Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General...

35
Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade Surfaces, International General Equilibrium Solutions and Factor Allocations. Bjarne S. Jensen and Jacopo Zotti University of Southern Denmark, Dept. of Environmental and Business Economics University of Trieste, Department of Political and Social Sciences Abstract This paper gives analytical parametric solutions for the basic, two-sector-two-factor-two- country, (2x2x2) model of international trade. Such analytical approach to the involved non-linear economic systems must start with the Cobb-Douglas specifications of sector technologies and consumer preferences. The closed-form expressions provide a unified framework for all traditional basic trade models. The solutions allow for international differences in country sizes, endowments, technology and preferences, encompassing the major ”pure trade theories” within a systematic analytic and historical perspective. In this unified framework, we derive the general existence conditions for the solutions under diversification and incipient country specialization. Keywords: Trade models, general equilibrium, terms of trade JEL Classification: F11, F43, E21 1

Transcript of Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General...

Page 1: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns,

Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade Surfaces,

International General Equilibrium Solutions and Factor Allocations.

Bjarne S. Jensen and Jacopo Zotti

University of Southern Denmark, Dept. of Environmental and Business Economics

University of Trieste, Department of Political and Social Sciences

Abstract

This paper gives analytical parametric solutions for the basic, two-sector-two-factor-two-

country, (2x2x2) model of international trade. Such analytical approach to the involved

non-linear economic systems must start with the Cobb-Douglas specifications of sector

technologies and consumer preferences. The closed-form expressions provide a unified

framework for all traditional basic trade models. The solutions allow for international

differences in country sizes, endowments, technology and preferences, encompassing the

major ”pure trade theories” within a systematic analytic and historical perspective. In

this unified framework, we derive the general existence conditions for the solutions under

diversification and incipient country specialization.

Keywords: Trade models, general equilibrium, terms of trade

JEL Classification: F11, F43, E21

1

Page 2: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

1 Introduction

The pure theory of international trade has always been involved with the fundamental

questions of what decides : 1. The commodity pattern (composition) of international trade

between countries, 2. The ”international values”, i.e., the prices of both the free traded

commodities and their primary production factors, 3. The gains from foreign trade.

Evidently the literature is overwhelming and hence many surveys have been made,

Haberler (1936,1961), Mundell (1960), Bhagwati (1964), Chipman (1965-1966). The

latter still surpasses all other historical accounts and expositions of theory evolution (to-

gether with many references to contemporary authors/discussions). His theory chronology

has three periods of main/early contributors : I. Classical theory of comparative advan-

tage, gains from trade (Smith, Ricardo, Mill), II. Neo-Classical theory of international

trade equilibrium and the equilibrium terms of trade (Marshall, Edgeworth, Haberler),

III. Modern theory of factor endowments, factor price equalization, factor income distri-

bution, two-sector growth models (Heckscher, Ohlin, Samuelson, Solow, Uzawa, Kemp).

Economic laws (theory) governing trade between two countries dawned in Adam Smith

- Chapter 11 of restraints upon the importation from foreign countries of goods that can

be produced at home, Smith (1776, 1961, p.478): ”What is prudence in the conduct

of every private family, can scarcely be folly in that of a great kingdom. If a foreign

country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better

buy [import] it from them with some part [export] of the produce of our own industry,

employed [produced] in a way in which we have some advantage”.

By scrutinizing the principle of cheapness and advantage in more detail with some

illustrations, Ricardo (1817, p.81, p.175), cf. Ruffin (2002, p.743), came up with the

law of comparative advantage: ”Under a system of perfectly free commerce, each country

naturally devotes its capital and labour to such employments [industries, goods, sectors] as

are most beneficial to each. This pursuit of individual advantages is admirably connected

with the universal good of the whole.”

Precisely, the Ricardian term comparative advantage means the ability in autarky to

produce a good at lower cost/price (relative to other goods), compared to another autarky

country. Moreover, the law of comparative advantage (cost) says that a country exports

2

Page 3: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

(imports) the good with the low (high) relative (p = P1/P2) autarky price, and it can be

expressed an inequality in relative autarky prices :

P1A/P2A = pA < P1B/P2B = pB : X1A > 0 (1)

The prediction of trade patterns - X1A > 0 : export of good 1 by country A - in open

economies by the autarky condition, (1), is (with precise assumptions) not violated in any

trade model for : Two countries, two goods [commodities, sectors], two factors, (2x2x2).

The world equilibrium terms of trade (p∗) are usually just taken (assumed, not proved)

to fall strictly between the two countries relative prices (price ratios) under autarky, i.e.,

pA < p∗ < pB (2)

excluding the case of one country (say A) being ’small’, hence p∗ = pB.

The bilateral rule of comparing relative prices under autarky to determine trade pat-

terns, (1), is not valid for a multicommodity (multisector, i ≥ 3) world, as demonstrated

by Drabicki and Takayama (1979, p.217). On these ”higher dimensional” issues, see

Deardorff (1980), Shimomura and Wong (1998). We focus on a full story of the (2x2x2)

model, but in contrast to the available literature so far, our objective is to deduce and

finally present explicit analytical solutions of the world trade model (2x2x2).

While comparative advantage explains why and how trade takes place, it does not

explain (give) the terms of trade : relative prices, p∗ in (2). Ricardo’s numerical examples,

cf. Chipman (1965, p.482), offer no clear size of (p∗) or hints to general answers. It was

Stuart Mill, who first gave an analysis of the formation of ”international values” [world

market prices, determination of p∗ in (2)], that offered a rigorous answer - discussed in

detail by Chipman (1965, p.485-86) - upon a pure trade theory example left by Ricardo.

Stuart Mill (1875, p.352) stated: ”When trade is established between two countries,

the two commodities will exchange for each other at the same rate of interchange in

both countries”, i.e. the ”law of one price” that will also be adhered to in our (2x2x2)

model. Next Mill (1875, p.359) says: ”All trade, either between nations or individuals,

is an interchange of commodities, in which the things that they respectively have to sell,

constitute also their means of purchase: the supply brought by the one constitutes his

demand for what is brought by the other. So that supply and demand are but another

3

Page 4: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

expression for reciprocal demand - or named the Equation of International Demand” - or

today: the trade balance equation with a zero constraint - which is adopted here, too.

To handle the special trade case of Ricardo, Mill assumed that consumers in both

countries had identical commodity demand functions of simplest functional form, Mill

(1875, p.361): ”Let us therefore assume, that the influence of cheapness on demand

conforms to some simple law, common to both countries and to both commodities. As

the simplest possible and most convenient, let us suppose that in both countries any given

increase of cheapness [fall in price] produces an proportional increase of consumption: or,

in other words that value expended in the commodity, the cost incurred for the sake

of obtaining it, is always the same, whether that cost [expenditure] affords a greater or

smaller quantity of the commodity.” In short, Mill used here consumer demand functions,

generated today by Cobb-Douglas utility functions, as we will do for preferences below.

Marshall (1879, 1974) continued the study of Mill’s examples with an in-depth analysis

of the trade balance equilibrium determination of ”international values” (terms of trade)

by ”reciprocal demand” (offer, net-export) curves of two countries. Let us hear, Marshall

(1879, 1974, p.1): ”The function of pure theory and models is to deduce definite conclu-

sions from definite hypothetical premises. The premises should approximate as closely as

possible to the facts with which the corresponding applied theory has to deal. But the

terms used in the pure theory must be cable of exact interpretation, and the hypotheses

on which it is based must be simple and easily handled. The pure theory of foreign

trade satisfies these conditions”. Marshall supported his propositions/corollaries with 24

offer-curve diagrams; many now standard, cf. summary in Deardorff (2006, pp.322).

While ”classical” trade theory (Smith, Ricardo) may have assumed, cf. Chipman

(1966, p.18), ”constant factor prices and different technologies” among countries, Heckscher

(1919, 1991, p.47) examined some : ”fundamental assumptions concerning the reasons

for differences in comparative costs among countries”, i.e. why are in (1) the autarky

relative costs (prices) pA and pB different ? As a keen economist, Heckscher correctly

argued that countries with same - technologies and relative factor prices - do not trade;

since then: ”relative costs in one country cannot possibly differ from those in the other.

Therefore trade between the countries will not arise”, Heckscher (1991, p.47).

4

Page 5: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Hence behind the Ricardian inequality in (1), he saw (emphasized) as a prerequisite

an inequality in autarky relative factor prices, ωA and ωB : ”different relative prices of

the factors of production in the exchanging countries”, Heckscher (1991, p.48). But next

opening free trade would itself affect the relative factor prices and maybe, even under

some conditions, bring about not just partial, but full factor price equalization (FPE).

As to ”modern factor endowment theory”, Ohlin (1935, Appendix I) re-examined and

extends the general equilibrium equation systems of Walras-Cassel for the mutual interde-

pendence pricing of commodities and factors to trading regions (countries). He introduced

and emphasized the role of different factor endowments ratios, (kA, kB), among regions;

but Ohlin (1933, p.561-62) opted in most situations for partial factor price equalization.

Next Samuelson (1948, p.169) enters the discussion: ‘In attempting to devise a rigor-

ous proof of the partial character of factor-price equalization, I made a surprising discov-

ery: the proposition is false. It is not true that factor price equalization is impossible. It

is not true that factor price equalization is highly improbable. On the contrary, not only

is factor-price equalization possible and probable, but in a wide variety of circumstances

it is inevitable.” Samuelson (1949, p.182) restated verbally eight conditions for FPE.

A major problem with Pareto efficient factor allocation in even two-sector economies

with flexible sector technologies is that they in fact constitute ”miniature Walrasian

general equilibrium systems”. Thus early work upon two-sector growth models in various

qualitative versions addressed some of the major issues of this paper, cf. Uzawa (1962-63),

Oniki-Uzawa (1965), that were recently resolved quantitatively in Jensen (2003).

Our main result is finally for internationally different technologies and consumer pref-

erences to have solved explicitly the Basic Trade Model (2x2x2) for the endogenous terms

of trade, ( p∗), and presenting analytically the international general equilibrium solutions

with explicit existence conditions upon country endowments for preserving diversification

of the two trading economies. We proceed axiomatically in exposition and sections.

Section 2 gives the general framework of autarky and open economies. Autarky general

equilibrium serves as benchmark and gives expressions of comparative advantage. Section

3 solves the world trade balance equation and gives ( p∗) in Propositions 1-2. Section 4

exhibit results of basic trade models. Section 5 concludes and suggests further research.

5

Page 6: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

2 The Structure of Two-Sector Economies

2.1 Framework: Factor endowments, GDP accounting

There are two countries in the world, A and B. These countries may produce two consumer

goods (sectors), i = 1, 2, which are fully homogeneous throughout the world. In both

sectors, they are using two primary production factors, labour and capital. Labour

endowment (supply) in country J = A,B is LJ , while capital endowment is KJ ; its

factor proportion (endowment ratio) is, kJ = KJ/LJ . Migration of the primary factors is

excluded, while reallocation (mobility) among sectors is always possible and frictionless.

It is assumed that both factors are fully employed in each country :

K1J +K2J = KJ ; L1J + L2J = LJ ; kJ ≡ KJ/LJ , J = A,B

kJ = KJ/LJ = λL1Jk1J + λL2J

k2J ; kiJ ≡ KiJ/LiJ , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (3)

λL1J=

kJ − k2J

k1J − k2J

, λL2J= 1− λL1J

; λLiJ≡ LiJ

LJ

, i = 1, 2 J = A,B (4)

λK1J=k1J

kJ

λL1J, λK2J

= 1− λK1J; λKiJ

≡ KiJ

KJ

, i = 1, 2 J = A,B (5)

where λLiJ, λKiJ

, are the fractions of labour (capital) of country J employed in sector

(i), and kiJ is the capital-labour ratio (sometimes called ’capital intensity’) in sector (i),

country J . It follows from (4) that a diversification condition, 0 < λL1J< 1 - i.e., actual

production of both goods in country J - is equivalent to a pair of inequalities,

0 < λL1J< 1 : k1J < kJ < k2J or k2J < kJ < k1J , J = A,B (6)

Technology exhibits constant returns to scale (CRTS) in both countries. Since factor

markets are assumed perfectly competitive (zero profit), the Euler theorem ensures that

the monetary value (revenue) from production (YiJ) in each sector equates the factor

income of employed primary factors, which is also total minimum production cost (CiJ),

PiJ YiJ = wJ LiJ + rJ KiJ = CiJ , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (7)

with the sectoral cost shares of labour and capital :

εLiJ=wJ LiJCiJ

, εKiJ=rJ KiJ

CiJ; εLiJ

+ εKiJ= 1 , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (8)

6

Page 7: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Total national income (Gross Domestic Product, GDP), (YJ), is obtained as

YJ = P1J Y1J + P2J Y2J = wJ LJ + rJ KJ , J = A,B (9)

and the total (macro) factor income shares, δLJ , δKJ , in each country become,

δLJ =wJ LJ

YJ

, δKJ =rJ KJ

YJ

; δLJ + δKJ = 1 , J = A,B (10)

By (10), the shares , δLJ , δKJ , are identically linked to the country factor endowment

ratio, (kJ), and relative factor prices, (ωJ), stated as

kJ ≡δKJ

δLJ

[wJ

rJ

]=

δKJ

δLJ

ωJ , ωJ ≡wJ

rJ, J = A,B (11)

Let QiJ , i = 1, 2, denote the quantitative size of the domestic final demands (absorp-

tion level) for good 1 and good 2, and they are respectively equal to domestic production,

YiJ , (7), minus exports XiJ , (imports = - XiJ ), i.e.,

Q1J = Y1J −X1J , Q2J = Y2J −X2J , J = A,B (12)

The trade balance is assumed to satisfy the constraint,

P1JX1J + P2JX2J = 0 ; i.e. YJ = P1JQ1J + P2JQ2J , J = A,B (13)

i.e., balanced trade prevails with no foreign borrowing/lending allowed. The composition

of GDP, YJ , (13), into ’final demand’ (expenditure shares), siJ , is

siJ = PiJQiJ/YJ ;∑2

i=1 siJ ≡∑2

i=1 PiJQiJ/YJ = 1 , J = A,B (14)

The macro factor income shares δLJ , δKJ , (10), are GDP expenditure-weighted, (39),

combinations of sectoral factor (cost) shares, εLiJ, εKiJ

,

δLJ =∑2

i=1 siJ εLiJ, δKJ =

∑2i=1 siJ εKiJ

, δLJ + δKJ = 1 , J = A,B (15)

The factor allocation fractions, (4), (5), can then be restated as,

λLiJ= siJ εLiJ

/δLJ , λKiJ= siJ εKiJ

/δKJ , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (16)

The total factor endowment ratio, (kJ), satisfies the identity, cf. (11), (15) :

KJ/LJ = kJ =δKJ

δLJ

ωJ =[∑2

i=1 siJ εKiJ/∑2

i=1 siJ εLiJ

]ωJ , J = A,B (17)

which is a convenient representation of full employment and factor endowment ratio, (3).

7

Page 8: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

2.2 Sector technologies, cost functions and relative prices

For sector i = 1, 2 in country J = A,B, we assume standard CD technologies (FiJ) :

YiJ = FiJ(LiJ , LiJ) = γiJ(LiJ)1−aiJ (KiJ)aiJ , yiJ = γiJ(kiJ)aiJ , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (18)

where YiJ is output of sector (i) in country J - with sectoral labour productivity, yiJ ≡

YiJ/LiJ , capital-labor ratio, kiJ ≡ KiJ/LiJ , and the capital intensity parameter, aiJ .

Free factor mobility and efficient factor allocation between sectors impose a common

marginal rate of factor substitution within each country, (equal to the relative factor

prices, ωJ ≡ wJ/rJ = wiJ/riJ ≡ ωiJ), which with the CD technologies (18) become :

ωJ = ωiJ =1− aiJaiJ

kiJ ; kiJ =aiJ

1− aiJωiJ ;

k1J

k2J

=a1J/ (1− a1J)

a2J/ (1− a2J), J = A,B (19)

The standard dual CD sector cost functions of (18-19) are,

CiJ(wJ , rJ , YiJ) =1

γiJ

[wJ

1− aiJ

]1−aiJ[ rJaiJ

]aiJYiJ , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (20)

and the sectoral cost shares (8) are :

εLiJ= 1− aiJ , εKiJ

= aiJ ; εLiJ+ εKiJ

= 1 , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (21)

The relative commodity (output) prices (unit costs) are derived from (20), (19) as,

pJ =P1J

P2J

=C1J/Y1J

C2J/Y2J

=c1J (ωJ)

c2J (ωJ)=

1

aJ

γ2J

γ1J

[ωJ ] a2J−a1J ≡ pJ(ωJ) , J = A,B (22)

where

aJ =(a1J)a1J (1− a1J)1−a1J

(a2J)a2J (1− a2J)1−a2J > 0 , J = A,B (23)

Relative prices pJ(ωJ) with CD (22) can range from zero to infinity, cf. Fig. 1, Case 1-2.

Next, we can use the inverse of relative prices (22) to get the relative factor prices,

ωJ =[ γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J , J = A,B (24)

Inserting (24) into (19), (18), give sectoral capital-labour ratios (intensities) and sectoral

labour productivities with the relative good price (pJ) as the ’independent’ variable,

kiJ(pJ) =aiJ

1− aiJ[ γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (25)

8

Page 9: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

yiJ(pJ) = γiJ[ aiJ

1− aiJ]aiJ [ γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] aiJa2J−a1J , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (26)

The ratios of sectoral labour productivities within countries follow from (26), cf. (18-19),

as :

y2J

y1J

=1− a1J

1− a2J

pJ , J = A,B (27)

Next rewrite (4) - with CD technologies, (19) - as,

λL1J(pJ) =

kJk2J (pJ )

− 1

k1J (pJ )k2J (pJ )

− 1=

kJk2J (pJ )

− 1

a1J/(1−a1J )a2J/(1−a2J )

− 1, J = A,B (28)

and use (25) to get the allocation fractions of labour (28) and capital (5) in (pJ):

λL1J(pJ) =

a2J (1− a1J)

a1J (1− a2J)− a2J (1− a1J)

[1− a2J

a2J

[γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a1J−a2J

kJ − 1

](29)

λK1J(pJ) =

k1J(pJ)

kJ

λL1J(pJ) , J = A,B (30)

A diversified economy clearly requires that, λL1J, (6), here satisfies the diversification

condition : 0 < λL1J(pJ) < 1, (29). Solving this inequality (29) with respect to pJ yields

(impose after some manipulations) the following relative price interval restriction :

0 < λL1J< 1⇔ p

J=

1

aJ

γ2J

γ1J

[1− a2J

a2J

kJ

](a2J−a1J )

< pJ <1

aJ

γ2J

γ1J

[1− a1J

a1J

kJ

](a2J−a1J )

= pJ

(31)

where pJ< pJ for any feasible parameter set. The relative price limits in condition (31)

define the closed interval :[p

J, pJ

]- cf. the two-sector geometry in Fig.1.

This interval (31) is solely determined by technology parameters and by technologically

(Pareto) efficient factor endowment allocation. Since the relative prices (”opportunity

cost”) pJ (22) are always the slope of the production possibility frontier (PPF), pJ

(p J)

in (31) is the slope of the PPF, when production of sector 1 (sector 2) is zero. Condition

(31) in fact, is equivalent to the ’diversification cone’, (6). To see this, re-write (31) as

a2J > a1J :a1J

1− a1J

[γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J

< kJ <a2J

1− a2J

[γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J

(32)

a1J > a2J :a2J

1− a2J

[γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J

< kJ <a1J

1− a1J

[γ1J

γ2J

aJ pJ

] 1a2J−a1J

(33)

and recall (25). Moreover, the relative price diversification condition (31) is equivalent

to the following relative factor price interval restrictions:

a2J > a1J :1− a2J

a2J

kJ < ωJ(pJ) <1− a1J

a1J

kJ (34)

9

Page 10: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

a1J > a2J :1− a1J

a1J

kJ < ωJ(pJ) <1− a2J

a2J

kJ (35)

As will be clear from Fig.1 and further explained below, the conditions (31)-(35) are

always satisfied by the general equilibrium solution (43) in autarky. The intervals for the

autarky general equilibrium solution pJ(kJ), (45), are given by closed intervals of (31).

Case 1, a2J > a1J Case 2, a2J < a1J

J

2J

1J 2J

1J

J

Jp Jp JkJk

J J

Jk Jp Jp

JkJ

pJ

p

Figure 1. Relative factor prices, ωJ, capital-labour ratios, kiJ, (19), relative commodity

prices, pJ(ωJ), (22), price interval of pJ, (31), Walrasian autarky equilibria, ΨJ(ωJ), (43).

2.3 Consumer preferences and demand functions

In each country J = A,B, we have a representative consumer with homothetic utility

function (preferences) of the CD form with country-specific parameters (αJ):

uJ = UJ (Q1J , Q2J) = (Q1J)αJ (Q2J)1−αJ , J = A,B (36)

where QiJ is the consumption of final good (i) in country J .

Maximization of utility (36) under the budget constraint, cf. (9), (13) :

YJ = P1J ·Q1J + P2J ·Q2J , J = A,B (37)

yields the optimal demanded quantities QiJ and expenditure shares, siJ , (14),

Q1J = αJ · (YJ/P1J) ; Q2J = (1− αJ) · (YJ/P2J), J = A,B (38)

s1J = P1JQ1J/YJ = αJ ; s2J = P2JQ2J/YJ = 1− αJ ;∑2

i=1 siJ = 1 (39)

10

Page 11: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

2.4 Walrasian general equilibrium of two autarky economies

In autarky, final demand for good i in country J must equate internal production (output),

i.e., cf. (12),

QiJ = YiJ , XiJ = 0 , i = 1, 2 , J = A,B (40)

By combining the sectoral factor (cost) shares, εLiJ, εKiJ

, (21), and expenditure shares,

siJ , (39), our factor income shares, δLJ , δKJ , (15), here become,

δLJ = αJ(1− a1J) + (1− αJ)(1− a2J) , δKJ = αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J ≡ βJ , J = A,B (41)

and hence the factor allocation fractions, (4), (5), are here given as :

λLiJ=

αJ(1− aiJ)

αJ(1− a1J) + (1− αJ)(1− a2J), λKiJ

=αJaiJ

αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J

(42)

Thus with CD technologies, (18), and CD consumer preferences, (36), the Walrasian

general equilibrium (with market clearing prices on commodity and factor markets and

Pareto efficient endowment allocations) of the autarky economy is obtained by the factor

endowment (kJ) - factor price (ωJ) correspondence, satisfying the identity, (17), as a

complete Walrasian general equilibrium condition for J = A,B, cf. Jensen (2003, p.69) :

kJ = ΨJ(ωJ) =δKJ(ωJ)

δLJ(ωJ)ωJ =

αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J

αJ(1− a1J) + (1− αJ)(1− a2J)ωJ =

βJ

1− βJ

ωJ (43)

with the locus, kJ = ΨJ(ωJ), J = A,B, shown in Figures 1-2.

With factor endowment ratios (kJ) as as exogenous variables, the endogenous general

equilibrium autarky factor price ratios, ωJ(kJ), follow from (43) as,

ωJ = Ψ−1J (kJ) =

1− [αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J ]

αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J

kJ =1− βJ

βJ

kJ , J = A,B (44)

Hence the autarky relative commodity price (price ratio) is obtained by (44) and (22):

pJ(kJ) =P1J

P2J

=1

aJ

γ2J

γ1J

[1− [αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J ]

αJa1J + (1− αJ)a2J

kJ

]a2J−a1J=

1

aJ

γ2J

γ1J

[1− βJ

βJ

kJ

]a2J−a1J(45)

which are, e.g., illustrated for country A and B in Figure 2 - shown by pA(kA) and pB(kB).

If the two autarky CD economies have identical technologies, the same preferences, and

hence only differ in endowments, the general CD price ratio formula (45) is reduced to,

pJ(kJ) =1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− [α a1 + (1− α) a2 ]

α a1 + (1− α) a2

kJ

]a2−a1≡ 1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− ββ

kJ

]a2−a1, J = A,B (46)

11

Page 12: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

*( ) ( )B B A A 1A A 2A 1B B 2 Bp k p p k k k k k k k

A B 1A 1B B A 2A 2B p = p ω = ω ψ ψ ω = ω

( )B Bω k

( )A Aω k

wJ

pJ k

J

Figure 2. Relative prices pJ(ωJ), (22), cf. Case 1, Fig.1 (same technology), autarky

general equilibria kJ = ΨJ(ωJ), (43), autarky relative factor prices ωJ(kJ), (44), autarky

relative commodity prices pJ(kJ), (45), and terms of trade p∗, (2).

Thus the Ricardian Law of Comparative Costs (1) can be expressed by the following

inequality in the bilateral autarky general equilibrium relative prices (price ratios), (45) :

P1A/P2A = pA(kA) < P1B/P2B = pB(kB) : X1A > 0 (47)

Simple applications of the comparative advantage principle for obtaining trade patterns

by the general autarky rule (47), (45), are :

Lemma A. Countries with same - technologies, preferences, endowments - do not trade.

Countries with same - technologies and relative factor prices - do not trade.

Country sizes are irrelevant for the bilateral trade pattern, which are uniquely determined

by : technology parameters, preference parameters, and the factor endowment ratios.

Proof. If kA = kB in (46), then, pA (kA) = pB (kB), which implies : X1A = 0, by (47).

If ωA = Ψ−1A (kA) = 1−βA

βAkA = 1−βB

βBkB = ωB in (44), then, pA (kA) = pB (kB); cf. Fig. 2.

The general solution for the autarky price ratios pJ(kJ), (45), depend only on : techno-

logical parameters, consumer preferences, endowments ratios - but not vJ , cf. (64).

A parametrically restricted version of (45) are autarky price ratios pJ(kJ) given by :

a1A = a1B = a1 ; a2A = a2B = a2 ; βJ ; pJ(kJ) =1

a

γ2J

γ1J

[1− βJ

βJ

kJ

]a2−a1, J = A,B (48)

12

Page 13: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

which gives the trade patterns (47) of submodels in Proposition 1 and Table 1 below.

Trade patterns (47) of Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (HOS) CD models follow (46), i.e. kJ .

Lemma B. If two countries differ in preferences and in technologies (or endowments),

then endowments (or technologies) alone cannot explain their trade patterns.

Proof. It follows from (47) and autarky price expressions in (48) and the general (45).

2.5 Sector technologies, endowments and global diversification

For later purposes, we will consider a parametrically constrained version of the relative

price interval restriction (31) - with a1A = a1B = a1 ; a2A = a2B = a2 and hence,

aA = aB = a cf. (23), (71) - for our two countries, J = A,B :

0 < λL1J< 1 : p

J=

1

a

γ2J

γ1J

[1− a2

a2

kJ

](a2−a1)

< pJ <1

a

γ2J

γ1J

[1− a1

a1

kJ

](a2−a1)

= pJ (49)

In this two-country world, the diversification condition, 0 < λL1J< 1, J = A,B, (49),

defines two closed price intervals:[p

A(kA), pA(kA)

]and

[p

B(kB), pB(kB)

], see Figure 3.

It is excluded that any of these two closed price intervals fully contains the other.

Figure 3 a. The intersection price interval ( p ) : p ≡ [ pA, pB].

0 A Ap k A Ap k A Ap k

0 B Bp k B Bp k B Bp k

Figure 3 b. The intersection price interval ( p ) : p ≡ pA≡ pB.

1

0 A Ap k A Ap k A Ap k

0 B Bp k B Bp k B Bp k

Figure 3 c. The intersection price interval ( p ) : p ≡ [ pA, pA] ≡ [ p

B, pB]

0 A Ap k A Ap k A Ap k

0 B Bp k B Bp k B Bp k

Figure 3. The price intervals, (49), and intersections ( p ), (54-55), for countries A, B.

13

Page 14: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Without loss of generality: Let pA≥ p

B, cf. Fig. 3, and note that p

A≥ p

B⇔ pA ≥ pB

due to (49). Hence by (49), we get limits for their factor endowment ratio, (kA/kB), as :

pA≥ p

B⇔ pA ≥ pB ⇔ a1 > a2 :

kAkB≤[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ γ (50)

pA≥ p

B⇔ pA ≥ pB ⇔ a1 < a2 :

kAkB≥[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ γ (51)

Evidently, a necessary condition for existence of a diversified international general equi-

librium solution for the relative prices (p∗) is that the intersection of the price intervals:[p

A, pA

]∩[p

B, pB

]≡ p 6= ∅, is non-empty. With p

A≥ p

B, Fig. 3, then p 6= ∅ requires:

pA≤ pB, which stipulates that factor endowment ratios, (kA/kB) satisfy, cf. (49),

pA≤ pB ⇔ a1 > a2 :

kA

kB

≥ a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ a γ (52)

pA≤ pB ⇔ a1 < a2 :

kA

kB

≤ a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ a γ (53)

Note that, when a1 > a2 [a1 < a2], then a < 1 [ a > 1 ].

Thus the condition, pB≤ p

A≤ pB ⇔ p 6= ∅, is met, if (kA/kB), cf.(50), (52), (51), (53):

p 6= ∅, a1 > a2 : a γ ≡ a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≤ kAkB≤[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ γ (54)

p 6= ∅, a1 < a2 : γ ≡[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≤ kAkB≤ a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

≡ a γ (55)

If the necessary ”factor endowment ratio” conditions (54-55) are satisfied, the intersection

[ p ] between the two price (minimal cost) intervals is non-empty (Fig. 3 a).

If the two countries have the same sector technologies (HOS-HOL models below) with

γ = 1, necessary diversification conditions (54-55) for factor endowment ratios (kA/kB)

are:

p 6= ∅, a1 > a2 : a ≡ a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)<

kAkB≤ 1 (56)

p 6= ∅, a1 < a2 : 1 ≤ kAkB

<a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)≡ a (57)

When the equality (kA/kB) = a γ holds - endpoint of (54-55) - then pA

= pB, and hence

the intersection, p, between [ pA, pA] and [ p

B, pB] is a single common point, (Fig.3 b).

When the other equality (kA/kB) = γ holds - endpoint of (54-55) - then two intervals,

[ pA, pA] and [ p

B, pB], coincide (equal to p), (Fig. 3 c).

14

Page 15: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Thus, we see that the respective endpoints of (54), (55), (56), (57) determine the largest

potential interval (range) for the factor endowment ratio, (kA/kB), that are compatible

with preserving the production diversification (two sectors) in both trading countries.

Let us see two case examples, cf. Fig. 1, of the endowment ratio intervals (56), (57),

Case 2 : a1 = 0.5, a2 = 0.25; a1 > a2 : a =a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)= 1/3 <

kAkB≤ 1 (58)

Case 1 : a1 = 0.25, a2 = 0.5; a1 < a2 : 1 ≤ kAkB

< 3 =a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)= a (59)

Although the assumption (hypothesis) of diversification was stressed as a necessary con-

dition for factor price equalization (FPE), Samuelson (1948, p.175,178; 1949, p.182,193),

no explicit factor endowment interval like (56-57) for two countries was given then (later).

Moreover, consumer preferences and country sizes will modify these intervals (54-59)

- necessary, but not sufficient - of compatible endowment ratios, (kA/kB), cf. section 3.3.

Incidentally, Figures 3a, 3b, reveal that the simple illustrative assumption : pA≥ p

B

plays a role in outlining limiting cases of ”incipient specialization” in the two countries

[ ”where nothing is being produced of one commodity, but where it is a matter of indif-

ference, whether an infinitesimal amount is or is not being produced, so that price and

marginal cost are equal”, Samuelson (1949, p.182) ].

When condition pA≥ p

Bholds, cf. (50-51), there are three possible specialization cases:

(i) Country A produces only good 2 (i.e. p∗ = pA), and country B does not specializes

in any sector (because pB< p∗ < pB); Fig. 3a.

(ii) Country B produces only good 1 (i.e. p∗ = pB), while country A produces both goods

(since pA< p∗ < pA); Fig. 3a.

(iii) Both countries are specialized (p∗ = pA

= pB), A (B) makes good 2 (1) ; Fig. 3b.

Clearly, these specialization patterns above just reverse with the assumption : pA< p

B.

By the way, Samuelson (1949, p.188) first used curves (qualitatively), as in Fig. 1-

2, to summarize the connections between relative prices (pJ = P1J/P2J), relative factor

prices (wiJ/riJ = ωiJ), and sectoral capital-labor ratios (kiJ = KiJ/LiJ). But he used,

Li/Ki = 1/ki, on the right horizontal axis; hence in Fig. 1-2, the rays would then be two

rectangular hyperbolas: ωi = [(1 − ai)/ai]/ki, cf. (19). It is more convenient with every

curve ωi(ki) in all cases to originate from: (0, 0); that also applies to: kJ = ΨJ(ωJ), (43).

15

Page 16: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

3 International free trade and world market prices

We assume free trade between two countries, J=A,B, with perfect integration of the

national commodity markets. Due to the absence of frictions in international trade the

law of one commodity price, Pi, and hence one relative price, (p) apply:

PiA = PiB = Pi , i = 1, 2 : pA = P1/P2 = pB = p (60)

3.1 Free trade balances and world market equilibrium

Country trades are here always balanced. As commodity markets are fully integrated,

world market equilibrium implies, cf. (12) :

XiA = YiA −QiA = −XiB = − (YiB −QiB) ; i = 1, 2 (61)

where XiJ are exports (imports = - XiJ) of good (i) by country J .

In order to derive the equation of the world trade balance and its terms of trade,

rewrite the optimal consumption demand for good 1 (38), using the definition of exports

in equation (61), and using (9), (13), (14), (39), to give the expenditure expressions :

P1Q1J = P1 · (Y1J −X1J) = αJ · (P1Y1J + P2Y2J)

P1X1J = (1− αJ)P1Y1J − αJ · P2Y2J . (62)

In ”real (goods) terms” - exports per capita, x1J = X1J/LJ - (62) becomes, cf. (18), (4),

x1J = X1J/LJ = (1− αJ)λL1J· y1J −

αJ

pλL2J

· y2J , J = A,B (63)

Let vA, vB represent the country shares of world labour force (population), i.e.,

vA = LA/(LA + LB), vA + vB = 1. (64)

Lemma 1. For two free trading economies, with CD utility functions (36) and regular

sector technologies (production functions), yiJ , i=1,2 , J=A,B, the international equilib-

rium terms of trade, p = P1/P2, (60), satisfies the condition:

p =υA αA · λL2A

· y2A + υB αB · λL2B· y2B

υA (1− αA)λL1A· y1A + υB (1− αB)λL1B

· y1B

=y2A

y1A

υA αA · λL2A+ υB αB · λL2B

· (y2B/y2A)

υA (1− αA) · λL1A+ υB (1− αB)λL1B

· (y1B/y1A)(65)

16

Page 17: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

and with the same sector technologies, yiA = yiB = yi, (i = 1, 2), in A and B :

p =y2

y1

υA αA · λL2A+ υB αB · λL2B

υA (1− αA) · λL1A+ υB (1− αB)λL1B

(66)

Proof. Inserting (63-64) in (61) gives world market equilibrium condition (65).

3.2 Computation of the endogenous terms of trade

The ratios of sectoral labour productivities between countries become by (26):

yiAyiB

= Di p

[a1A a2B−a1B a2A

(a2A−a1A)(a2B−a1B)

], i = 1, 2 (67)

Di =γiA

[γ1Aγ2A

] aiAa2A−a1A

γiB

[γ1Bγ2B

] aiBa2B−a1B

[aiA

1−aiA

]aiA[aiB

1−aiB

]aiB [aA]aiA

a2A−a1A

[aB]aiB

a2B−a1B

> 0 , i = 1, 2 (68)

where aA, aB, were given in (23).

With (67-68), (27), (29), and (60), we have expressions to turn world market equilib-

rium condition (65) into formulas for the terms of trade (p) expressed in its fundamental

determinants : parameters of technology and preference and the exogenous factor endow-

ments, (kA, kB). Inserting (67-68), (27), (29): λL2J= 1− λL1J

, into (65), we get :

p =

[υA (1− αA) (1− a2A)λL1A

− υAαA (1− a1A) (1− λL1A)

υB

[αB(1−a1A)

D2(1− λL1B

)− (1−αB)(1−a2A)D1

λL1B

] ] (a2A−a1A)(a2B−a1B)a1B ·a2A−a1A·a2B

(69)

This is an implicit function for the terms of trade (p) in the factor endowments kA and

kB: Ω(p, kA, kB) = 0, as the labour allocation fractions, λL1A, λL1B

, in (69) also - with

common prices (60) - include (p, kA, kB). Hence by (69), (29), (60), and after several

manipulations, we can give the expression for the implicit function Ω (p, kA, kB) in,

Theorem 1. For (2x2x2) models of trading economies with CD sector technologies,

(18), CD utility functions, (36), the international equilibrium terms of trade (relative

price), p∗ = P1/P2, (2), is an implicit function of the factor endowments, (kA, kB) :

Ω (p, kA, kB) = 0 - with solutions, (roots p = p∗ > 0), given by the equation (locus) :

17

Page 18: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

υA

a1B − a2B

a2B (1− a1B)

[1

aA

γ2A

γ1A

] 1a2A−a1A

[αA (1− a1A) + (1− αA) (1− a2A)] kA · p(1)

− υB

a1A − a2A

(1− a1A) (1− a2A)

[a1B (1− a2B)

a2B (1− a1B)(1− a1A)

αB

D2

+ (1− a2A)1− αB

D1

]· p(2)

+ υB

a1A − a2A

1− a1A

1− a2B

a2B

[1

aB

γ2B

γ1B

] 1a2B−a1B

[1− αB

D1

+1− a1A

1− a2A

αB

D2

]kB · p(3)

− υA

a1B − a2B

a2B (1− a1B)[αAa1A + (1− αA) a2A] = Ω (p, kA, kB) = 0 (70)

with : p(1) = p1

a1A−a2A , p(2) = pa2A·a1B−a1A·a2B

(a1A−a2A)(a1B−a2B) , p(3) = pa1A(1−a2B)−a2A(1−a1B)

(a1A−a2A)(a1B−a2B)

and where, (aA, aB), were given by, (23), and, (D1, D2), by (68).

Proposition 1. Basic World Trade Model - The implicit function, Ω(p, kA, kB) = 0, (70),

becomes an explicit analytic terms of trade function (surface), p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), if the CD

sector technologies, (18), in both countries have parameter restrictions, cf. (23), (49) :

aiA = aiB = ai , i = 1, 2 : aA = aB = a (71)

p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) =1

a

γ υA

[γ2Aγ1A

] 1a2−a1 [1− βA] kA + υB

[γ2Bγ1B

] 1a2−a1 [1− βB] kB

γ υAβA + υBβB

a2−a1

(72)

where : a ≡ aa11 (1− a1)1−a1

aa22 (1− a2)1−a2 ; γ ≡

[[γ2B

γ2A

]a1 [γ1A

γ1B

]a2] 1a2−a1

(73)

βJ ≡ αJ a1 + (1− αJ) a2 , J = A,B (74)

and factor endowments, (kA, kB), satisfy diversification conditions in Proposition 2 below

that impose relevant restrictions (intervals) for the the factor endowment ratios, (kA/kB).

Proof. With, aiA = aiB = ai by (71), we get in (70): p(1) = p(3) = p1

a1−a2 , i.e. a

common price exponent , and p(2) = p0 = 1. By (71), the last two components of Di,

(68) [and D1,D2 in (70)], drops out. Hence (71) implies a drastic simplification of (70),

which with further compilations, cf. (73-74), become the explicit relative price function

(72). The equilibrium value of the terms of trade (72) is positive, since βJ , (74), is less

than one for any 0 < ai < 1 and 0 < αJ < 1, which is sufficient for a positive p∗ in (72),

(when feasible p∗ exist, cf. Proposition 2.)

In comparison to the general implicit solution, p∗, (70), in Theorem 1, solution, p∗,

(72) in Proposition 1 has the advantage to be in closed form, and yet encompass some

degree of ”heterogeneity” (γ), (73), in the sector technologies across the trading countries.

18

Page 19: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

The international terms of trade expression, p∗, (72) - illustrated geometrically as surfaces

(contours) in Figures 4a-4b - depends as a GE solution on four sets of Determinants:

1. Factor endowment ratios (exogenous variables), 2. All sectoral technology parameters,

3. All consumer preference parameters, 4. Relative country sizes (parameters).

Figure 4 a. Terms of trade surface: p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), (76), Case 1: a1 = 0.25 , a2 = 0.5,

with: a = 1.1398 , γ1 = 2, γ2 = 2.6, αA = 0.4, αB = 0.8, υJ = 0.5, βA = 0.4, βB = 0.3,

p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) = 1aγ2γ1

[υA(1−βA)kA+υB(1−βB)kB

υA·βA+υB ·βB

]a2−a1= 1.1406 [ 0.8571 kA + 1.0 kB ]0.25

kA kB

p* kB

kA

2.3

2.2

2.1

2.0

1.5

Figure 4 b. Terms of trade surface: p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), (76), Case 2: a1 = 0.50, a2 = 0.25,

with: a = 0.8774 , γ1 = 2, γ2 = 2.6, αA = 0.4, αB = 0.8, υJ = 0.5, βA = 0.35, βB = 0.45,

p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) = 1aγ2γ1

[υA(1−βA)kA+υB(1−βB)kB

υA·βA+υB ·βB

]a2−a1= 1.4817 / [ 0.8125 kA + 0.6875 kB ]0.25

kA

kB

kA

kB

p*

0.8

0.9

1.2

1.1

1.0

19

Page 20: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

wJ

* * ** ***( ) ( )B B A A 1A A A B A B B 2Bp k p p k k k k k k k k k

A B 1A 1B B A 2A 2Bp p ω = ω ψ ψ ω = ω

( )B Bω k

*Bω

*Aω

( )A Aω k

Bp

Ap

pJ k

J

Figure 5. Relative commodity prices, pJ(ωJ), (22), cf. cases in Figure 1, Walrasian

autarky equilibria, kJ = ΨJ(ωJ), (43), autarky relative factor prices, ωJ(kJ), (44), autarky

relative commodity prices, pJ(kJ), (48), size of terms of trade, p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), (72), and

the diversification cone boundaries, k∗J , k∗∗J , by inserting solution p∗ (72) into (32), (33).

A straightforward Corollary of Proposition 1 gives a perspective on simple submodels.

Corollary 1. If CD sector technology parameters (’total factor productivity’), γiJ , (18),

γiA = γiB = γi , i = 1, 2 : γ = 1 (75)

are also the same in both countries, then (72) becomes :

p = p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) =1

a

γ2

γ1

[υA (1− βA) kA + υB (1− βB) kB

υA · βA + υB · βB

]a2−a1(76)

i.e, the terms of trade solution (p∗) with same CD sector technologies in both countries.

With the same tastes, CD preferences, utility functions, cf. (36), and (74),

βA = βB = β ≡ α a1 + (1− α) a2 (77)

the terms of trade (76) becomes :

p = p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) =1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− ββ

(υAkA + υBkB)

]a2−a1(78)

With the same size of two countries, υA = υB = 12, then (78) gives a HOS model solution:

p = p∗ = Φ(kA, kB) =1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− β2 β

(kA + kB)

]a2−a1(79)

20

Page 21: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Finally, with the same factor endowments ratios, kJ = kA = kB, then (79) becomes :

p = p∗ = Φ(kJ) =1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− ββ

kJ

]a2−a1(80)

i.e., the special Walrasian (general) equilibrium relative price ratio in autarky, (46).

3.3 Existence of international general equilibrium solutions

Proposition 2. Existence of international GE solutions to Basic Trade Model.

The solution p∗ (72) of the (2x2x2) model exists economically as a feasible GE solution,

when the factor endowments, (kA, kB), satisfy the GE diversification cone conditions :

(84-92) - expressed, cf. (54-55), in terms of the composite parameters: (γ), (73); (γ),

(50); (a), (52), together with the composite parameters, (ϑ), (ϑ), (ϑ), defined by,

ϑ =υB

υA

1− αB

αA

1− a2

1− a1

(81)

ϑ =υB (1− βB) a2

γ · υAαA (a1 − a2) + υBβB (1− a2)(82)

ϑ =γ · υAβA (1− a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2)

γ · υA (1− βA) a1

(83)

When a1 > a2, the restrictions (intervals) upon the ratio, (kA/kB) are given by:

a1 > a2 : If γ < ϑ , then (84)

kAkB∈ [ ϑ γ, γ ] =

[υB (1− βB) a2

γ · υA (a1 − a2)αA + υBβB (1− a2)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

,

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

](85)

a1 > a2 : If γ > ϑ , then (86)

kAkB∈[ ϑ γ, γ]=

[γ · υAβA (1− a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2)

γ · υA (1− βA) a1

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

,

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

](87)

a1 > a2 : If γ = ϑ , thenkAkB

= ϑ γ = ϑ γ = a γ =a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

(88)

When a1 < a2, the restrictions (intervals) upon the ratio, (kA/kB) are given by:

a1 < a2 : If γ < ϑ , then (89)

kAkB∈ [ γ , ϑ γ ] =

[[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

,υB (1− βB) a2

γ · υA (a1 − a2)αA + υBβB (1− a2)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

](90)

21

Page 22: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

a1 < a2 : If γ > ϑ , then (91)

kAkB∈[γ , ϑ γ]=

[[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

,γ · υAβA (1− a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2)

γ · υA (1− βA) a1

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

](92)

a1 < a2 : If γ = ϑ , thenkAkB

= ϑ γ = ϑ γ = a γ =a2/(1− a2)

a1/(1− a1)

[γ1A/γ2A

γ1B/γ2B

] 1a2−a1

(93)

Proof. See Appendix A.

Note that in contrast to conditions (54-55), preference parameters and country sizes

appear in (81-83), and hence also appear in GE diversification intervals (84-92) for the

endowment ratio (kA/kB), (sufficient conditions, to ensure p∗ with diversification exists).

Corollary 2. The GE diversification cone restrictions (intervals) for factor endowment

ratios (kA/kB) corresponding to Corollary 1, Assumption, (75), are given by, cf. (84-92) :

a1 > a2 : If 1 < ϑ , thenkAkB∈[ υB (1− βB) a2

υA (a1 − a2)αA + υBβB (1− a2), 1]

(94)

a1 > a2 : If 1 > ϑ , thenkAkB∈[υAβA (1− a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2)

υA (1− βA) a1

, 1]

(95)

a1 < a2 : If 1 < ϑ , thenkAkB∈[

1 ,υB (1− βB) a2

υA (a1 − a2)αA + υBβB (1− a2)

](96)

a1 < a2 : If 1 > ϑ , thenkAkB∈[

1 ,υAβA (1− a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2)

υA (1− βA) a1

](97)

The two cases in Fig. 4a-4b have GE endowment ratio intervals, cf. (81-83), (97), (95),

Case 1 : a1 = 0.25, a2 = 0.5; a1 < a2 : 1 > ϑ = 1/3 ; 1 ≤ kAkB

< 2.3333 = ϑ (98)

Case 2 : a1 = 0.5, a2 = 0.25; a1 > a2 : 1 > ϑ = 3/4 ; ϑ = 0.3846 ≤ kAkB

< 1 (99)

which are smaller than the corresponding ”autarky” endowment ratio intervals in (59-58).

The analysis of the effects on factor prices of free international trade in a few goods by

Samuelson (1948,1949) was supposedly extended to any number of goods and factors in

general equilibrium, by ”a succinct summary of the Walrasian statical model of general

equilibrium in its competitive aspects”, Samuelson (1953-1954, p.1). However, it mostly

deals with the interrelations between the factor prices and commodity prices of Pareto ef-

ficient (competitive) resource allocations mainly belonging to production sector equilibria.

But interrelations between ”localisation” (countries) and ”international trade” are only

addressed by giving formal equation systems, Samuelson (1953-1954, p.13). No existence

proof of an international general equilibrium is provided - as in Propositions 1-2.

22

Page 23: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

4 International Free Trade Models and Results

The international trade models of Propositions 1-2 with solution : p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), (72)

allow for countries differing in sizes, endowments, technologies and preferences. They

constitute a comprehensive framework for seeing how these elements affect the existence

and the quantitative aspects of a world trade equilibrium. Moreover, if countries have

the same size, vJ = 0.5, they may be considered as the unified model of traditional

trade models with two production factors. All well-known models can be obtained as

special cases of the Basic Model of Propositions 1-2 - with six submodels reported in

Table 1. The table indicates by (x) aspects, which differ across countries. For example,

international differences in technologies are seen in Ricardian models (Model I). This

Table 1 also give information about parameters that are assumed identical internationally.

In model V (HOS), for instance, these are technology and preference parameters.

Table 1. Models in trade theory as submodels of the Basic Model : Propositions 1-2.

Models Technology Endowments Preferences

I Ricardo x

II Mill x

III Marshall x x

IV Heckscher-Ohlin (HO) x x

V Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (HOS) x

VI Heckscher-Ohlin-Linder (HOL) x x

VII Basic Model x x x

4.1 International terms of trade with diversification

For each model, the explicit expression of the international terms of trade can be easily

obtained from equation (72). Table 2 presents the explicit analytic expressions of the

terms of trade (p∗) for the six models under the general assumption that countries also

differ in size, vJ . The simpler formulas for same country size follow immediately by using

υJ = 0.5. Complying with (84-97), all terms of trade values (p∗) from Table 2 lie between

the relative autarky general equilibrium prices (45); see pA, pB, and p∗ in Tables 3-9.

23

Page 24: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Table 2. Terms of trade (72) from the Basic Model of trade theory in Proposition 1.

I Ricardo p∗ =1

a

[1− ββ

]·γ · υA

[γ2Aγ1A

] 1a2−a1 + υB

[γ2Bγ1B

] 1a2−a1

γ · υA + υB· k

a2−a1

II Mill p∗ =1

a

γ2

γ1

[υA [1− βA] + υB [1− βB]

υAβA + υBβB· k] a2−a1

III Marshall p∗ =1

a

γ · υA[γ2Aγ1A

] 1a2−a1 [1− βA] + υB

[γ2Bγ1B

] 1a2−a1 [1− βB]

γ · υAβA + υBβB· k

a2−a1

IV HO p∗ =1

a

[1− ββ

]·γ · υA

[γ2Aγ1A

] 1a2−a1 kA + υB

[γ2Bγ1B

] 1a2−a1 kB

γ · υA + υB

a2−a1

V HOS p∗ =1

a

γ2

γ1

[1− ββ· [υAkA + υBkB]

] a2−a1VI HOL p∗ =

1

a

γ2

γ1

[υA [1− βA] kA + υB [1− βB] kB

υAβA + υBβB

] a2−a1

VII Basic Model p∗ =1

a

γ υA

[γ2Aγ1A

] 1a2−a1 [1− βA] kA + υB

[γ2Bγ1B

] 1a2−a1 [1− βB] kB

γ υAβA + υBβB

a2−a1

HO=Heckscher-Ohlin, HOS=Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson, HOL=Heckscher-Ohlin-Linder

4.2 Factor price equalization

The Basic Model of international trade allows an exact analysis of the conditions under

which factor price equalization occurs. We distinguish between cases when both countries

are diversified - their exogenous endowment ratios (kA, kB) belong to the intervals (84-92)

of Proposition 2 - and some cases with ”incipient specialization” in the two countries.

Without specialization, both countries produce two goods and equalization of free trade

commodity prices (unit costs), (22), gives their factor price ratio: ωJ(p∗) by (24).

Corollary 3. With incomplete specialization in both countries (84-92), factor price

equalization occurs only and always, when CD technologies are internationally identical.

Hence FPE diversification intervals for the factor endowment ratios, (kA/kB), must here be

restricted to the closed intervals (94-97) of Corollary 2. FPE implies : kiA(p∗) = kiB(p∗).

24

Page 25: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Proof. Simply observe that relative factor prices (24) with p J = p∗ solely depends on

technology parameters - only if they are identical in the two countries are : ωA = ωB.

Thus, the wage-rental ratios (ωA, ωB) are equal - FPE - in the international general

equilibrium solutions of the Mill, HOS, HOL, trade models, cf. Table 3,5, irrespective

of different consumer preferences and different endowments (but satisfying Corollary 2).

4.3 World General Equilibrium Allocations and Net Exports

Using the analytical framework of both autarky and world trade models, we show - in

Tables 3-6, [ for autarky and free international trade ] - the general equilibrium (GE)

solutions of selected endogenous variables : (43), (48) [autarky], and : (24), (25), (29-30),

(63) [governed by the world market terms of trade: pJ = p∗ = Φ(kA, kB), (72) ].

In Tables 3-6, we have always chosen : a1 = 0.50 > a2 = 0.25, cf. Case 2, Fig. (1,4b,5).

In Tables 3-5, the relative price intervals (49) are the same, being unaffected by (αA, αB).

First it is shown that preferences (the demand-side of the economy) are as important

in affecting sectoral factor allocations and the trade patterns, (trade flows, net-export) as

the supply-side is. Thus Table 3 gives numerical examples about the roles of tastes in

Table 3. Selected GE solutions of the extended Mill trade model - Table 2.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.5 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1 2 ; 2 2.6 ; kJ 2

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY : (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B pA pA pB pB A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B L 1 A

L 1B

K 1 A

K 1B

x1A

0.2 0.5 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 4.67 3.33 1.01 1.10 1.05 3.93 3.93 3.93 3.93 1.31 1.31 0.26 0.26 0.52 0.52 0.45

0.5 0.5 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 3.33 3.33 1.10 1.10 1.10 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 1.11 1.11 0.40 0.40 0.67 0.67 0.00

0.8 0.5 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 2.44 3.33 1.18 1.10 1.14 2.85 2.85 2.85 2.85 0.95 0.95 0.55 0.55 0.79 0.79 -0.43

0.2 0.2 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 4.67 4.67 1.01 1.01 1.01 4.67 4.67 4.67 4.67 1.56 1.56 0.14 0.14 0.33 0.33 0.00

0.5 0.2 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 3.33 4.67 1.10 1.01 1.05 3.93 3.93 3.93 3.93 1.31 1.31 0.26 0.26 0.52 0.52 -0.45

0.8 0.2 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 2.44 4.67 1.18 1.01 1.10 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 1.11 1.11 0.40 0.40 0.67 0.67 -0.88

0.2 0.8 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 4.67 2.44 1.01 1.18 1.10 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 1.11 1.11 0.40 0.40 0.67 0.67 0.88

0.5 0.8 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 3.33 2.44 1.10 1.18 1.14 2.85 2.85 2.85 2.85 0.95 0.95 0.55 0.55 0.79 0.79 0.43

0.8 0.8 0.95 1.25 0.95 1.25 2.44 2.44 1.18 1.18 1.18 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 0.81 0.81 0.73 0.73 0.89 0.89 0.00

shaping the trade patterns and the size of net exports. The two columns from left contain

the size of the preference parameters, αA and αB. Note that preferences need here to be

different across nations, since there would be no trade otherwise (as seen in three rows).

In the first two rows, consumers in country A relatively dislike good 1 in comparison

25

Page 26: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

to their counterparts in country B (αA < αB), while in rows 4-5 they prefer good 1. For

this reason, in rows 1-2, country A is a net exporter of good 1, i.e. X1A > 0 (last column),

and a net importer in rows 4-5. Evidently, the comparative cost (advantage) principle for

obtaining trade patterns by the general autarky rule (47) changes this inequality relation

with (48) in rows 4-5. Moreover, as the international gap in preferences rises, the traded

quantities increase.

As indicated by the terms of trade expression for the Mill’s Model (Table 2, Model II),

(p∗) also depends on preference parameter αJ via : βJ = αJ a1 + (1− αJ) a2 , J = A,B,

cf. (74). The higher αJ (J = A,B) are, the higher is here p∗, (72), as an increase in αJ is

responsible for a larger demand of good 1 on the world level. Note that the supply sides

of the two economies are identical (γ1A = γ1B = γ1, γ2A = γ2B = γ2) in the Mill’s model.

Thus sectoral factor allocations in the two economies are in fact the same after trade,

i.e. λL1A= λL1B

and λK1A= λK1B

, Table 3 - demonstrating that international differences

in consumers’ tastes can overwhelm the effect due to technology or endowments. Similar

results for trade patterns and factor allocations are illustrated in Tables 4-6.

Table 4 considers countries with differences in technologies and preferences. In this

Marshall model (combining Ricardo and Mill), we have: γ2A/γ1A > γ2B/γ1B, i.e., country A

is technologically relatively more efficient in good (sector) 2. Preferences are only identical

in the boldface cases. But once national consumers’ tastes start to diverge, trade patterns

are affected even to the point in which they are reversed. If consumers in country A start

preferring good 1, trade patterns remain unchanged with increasing imports of good 1.

This is true, if preferences of country B’s consumers remain unchanged or dislike for

good 1 increases in country B. However, if consumers in country A (B) stop preferring

(disliking) good 1, trade patterns may be reversed. Country A becomes a net exporter of

good 1. But the comparative cost/price principle (47), (45), never fails.

Let us briefly look into the logic behind the results of HOS-HOL models in Table 5.

Here trade patterns and factor allocations are determined by endowments and preferences.

Countries have different factor endowments (country A is more labour-abundant than

country B), but are equipped with the same technologies (γiA = γiB). As sector/good 2

is more labour intensive than sector 1, country A ”should tend to” export commodity 2.

26

Page 27: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Table 4. Selected GE solutions of the extended Marshall trade model - Table 2.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.5 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1A 2.4 ; 1B 2.7 ; 2 A 2.6 ; 2B 2.8 ; kJ 2

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY : (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B pA pA pB pB A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B L 1 A

L 1B

K 1 A

K 1B

x1A

0.2 0.5 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 4.67 3.33 0.84 0.87 0.86 4.27 3.59 4.27 3.59 1.42 1.20 0.20 0.34 0.43 0.60 0.27

0.5 0.5 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 3.33 3.33 0.91 0.87 0.89 3.66 3.07 3.66 3.07 1.22 1.02 0.32 0.48 0.59 0.73 -0.30

0.8 0.5 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 2.44 3.33 0.99 0.87 0.93 3.15 2.64 3.15 2.64 1.05 0.88 0.45 0.63 0.71 0.84 -0.86

0.2 0.2 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 4.67 4.67 0.84 0.80 0.82 5.12 4.30 5.12 4.30 1.71 1.43 0.09 0.20 0.22 0.43 -0.29

0.5 0.2 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 3.33 4.67 0.91 0.80 0.86 4.34 3.64 4.34 3.64 1.45 1.21 0.19 0.32 0.42 0.59 -0.87

0.8 0.2 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 2.44 4.67 0.99 0.80 0.89 3.71 3.12 3.71 3.12 1.24 1.04 0.31 0.46 0.57 0.72 -1.42

0.2 0.8 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 4.67 2.44 0.84 0.95 0.90 3.60 3.02 3.60 3.02 1.20 1.01 0.33 0.49 0.60 0.74 0.81

0.5 0.8 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 3.33 2.44 0.91 0.95 0.93 3.10 2.60 3.10 2.60 1.03 0.87 0.47 0.65 0.73 0.85 0.24

0.8 0.8 0.79 1.04 0.76 0.99 2.44 2.44 0.99 0.95 0.96 2.68 2.25 2.68 2.25 0.89 0.75 0.62 0.83 0.83 0.94 -0.31

Table 5. Selected GE solutions of the extended HOS - HOL trade models - Table 2.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.5 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1 2 ; 2 2.6 ; kA 1.8 ; kB 2.2

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY : (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B pA pA pB pB A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B L 1 A

L 1B

K 1 A

K 1B

x1A

0.2 0.5 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 4.20 3.67 1.04 1.07 1.05 3.90 3.90 3.90 3.90 1.30 1.30 0.19 0.35 0.42 0.61 0.18

0.5 0.5 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 3.00 3.67 1.13 1.07 1.10 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 1.11 1.11 0.31 0.49 0.57 0.74 -0.27

0.8 0.5 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 2.20 3.67 1.22 1.07 1.14 2.87 2.87 2.87 2.87 0.96 0.96 0.44 0.65 0.70 0.85 -0.71

0.2 0.2 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 4.20 5.13 1.04 0.98 1.01 4.67 4.67 4.67 4.67 1.56 1.56 0.08 0.21 0.20 0.44 -0.26

0.5 0.2 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 3.00 5.13 1.13 0.98 1.05 3.95 3.95 3.95 3.95 1.32 1.32 0.18 0.34 0.40 0.60 -0.72

0.8 0.2 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 2.20 5.13 1.22 0.98 1.09 3.37 3.37 3.37 3.37 1.12 1.12 0.30 0.48 0.56 0.73 -1.15

0.2 0.8 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 4.20 2.69 1.04 1.16 1.10 3.29 3.29 3.29 3.29 1.10 1.10 0.32 0.50 0.59 0.75 0.60

0.5 0.8 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 3.00 2.69 1.13 1.16 1.14 2.83 2.83 2.83 2.83 0.94 0.94 0.45 0.67 0.71 0.86 0.15

0.8 0.8 0.97 1.28 0.92 1.22 2.20 2.69 1.22 1.16 1.18 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 0.81 0.81 0.60 0.85 0.82 0.94 -0.28

But such trade pattern can again be reversed, if the dislike (preference) for good 1 by

consumers in country A (country B) is sufficiently high. Note again that comparative

cost (price) principle (47), (45), never fails.

Table 6 provides some examples from HO trade models. In all cases, country A is

relatively labour abundant (kA < kB), and sector (good) 1 is capital intensive (a1 > a2).

Under these assumptions, country A ”should traditionally” be exporter of good 2 (the

labour-intensive commodity) and importer of good 1 - as seen in all rows, except one.

Note that the interaction between the technological efficiency parameters (γiA, γiB) of

sectors in the two countries affects the size of net exports of country A and thus all other

variables. If the relative technological efficiency, (γ2B/γ1B), in country B becomes very

large (very favourable for good 2), as in row 2, Table 6, the comparative cost advantage

27

Page 28: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

of country B in good 1 vanishes totally, and country A will then be exporter of good 1.

Table 6. Selected GE solutions of the extended HO trade models - Table 2.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.5 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1A 2.4 ; 2 A 2.6 ; J 0.5 ; kA 1.8 ; kB 2.2

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY : (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

1B

2B

pA pA pB pB A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B L 1 A

L 1B

K 1 A

K 1B

x1A

2.4 2.7 0.81 1.07 0.80 1.05 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.93 0.93 3.08 3.58 3.08 3.58 1.03 1.19 0.38 0.42 0.64 0.69 -0.08

2.4 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.83 1.09 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.96 0.95 2.85 3.84 2.85 3.84 0.95 1.28 0.45 0.36 0.71 0.63 0.16

2.7 2.6 0.81 1.07 0.68 0.90 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.79 0.85 4.35 2.72 4.35 2.72 1.45 0.91 0.12 0.71 0.29 0.88 -1.17

2.7 3.0 0.81 1.07 0.79 1.04 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.92 0.93 3.17 3.51 3.17 3.51 1.06 1.17 0.35 0.44 0.62 0.70 -0.17

3.0 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.66 0.87 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.77 0.84 4.76 2.62 4.76 2.62 1.59 0.87 0.07 0.76 0.18 0.90 -1.45

3.0 3.0 0.81 1.07 0.71 0.94 3.00 3.67 0.94 0.82 0.87 4.06 2.95 4.06 2.95 1.35 0.98 0.17 0.62 0.37 0.83 -0.94

In Table 7, the HO trade model cases of Table 6 are extended to also encompass hetero-

geneity in consumer preferences and in different country sizes.

Table 7. Selected GE solutions of Basic Model, sizes, technologies, preferences - Table 2.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.38 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1A 2.4 ; 2 A 2.6 ; kA 1.8 ; kB 2.2

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY: (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B 1B 2B Ap Ap Bp

Bp A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B L 1 A

L 1B

K 1 A

K 1B

x1A

0.69 0.32 2.35 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.85 1.12 2.46 4.47 0.99 0.93 0.95 2.82 4.12 2.82 4.12 0.94 1.37 0.46 0.30 0.72 0.56 -0.43

0.60 0.40 2.35 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.85 1.12 2.70 4.09 0.96 0.96 0.96 2.76 4.04 2.76 4.04 0.92 1.35 0.48 0.32 0.73 0.58 -0.07

0.40 0.60 2.35 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.85 1.12 3.34 3.30 0.91 1.01 0.97 2.59 3.80 2.59 3.80 0.86 1.27 0.54 0.37 0.78 0.64 0.78

0.32 0.69 2.35 2.8 0.81 1.07 0.85 1.12 3.65 3.01 0.89 1.03 0.98 2.52 3.68 2.52 3.68 0.84 1.23 0.57 0.40 0.80 0.66 1.14

0.32 0.69 2.7 2.55 0.81 1.07 0.67 0.88 3.65 3.01 0.89 0.82 0.84 4.65 2.69 4.65 2.69 1.55 0.90 0.08 0.73 0.21 0.89 -0.73

0.35 0.65 2.7 2.55 0.81 1.07 0.67 0.88 3.53 3.13 0.90 0.81 0.84 4.73 2.73 4.73 2.73 1.58 0.91 0.07 0.71 0.19 0.88 -0.89

0.65 0.35 2.7 2.55 0.81 1.07 0.67 0.88 2.56 4.32 0.98 0.75 0.82 5.18 2.99 5.18 2.99 1.73 1.00 0.02 0.60 0.06 0.82 -2.28

0.69 0.32 2.7 2.55 0.81 1.07 0.67 0.88 2.46 4.47 0.99 0.74 0.82 5.21 3.01 5.21 3.01 1.74 1.00 0.02 0.60 0.05 0.82 -2.44

In Tables 8 - 9, we give two cases with ”incipient specialization” in the two countries,

where Table 8 refers to Fig. 3a - Table 9 to Fig. 3b - discussed at the end of section 2.5.

Table 8. Selected GE solutions of Basic Model, country A specialized in good 2: p∗ = pA

.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.38 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1A 2.4 ; 2 A 2.6 ; kA 1.8 ; B Ak k , (85)

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY: (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B 1B 2BBk Ap

Ap BpBp A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B

1 AL 1BL

1 AK 1BK x1A

0.69 0.32 2.35 2.80 5.30 0.81 1.07 0.68 0.90 2.46 10.75

0.99 0.75 0.81 5.40 7.90 0.00 7.90 1.80 2.63 0.00 0.51 0.00 0.75 -2.57

0.60 0.40 2.35 2.80 5.51 0.81 1.07 0.67 0.89 2.70 10.24

0.96 0.76 0.81 5.40 7.90 0.00 7.90 1.80 2.63 0.00 0.55 0.00 0.78 -2.23

0.40 0.60 2.35 2.80 6.18 0.81 1.07 0.65 0.86 3.34 9.26 0.91 0.78 0.81 5.40 7.90 0.00 7.90 1.80 2.63 0.00 0.67 0.00 0.86 -1.49

0.32 0.69 2.40 2.60 4.56 0.81 1.07 0.64 0.84 3.65 6.24 0.89 0.78 0.81 5.40 5.40 0.00 5.40 1.80 1.80 0.00 0.77 0.00 0.91 -1.19

0.32 0.69 2.70 2.55 2.70 0.81 1.07 0.64 0.84 3.65 3.68 0.89 0.78 0.81 5.40 3.12 0.00 3.12 1.80 1.04 0.00 0.80 0.00 0.92 -1.19

0.35 0.65 2.70 2.55 2.63 0.81 1.07 0.64 0.84 3.53 3.75 0.90 0.77 0.81 5.40 3.12 0.00 3.12 1.80 1.04 0.00 0.77 0.00 0.91 -1.30

0.65 0.35 2.70 2.55 2.32 0.81 1.07 0.66 0.87 2.56 4.55 0.98 0.74 0.81 5.40 3.12 0.00 3.12 1.80 1.04 0.00 0.62 0.00 0.83 -2.42

0.69 0.32 2.70 2.55 2.30 0.81 1.07 0.66 0.87 2.46 4.68 0.99 0.73 0.81 5.40 3.12 0.00 3.12 1.80 1.04 0.00 0.61 0.00 0.82 -2.57

28

Page 29: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Table 9. Selected GE solutions of Basic Model, both countries specialized: p∗ = pA

= pB.

Parameters and Endowments : J 0.38 ; a1 0.5 ; a2 0.25 ; 1 1A A ; 2 A 2.6 ; kA 1.8 ; , 1 3B Ak k a

, (88)

PRICE INTERVAL : (49) AUTARKY: (44), (45) INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM : (72), (24), (25), (29-30), (63)

A B 1B 2B Bk Ap Ap Bp Bp A B pA pB p A B k1A k1B k2A k2B1 AL

1BL 1 AK

1BK x1A

0.69 0.32 2.35 2.80 0.12 2.31 3.05 1.76 2.31 2.46 0.24 2.82 1.94 2.31 5.40 0.12 0.00 0.12 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -0.90

0.60 0.40 2.35 2.80 0.11 2.35 3.09 1.78 2.35 2.70 0.21 2.79 2.01 2.35 5.40 0.11 0.00 0.11 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -0.77

0.40 0.60 2.35 2.80 0.11 2.35 3.09 1.78 2.35 3.34 0.17 2.65 2.12 2.35 5.40 0.11 0.00 0.11 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -0.51

0.76 0.69 2.40 2.60 5.40 0.81 1.07 0.62 0.81 2.29 7.38 1.00 0.75 0.81 5.40 5.40 0.00 5.40 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -2.82

0.32 0.69 2.70 2.55 0.18 1.64 2.16 1.25 1.64 3.65 0.25 1.81 1.52 1.64 5.40 0.18 0.00 0.18 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -0.59

0.35 0.65 2.70 2.55 0.16 1.69 2.23 1.29 1.69 3.53 0.23 1.88 1.55 1.69 5.40 0.16 0.00 0.16 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -0.62

0.65 0.35 2.70 2.55 0.16 1.69 2.23 1.29 1.69 2.56 0.32 2.04 1.43 1.69 5.40 0.16 0.00 0.16 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -1.15

0.69 0.32 2.70 2.55 0.17 1.67 2.20 1.27 1.67 2.46 0.35 2.03 1.40 1.67 5.40 0.17 0.00 0.17 1.80 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 -1.24

Note especially in Tables 8-9 that FPE, cf. Corollary 3, are preserved with countries

”incipiently specialized”; we see: k2A(0.81) = k2B(0.81) = 1.80, and kA/kB = 1.8/4.56 =

0.39, as endpoint of the interval, (94), ϑ = 2.37 - and : kA/kB = 1.8/5.40 = 1/3 at (88).

Propositions 1-2 and their consequences illustrated Tables 3-9 avoid, ”the curse

of general equilibrium models, in which all that can be said is that everything depends

on everything else”, Samuelson (1983, p.1481). We may elaborate a bit on this ’curse’,

as the mutual interdependence theory of pricing was stated, Ohlin (1933, p.4) as: ‘The

chain of causation does not proceed from costs to prices or from prices to costs, but is

always characterized by mutual interdependence’, and ‘The law of supply and demand

is everywhere developed into a system of general equilibrium, in which the principle of

mutual interdependence is fundamental.’ Accordingly Ohlin (1935, Appendix I) wanted

to extend the closed general equilibrium equation systems of Walras-Cassel to a general

equilibrium price mechanism for the commodities and factors of trading countries.

Proposition 1 lifts the ”curse” by giving one complete equation, (72), for p∗ that decides

all the other international equilibrium variables by their equations, listed in Tables 3-9.

Two principles played a major role for the calculation of commodity prices: The cost

approach and the total interdependence approach of supply and demand determination.

As we have seen, the relative cost functions, pJ = pJ(ωJ), J=A,B, are not made

superfluous by the Walras equilibrium relations, kJ = ΨJ(ωJ) ; the ’invisible’ comparative

costs, pJ(ωJ), rule in autarky under the loci (curves) : kJ = ΨJ(ωJ), and rule in free trading

economies below the surfaces of the international general equilibrium : p∗ = Φ(kA, kB).

We see them side by side with Ricardo, Walras, and Ohlin in Figures (1, 2, 4, 5).

29

Page 30: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

5 Conclusion

The problems with the comparative cost (price, advantage) principle in deriving trade

patterns from autarky price ratios (1), and the problems with deriving explicitly the

international general equilibrium terms of trade (p∗) of two countries, (2), have been

with us for two hundred years (1817). We have seen that rigorous analytic (parametric)

general equilibrium model solutions are not superfluous luxuries. They are indispensable

for true understanding and for answering many long-open questions, as demonstrated by

the Basic World Trade Model solutions and existence conditions in Propositions 1-2.

Methodologically (mathematically), it should be noted that our general equilibrium

modelling was designed to generate relevant comparative static solutions. It is by aiming

for comparative statics that factor endowments of the countries (as exogenous variables)

got their crucial analytic trade model significance by giving an answer to (1) with the au-

tarky general equilibrium formulas of comparative advantage : pJ(kJ), (45), (47), and fixing

international general equilibrium issues to get (2) on parametric form: p∗ = Φ(kA, kB),

(72), which in Table 2 moreover could unify Ricardo (I), Mill (II) into Marshall (III),

that then combined with Heckscher-Ohlin (IV) constitute the Basic Model (VII).

In this paper, we have only dealt with the cases of ”incipient specialization”. The

situations with the factor endowment ratios (kA/kB) beyond the interval boundaries of

Proposition 2 have, for space reasons, not been included; but such specialization cases

would only require revision (reductions) of the terms of trade expression in Lemma 1.

We have mainly illustrated the international general equilibrium allocations of the

Basic Model for free trade applications. But the level (γiJ) parameters (total factor

productivity, TFP) may also play role as tariffs. Propositions 1-2 and Table 1-9 do

indicate intricacies of tariff effects on international trade, as well as the complexity of

trade policies.

Subject of further research would naturally be extensions to CES specified autarky

and globally trading economies (regions), allowing for a larger parametric heterogeneity

of their technologies and preferences.

30

Page 31: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

Appendix A

Remark. The assumption pA≥ p

Bcan be made without loss of generality.

In order to see this, verify with (49), that pA≥ p

B⇔ pA ≥ pB. This means that it

is excluded that any of the two intervals [ pJ, pJ ], J = A,B is a proper superset of the

other. Hence, either the two intervals coincide (because pA

= pB⇔ pA = pB), or they

do not. If they do not coincide, one of them will be located to the right side of the other.

Note that only two cases are possible (because there are two countries in the model), i.e.

either pA≥ p

Bor p

B≥ p

A. Since each case can be obtained from the other by simply

switching the two country-specific indexes, it suffices to study only one of them.

Proof of Proposition 2

Proposition 2 distinguishes the two cases a1 > a2 and a1 < a2. Since the proof is

analogous (’symmetric’) in the two cases, let us assume a1 > a2, and show how the

conditions on the ratio kA/kB are obtained with a1 > a2 : Conditions (85), (87) and (88).

Observe first the condition kA/kB ≤ γ. It is easily seen that this condition equally

holds in (85), (87) and (88), since a is less than one when a1 > a2. The condition

kA/kB ≤ γ corresponds to the assumption pA≥ p

B. To see this, re-write p

A≥ p

Bas

(kA/kB )a2−a1 ≤ (γ1A/γ2A )/(γ1B/γ2B ) in virtue of (49) and use definition (51).

When pA≥ p

B, an international general equilibrium solution exists only if the interval

[ pA, pB ] is non-empty, i.e. p

A≤ pB. Verify that this condition is equivalent to kA/kB ≥

a · γ because of the definitions of pJ

and pJ given in (49). Note in particular that the

interval collapses to to one single point (i.e., pA

= pB) if kA/kB = a · γ.

The condition kA/kB ≥ a · γ is clearly verified in (88), where kA/kB = a · γ. In (85),

it follows from the fact that kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ because ϑ is larger than a for any γ < ϑ.

To see this, simply insert definition (82) for ϑ and definition (52) for a into ϑ > a, and

prove that ϑ > a ⇔ γ < ϑ. With the same logic, the condition kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ in (87)

automatically implies kA/kB ≥ a · γ because ϑ > a since γ > ϑ.

Derive now conditions (85), (87) and (88), which all ensure that the international

general equilibrium solution p∗ belongs to the closed interval [ pA, pB ], which is non-

empty because a · γ ≤ kA/kB ≤ γ. In (88), the interval coincides with one single point

(i.e., pA

= pB), as kA/kB = a · γ. In this case, an international general equilibrium

31

Page 32: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

solution only exists if p∗ = pA

= pB. Prove that this requires kA/kB = ϑ γ = ϑ γ, which

occurs when γ = ϑ. To this aim, show that the condition p∗ = pA

(which indicates that

country A produces only good 2) may be written as kA/kB = ϑ · γ. To see this, insert

the explicit expression for p∗ (72) and the definition of pA

(49) into p∗ = pA, and obtain

kA/kB = γ [υB (1− βB) a2]/ [υBβB (1− a2) + γ · υA (βA − a2)]. Use definitions (74) and

(82) to show that this condition is equivalent to kA/kB = ϑ · γ. Similarly, verify that the

condition p∗ = pB (which indicates that country B produces only good 1) is equivalent to

kA/kB = ϑ · γ. From above, we know that ϑ = a⇔ γ = ϑ and that ϑ = a⇔ γ = ϑ. For

transitivity it follows that ϑ = ϑ. We conclude that an international general equilibrium

solution exists when kA/kB = a · γ if γ = ϑ. Note that the condition γ = ϑ necessarily

implies a positive ϑ, which is negative only if γ < (υB/υA ) · a1/(1− a1) · βB/βA < ϑ.

Observe now conditions kA/kB ∈ [ ϑ γ, γ ] in (85) and kA/kB ∈ [ ϑ γ, γ ] in (87). Verify

first that in (85), ϑ · γ < γ while in (87), ϑ · γ < γ. Prove in fact that ϑ < 1 and ϑ < 1

for any γ > 0. To this aim, use definition (82), and verify that ϑ < 1 is equivalent to

[γ · υAαA + υB (1 + αB)] (a1 − a2) > 0, which is true per assumption (a1 > a2). Similarly,

insert (82) in ϑ < 1, and see that this yields γ · υA (βA − a1)− υB (1− αB) (a1 − a2) < 0,

which holds true since (βA − a1) is negative (αA < 1). Note that ϑ may be zero or

negative (when γ ≤ (υB/υA) · a1/(1− a1) · βB/βA).

Derive now conditions kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ in (85) and kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ in (87). Recall that

in these two cases, kA/kB > a · γ, which means that the interval [ pA, pB ] is non-empty

and discrete. In order to be feasible, the solution p∗ has to belong to this interval, i.e.

pA≤ p∗ ≤ pB. Prove that this inequality is equivalent to the condition kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ

when γ < ϑ and it is equivalent to kA/kB ≥ ϑ· γ in the opposite case (γ < ϑ). To this aim,

extend the result above (p∗ = pA⇔ kA/kB = ϑ · γ) and obtain p∗ ≥ p

A⇔ kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ.

With the same logic, recover p∗ ≤ pB ⇔ kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ (for ϑ > 0) and kA/kB > 0 (for

ϑ ≤ 0). It is thus proved that the condition pA≤ p∗ ≤ pB is satisfied when a pair of

conditions contemporaneously holds. These are kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ and kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ (when

ϑ > 0) or kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ and kA/kB > 0 (when ϑ ≤ 0). From above we know that

ϑ > a ⇔ γ < ϑ and ϑ < a ⇔ γ < ϑ. For transitivity it follows that ϑ > ϑ ⇔ γ < ϑ,

which yields kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ in (85) and kA/kB ≥ ϑ · γ in (87).

32

Page 33: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

References

[1] Baldwin, Robert E. (2008). The Development and Testing of Heckscher-Ohlin Trade

Models : A Review. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

[2] Bhagwati, Jagdish (1964). ”The Pure Theory of International Trade : A Survey”,

Economic Journal, 74, 1-78 ; The Royal Economic Society, Surveys of Economic

Theory, Volume 2, (1965), 156-239, London, Macmillan.

[3] Chipman, John S. (1965). ”A Survey of the Theory of International, Part I. The

Classical Theory.” Econometrica, 33, 477-519; ”Part II. The Neo-Classical Theory.”,

33, 685-760; ”Part III. The Modern Theory”, (1966), Econometrica, 34, 18-76.

[4] Edgeworth, Francis Y. (1894). “The Theory of International Values, I, II, III.”

Economic Journal 4, 35-50, 424-443, 606-638.

[5] Deardorff, Alan V. (1980). “The General Validity of the Law of Comparative Ad-

vantage”, Journal of Political Economy, 88, 941-957.

[6] Deardorff, Alan V. (2006). Terms of Trade, Glossary of International Economics.

World Scientific, Singapore.

[7] Drabicki, John and Akira Takayama (1979). “An Antinomy in the Theory of Com-

parative Advantage”, Journal of International Economics, 9, 211-223.

[8] Flam, Henry, and M. June Flanders, (1991); editor & translator. Heckscher-Ohlin

Trade Theory. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

[9] Haberler, Gottfried. (1936). The Theory of International Trade. W. Hodge and

Comp., London.

[10] Heckscher, Eli F. (1919). ‘The Effect of Foreign Trade on Distribution of Income’,

Ekonomisk Tidsskrift, 21 (Del II), 1-32; translated (Svend Laursen) in Ellis, H.S.

and Metzler, L.A., eds. Readings in the Theory of International Trade, Blakiston,

Philadelphia, 1949, 272-300; transl., in Flam. H & Flanders, M.J. (1991), (43-69).

33

Page 34: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

[11] Jensen, Bjarne S. (2003). ”Walrasian General Equilibrium Allocations and Dynam-

ics in Two-Sector Growth Models”. German Economic Review 4, 53-87.

[12] Jensen, Bjarne S. (2012). ”Comparative Cost and Factor Endowments: Ricardo

and Ohlin”; in Kemp, M.C., Nakagawa, H. and Uchida, T. , eds. (2012), p. 54-83.

[13] Laursen, Svend (1952). ”Production Functions and the Theory of International

Trade”. American Economic Review 42, 540-557.

[14] Linder, S. Burenstam (1961). An Essay on Trade and Transformation. New York,

John Wiley and Sons.

[15] Kemp, Murray C. (1969). The Pure Theory of International Trade and Investment.

Prentice-Hall: New Jersey.

[16] Kemp, M.C., Nakagawa, H. and Uchida, T., eds. (2012). Positive and Normative

Analysis in International Economics. Palgrave Macmillan: UK, London.

[17] Marshall, Alfred, (1879, 1930, 1974). The Pure Theory of Foreign Trade, The Pure

Theory of Domestic Values., Privately printed (1879); LSE, University of London

(1930); Augustus M. Kelley Publishers (1974), New Jersey.

[18] Mills, John S. (1848, 1875). Principles of Political Economy. People’s Edition, Long-

mans, Green, Reader, and Dyer: London.

[19] Mundell, Robert M. (1960) ‘The Pure Theory of international Trade.’ American

Economic Review, 50, 67-110.

[20] Ohlin, Bertil (1924). The Theory of Trade, AB Nordiska Bokhandelen, Stockholm;

translated in Flam. H & Flanders, M.J. (1991), (76-214).

[21] Ohlin, Bertil (1933, 1967). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press; Revised Edition (1967), Harvard University Press.

[22] Ohlin, Bertil (1970). ‘The Business Cost Account Approach to International Trade

Theory.’ The Swedish Journal of Economics 72, 12-20.

34

Page 35: Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade ... · Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade

[23] Oniki, Hajime, and Hirofumi Uzawa (1965). “Patterns of Trade and Investment in

a Dynamic Model of International Trade.” Review of Economic Studies 32, 15-38.

[24] Ricardo, David (1817). The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, London:

J.M. Dent and Sons, 1965.

[25] Ruffin, R.J. (2002). ‘David Ricardo’s Discovery of Comparative Advantage’. History

of Political Economy, 34, 727-748.

[26] Samuelson, Paul A. (1938). ‘Welfare Economics and International Trade.’ American

Economic Review, 28, 261-266.

[27] Samuelson, Paul A. (1948, 1949). ‘International Trade and Equalisation of Factor

Prices,’ Economic Journal, 58, 163–184 ; ‘International Factor Price Equalisation

Once Again,’ Economic Journal, 59, 181–197.

[28] Samuelson, Paul A. (1953-1954). ‘Prices of Factors and Goods in General Equilib-

rium’, Review of Economic Studies, 21, 1-20.

[29] Samuelson, Paul A. (1967). ‘Summary on Factor-Price Equalization.’ International

Economic Review, 8, 286–295.

[30] Samuelson, Paul A. (1983), ”Thunen at Two Hundred,” Journal of Economic Lite-

rature, 21, 1468-1488.

[31] Shimomura, Koji and Kar-yiu Wong (1998). ‘The Law of Comparative Advantage

without Social Utility Functions.’ Review of International Economics, 6, 401-406.

[32] Shoven, John B. and John Whalley (1992) Applying General Equilibrium, Cam-

bridge University Press.

[33] Smith, Adam (1776, 1961). The Wealth of Nations, (ed. E. Cannan). Vol. 1,

Methuen, London.

[34] Solow, Robert M.(1961-62): Note on Uzawa’s Two-Sector Model of Economic

Growth, Rev. Econ. Stud. 29 (1961-62), 48-50.

[35] Uzawa, Hirofumi (1962-63). ’On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth’ : I-II,

Rev. Econ. Stud. 29, 40-47 ; Rev. Econ. Stud. 30, 105-18;

35