    Strohmayer, M. (1996).   Expansion durch Kooperation: Wach-

    stumsstrategien mittelstaendischer Unternehmen im europaeischen

    Binnenmarkt. Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang.

    482   M. Fink and A. Kessler

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.

  • 8/9/2019 Cooperation, Trust and Performance

    15/15

    Sydow, J. and A. Windeler (2000). ‘Steuerung von und in

    Netzwerken – Perspektiven, Konzepte, vor allem aber offene

    Fragen’. In J. Sydow and A. Windeler (eds),   Steuerung von

    Netzwerken – Konzepte und Praktiken, pp. 1–24. Wiesbaden:

    Opladen.

    Troendle, D. (1987).  Kooperationsmanagement Steuerung inter-

    aktioneller Prozesse bei Unternehmenskooperationen. Bergisch

    Gladbach: Eul.

    Wathne, K. and J. Heide (2000). ‘Opportunism in interfirm

    relationships: forms, outcomes, and solutions’,   Journal of 

    Marketing,  64, pp. 36–51.

    Williamson, O. E. (1991). ‘Comparative economic organi-

    zation: Vergleichende oekonomische Organisationstheorie:

    Die Analyse diskreter Strukturalternativen’. In D. Ordel-

    heide, B. Rudolph and E. Buesselmann (eds),   Betriebs-

    wirtschaftslehre und oekonomische Theorie, pp. 13–49.

    Stuttgart: Poeschel.

    Wurche, S. (1994). ‘Vertrauen und oekonomische Rational-

    itaet in kooperativen Interorganisationsbeziehungen’.

    In J. Sydow and A. Windeler (eds),   Management inter-

    organisationaler Beziehungen, pp. 142–159. Wiesbaden:

    Opladen.

    Zenger, T. R. and W. S. Hesterly (1997). ‘The disaggregation

    of corporations: selective intervention, high-powered incen-

    tives, and molecular units’,   Organization Science,   8, pp.

    209–222.

    Matthias Fink is an assistant professor at the Institute for Small Business Management and

    Entrepreneurship at the WU Vienna University of Economics and Business where he also earned his

    PhD in Small Business Management. Furthermore, he is a senior researcher at the Research Institute

    for Co-operation and Co-operatives and Visiting Professor at Vaasa University (Finland) and

    Universidad Auto ´ noma de Barcelona (Spain). Mr. Fink is lecturer at several European universities.

    He holds a three-year fellowship (APART – Austrian Program for Advanced Research andTechnology) granted by the Austrian Academy of Sciences. His main research interests are

    interorganizational cooperation, trust in the economic context, internationalization of SMEs,

    community-based entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial marketing.

    Alexander Kessler is an associate professor and head of the Competence Center Entrepreneurship at

    the Institute for Management and Entrepreneurship at FHWien University of Applied Sciences of 

    WKW, Vienna. Furthermore he is a lecturer and researcher at the Institute for Small Business

    Management and Entrepreneurship at the WU Vienna University of Economics and Business and a

    visiting professor at the Masaryk University in Brno, Czech Republic. He earned his master’s

    degree, his PhD and his Habilitation in business administration at WU Vienna University of 

    Economics and Business. His main research interests are business start-up and development,

    corporate entrepreneurship, entrepreneurship in countries of transition, international comparisons

    in entrepreneurship research, family business research, and trust in SME cooperation relationships.

    Cooperation, Trust and Performance   483

    r 2009 British Academy of Management.