Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed Preference · 5 Mathematically Representing Utility In...

69
1 Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed Preference

Transcript of Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed Preference · 5 Mathematically Representing Utility In...

  • 1

    Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed Preference

  • 2

    Agenda Consumer Utility Consumer Choice Revealed Preference

  • 3

    Consumer Theory There are two important pillars that

    consumer theory rests upon: The utility function The budget constraint

  • 4

    Utility Function A utility function is a function/process that

    maps a bundle of goods into satisfaction where the satisfaction can be ranked for each bundle of goods. In essence, it allows us to rank the desirability of

    consuming different bundles of goods. A bundle of goods is a particular set of goods

    you choose to consume. This is also referred to as a consumption bundle.

  • 5

    Mathematically Representing Utility In Economics, we tend to define the utility

    function as the following: U = u(x1, x2, …, xn) where

    U is the level of satisfaction you receive from consuming the bundle of goods consisting of x1, x2, …, xn

    u( ) is the function that maps the bundle of goods into satisfaction. (Think of this as the mathematical representation of your brain.)

    xi for i = 1, 2, …, n is the quantity of a particular good consumed from a bundle of goods, e.g., x1 may be 5 pancakes.

  • 6

    Example of Representing Utility in Mathematical Terms Suppose you have a utility function that is

    based on three goods pizza, soda, and buffalo wings. We can represent your utility function as U = u(x1, x2, x3). x1 = amount of pizza consumed x2 = amount of soda consumed xn = x3 = amount of buffalo wings

    consumed

  • 7

    Example of Representing Utility in Mathematical Terms Suppose you have a choice of

    consuming one of two different bundles of goods. Bundle 1 has a large pepperoni pizza, a

    two liter bottle of coke, and 20 spicy buffalo wings.

    Bundle 2 has a large pepperoni pizza, a two liter bottle of coke, and 40 spicy buffalo wings.

  • 8

    Example of Representing Utility Cont. For bundle 1

    x1 = a large pepperoni pizza x2 = a two liter bottle of coke xn = x3 = 20 spicy buffalo wings

    For bundle 2 x1 = a large pepperoni pizza x2 = a two liter bottle of coke xn = x3 = 40 spicy buffalo wings

  • 9

    Example of Representing Utility Cont. We can further write the following:

    U1 = u(a large pepperoni pizza, a two liter bottle of coke, 20 spicy buffalo wings)

    U2 = u(a large pepperoni pizza, a two liter bottle of coke, 40 spicy buffalo wings) Remember u( ) is just a function that transforms bundles

    of goods into satisfaction. (Think of it as your brain.) What might be inclined to say that U2 > U1.

    Why?

  • 10

    Some Notes on Utility It was once thought that utility could be

    broken down into units called utils. Total utility is defined as the utility you

    receive from consuming a particular bundle of goods.

    For analytical tractability, total utility can be given a number value. In our previous example we could say that U1 =

    100 and U2 = 200.

  • 11

    Some Notes on Utility Cont. There are two views of utility:

    Cardinal Utility Cardinal utility is the belief that utility can be measured

    and compared on a unit by unit basis. E.g., A utility measure of 200 is twice as big as a utility

    measure of 100.

    Ordinal Utility Ordinal utility is where you rank bundles of goods, but

    cannot say how much greater one bundle is to another. Ranking is the only thing that matters when dealing with

    ordinal utility.

  • 12

    Utility from Consuming One Good When examining utility, we sometimes would

    like to examine how one good affects our utility.

    This can be looked at by assuming that we have only one good in our utility function, i.e., U=u(x).

    A more realistic outlook is that we examine only one good in our utility function, holding all the other goods constant.

  • 13

    Utility from Consuming One Good Cont. Mathematically, we can represent

    holding things constant in the following two manners for one good: U = u(x1; x2, x3, …, xn) or U = u(x1 | x2 , x3, …, xn)

    Where it is understood using this notation that goods x2 through xn are held at some constant level.

  • 14

    Marginal Utility (MU) Marginal utility is defined as the change

    in total utility divided by a change in the consumption of a particular good.

    In mathematical terms, marginal utility of good i is defined as du(x)/dx, which is just the first derivative of the utility function with respect to good x.

  • 15

    Calculating Marginal Utility Suppose Dr. Hurley only like to consume

    chocolate. Also, assume that Dr. Hurley’s total utility

    function can be represented as U(x) = 10x-x2 This implies that MU(x)=du/dx= 10 - 2x

    Assuming that chocolates were free, how many chocolates would Dr. Hurley consume?

  • 16

    Total Utility and marginal Utility of U(x)=10x-x2

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    -15-10-505

    1015202530

    0 2 4 6 8 10 12

    Number of Goods

    Utils U(x)

    MU(x)

    Chart2

    11

    22

    33

    44

    55

    66

    77

    88

    99

    1010

    1111

    U(x)

    MU(x)

    Number of Goods

    Utils

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    9

    8

    16

    6

    21

    4

    24

    2

    25

    0

    24

    -2

    21

    -4

    16

    -6

    9

    -8

    0

    -10

    -11

    -12

    Sheet1

    1133.16624790361.5075567229

    1234.64101615141.443375673

    1336.05551275461.3867504906

    1437.41657386771.3363062096

    1538.72983346211.2909944487

    16401.25

    1741.23105625621.2126781252

    1842.42640687121.178511302

    1943.58898943541.1470786694

    2044.721359551.1180339887

    2145.82575694961.0910894512

    2246.90415759821.0660035818

    2347.95831523311.0425720703

    xU(x)MU(x)

    198

    2166

    3214

    4242

    5250

    624-2

    721-4

    816-6

    99-8

    100-10

    11-11-12

    12-24-14

    Sheet1

    U(x)

    MU(x)

    Number of Goods

    Utils

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    Sheet2

    Sheet3

  • 17

    Deriving Total and Marginal Utility from a Function Suppose you could represent your

    utility function for drinking Mountain Dew as the following: U = u(x) Where u(x) = 10x½

    What is Total Utility and Marginal Utility? Graph both.

  • 18

    Total Utility and marginal Utility of U(x)=10x½

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    0 5 10 15 20 25

    Number of Goods

    Utils U(x)

    MU(x)

    Chart1

    11

    22

    33

    44

    55

    66

    77

    88

    99

    1010

    1111

    1212

    1313

    1414

    1515

    1616

    1717

    1818

    1919

    2020

    2121

    2222

    2323

    U(x)

    MU(x)

    Number of Goods

    Utils

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    10

    5

    14.1421356237

    3.5355339059

    17.3205080757

    2.8867513459

    20

    2.5

    22.360679775

    2.2360679775

    24.4948974278

    2.0412414523

    26.4575131106

    1.889822365

    28.2842712475

    1.767766953

    30

    1.6666666667

    31.6227766017

    1.5811388301

    33.1662479036

    1.5075567229

    34.6410161514

    1.443375673

    36.0555127546

    1.3867504906

    37.4165738677

    1.3363062096

    38.7298334621

    1.2909944487

    40

    1.25

    41.2310562562

    1.2126781252

    42.4264068712

    1.178511302

    43.5889894354

    1.1470786694

    44.72135955

    1.1180339887

    45.8257569496

    1.0910894512

    46.9041575982

    1.0660035818

    47.9583152331

    1.0425720703

    Sheet1

    xU(x)MU(x)

    1105

    214.14213562373.5355339059

    317.32050807572.8867513459

    4202.5

    522.3606797752.2360679775

    624.49489742782.0412414523

    726.45751311061.889822365

    828.28427124751.767766953

    9301.6666666667

    1031.62277660171.5811388301

    1133.16624790361.5075567229

    1234.64101615141.443375673

    1336.05551275461.3867504906

    1437.41657386771.3363062096

    1538.72983346211.2909944487

    16401.25

    1741.23105625621.2126781252

    1842.42640687121.178511302

    1943.58898943541.1470786694

    2044.721359551.1180339887

    2145.82575694961.0910894512

    2246.90415759821.0660035818

    2347.95831523311.0425720703

    Sheet1

    U(x)

    MU(x)

    Number of Goods

    Utils

    Utility and Marginal Utility

    Sheet2

    Sheet3

  • 19

    Lessons Learned from Example As long as marginal utility is positive,

    total utility will increase. Total and marginal utility can be

    negative. When marginal utility is zero, total

    utility is maximized. This graph demonstrated the Law of

    Diminishing Marginal Utility.

  • 20

    Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility This law states that as you consume

    more units or a particular good during a set time, at some point your marginal utility will decrease as your consumption increases. Note: Beware of laws in economics, they

    are not like physical laws. This is equivalent to saying that the

    derivative of MU is negative.

  • 21

    Utility from Consuming Two Goods When examining utility, we sometimes would

    like to examine how two good interrelate in our utility function.

    This can be looked at by assuming that we have only one good in our utility function, i.e., U=u(x1, x2).

    A more realistic outlook is that we examine two goods in our utility function, holding all the other goods constant.

  • 22

    Utility from Consuming Two Goods Cont. Mathematically, we can represent

    holding things constant in the following two manners for two goods: U = u(x1, x2; x3, …, xn) or U = u(x1, x2 | x3, …, xn)

    Where it is understood using this notation that goods x3 through xn are held at some constant level.

  • 23

    Isoutility To this point we have examined utility

    based on the consumption of one good. Realistically, our consumption bundles

    have more than one item in them. When more than one good exist in our

    consumption bundle and utility function, it becomes important for us to examine the idea of isoutility.

  • 24

    Isoutility Isoutility is a concept where differing

    bundles of goods provide the same level of utility.

    From the idea of isoutility comes the graphical representation--an indifference curve. An indifference curve is the graphical

    representation of differing bundles of goods giving the same level of utility.

  • 25

    Demonstrating an Indifference Curve Suppose we have two goods in our utility

    function—corn dogs (C) and sandwiches (S). To obtain an indifference curve, we want to

    hold our utility constant and look at the different bundles of consumption of each good that provide the same utility.

    Suppose we know that we have the following utility function U = u(C, S) = C*S

  • 26

    Demonstrating an Indifference Curve Cont. To derive the indifference curve, we

    want to keep U constant. In this case we will assume U = 10

    What bundles of goods will give us this level of satisfaction?

    What if U = 20?

  • 27

    Increasing Utility

    Chart1

    22

    33

    44

    55

    66

    77

    88

    99

    1010

    Utility = 10

    Utility = 20

    Number of Corn Dogs

    Number of Sandwiches

    5

    10

    3.33

    6.66

    2.5

    5

    2

    4

    1.7

    3.4

    1.4

    2.8

    1.25

    2.5

    1.1

    2.2

    1

    2

    Sheet1

    2345678910

    Utility = 1053.332.521.71.41.251.11

    Utility = 20106.66543.42.82.52.22

  • 28

    Observations The two utility curves do not cross each

    other. Why?

    Utility is increasing as you move away from the x and y-axis.

    As you consume more of one of the goods, the consumption of the other good has relatively more value to you.

    Any other observations?

  • 29

    Notes on Indifference Curves Indifference curves usually are not

    considered thick. Why.

    Indifference curves tend to not be upward sloping. Why?

  • 30

    Example of a Thick Indifference Curve

    x2

    x1

    106

    7

    ••

  • 31

    Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) When examining indifference curves, it is

    important to look at the tradeoff between consuming one good versus the other. This is called examining the marginal rate of

    substitution. The marginal rate of substitution can be defined

    as the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade one good for another.

    Why is this important to examine?

  • 32

    Mathematical Representation of MRS MRS of good xi for good xj

    =dxj /dxi

  • 33

    Example of Calculating MRS From our previous example, we had the

    following utility function: U = u(C,S) = C*S Setting U = 10, what is the MRS of

    corndogs for sandwiches at 2 sandwiches and 5 corndogs, i.e., dS /dC?

  • 34

    Implication of Indifference Curve Due to indifference curves, we have the

    following relationship for differing bundles of goods: (dxj / dxi) = -(MUxi /MUxj)

    Which implies (dxj * MUxj) = -(MUxi * dxi) Which implies (dxj * MUxj) + (MUxi * dxi) = 0

    This implies that the loss in utility from consuming less of good xj is just matched by the gain in utility from consuming more of xi.

  • 35

    Budget Constraint This constraint defines the feasible set of

    consumption bundles you are able to consume.

    It is dependent on three things: The prices of the goods in your consumption

    bundle. The quantity of each good in your consumption

    bundle. Your income.

  • 36

    Budget Constraint Cont. The budget constraint for two goods is

    defined as the following: m = p1*x1 + p2 * x2

    m = income p1 = the price of x1 p2 = the price of x2 x1 = the quantity consumed of good 1 x2 = the quantity consumed of good 2

  • 37

    Budget Constraint Cont. Assume that we want to graph are budget

    constraint and choose x2 as the good we want to put on the y-axis.

    m = p1*x1 + p2 * x2 can be rewritten as: x2 = (m/p2) – (p1/p2) * x1

    With this equation we can draw the budget constraint on a graph.

    Note that the slope of the budget constraint is equal to the negative of the price of good 1 divided by the price of good 2.

  • 38

    Budget Constraint Example Suppose you have $100 to spend on

    chips and soda. You know that the price of chips is $1 and the price of soda is $2. Draw your budget curve assuming that chips will be on the y-axis.

  • 39

    Budget Constraint Example Budget equation:

    $100 = $2 *x1 + $1 *x2 ⇒x2 = 100 – 2*x1

  • 40

    Budget Constraint Cont.# of Chips

    # of Sodas50

    100x2 = 100 – 2*x1

    Feasible Set

    Not Feasible

  • 41

    Consumer Equilibrium Consumer equilibrium is comprised of

    two concepts: The utility function The budget constraint

    Consumer equilibrium can be defined as a consumption bundle that is feasible given a particular budget constraint and maximizes total utility.

  • 42

    Consumer Equilibrium Cont. If there was no budget constraint, a person

    would consume each good to the point where marginal utility of consumption for each good is zero. Why?

    Given a budget constraint, the consumer maximizes total utility by consuming a bundle that is feasible. A feasible bundle is one that lies either on or

    inside the budget constraint.

  • 43

    Consumer Equilibrium Cont. In graphical terms, consumer

    equilibrium is defined as the point where the highest utility function touches the budget constraint.

  • 44

    General Utility Maximization Model

    ∑=

    ≥n

    iii

    nxxx

    xpm

    xxxuMaxn

    1

    21,...,,

    :subject to

    ),...,,(21

  • 45

    Utility Maximization with One Good

    0

    0

    )()(),(

    :subject to

    )(

    ≥−=∂Γ∂

    =∂∂

    =⇒

    =−∂∂

    =∂Γ∂

    −+=Γ≥

    pxm

    pMU

    pxu

    pxu

    x

    pxmxuxpxm

    xuMaxx

    λ

    λ

    λ

    λλ

  • 46

    Utility Maximization with One Good Cont. When your maximizing utility with respect to

    one good, there are two scenarios that occur: You have more money than you need to maximize

    your utility, so you do not spend all of your money. This implies λ = 0 and m > px.

    You run out of money before you reach the highest amount of utility you can achieve. This implies λ > 0 and m = px.

    To solve this problem, you need to check which scenario provides the highest utility while satisfying the constraint.

  • 47

    Consumer Equilibrium Example for One Good Suppose we have the following utility

    function: U = u(x) = x½

    Suppose the price of good x is $5 and the income available is $125.

    What is the optimal utility and how much money do you have left?

  • 48

    Consumer Equilibrium Example for One Good Cont. Now, Suppose we have the following

    utility function: U = u(x) = 10x-x2

    Suppose the price of good x is $5 and the income available is $125.

    What is the optimal utility and how much money do you have left?

  • 49

    Utility Maximization for Two Goods Suppose we have the following utility

    function: U = u(x1,x2)

    Where x1 is equal to the number of good 1 Where x2 is equal to the number of good 2

    Suppose we have the following budget constraint: M = p1*x1 + p2*x2

    Where p1 is equal to the price of good 1 Where p1 is equal to the price of good 2

  • 50

    Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.

    2211

    21,

    :subject to

    ),(21

    xpxpm

    xxuMaxxx

    +=

  • 51

    Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.

    2

    2

    222

    1

    1

    111

    22112121

    2

    2

    1

    1

    0

    0

    )(),(),,(

    pMU

    pMU

    pxu

    x

    pMU

    pMU

    pxu

    x

    xpxpmxxuxx

    x

    x

    x

    x

    =⇒

    =⇒

    =−∂∂

    =∂Γ∂

    =⇒

    =⇒

    =−∂∂

    =∂Γ∂

    −−+=Γ

    λ

    λ

    λ

    λ

    λ

    λ

    λλ

  • 52

    Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont. (pj/pi) = (MUj/MUi) can be rewritten as:

    (MUj / pj) = (MUi / pi) This says that you are normalizing the change in

    utility by the price of the good and then equating it to the normalized marginal utility of the other good.

    Another way to look at this is to say that the marginal utility derived from the last dollar spent for each good is equal.

    What happens if one side is greater than the other?

  • 53

    Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont. Intuitively what we have done in the

    graph is equate the tradeoff from prices to the tradeoff in utility. I.e., (pj/pi) = (MUj/MUi)

    Where pj is the price of good j and pi is the price of good i

    Where MUj is the marginal utility of consuming good j and MUi is the marginal utility of consuming good i

  • 54

    Consumer Equilibrium Example for Two Goods Suppose we have the following utility

    function: U = u(x1,x2)= x1 * x2

    Where x1 is equal to the number of hotdogs consumed Where x2 is equal to the number of sodas consumed

    Suppose we have the following budget constraint: M = p1*x1 + p2*x2

    Where p1 is equal to the price of hotdogs consumed Where p2 is equal to the price of sodas consumed

  • 55

    Consumer Equilibrium Example Cont. Now consider that you have a price of

    hotdogs (x1) equal to $2 and a price of soda (x2) is a $1.

    Also suppose that our income is $16. Solution will be done in class.

  • 56

    Revealed Preference Revealed Preference is about making

    observations of people’s consumption values to understand their preferences.

    Suppose there are two bundles of goods (x1,x2) and (y1,y2).

    An assumption of revealed preference is that the consumer always chooses the optimal bundle given her budget constraint.

    If prices are p1 and p2, then we can represent these two bundles on a graph.

  • 57

    Revealed Preference Cont.

    Good 1

    Good 2

    ●(x1,x2)

    ●(y1,y2)

  • 58

    Revealed Preference Cont. Define m = p1x1+p2x2 We know from the above graph that

    p1y1+p2y2 ≤ m. Why?

    We also know that p1x1+p2x2 ≥ p1y1+p2y2. Why?

  • 59

    The Principle of Revealed Preference If (x1,x2) is the chosen bundle of goods at

    prices (p1,p2), and if (y1,y2) is affordable, i.e., p1x1+p2x2 ≥ p1y1+p2y2, then the bundle (x1,x2) is preferred to (y1,y2), i.e., (x1,x2) > (y1,y2). In this case, we say (x1,x2) is directly revealed

    preferred to (y1,y2). Note: If the consumer is choosing the optimal

    bundle, then revealed preference will imply preference.

  • 60

    Indirectly Revealed Prefer Suppose that there is a set of prices

    (q1,q2) where (y1,y2) is directly revealed prefer to (z1,z2), i.e., the consumer chooses (y1,y2) while q1y1+q2y2 ≥ q1z1+q2z2.

    Also assume that at price (p1,p2), (x1,x2) is directly revealed preferred to (y1,y2).

  • 61

    Indirectly Revealed Prefer Then we know that (x1,x2) is indirectly

    revealed preferred to (z1,z2), even if (z1,z2) was not affordable at (p1,p2).

    The graph on the next slide gives a visual representation of this.

  • 62

    Indirectly Revealed Prefer Cont.

    Good 1

    Good 2

    ●(x1,x2)

    ●(y1,y2)●(z1,z2)

  • 63

    Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP) If the bundle (x1,x2) is directly revealed

    preferred to bundle (y1,y2) and the two bundles are not the same, then it is not possible that (y1,y2) is directly revealed preferred to (x1,x2) when (x1,x2) is affordable.

  • 64

    Graphical Example of WARP Being Violated

    Good 1

    Good 2

    ●(x1,x2)

    ●(y1,y2)

  • 65

    Example of WARP Being ViolatedObservation p1 p2 x1 x2

    1 2 6 3 5

    2 3 3 4 4

  • 66

    Example of WARP Being Violated Cont.

    Observations (x1,x2)

    1(3,5)

    2 (5,4)

    Prices (p1,p2)

    1 (2,6)

    36 34*

    2 (3,3)

    24* 27

  • 67

    Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference If the bundle (x1,x2) is directly or

    indirectly revealed preferred to bundle (y1,y2) and the two bundles are not the same, then it is not possible that (y1,y2) is directly or indirectly revealed preferred to (x1,x2).

  • 68

    Example of SARP Being ViolatedObservation p1 p2 x1 x2

    1 1 1 9 4

    2 2 1 3 7

    3 1 2 1 10

  • 69

    Example of SARP Being Violated Cont.

    Observations (x1,x2)

    (9,4) (3,7) (1,10)

    Prices (p1,p2)

    (1,1) 13 10 11

    (2,1) 23 13 12(1,2) 17 17 21

    Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed PreferenceAgendaConsumer TheoryUtility FunctionMathematically Representing UtilityExample of Representing Utility in Mathematical TermsExample of Representing Utility in Mathematical TermsExample of Representing Utility Cont.Example of Representing Utility Cont.Some Notes on UtilitySome Notes on Utility Cont.Utility from Consuming One GoodUtility from Consuming One Good Cont.Marginal Utility (MU)Calculating Marginal UtilityTotal Utility and marginal Utility of U(x)=10x-x2Deriving Total and Marginal Utility from a FunctionTotal Utility and marginal Utility of U(x)=10x½Lessons Learned from ExampleLaw of Diminishing Marginal UtilityUtility from Consuming Two GoodsUtility from Consuming Two Goods Cont.IsoutilityIsoutilityDemonstrating an Indifference CurveDemonstrating an Indifference Curve Cont.Slide Number 27ObservationsNotes on Indifference CurvesExample of a Thick Indifference CurveMarginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)Mathematical Representation of MRSExample of Calculating MRSImplication of Indifference CurveBudget ConstraintBudget Constraint Cont.Budget Constraint Cont.Budget Constraint ExampleBudget Constraint ExampleBudget Constraint Cont.Consumer EquilibriumConsumer Equilibrium Cont.Consumer Equilibrium Cont.General Utility Maximization ModelUtility Maximization with One GoodUtility Maximization with One Good Cont.Consumer Equilibrium Example for One GoodConsumer Equilibrium Example for One Good Cont.Utility Maximization for Two GoodsUtility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.Utility Maximization with Two Goods Cont.Consumer Equilibrium Example for Two GoodsConsumer Equilibrium Example Cont.Revealed PreferenceRevealed Preference Cont.Revealed Preference Cont.The Principle of Revealed PreferenceIndirectly Revealed PreferIndirectly Revealed PreferIndirectly Revealed Prefer Cont.Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)Graphical Example of WARP Being ViolatedExample of WARP Being ViolatedExample of WARP Being Violated Cont.Strong Axiom of Revealed PreferenceExample of SARP Being ViolatedExample of SARP Being Violated Cont.