Commercialisation or Citizenship Colin Crouch … · FABIAN SOCIETY Commercialisation or...

86
Commercialisation or Citizenship Education policy and the future of public services Colin Crouch Fabian ideas 606

Transcript of Commercialisation or Citizenship Colin Crouch … · FABIAN SOCIETY Commercialisation or...

FABIA

N SO

CIETY

Com

mercia

lisatio

n o

r Citize

nsh

ipC

olin Crouch

Fabian ideas 606

Commercialisation or CitizenshipEEdduuccaattiioonn ppoolliiccyy aanndd tthhee ffuuttuurree ooff ppuubblliicc sseerrvviicceess

Colin Crouch

Commercialisation orCitizenshipEEdduuccaattiioonn ppoolliiccyy aanndd tthheeffuuttuurree ooff ppuubblliicc sseerrvviicceessColin Crouch

Fabian ideas 606

Fabian ideas 606

ISBN 0 7163 0606 9ISSN 1469 0136

£6.95

So far the argument over the role of private firms in the provision of publicservices has mainly been waged in terms of efficiency. Those in favour ofgreater involvement have focused on the improvements to service quality andthe cost-effectiveness offered by private sector providers; those opposed havequestioned the truth of these claims. Yet there is another debate about theimplications of private involvement for the character of public services whichdeserves attention.

In Commercialisation or Citizenship Colin Crouch looks at how this use of pri-vate business in public services changes the character of the services deliveredand the notions of citizenship which underpin them. He argues that publicservices were designed to provide entitlements or rights – to education, healthand social care – and that they did this through an equitable allocation ofresources on a universal basis. The role now being given to private business inthis field does not simply ignore this foundation, it actively undermines it.

Using education as his example, Crouch gives a comprehensive analysis ofprivate sector involvement showing how this threatens the citizenship basis ofeducation. He then offers a number of practical proposals for a strategy ofmodernising public services in a manner which is compatible with the conceptof the welfare state as a fundamental component of social citizenship.

Colin Crouch is Professor of Sociology at the European University Institute,Florence, and External Scientific member of the Max Planck Institute for SocietyResearch, Cologne. He is Chair of the editorial board of the PoliticalQuarterly, of which he was previously joint editor. His recent books includeIndustrial Relations and European State Traditions (1993), Are Skills theAnswer? (with David Finegold and Mari Sako, 1999), Social Change inWestern Europe (1999) and Coping with Post-Democracy (2000).

cover.qxd 12/03/2003 17:44 Page 1

The Fabian Society

The Fabian Society has played a central role for more than a century inthe development of political ideas and public policy on the left ofcentre. Analysing the key challenges facing the UK and the rest of theindustrialised world in a changing society and global economy, theSociety’s programme aims to explore the political ideas and the policyreforms which will define progressive politics in the new century.

The Society is unique among think tanks in being a democratically-constituted membership organisation. It is affiliated to the Labour Partybut is editorially and organisationally independent. Through itspublications, seminars and conferences, the Society provides an arenafor open-minded public debate.

i

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page i

Fabian Society11 Dartmouth StreetLondon SW1H 9BNwww.fabian-society.org.uk

Fabian ideasSeries editor: Ellie Levenson

First published March 2003

ISBN 0 7163 0606 9ISSN 1469 0136

This book, like all publications of the Fabian Society, represents not thecollective views of the Society but only the views of the author. Thispublication may not be reproduced without express permission of theFabian Society.

British Library Cataloguing in Publication data.A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

Printed by Bell & Bain Limited, Glasgow

ii

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page ii

iii

Contents

1 | The clash between citizenship and 1

commercialisation

2 | The case of education 26

3 | Towards a redefinition of public service 58

References and bibliography 75

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page iii

About the authors

Colin Crouch is Professor of Sociology at the European UniversityInstitute, Florence, and External Scientific member of the Max PlanckInstitute for Society Reserach, Cologne. He is Chair of the editorialboard of the Political Quarterly, of which he was previously joint editor.He was Chair of the Fabian Society in 1976. His recent books includeIndustrial Relations and European State Traditions (1993), Are Skills theAnswer? (with David Finegold and Mari Sako, 1999), Social Change inWestern Europe (1999) and Coping with Post-democracy (2000).Coping with Post-democracy won the Jenny Jeger prize for best FabianSociety Publication in 2001.

iv

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page iv

Since 1997 the Labour Government has made clear that itshighest priority in domestic policy is the improvement ofpublic services. It starts from the premise that public serv-

ices – notably in education and health – are in general under-perfoming. The centrepiece of its programme for reform hasbeen and is the use of the private sector to provide various kindsof public services. The use of private provision was introducedby previous Conservative Governments, but has been extendedin important ways by New Labour.

Argument over the role of private firms in the provision ofpublic services has mainly been waged in terms of efficiency. Isthe Government right that, because they have been tried andtested in the competitive market, private businesses will gener-ally provide a superior and more cost-effective service thanpublic organisations? Do the Private Finance Initiative (PFI) andother forms of Public-Private Partnerships (PPP) give bettervalue for money than their purely public equivalents? A numberof studies have examined the evidence on these questions, mostof them in fact concluding that use of the private sector does notlead to greater efficiency.1

Governments and their advisers believe that private firms willnecessarily bring increased efficiency to public services, because

1

1 | The clash between citizenshipand commercialisation

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 1

they have been tested in the market; an inefficient private firmdisappears under the impact of competitive pressure, so thesurvivors are known to be efficient. There is no similar mecha-nism in public service, it is argued. If the private firms are smalland selling successfully in an almost perfect market to ultimateconsumers, the argument is a strong one. However, as we moveaway from these conditions towards those more typical of muchof the area of contracted-out public services, its power weakens.

First, the primary duty of a private firm is to maximise share-holder value. This coincides with meeting customers’ needs effi-ciently in a near-perfect market, because a firm which ignoresthis need will lose business. However, where competition isimperfect or where contracts can be won by insider lobbyingrather than by demonstrating superior performance, the linkbetween shareholders’ profits and efficiency for the customer isweakened. This is frequently the case with public-servicecontracts, as shown at several points below.

Second, the superior efficiency argument depends heavily onthe dogmatic assumption that abstract general managementskills are more important than those specific to the activityconcerned. Since the specific knowledge relevant to most publicservices is a virtual monopoly of the public sector, firms biddingfor these contracts usually come from other parts of the economy.For example, when a road construction company enters the busi-ness of running primary schools, it has to be believed that thegain that comes from its knowledge of general managementoutweighs the inefficiency loss that flows from its inexperience ofeducation.

Third, most of the managers and other staff who work in aprivate firm do not themselves have a direct stake in the firm’sprofits. Analogues of this stake are constructed for them by topmanagement to give them incentives to maximise performance.Their own motivation is similar to that of persons working in a

Commercialisation or Citizenship

2

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 2

3

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

public service organisation; they respond to the incentive struc-ture established by top management. If the top political level isitself committed to maximising efficiency, it is able to use tech-niques derived from the private sector to convert this motive intoincentives for middle management, as the ConservativeGovernments of the 1980s did in several areas. It is not necessaryto use private contractors themselves to achieve this.

Fourth, and as will again be discussed in more detail below,many of the techniques important to private service managers inachieving efficiency are not available in the public service. Forexample, an important skill of private management lies in iden-tifying the firm’s target market, who does it want to be itscustomers? This skill cannot be transferred to a national educa-tion system unless it is considered acceptable that some childrenshould be offered no school at all.

Finally, also addressed in detail below, in public servicecontracts efficiency for the customer does not necessarily coin-cide with satisfaction for the ultimate consumer. The customer isa government department, not the actual user of a service, and itis possible to imagine many situations where the interests ofgovernment and citizens are not identical.

These last two points take us beyond a simple value for moneyapproach to efficiency, and raise the question of efficiency forwhom? This brings us to the central issue that I want to addressin this pamphlet: how does use of the private sector to deliverpublic services affect, not the efficiency, but the very character ofsuch services?

Post-industrial capitalismAttempts at marrying what have until now been primarily publicservices with capitalist practices take a variety of forms: marketswithin public ownership; privatisation with or without fully freemarkets; contracting out both capital projects and service

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 3

4

Commercialisation or Citizenship

delivery, sometimes without either privatisation or markets. Therelationship of the market to private ownership is moreambiguous than is often assumed. Certainly perfect marketsalongside private ownership of economic resources provide theconditions for the capitalism of economics text-books, and thetwo criteria fit together well. It is however entirely possible tohave markets without private ownership: an authority owningcollective resources can decide to use a system of prices to makea market through which to allocate these resources within apublic or charitable service. This idea informed manyConservative reforms of the 1980s. Government departmentsand service units were required to trade services with other unitsas though they were in a market relationship, abandoning theprofessional colleague model that had previously governed theirinteractions. A major example was the internal market intro-duced into the National Health Service. It has largely fallen toNew Labour to take the further step of introducing privateprofit-making firms into what had been, under theConservatives, still public service – though often this paradoxi-cally takes the form of private provision without true markets.

The generic term which will be used here for all these practicesis commercialisation, because each is premised on the assump-tion that the quality of public services will be improved if theexisting practices and ethos of public service are replaced bythose typical of commercial practice. This concept is more accu-rate than that of marketisation, for some of the processes nowbeing introduced involve distortions of the market rather than itspurification. And it is more general than privatisation, whichstrictly speaking refers only to the transfer of ownership ofassets.

Although capitalism originated in post-mediæval Europe inservices sectors which have again become fundamental to it –mainly banking – it fully took wing with industrialisation. The

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 4

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

5

greatly enlarged production of material goods which this madepossible released the spiral of investment in plant and equip-ment, production and sale of a good, and further investment ofthe proceeds from these sales which became the great engine of19th and 20th century wealth and prosperity. But capitalismexpands its scope, not just by developing new goods and produc-tion methods, but also by pulling more and more areas of lifewithin the spiral. Services which might have been rendered as,say, a community or family obligation are transformed into wagelabour and sold. Much of the political conflict of the last twocenturies concerned the boundaries which a great diversity ofother interests – for example, churches and the working class –sought to erect around this rampaging force.2

Various compromises were eventually established. Sundaysand other religious holidays were more or less protected fromthe grasp of the working week; family life remained uncommod-ified, mainly through the withdrawal of the majority of marriedwomen from the labour market; various limits were imposed onthe exploitation of labour; and by the mid-20th century a series ofbasic services were at least partly removed from the reach ofcapitalism, because their provision was considered too impor-tant. As T H Marshall memorably argued, people acquired rightsto these goods and services, mainly the latter, by virtue of theirstatus as citizens, and not because they were able to buy them inthe market.3 Just as it became a mark of democracy that the rightto vote or to a fair trial were not available for market purchase,so with entitlement to certain services; provision of them throughmarket means would demean their citizenship quality. Theywere not necessarily delivered free of charge, but any chargeswere notional, and designed explicitly not to be used as rationingor allocation devices.

The list of items included in what we can call ‘citizenship serv-ices’ has varied across societies and over time, but usually

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 5

6

Commercialisation or Citizenship

includes entitlement to certain levels of education, health serv-ices, certain forms of care service in case of need, financialsupport in old age and in the event of temporary or permanentloss of earning capacity through unemployment, ill health orinjury.

Although conflicts over these exclusions from the reach of themarket were often intense, the task of those trying to achievethem was made easier by the fact that for most of the period thebest opportunities for profit and extending the scope of themarket lay in industrial production. This was particularly true inthe years around the Second World War, when the exigencies ofincreasingly technological warfare stimulated invention,research and development in many fields, with manifold subse-quent peacetime uses. Important compromises over labour rightsand the welfare state were negotiated as western capitalism wasrelaxing into enjoying these possibilities. By the late 1960s andearly 1970s this process had peaked. While innovations in theproduction of goods have continued apace, major new develop-ments have required increasingly costly research and large-scaleinvestment. At the same time many new opportunities began toopen in the provision to an increasingly wealthy population ofservices rather than goods: new forms of distribution, increasingtravel, new forms of financial and other business services,growing use of restaurants and other food outlets, more interestin taking advantage of health, education, legal and other profes-sional services. Increasingly capitalist firms have sought theirprofits in these sectors as well as, and gradually instead of,manufacturing.

But this has raised a problem. Some services provided by thewelfare state are potentially very profitable but are protectedfrom private ownership and the market as part of the mid-century citizenship package. So long as the welfare statesurvives, potential areas of profit-making are excluded from

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 6

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

7

capital’s reach. Post-industrial capitalism has therefore started totry to undo the deals made by its industrial predecessor. It is nowbeing aided in this by the World Trade Organisation (WTO),which has been charged by the governments of the world’s mostpowerful countries with liberalising the international exchangeof goods and services. It has no other responsibilities and recog-nises no other priorities. The only right it protects against opencompetition is the right of patent. In addition to liberalisingexisting markets, the WTO is now trying to introduce them intofields which have previously been governed by different princi-ples. It has in particular identified the welfare state, includingstate education and health services, as areas which should beopened up to markets, or to privatisation.

But is opposition to this not just a knee-jerk reaction, based onoutmoded prejudices? Markets and capitalist producers provideus reasonably efficiently with toothpaste, motor vehicles andbanking facilities; why not let them do the same with schools andhospitals? That is what we must now investigate.

Citizenship and marketsAn essential starting point for a critique of commercialisation isthe observation that the maximisation of markets and privateownership can conflict with other social goals. While the WTOhas not been given the mandate to consider these, individualgovernments, organisations and private persons are free to placemarkets into perspective and to debate whether they should beaccepted uncritically as the sole criterion to govern our affairs.Almost no-one except a tiny number of extreme libertarianswould disagree with this in principle. For example, virtually no-one believes that sexual relationships, or those between parentsand children, should be forced into a market frame; or thatnational political sovereignty should be capable of being tradedin the market; or that the ability of people to change their resi-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 7

Commercialisation or Citizenship

8

dence from country to country should be governed only bylabour-market opportunities and not by state immigrationpolicy.

The market is not capable of being an absolute principle, sinceit is a means for achieving ends and not an end in itself. The casefor the market is that if we follow its rules we shall make alloca-tion decisions that better reach our goals, whatever these are.Other means of making allocations always remain open to thedoubt that they do not provide as efficient a means of calculatingcosts, including opportunity costs, as the actual market. But thisdoes not dispose of two principal points: that the market can failto register all relevant elements of a choice of good; and that itsuse can itself change negatively the quality of a good. The formercriticism is of major practical importance, but it is at least capableof being remedied by improving the quality of the market itself,rather than by suppressing it. For example, if the price of a goodfails to represent the costs of pollution created in its production,it is possible to impose a tax reflecting the cost of the pollution,which will then be reflected in the price.

The second objection, that use of the market per se negativelychanges the sought good itself, is more fundamental. Forexample, most people consider that sexual relationships offeredunder conditions of prostitution are inherently inferior to non-marketed ones. Prostitution could doubtless be improved if itsmarket were made more perfect; for example, if it were subject tono legal prohibitions, the level of exploitation it involved and itssordid conditions of service delivery would be alleviated. Butthat is not the main point of the objection, which relates to anabsolute judgement of quality.

Can objections of this kind be considered to apply in the fieldof citizenship services? The issue turns on two principal prob-lems that can be caused by the application of commercial princi-ples: distortion and residualisation.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 8

9

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

DistortionProviding goods or services through markets involves an elabo-rate procedure of creating barriers of access so that we cannot getthem without payment. Sometimes the character of a good itselfhas to be changed to do this. We accept these distortions or mostgoods and services would not be provided at all; most obviously,traders would not be willing to set up shops if we did not acceptcash desks and the whole procedure of money exchange. Thereare instances however where the extent of distortion required sodamages the quality of the good in question or erects barriers soartificial that one may reasonably doubt whether the gains fromany efficiency improvement are worth the losses incurred: forexample when entrepreneurs are allowed to fence off pieces ofcoastline and charge for access to beaches or cliff walks.

Another form of distortion occurs when artificial attempts aremade to provide indicators that can serve as analogues of prices.Where markets are virtual and goods and services are not reallytraded, as with the NHS internal market, there is a strong temp-tation to use as an indicator those elements which can be easilymeasured, rather than the qualities of the good or service reallyat stake. Service providers are likely to concentrate on thoseaspects of their work which are included in the indicators,neglecting others, not because they are intrinsically less impor-tant but because they are less measurable. The LabourGovernment’s attempts to benchmark reduction of certainwaiting lists for medical treatment have produced several suchdistortions; health service managers and professionals concen-trate resources on those items being assessed and made politi-cally prominent by drawing off resources from other, less easilyobserved, parts of the service. The apparent efficiency gains ofthis kind of targeting can become quite illusory; if, as may wellbe the case, the easily measured items are not in fact the mostimportant, there may even be a loss of real effectiveness. This can

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 9

Commercialisation or Citizenship

10

be tackled by increasing the number of indicators, but that even-tually leads to measurement overload and excessive complexity.

The value of an indicator depends on its ability to measureaccurately the quality that the customer is seeking, and this canbe in doubt, even in ‘real’ markets. Stock-exchange evaluations ofcompanies often present biased and distorted estimates of afirm’s long-term worth; the exchange rates of currencies oftenbear only a poor relationship to their respective purchasingpower; relative incomes are not the only legitimate means ofcomparing the value of two occupations. The problem intensifiesin the case of shadow or artificial markets, as in public serviceapplications. Here the indicator is typically chosen by a politicalor administrative authority and not by users, with the result thatit is likely to suit political or managerial criteria rather than theclient sensitivity which is in principle a major objective of theexercise. In the stock-exchange-led form of capitalism thatbecame dominant by the end of the 20th century, this problem ofindicators ceased to be a matter of concern. As was seen with alarge number of information technology firms, which had veryhigh share values before they ever sold a product to a customer,the value of a firm’s shares can become self-justifying: if enoughpeople believe that the share value is an indicator of somethingimportant, they will buy the shares and the value will have justi-fied itself. It is not acceptable for democratic welfare policy todevelop in this way.

Degradation and residualisationThe market is often depicted as a realm of consumer sovereignty:firms can sell their goods and services only if we choose to buythem. But it is providers who initially choose their customers, bydeciding on which segments of the market they wish to targettheir products. There can be no obligation on a firm to try to meeteveryone’s needs. Citizen services differ fundamentally from this

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 10

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

11

in that they must be universally provided to the defined categoryof citizens. Where Public-Private Partnerships allow privateproviders to chose the segments they want, while the publicservice guarantees provision for those in whom the private sectorhas no interest, such provision becomes residual. We know bothin theory and in practice from the works of scholars like AlbertHirschman4 and Richard Titmuss,5 that residual public servicesbecomes services of poor quality, because only the poor andpolitically ineffective have to make use of them.

Matters become even worse when citizenship services arerequired to have residual status and degraded quality becausegovernment is deliberately making space for commercial provi-sion. Such services are then excluded from the realms of bothmarkets and citizenship. Public services of this kind cannot bedescribed as ‘citizenship’: access to them is more a penalty thana right; and the essential citizenship mechanism of voice mustnot be made available to residual recipients or they might seekimprovements that would break the rule of no competition withmarket provision. An important example may be taken from theworld of employment placement and unemployment assistance.The logic of a neo-liberal market regime is to privatise as muchemployment placement as possible, leaving a public service todeal with the hard-to-place, the unemployed. They are thenplaced into a special, stigmatised form of employment serviceisolated from everyone else.

The current British debate, which does not envisage the use ofmarket prices to ultimate consumers of education and health,limits the risk of residualisation, though as we shall see in thefollowing chapter it does not entirely exclude it. But it fullyenvisages the use of pricing and markets in relation to interme-diate customers and suppliers within the service provision chain,and we see how this can produce residualisation on a wide scale.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 11

Commercialisation or Citizenship

12

The degradation of marketsIt has already been pointed out that there can be resort to privateownership or a contribution from private providers withoutmarketisation of the service concerned, especially if by marketwe understand the pure market of the economics text-books. Thisrequires a very large number (tending to infinity) of competingproducers and customers, with low barriers to entry by newproducers. The regulatory system must also confine itself tomaintaining the conditions of perfect competition, and mustoffer absolutely no favours or privileges to individual producersor customers. These stringent conditions fulfil two purposes.First, they ensure the lowest possible prices consistent withkeeping producers in the market. Under perfect competitionevery producer is a price taker; no-one is in a position to fix oreven influence prices by their individual action. Second, thecondition of anonymity that this condition and the requirementof no privileged access to the regulatory authority impose meansthat there can be no political interference to favour individualproducers over others. Indeed, in neo-classical economics there isno scope for lobbying the regulatory authority on behalf ofproducer interests at all.

There are many goods and services where something like theseconditions are fulfilled, but it is obviously not true of someothers, where it is difficult to sustain large numbers of firms.Recent economic theory has compromised with the unrealisticnature of these conditions for oligopolistic sectors. It has beennoted that very small numbers of giant firms can in fact competevery keenly indeed with each other on price; therefore oligopolyin sectors like petrol, and sheer monopoly in computer software,are not considered to offend against anti-trust regulations.However, this assumes that only price is of interest. It completelyignores the important political concerns about privilegedlobbying of political authorities which the conditions of the pure

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 12

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

13

market were also intended to address. For 18th century politicaleconomists, in particular Adam Smith, as well as such 20thcentury successors as Friedrich von Hayek, the guarantee ofanonymity and the incapacity of any individual producer toaffect the market alone were also important for political reasons,to avoid privileged insider lobbying.

This becomes of fundamental importance when we addressprivatisation and major exercises in public-service sub-contracting, for here lobbying and the development of specialrelationships with politicians and civil servants of the kind whichvery large, far from anonymous, firms can carry out, becomeacutely relevant. Securing the privatisation contract, establishingits terms, and planning its eventual renewal, have become occa-sions for intensive interaction between very small numbers ofindividuals representing corporations (often former ministersand civil servants), and current ministers and civil servants. Evenif unwitting, there are clear risks to the maintenance of properstandards in public life in such exchanges. In the case of fullprivatisation, the fact that the firms involved are not perfectmarket agents is frequently recognised by the establishment ofregulatory authorities to monitor the subsequent behaviour ofthe industry. There are then grounds for concern over the rela-tionship between the regulator and the lobbyists. The claim madefor privatisation that it would depoliticise an industry or serviceand prevent corruption was simply untrue.

A central part of the case for bringing private providers intopublic provision is that this will bring increased diversity. Themarket ensures diversity and innovation when a large number offirms is trying to find new ways to make a profit. Many of theideas they produce fail, but some succeed, and new products andservices appear. This works very well in markets where there ismuch scope for diversity and novelty, where there are manyfirms, and where there are no serious overall consequences if

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 13

Commercialisation or Citizenship

14

individual firms fail. Private ‘markets’ within the welfare statelack these characteristics. The number of producers is very small.The number of risks that can be taken with how schools andhospitals are run has to be low.

This does not mean that oligopolistic firms cannot providediversity. Such firms are well equipped for making innovationsprovided their managers have a strong incentive to do so and cangive further incentives to those lower down their hierarchies.Here private firms are in the same position as government organ-isations themselves, which can also, if they choose to do so, findincentives to encourage innovation among their staff despite thelack of competitive pressure. Outside pure markets there is littleto distinguish oligopolies in the private sector from public bodiesor charitable foundations.

Not only is the number of suppliers small, but so is the numberof customers. Although the rhetoric of commercialisation invari-ably speaks of the users or clients of public services as‘customers’, the term is falsely applied. A customer chooses agood or service in exchange for paying the demanded marketprice. The users of contracted-out public services are very rarelyin this position: the customer is the government or other publicauthority which places the contract to provide the service. Theultimate user or consumer of the service may have little choice inthe matter, and has no direct relationship with the provider, allof whose attention in winning custom is directed at representa-tives of the public authority concerned.

The market for public services is therefore one in which oligop-olistic providers make deals with monopsonist customers. Mostof the characteristics normally intended by the idea of the marketare missing from such arrangements.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 14

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

15

Privatising or contracting out?The distinction between privatisation and contracting outrequires further analysis. Under the former, ownership of apreviously public resource is transferred to private firms. Underthe latter, ownership remains with the public sector, but theperformance of individual parts of the service is provided byprofit-seeking firms, on contracts of varying length. There isclearly a difference. For example, in privatising the railwaysgovernment could have retained ownership of the railwaynetwork and contracted out just the provision of train, station,and goods handling services – a solution it was forced to intro-duce following the failure of Railtrack in 2001.

This distinction is very important to the Labour Government,since its strategy towards health and education involves partner-ships between public and private finance and sub-contractingservice delivery, not privatisation. However, while theseprocesses avoid loss of public ownership and of ultimate controlof a public asset, they not only share but in fact intensify one ofthe most disturbing aspects of privatisation: privileged lobbyingand access to ministers and civil servants – the monopsonistcustomers – by individual corporations. Precisely because thereis no final transfer of assets in public private financial partner-ships and contracting out, the relationship between publicauthority and private provider becomes a continuing one, andtherefore the lobbying and temptations of mutual exchanges offavours becomes permanent. Both forms necessarily featurecontracts of long duration. In the case of privately financedcapital projects, like a hospital or large school, contracts have tobe very long indeed, often over 30 years. Given the short lifespanof contemporary political and organisational arrangements,these are more than lifetime contracts. When only services arecontracted out there is not the need for such very lengthyperiods, but there are still certain sunk costs and also a lengthy

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 15

Commercialisation or Citizenship

16

learning curve for the private contractor. Contracts of five toseven years are normal.

During contracts of both these typical lengths, the principalbecomes very dependent on the agent for the quality of delivery.There may be penalty clauses for non-delivery, but these andperformance targets can be specified only for currently foreseenneeds and objectives. Contracts are legally binding documentswhich cannot be easily amended to take account of change; long-term contracts are a curiously rigid and inflexible instrument tobe adopting during a period which is normally seen as onerequiring particularly rapid adaptability and flexibility.

In the case of the shorter-term service contracts, firms have tostart thinking about contract renewal after a fairly short period.This certainly gives them incentives to perform well on theexisting contract, but cultivating good relations with a decision-makers can also help.

It is particularly interesting to observe, as discussed in moredetail in the next chapter, how a number of firms are emergingwho are specialists in the general art of government contracting,and pursue contracts across a wide diversity of sectors – to takethe real example of Serco, a firm that builds missile warningsystems and inspects schools. Clearly such firms have no initialexpertise and therefore no particular substantive value added tooffer within a new field like education when they first enter it.Indeed, it is notable that they almost always recruit their profes-sional staff from the very public authorities – such as inspec-torates and local education authorities – to which they thencontract back their services. What they possess rather is aspecialist skill in winning and possibly managing governmentcontracts from politicians and civil servants. This is not neces-sarily a skill which passes value added and service quality to theultimate consumers. After all, the need for the skill could havebeen avoided simply by not bringing in the private agent at all.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 16

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

17

Loss of the concept of public authority Government’s behaviour in relation to actual and potentialprivate contractors, and uncritical acceptance of their participa-tion in making the public policies from which they will benefit,draws attention to another loss involved in commercialisation:that of the meaning of public authority and public service itself.It is useful here to remember that public service was originally aVictorian, rather than a social democratic, concept. In otherwords, it was developed during the heyday of what we nowoften see as unrestrained capitalism. The explanation of theparadox is that, precisely because they were staking out the liber-ties of capitalism, and frequently encountering the points wherethese clashed with other values and interests, late 19th centuryreformers took seriously Adam Smith’s concern that the businessworld could corrupt politics just as much as politics couldcorrupt business. Politicians and civil servants therefore neededan ethic of their own, which demanded from them conductdifferent from, though not hostile to, that of the business world.They frequently failed to live up to these ideals, which is why weoften see the Victorian age as hypocritical, but the ideals werethere. Public officials were expected to be very careful in theirdealings with persons who represented concentrations of busi-ness power. They were also expected to maintain a sense of thepublic interest which was more than the sum of individual busi-ness ambitions. This idea developed out of the concept of thesuperior interests of the monarch, but it adapted itself to bour-geois life, and then reached its apogee in the social democraticideal of the state as the servant of the universal citizen.

One of the changes introduced by ‘new public management’during the 1980s was a redefinition of the boundary betweengovernment and private interests as a semi-permeable one. It is aone-sided interpretation of the political teaching of classicaleconomics, and in practice represents an unprincipled adapta-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 17

Commercialisation or Citizenship

18

tion to the realities of business lobbying power and theincreasing contribution of business funding to political parties.The intellectual rationalisation it uses is a combination of‘rational expectations’ and ‘public choice’ theory, which combineto assert the essential wisdom of firms and the essential folly ofgovernment. This argument, which for right-wing theorists is animportant motive for bringing private firms into public service,is the following. Competitive success in a perfect marketdepends in part on having the best possible knowledge, forincorrect knowledge will lead to errors of strategy and eventualbankruptcy. Therefore successful firms can be assumed to havethe best possible knowledge, which includes the capacity toanticipate the actions of all other market actors. This is anaxiomatic assumption, since it is assumed that in the long run themarket ensures the survival of only the fittest – in this case, thefirms with the best capacity for acquiring knowledge. No suchassumptions can be made about government. It does not exist ina state of perfect competition and therefore has no incentive toact competently. Therefore its knowledge is deeply suspect.

This thesis is used by its more extreme advocates to argueagainst all government intervention in the economy; if firms inthe market necessarily have superior knowledge to government,anything government tries to persuade them to do will be lessefficient than what they are doing already. In fact, given theircapacity for perfect anticipation, firms will have already workedout what government will be trying to achieve by its interventionand taken evasive action. This perfect knowledge is seen asresiding in particular in firms which have achieved successfulsurvival in the financial markets, who deal specifically ineconomic knowledge, and whose judgement is therefore notopen to challenge.

The argument has three practical weaknesses. First, since verymany markets are far from perfect, it cannot be assumed that

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 18

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

19

even the most successful firms have honed their knowledge gath-ering capacities to the highest possible degree. Second, in arapidly changing world, we cannot ever specify what will actu-ally constitute perfect knowledge after the immediate future;since knowledge acquisition takes time, we cannot assume thatany firm has enough knowledge to deal with the longer-termfuture. During the extended stock-market boom of the 1990smany normally thoughtful people came to believe that somehowthe information technology sector had finally solved all suchproblems. The collapse of that boom during 2000 should serve asa valuable reminder that the knowledge embedded in stockexchanges can be less than perfect.

Both these points suggest that the market does not have auto-matic superiority over public planning. The third point isstronger: certain forms of knowledge are peculiarly available tocentrally located agents (i.e. governments), who are able toacquire knowledge from outside the market process. In otherwords, while firms may have advantages over governments insome kinds of knowledge acquisition, governments may havethe edge in certain other kinds.

Though in practice absurd, this theory has nevertheless exerteda powerful implicit grip over public policy thinking in recentyears, to the extent that chronic lack of self-confidence hasaffected public authorities at all levels. To sustain their self-respect and give themselves any legitimacy at all, they respondby trying to make themselves as much like private firms aspossible (e.g. through internal marketisation), by bringing inexpertise, consultants and actual service delivery from theprivate sector, and by privatising to it and generally exposing asmuch of government (or former government) services as possibleto the judgement of the financial markets. Former distinctionsbetween the ethic of public service and that of private profit-making business are necessarily cast aside in such a process. If

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 19

Commercialisation or Citizenship

20

the wisdom of firms is always superior to that of government, theidea of a proper limit of business influence on governmentbecomes absurd. While these processes were already firmly inplace during the Conservative Governments of the 1980s andearly 1990s, they have reached a certain climax with NewLabour, which, in view of its party’s past, feels a particular needto demonstrate its business friendliness. One of the most startlingexamples of this is the decision to allow individual corporationsto place staff members on temporary secondment to ministries.Equally significant is the way in which government has so muchlost confidence in its own distinctive contribution that it hasallowed even some regulatory activities to be privatised, as weshall see in the following chapter.

This process becomes self-fulfilling. As government contractsout an increasing range of its activities, its employees really dolose competence in the areas being covered by the contractors,areas within which public servants have until now had unri-valled expertise. As they become mere brokers between publicprincipals and private agents, so professional and technicalknowledge pass to the latter. Before long it will become an argu-ment in favour of private contractors that only they have the rele-vant expertise.

In the process of trying to make themselves as similar aspossible to private firms, public authorities also have to divestthemselves of an intrinsic aspect of their role: the fact that theyare authorities, in the sense that they must regulate, and occa-sionally make decisions which admonish. This loss does notextend to the political centre of national government itself. Infact, far from achieving the disappearance of state powerdreamed of by libertarians, the privatising state concentratespower into a tight central nucleus, which deals predominantlywith its peer elites in private business. This happens in thefollowing way. Lower and intermediate authorities, in particular

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 20

21

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

local government, have to transform their activities into thepurchaser/provider model given by the market. The authorityrole is therefore sucked out of them. Central government alsoprivatises many of its own functions to consultants and suppliersof various kinds. But there is an irreducible political core whichconstitutes the elected part of capitalist democracy, which cannotbe sold off (though it can be compromised to lobbyists), andwhich wields the ultimate authority, at least over decisions howand whether to privatise and contract out. This core becomesever smaller as privatisation progresses, but it cannot be elimi-nated altogether without a collapse of the concept of both thestate and democracy. The more that there is privatisation and amarketisation model for public service delivery, particularly atlocal level, the more a Jacobin model of centralised democracyand a citizenship without intermediate levels of political actionhas to be imposed.

The loss of citizenship capacityThere are further, more direct problems for citizens’ rights in themodels of both privatisation and contracting out. Freedland hasdrawn attention to the triangular relationship: government,citizen, privatised supplier of services.6 The citizen has a link,through the electoral and political system, to government(national or local). Government has a link, through the law ofcontract, with the privatised supplier. But the citizen has no link,neither of market nor of citizenship, to the supplier; as we havenoted, service users are not technically customers. And followingprivatisation they can no longer raise questions of servicedelivery with government, because it has contracted suchdelivery away. Henceforth government is responsible only forpolicy, not for operations.

Freedland wrote before the various railway crises of 2000 and2001, which demonstrated a further aspect: the sub-contracting

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 21

22

Commercialisation or Citizenship

chain. Following either privatisation or contracting out, firmsfurther sub-contract elements of their task, and the service moveseven further away from citizens’ reach. One of the main difficul-ties in establishing responsibility for railway failure has been thecapacity of different sub-contractors in an ever-lengthening chainto lose responsibility in the legal labyrinth of contract termswhich links them. A question over service delivery can be untan-gled only, if at all, in complex litigation.

An important argument in support of contracting out certainelements of health and education provision is that privatecontractors are already used quite uncontroversially by publicservice (e.g. government offices buy their stationery in thenormal way). This argument becomes particularly strong whenlinked to contemporary business theory about the value of firmsconcentrating on their ‘core business’ and contracting out fringeactivities. The general concept of core business is valid andimportant, and must in fact be used by those who want to insiston the distinctive place of citizenship in the services we arediscussing. The citizenship component constitutes the core, andthere clearly are ‘fringe’ components which can be safely hivedoff without damaging this. The important issue is how the coreshould be defined. There are two rival approaches: (a) define thecore extensively, with a policy priority being to safeguard theneeds of public authority and service – which as we have seenincludes safeguarding the need for detailed knowledge of theconduct of services by those publicly responsible for them; or (b)maximise privatisation opportunities by defining the core asnarrowly as possible. This disregards the needs set out in (a),producing some of the negative results we have been discussing.By committing itself so fully to the attractions of commercialisa-tion, Labour has been effectively adopting option (b).

During the late 1990s and early 2000s many firms decided thattheir earlier enthusiasm for minimising their definition of the

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 22

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

23

core business, down-sizing and de-layering, had gone too far.They had become dependent on external suppliers who, oncethey had won a long-term contract, were not always concernedabout maximising efficiency. Also, the contracting-out routecontradicts another aspect of good business practice: the impor-tance of developing a corporate culture and staff commitment.This is, ironically, particularly important in services rather thanmanufacturing, there often being little distinction between thepersonnel and the product in service delivery. Can an organisa-tional ethos be fully maintained if the personnel concerned arethe employees of a sub-sub-sub-contractor?

There are therefore major risks in following the contracting outroute. Indeed, if we follow the logic of commercialisation to itsconclusion, one can envisage the emergence of a quite differentidea of politics. By distancing itself from service delivery throughlengthy contract chains, government could imitate a discovery ofthe really smart firms of the 1990s: get rid of the core businessitself. Companies found that if all the work of making a productwere contracted out, the firm itself could concentrate on the soletask of developing its brand image. The role of the successfulfirm, liberated from any substantive tasks, became just thedevelopment of the brand and its association with fashionableideas and celebrities – and this, rather than intrinsic productquality, became the key to its sales. This process has been skil-fully exposed by Naomi Klein in her book No Logo.7 How mucheasier would the work of governments be if they needed to culti-vate only their brand and image, and were not directly respon-sible for the actual quality of their policy products!

This leads us in turn to the final answer to the puzzle of whatit is that private firms might offer which cannot be provided fromwithin the public service itself: presentation. Public serviceprofessionals tend to neglect presentation to a fault; their distinc-tive ethic tells them to concentrate on the quality of the service

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 23

Commercialisation or Citizenship

24

itself. Politicians themselves, although they are part of the publicsector, inhabit a world far closer to that of the private sector, asthey are constantly having to sell themselves and increasingly doso through packaging and media ‘spin’ rather than by ensuringsubstantive quality. It is a small step to the realisation that thegrowth of the presentation approach within these services couldremove the public gaze from their actual quality and focus it onthe advertising schemes that private firms bring with them.

The logical conclusion to this process would then be a ‘fullyspun’ political world where health, education and other serviceswould continue to be central to political debate, but where thatdebate took the form of rival efforts at branding, just as most tele-vision advertisements refer somewhere to a product but areprimarily concerned with associating that product with certainimages that have nothing to do with its intrinsic qualities.Electoral competition in such a context would no doubt continueto be intense and creative, as rival parties sought to associatethemselves with winning imagery – but it would be a competi-tion detached from the awkward facts of real life.

I am not suggesting that such a world is the aim of today’spoliticians, but it can be seen as the ultimate destination towardswhich the processes of commercialisation are leading. Oncegovernments have sub-contracted their services to elongatedsupply chains of private firms, they will no more be responsiblefor their production than Nike is for making the shoes it brands.If one runs this scenario through the Freedland triangle, one seesthat citizens would lose virtually all capacity to translate theirconcerns into political action. Elections would then becomegames around brands, rather than opportunities for citizens totalk back to politicians about the quality of services. Extremethough this might seem, it is only an extension of a process withwhich we have become so familiar that we no longer even noticeit: the approximation of the democratic electoral process, the

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 24

The clash between citizenship and commercialisation

25

highest expression of citizenship rights, to a marketing campaignbased quite openly on the manipulative techniques used to sellproducts.

In fact the alarm bells should be ringing well before that finalstage is reached. For once public services are treated in mostrespects as commodities just like any other, how much longerwill it be possible to defend their being subsidised and notbought and sold in the market like other commodities too? Howlong will the current taboo on full privatisation then last? ThePrime Minister has recently suggested that the next stage ofreform is ‘co-payment’ for public services – that is, privateconsumer fees.8 It seems that we may already be on that path.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 25

26

Commercialisation or Citizenship

School-level education has been a policy field where thecontradictions between citizenship and commercialisationapproaches have been particularly clear in government

policy. The concept of citizenship entitlement is highly devel-oped in education. Partly because so much of its provision iscompulsory, partly because in a democracy all political partiesare required to advocate opportunities for social mobility, thereis an almost universal expectation that education should beavailable as a right, not needing to be purchased in the market –though in practice in the UK and some other countries this idealhas always been heavily compromised by the existence of fee-paying schools to which many wealthy people send their chil-dren.

The strong element of compulsion exists because, if havingtheir children educated was voluntary, many parents would failto do so. This would create problems of social order and mightweaken the eventual economic capacity of these children. It istherefore difficult to apply one fundamental attribute of themarket, freedom of consumer choice. It would be even moredifficult to apply the other fundamental attribute: the payment ofprices which reflect the production costs of the good or serviceoffered. If this were applied, even fewer parents would have

2 | The case of education

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 26

27

The case of education

their children educated, or they would buy very cheap and inad-equate schooling. In principle compulsory consumption could becombined with all other attributes of the market: parents couldbe left free to choose from a range of private school suppliers,and to pay fees. There would however be severe political objec-tions to enforced payment of private consumption. Educationpresents particularly difficult problems for a full application ofmarket logic – which would mean treating it like any other good,offered for sale according to supply and demand – withoutdistorting and degrading the service provided.

Markets and private firms therefore hover on the margins ofthe compulsory education system, in two main forms: the intro-duction of market analogues without privatisation into theschool admissions system; and the contracting out of educationalservices, including increasingly the teaching of subjects inschools, to firms. Both will be explored below.

Making markets in educationFor parents and their children, the choice of school which a childwill attend is the most market-like aspect of the educationsystem. Governments eager to introduce elements of the markethave therefore concentrated attention on extending parents’freedom of choice in this field. However, for the reasons outlinedabove, they have had to do this without use of the price mecha-nism. This limits heavily the degree of marketisation that can beintroduced, as it eliminates two fundamental roles of pricewithin a true market: as a unitary indicator which is consideredto summarise all relevant qualities of an item of the good in ques-tion, enabling it to be compared with rivals and facilitatingchoice; and as a rationing device for distribution. Governmentshave found solutions to these deficiencies. However, the resulthas been, not a happy compromise creating something newbetween citizenship and markets, but a dysfunctional stalemate.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 27

28

Commercialisation or Citizenship

The problem of the absence of price as a quality indicator can inprinciple be tackled by constructing analogues to guidecustomers, and doing this has been a major element of policy.The main solution found by the Conservative Government andcontinued by Labour has been the introduction of official tests ofpupils’ performance, administered at ages seven, eleven, four-teen and sixteen. The results of these are published and used torank and compare schools. Parents are encouraged to use themas indicators of quality when choosing schools for their children.At the same time, schools’ performances in the annual GCSE andA Level GCE examinations are calculated, ranked and widelypublished in the press. All this facilitates a market-like process,but it has two principal defects which may distort educationalprovision.

First, partial indicators encourage schools to maximiseperformance on those items reflected in the indicators alone. Ifsuccess in certain examinations is measured and published, therational school will concentrate on those at the expense of otheractivities. There have been many examples of this, leading todemands that government adjust the indicators used so that theycover all relevant areas, and government has been responsive tothese pleas. But there are two limitations to this strategy. First, ifindicators multiply, they become too complex, and people findthem difficult to appraise. As Onora O’Neill observed in the thirdof her 2002 BBC Reith Lectures, as targets become more and moretechnical and complex, and are changed with increasingfrequency, the ‘public’ ceases to be able to understand them atall.9 The new accountability is not to the public at all, but just tothe political centre. Second, as she also observed, the vast volumeof work involved in record keeping and target-making meansthat the attention of professionals is increasingly focussed onthese, giving them less time for genuine engagement with thereal public, their clients.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 28

29

The case of education

A second and highly contentious issue has been the use ofpupils’ performance as a judgement on school quality, when it iswell known that children’s academic achievements dependheavily on their social background. The Labour Governmentinitiated a system of baseline testing to reflect this: children aretested on entry to a school; subsequent test performances canthen be compared with their initial achievements to assess thevalue added by the school. The White Paper that eventuallybecame the Education Act 2002 announced that indicators basedon these baseline results will eventually be published alongside– but not instead of – the raw data. But many parents may bemore interested in the raw data. They want to know both whatthe school achieves and the quality of its raw material, for in thisway they can select schools with suitable fellow pupils for theirchildren. The indicator system sends signals which can be usedto reinforce social segregation. In any case, as Brighouse haspointed out, general school measures tell parents very little aboutthe particular balance of characteristics that they seek for theirchild.10

Test scores have not been the only forms of quality signaldeveloped by governments to make markets for school choice.Further indicators are provided by the reports of Ofsted, theOffice for Standards in Education, introduced by theConservatives to give more impetus to change and higher publicprominence to school inspection than the school visits of HMInspectorate of Schools. Ofsted grades schools into various cate-gories, including the highly negative ones of ‘having seriousweaknesses’, or ‘requiring special measures’ to improve them.

A further technique has been the development of differenttypes of school. In some parts of the country the old 1944 systemof a distinction between grammar schools and residual schoolswas never abolished, and New Labour has no objection to thissituation continuing. The Conservative Education Reform Act

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 29

30

Commercialisation or Citizenship

1988 had provided for the establishment of Grant MaintainedSchools (GMS). To encourage schools to become GMSs theGovernment introduced certain inducements, such as generouscapital and other grants which were not available to LEA schools.GMSs were permitted to select up to 15 per cent of their pupilsfrom outside their catchment areas, using whatever criteria theyliked. GMS status therefore served as a signal to parents that thiswas a school in favoured financial circumstances and to someextent able to recruit pupils of its choice – a strong market signal.

In practice the implications of this policy were limited: notmany GMSs were introduced; their distribution through thecountry was very uneven. Their contribution to increased choiceand to a market in schools was therefore small, arbitrary andsometimes negative. Further extensions of this experiment werestopped by the Labour Government of 1997, which also changedthe status of existing GMSs to that of foundation schools; formany purposes, including the crucial question of admissions,they were brought back under LEA responsibility.

However, at secondary level Labour also embarked on an alter-native policy of its own for inserting new forms of school withinthe state system but possessing attractive qualities which wouldmark them out from ordinary schools. The 2001 White Paperproposed a major expansion of the existing experimental policyof ‘specialist schools’. These seek to develop expertise in certainparticular kinds of education – such as technology, arts, sports,business studies. To help them fulfil their particular mission,they will be able to select up to 10 per cent of their pupils basedon ability within their chosen specialisms. The Governmentintends that 40 per cent of all secondary schools in Englandshould be ‘specialist’ by 2005, with a further group in the cate-gory of ‘working towards’ specialist status. (The Governmenthas now said that ultimately it wants all schools to have somekind of specialism.) In addition to LEAs, voluntary bodies, reli-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 30

31

The case of education

gious organisations and private firms can apply for the right toestablish them. In addition to their limited selection right,specialist schools will have the right to pay teachers more thanother schools. Schools which have been successful specialistschools for five years will have the chance to become advancedspecialist schools, receiving more funding than those aroundthem but also having some responsibilities to develop materialsand training and provide services for these others.

The Government argues that specialist schools do not mark areturn to selection, because a diversity of specialisms will berecognised, not just general academic ability, and no school isprohibited from working towards specialist status. It is in factmore concerned to make markets than intensify selection, theemphasis of the arguments of the White Paper being onexpanding diversity in order to increase choice. However, sincesuperior funding and privileges are to be a mark of specialistschools, it is clear that they are being marked out as more desir-able, and not just diverse.

The White Paper introduced a further distinction amongschools in its concept of the ‘successful’ school, formal criteria fordefining which will be devised. Under certain conditions‘successful’ schools might be permitted: to pay higher salaries totheir teachers; to be exempted for teaching parts of the NationalCurriculum; and to expand their size irrespective of local admis-sions and school size policies.

The Conservative Education Reform Act 1988, which intro-duced the tests and the Ofsted model, concomitantly gaveparents increased rights to choose individual schools within theirlocal authority, rather than being allocated to their neighbouringschool. Schools were then given incentives to attract parents, asthey were rewarded financially if they could compete success-fully with their neighbours in recruiting pupils. Labour retainedall these policies and, as we have seen above, is strengthening

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 31

32

Commercialisation or Citizenship

some of the mechanisms which divert pupils numbers andresources to certain schools.

Together all these policies over the 1988 to 2001 period haveput in place a powerful market analogue whereby customers(parents) are equipped with information to find the mostsuccessful schools, and providers (schools) have strong incen-tives to attract customers. This might seem to be a highly desir-able situation, but it has a number of negative consequences. If,as the 2001 White Paper implies, all that is happening is thatdiversity is being expanded so that customers with differenttastes can find providers to match, there would be little to worryabout, apart from a large number of minor frictions when supplyand demand for particular school characteristics did not match incertain areas. In reality however it is not a question of a widediversity, but a ranking of ‘good’ and ‘bad’ schools. Test andexamination results, Ofsted reports, the eventual designations of‘successful’ schools all point in the same direction. In theoryspecialist schools will cover a wider range of attributes, but manyof them will be ‘specialising’ in those areas of the curriculumwhich deliver the high test scores. Clearly, demand for these willexceed supply. In a true market the price of ‘good’ schools wouldrise to bring demand and supply into equilibrium. But thissecond, controversial role of price as a means of rationing is ruledout by the citizenship principles of the national educationsystem.

The market approach therefore has to operate without substan-tive prices. In doing this however it does not produce a compro-mise, but continues to violate citizenship principles. As ‘good’ orpopular schools use their additional resources to expand, ‘poor’schools, starved of both pupils and resources, will necessarilydecline, and will either eventually close or be left with aresiduum of children whose parents do not care. Alternatively,poor schools, shaken out of their complacency as the spiral of

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 32

33

The case of education

decline envelops them, will make determined attempts toimprove. In doing this they have an uphill task, as resources andpupils continue to haemorrhage from them.

If nearly all pupils end up in the successful schools while thepoor schools decline, there are further negative components. It isa long, slow process. Schools cannot expand quickly, and duringthat period whole cohorts of children will pass through help-lessly declining schools. It is also possible for schools to grow toobig to continue with their current regimes; a successful schoolmight be undermined by its very expansion. Further, in manyparts of the country the closure of some schools and the removalof pupils to a different one imposes high transport costs on chil-dren, which government is already reluctant to meet.

But more insidious than these problems is a perverse analogueof a school fee which emerges when elements of the market areintroduced into a theoretically non-selective system. If thesupply of places in ‘good’ schools cannot rise to meet demand,there is competition among parents. This competition is resolvedin ways which cannot be reconciled with the citizenship model.Schools’ achievements are determined by two factors: the initialcultural capital that pupils bring with them (the quality of theraw materials) and the quality of the education which the schoolprovides (the school’s added value). While parents are‘customers’, their children are the raw materials which are fash-ioned by the school to produce the end product. The customersthus make their own contribution to their children’s schools’performance, and hence to the schools’ ability to acquireresources. Schools therefore have an incentive to admit childrenfrom parents likely to contribute strong social capital and toreject those who lack cultural capital. Children’s educationalpotential therefore serves as a curious analogue of a school feewithin the new price analogue system; the higher the ability of achild, the better chances its parents have of acquiring the school

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 33

Commercialisation or Citizenship

34

place they wanted; and the higher the subsequent ‘profits’ of theschool. If this process proceeds unchecked, inequalities ofachievement between schools which attract the ‘best’ pupilsbecause of their own past record, and those which are unable todo so, will spiral. The quality of education of those in unfavouredschools will deteriorate. Any role which schools might play aschannels of social mobility will be completely undermined.

The citizenship approach to these problems first limits schools’ability to choose their pupils in order to reduce the onset of thespiral of inequality; and second and more important takes directaction of various kinds to improve education quality in poorschools. The market and citizenship approaches are here mutu-ally incompatible. The former works by using parental choice toencourage inequalities between schools to accumulate, and thenredistributes resources from poor to successful schools. The citi-zenship approach tries to limit the destabilising effects onschools of parental choice, redistributes resources to poorschools, and takes many direct action measures to improve theirperformance.

Contradictory though they are, the Labour Government seeksto honour simultaneously the citizenship model and the newmarketisation strategy. Since 1997 it has undertaken many meas-ures for directly improving poor schools, and Schools – AchievingSuccess set out further strong and imaginative new policies fordoing the same. The 2002 Green Paper proposed a number ofmeasures for recognising vocational forms of education along-side academic ones – though in doing so it threatened even morecomplex indicators and measures of performance. But the 2001White Paper had sustained and even reinforced all elements ofthe market analogue approach which constantly undermine theefforts of these schools to improve by encouraging parents withstrong cultural capital to avoid them. Additional resources willbe steered towards both successful schools and those experi-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 34

The case of education

35

encing particular difficulties; both specialist schools and those inareas of deprivation will be able to offer higher pay to help themrecruit the best teachers. Every help offered to schools with prob-lems is counteracted by an equivalent help offered to the privi-leged. There is little to prevent many of the former becomingresidual schools for children unable to find a place in either aspecialist school of some kind or a residentially favouredcomprehensive; and somewhere in the middle there will beschools excluded from both contradictory redistributive flows.The solution held out by the White Paper for resolving thesedilemmas was to increase the number of specialist schools andaspirants to that status, in order to ensure that they are not just asmall elite. But the more that this is done, the more extreme is theghetto to which the residual schools are consigned.

In many policy areas, in particular those concerned with thedistribution of income, it has been made clear that New Labour’sconcept of egalitarianism means trying to move the lowestpercentiles of the population closer to the median, whileremaining unconcerned that the distance between the medianand the top percentiles is increasing. The schools policy of the2001 White Paper is a perfect example of this philosophy: it isconcerned to ensure that the lowest percentiles achieve higherstandards than they do at present, while creating mechanisms forensuring that the upper percentiles move even further ahead. Asa policy for increasing the all-round educational performance ofthe national workforce, this is entirely coherent. However, as apolicy for securing equality of opportunity it cannot escape itsinternal contradictions. To the extent that competition for goodjobs is a zero-sum game, the mechanisms of parental and schoolchoice analysed above ensure that improving further the qualityof schools available to those with most cultural capital wipes outany compensatory measures taken to help poor schools.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 35

36

Commercialisation or Citizenship

The distortion and residualisation of LEAsThe market analogue model and the prominence of league tablesgives even schools which do not have official selection possibili-ties strong incentives to try to get the ‘best’ children, and equallyto avoid the ‘worst’. There are numerous ways in which they cando this, such as trying to dissuade parents of poorly performingchildren from choosing them, or by excluding children withbehaviour problems and passing them on to neighbouringschools. Schools’ admissions and catchment area practices haveto be strongly policed if this kind of ‘black market’ in schoolplaces is to be avoided, a policing which becomes more necessaryas marketisation grows. However, Conservative and LabourGovernments have instead weakened the available policingmechanisms, mainly through the weakening of local educationauthorities which has itself been a major aspect of the marketisa-tion strategy. Indeed, in 2001 a consultation document issuedalongside Schools – Achieving Success, acknowledged explicitlythat a free market in admissions was simply not working, andthat LEAs would in future play a stronger co-ordinating role.Once again the Government’s citizenship agenda had clashedwith its marketisation one. There was not however a clear changeback to the former; again the Government is simultaneouslypursuing contradictory approaches. Stressing the co-ordinatingrole of LEAs runs alongside, but does not replace, the recenthistory of their general disempowerment.

First, both Conservative and Labour Governments have marke-tised LEAs’ relationship to schools, changing it from one of amonitoring authority to that of a supplier of commercial services.Second, and consequent on this, Labour has sought to replacethem at as many points as possible by private firms. These poli-cies in themselves threaten major distortions and an eventualresidualisation of LEAs.

An initial major requirement for transforming relations

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 36

The case of education

37

between schools and LEAs into market analogues was a distor-tion of the organisational character of schools themselves.Producers in markets are firms, who have to buy the labour andraw materials they use to make their products. To fit this, schoolshave had to be changed from their historical model as organisa-tions sui generis, to increasingly resemble small firms.

First, the Education Act 1986 (No 2) introduced the localmanagement of schools (LMS) system, which granted increaseddecision-making powers to schools. Then the Education ReformAct 1988 removed schools’ earlier autonomy over the curriculumthrough the introduction of a National Curriculum, replacingthis with new autonomy in finance and management. Schools,and especially their heads, lost professional autonomy butacquired financial autonomy, encouraging them to see this busi-ness-type, non-educational role as their primary self-definition.Head teachers were further encouraged to see themselves asmanagers, distinct from the teachers who work for them ratherthan primi inter pares within a teaching profession, by the intro-duction of performance-related pay for classroom teachers by theLabour Government in 2000. Heads have the job, with externalcommercial assessors, of deciding on the allocation of perform-ance increments to their staff. They have also been forced tobecome managers and bureaucrats instead of education profes-sionals by the extraordinary number of short-term, soft-moneyopportunities which government offers schools as it attempts tosustain a high public profile with more and more initiatives.11

In 2001 the Government initiated a policy of encouragingtakeovers of unpopular schools by a more popular neighbour asan approach to the problem of inequalities between schools.Significantly it did not use normal professional or local govern-ment mechanisms for this – such as the administrative amalga-mations already in place and often used by LEAs needing toreduce the number of schools in an area – but the model of the

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 37

Commercialisation or Citizenship

38

corporate takeover: the acquiring school acts through a commer-cial acquisition of assets.

While schools have in these ways been persuaded to conceiveof themselves as firms, the relationship between them and LEAshas become one of purchasers and providers of educationalsupport services, with LEAs gradually becoming just one amonga number of potential providers. This policy was initiated by theConservatives, but in general during that period LEAs weresuccessful in retaining their role. The main difficulties they facedwere that if a school chose to become a GMS, it movedcompletely outside the LEA’s sphere, and funds notionally allo-cated to the LEA for its administrative support were transferredto the school. Head teachers were therefore able to use the threatof encouraging their governors to consider ‘going GMS’ as adeterrent to any attempts by an authority to express disagree-ment with whatever heads were doing.

While the Labour Government had abolished the GMS possi-bility, it never acknowledged how the existence of GMSs haddestroyed LEAs’ authority, but took advantage of that weaknessto accuse them of not having asserted authority, and used that tojustify undermining it even further. During the first two yearsafter 1997 the Government seemed to contemplate abolishingLEAs. This in itself encouraged some head teachers to regardthem as of no consequence. But more important have been theGovernment’s substantive policies for further weakening LEAs’authority.

These have been motivated by the exceptional priority that ithas placed on moving private sector suppliers into public serv-ices. At first, Labour’s dominant rhetoric was solely that of LEAfailure; it was taken as axiomatic that, while public organisationswere likely to fail, private firms delivered consistent success.Certain authorities were deemed to have failed, and private firmsgiven the contract to do their job. This happened to Hackney,

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 38

The case of education

39

Islington, Liverpool, Sheffield, Leeds, Rotherham, WalthamForest and Bradford. In all but one case, private firms (ratherthan action within the public sector) were the solution sought,though in one of these the private intervention itself later failedand was replaced by renewed public involvement. In November1999 the then schools minister, Estelle Morris, predicted that afurther fifteen LEAs would be found to have failed, leading tosuspicions that the Government had a privatisation target.12 Inthe event the longer list never materialised.

The failure model was also applied to individual schools. TheConservative-controlled Surrey County Council began this in1998, when it offered the contract to manage a failing school to aprivate firm. Contrary to widespread expectations that theGovernment would oppose such a policy, it applauded it. TheEducation Act 2002 extended the Surrey model by giving theSecretary of State the right to require a local authority to offer afailing school to a private company.

However, private education firms were not interested in beingconfined to a role of rescuing ‘failures’, which can be a difficulttask, but wanted chances to run profitable services. The ability to‘cherry-pick’, to spot where the profitable options are, is funda-mental to the entrepreneurial skill of firms who bid for govern-ment contracts.

Government responded to the lobbying, but this required achange of policy towards LEAs and a different rhetoric from thatof privatisation in the case of their failure. A kind of halfwayhouse had been the policy of Education Action Zones (EAZs),which retained the idea of private firms helping with areas ofsocial difficulty, but in co-operation with LEAs. Government waswilling to invest additional resources in areas with specifiedsocial problems, provided LEAs found partners from privatebusiness to join them, who would be willing to provide 25 percent of total funding and contribute some form of expertise. The

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 39

Commercialisation or Citizenship

40

management of schools within an EAZ ceases to be accountableto the LEA, and the business partners are able to influence thecurriculum. A similar policy has been the ‘city academies’whereby private sponsors can establish schools with innovativecurricula freed from some of the constraints of the nationalcurriculum. This might or might not be done in conjunction withthe LEA. These experiments have been less confrontationaltowards LEAs, but maintained the ideology that the privatesector held the answer to poor educational performance.

By 2000 Labour was developing from this a completely new,positive strategy of using LEAs themselves as active participantsin the search for opportunities for commercialisation. Authoritieswhich co-operated in this were held up for praise; additionalfinance was made available if they would participate in experi-ments that might lead to hiving off some of their services. Thecriteria applied by Ofsted in its inspections of LEAs rewardedthose which had structured themselves in a way amenable topiecemeal commercialisation. (Ofsted inspectors often work forfirms who will be seeking privatisation contracts.) Then, duringthe 2001 general election campaign the Prime Minister turned therhetoric up a further notch: bringing private contractors into thepublic education and health services became an indicator –indeed, the indicator – of commitment to modernisation. In hissubsequent statements on public service reform, ‘modernisation’has become a virtual synonym for bringing in the private sector.

LEAs were now in a full Catch-22; failure to succeed madethem vulnerable to privatisation; they could demonstrate theircommitment to success by being willing to privatise. TheEducation department invented a new term to describe the newprocess. LEAs were to be the ‘brokers’ of services to schools, withthe responsibility of creating open markets for these services.13

The Conservatives had initiated a policy of compulsorycompetitive tendering, whereby many services provided directly

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 40

The case of education

41

by local government, such as street cleaning and refuse collec-tion, had to be offered to private contractors, and could beretained by the public service only if it succeeded in under-bidding the competition – usually by worsening the terms ofemployment of employees. None of this concerned LEAs’ corebusiness. This was finally hit through Labour’s policy of ‘BestValue’ reviews. Council departments are required to comparetheir own structure of service provision throughout the range ofactivities with those of other authorities, with an emphasis onseeking opportunities for bringing in commercial suppliers. Afurther instrument has been the New Models project underwhich government established eleven partnerships betweenLEAs and a small number of private firms. Some projectscomprised consortia of a number of LEAs and a firm, othersmatched individual LEAs and firms. One, which involved a part-nership between an LEA and a book shop chain, giving the latterprivileged rights to disseminate schools information in the area,collapsed early. In the other experiments, in principle the author-ities and the private firm discuss how the LEAs’ services areorganised and carried out. This might facilitate subsequent bidsby the firm to take over certain services; it certainly puts it in avery privileged place with important inside knowledge.

Converting the services which LEAs provide to schools intocommercial ones does not necessarily distort them; there is noreason to regard the cutting of grass in school playing fields orthe purchase of exercise books as any different from equivalenttransactions by any other organisation. Distortions appear if thecharacter of the service offered is adversely changed by beingforced into a commercial mould. This does happen where thedistinctive position of LEAs’ work as the exercise of publicauthority and professional judgement is concerned, and yet thiskind of work has in no way been excluded from the govern-ment's privatisation attempts. The Best Value reviews and New

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 41

Commercialisation or Citizenship

42

Models experiments provide strong examples of this. Theseoperate by redefining the LEA activities concerned as thoughthey were indistinguishable from any kind of service providedfor customers by a firm. This is necessary, because if LEA func-tions are viewed in their actually existing form as the exercise ofprofessional monitoring authority on behalf of a public interest,it would be LEAs who would appear as having the superiorexperience and capacity.

Some of the resulting distortions are merely silly – as whentargets for ‘customer satisfaction’ are sought in the number ofparental preferences in school choice met, or in reductions in thenumber of appeals made over school admissions decisions.These outcomes depend heavily on the behaviour of individualschools and, in many cases, the character of the areas in whichschools are located, rather than in any deliberate actions by LEAstaff. More important is the way in which treating admissionsservices as a marketable customer service ignores the issuesdiscussed above: conflict between schools, their desire toimprove their pupil base, to try exclude children from ‘difficult’estates, and to pass disruptive pupils on to rivals through exclu-sions. Dealing with these and similar issues requires a policingrather than a service-supplier role.

Initially the positive arguments for contracting out had usedthe ‘core business’ argument, but this changed. For some yearsthe Government had acknowledged the non-commercialisablecharacter of many ‘core’ decisions made by LEA staff, and there-fore limited hiving off to routine tasks only; but this changed asits determination to maximise privatisation intensified. In spring2001 a simple Order of the then Department for Education andSkills extended the range of services which LEAs ought toconsider privatising to include those affecting authorities’ exer-cise of ‘discretion’. This mainly concerns judgements in indi-vidual children's cases. A small list of LEA functions remains still

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 42

The case of education

43

excluded from contracting out, but these are largely restricted toformal, budget-setting tasks, not educational ones. By the time ofSchools – Achieving Success, Government saw no reason whyschools should not contract out various lessons or subjects toprivate companies, or LEAs their school improvement work. Thepublic education service now no longer has a core business,which means that none of its activities are considered unsuitablefor commercialisation.

The likely outcome of this process will be not just the distor-tions of LEAs’ role discussed so far, but their residualisation.Firms are explicitly mentioned as eligible to seek to establishspecialist schools. Given that many LEAs are likely to havesevere reservations about the highly controversial specialistschool concept, that it is the Government who will decide on theestablishment of such schools, and that Government is eagerlyseeking ways of increasing private sector involvement in schoolprovision, it is probable that a high proportion of specialistschools will be run by firms. Some advanced specialist schoolswill also be privately run, receiving additional governmentsubsidy and a favoured chance of selling services to other schoolsin their area. The 2001 White Paper envisaged ensuring a majorrole for private firms in the establishment of new schools every-where. Henceforth, when an LEA identifies the need for a newschool, it must do all the preparatory work, including finding asite. At that point however it must invite bids to build and runthe school from voluntary and religious groups and commercialfirms. The Secretary of State will have the sole right to select thesuccessful bidder. Again, given the Government’s preferences, itis likely to grant a high number of these to the commercial sector.

In time private firms will come to own a large share of the priv-ileged specialist schools, and in general the newest and bestequipped schools, leaving the public sector to make good theobligation of universal provision by filling the gaps rejected as

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 43

Commercialisation or Citizenship

44

unprofitable. There are signs that the Government is consciouslypreparing such an outcome. It has been encouraging a modelwhereby local authority education departments are amalga-mated with social services departments. The latter are mainlyconcerned with services of social repair and casualties – espe-cially in the case of children’s services, the only part of socialservices work that touches the same client group as education.Education departments can only be sensibly merged with socialservices departments if the former have also become primarilyservices for social casualties. Virtually the only role in the directprovision of education reserved to LEAs by the 2002 EducationAct is that of running full-time, out-of-school pupil referral unitsin which an attempt must be made to educate pupils excludedfrom all the schools of their area because of their behaviour. Thenumbers of such pupils must be expected to rise, as the Act willalso make it easier for head teachers permanently to exclude chil-dren; and private firms can be expected to want to exclude suchpupils from the schools under their control.

It is a well established finding of occupational sociology thatthere is high morale among staff involved in experiment andinnovation, while that of those who know that they are engagedin an activity which is being run down declines. Private firmstaking over the running of schools in the USA have often beenable to show results superior to the existing public sector. Thestaff involved in these novelties are likely to feel a boost to theirmorale in comparison with colleagues labouring away in anincreasingly residual public service. In addition, the firm itselfdevotes high-quality senior staff and close attention to theseexperimental cases; they are ‘loss leaders’, being abnormallyhighly funded in order to win new contracts. The only faircomparison with an experimental, heavily resourced privateexperiment would be with a similar experiment taking placewholly within the public system, not with the routine mass.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 44

The case of education

45

The Government has also been trying to restrict the role ofLEAs’ advisory services, which advise schools on best practice,identify weaknesses, and assist schools with difficulties inmeeting their teaching objectives. They have been told to restricttheir activities to cases where schools are clearly in difficulties,and not to spend time with schools that are functioning well.14 Aprivate market is developing whereby firms of consultants givesuch advice, and they prefer to work with successful schools,which are in any case more likely to have resources to spend ontheir services. By being restricted to contacts with problemschools LEA advisors will not only lose their chance to act pro-actively and identify early weaknesses appearing in currentlysuccessful ones, but they will lose contact with best practicedeveloping in the best schools. This latter will become amonopoly preserve of the private firms, and LEA staff will againbe suitable only for dealing with casualties.

A very important theme of central government criticism oflocal government during Labour’s first few years of office wasthe neglect of ‘joined up government’ – the need for particulardepartments and units to integrate their work with others.Considerable use was also made of the virtues of the ‘one-stopshop’ – such as the ability of parents or schools to get most of theinformation they needed from an LEA from a single knownsource. These desiderata become increasingly difficult to achieveif various parts of an LEA’s services have been commercialised,and if former colleagues now have to relate to each other acrossa barrier erected by the terms of a purchaser/provider servicecontract. It is also difficult to secure services from a providerwhich have not been anticipated in advance in the terms of acontract. Contract terms necessarily trump any need to respondto newly emerging needs or to innovate in tackling problems.Performing the professional task is displaced and the substantivegoals of the education service are distorted.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 45

Commercialisation or Citizenship

46

More generally, the more services that an LEA contracts out,the more its staff lose detailed, day-to-day knowledge about itsschools. Information that previously passed between colleagueswithin the same organisation again has to cross thepurchaser/provider boundary. Some information will becomethe private property of the firm, and LEA staff may have to payto have access to it. This imposes rigidities, as it is difficult topredict all future information needs at the time a contract is beingdrawn up. Since so much of the knowledge needed for the day-to-day running of a system is informal, even tacit, it can in noway be defined in a contract and purchased.

The exclusion of LEAs from future-oriented roles goes further.In 2001 the Government established a Learning and SkillsCouncil (LSC), to have responsibility for all sixteen-nineteen yearold, adult and community education. Its members are appointedby central government, and it will itself appoint the members ofits 47 local councils; there will be no guaranteed LEA representa-tion, though the LSC and its local bodies will have a duty toconsult them.15 All education institutions providing for theselevels, including school sixth forms, will henceforth receive theirfunds from the LSC and not from LEAs, though the latter’s staffwill still have to do the clerical work involved in the transactions.This begins a process of removing LEAs from involvement withsixth-form education, a crucial part of the school system. In 2002the process was taken even further, when the Governmentannounced that the role of (and funding by) the LSC could movedown to age fourteen.

LEAs are today expected to retain a small and continuouslydeclining proportion of their funding for their own services,distributing the rest to schools. Meanwhile, in addition to theircontinuing duties, they have to use these funds to respond toincreasing demands from government to work on special proj-ects, much of it related to privatisation. The sums left to them for

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 46

The case of education

47

their own pro-active activities are becoming tiny – which makesit easier to stigmatise them as not being at the cutting edge.Almost the only chances they have of acquiring resources forinnovation are to bid for participation in government specialprojects, which almost always require working with a privatepartner. This not only strengthens a stereotype of LEAs inno-vating only when associated with such partners; it also forceseven authorities which are hostile to such relationships to under-take them, giving an impression of active support.

In all these developments we see the contradiction between themarket and citizenship. Marketisation involves contracting outto private firms those things which they consider that they canmake profitable. This ‘cherry-picking’ is an essential attribute ofthe successful government contractor – and it takes us to theheart of the main reason why the private sector often seems moreefficient than the public. But the citizenship ideal requires educa-tion to be a universal service, which means that someone has todo the unprofitable work. Under a marketisation model this isthe task of the residual public service. But residual provision is abetrayal of universal citizenship.

Privatisation before marketisationThe use of market analogues in school admissions and thecommercialisation of LEA services and school management areseparate policies, but they relate to each other at two points. First,as we have seen, the more that LEAs are commercialised - eitherby full privatisation or by themselves acting according tocommercial criteria – the less they are able to play the authorityrole in relation to schools which the latter’s marketisationrequires if abuses are to be checked. Second, while ‘cherry-picking’ is central to market behaviour, elements of the way inwhich it is being conducted raise doubts about whether thecurrent policy represents a true move to markets. We are here

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 47

Commercialisation or Citizenship

48

contending with distortions, not caused by the market, but of themarket itself.

The conversion of a citizenship service into a commercial onealongside surviving citizenship assumptions requires such anextensive upheaval in its character that not only the service itself,but the markets which develop, themselves become distorted.They have to be politically fixed, and in the process some of thepositive qualities associated with markets are lost. These distor-tions began under the Conservatives, but either because they lostoffice when the process was still in early stages of development,or because they believed that entrepreneurs would simplyappear if space was created for them, they did not make muchprogress in shaping markets and directly encouraging entrepre-neurs into the education arena. This task has therefore fallenprimarily to Labour.

A major advantage of market provision proposed by its advo-cates is that the market is anonymous and not vulnerable to polit-ical manipulation. However, the difficulty of constructingmarkets in the education sector means that government becomesinvolved in an intensive lobbying process with a small number ofkey players. Since this has been happening during a period whencentral government’s relations with local government have beencooling, a small number of firms have enjoyed a far closer polit-ical relationship to ministers than have local authorities, despitethe party and civil service links apparently connecting differentlevels of government. Central government has consistently main-tained a distance from LEAs, and is residualising their role inschools, as we have seen.

Not surprisingly, therefore, the various initiatives discussedabove have presented firms with very attractive terms. Forexample, when they or others run city academies, they must pay20 per cent of capital costs, but ownership of the land and build-ings is transferred to them from local government without

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 48

The case of education

49

charge. When, in July 2001, a semi-private City TechnologyCollege in Nottingham was enabled to acquire the lease of aneighbouring, under-subscribed comprehensive, additionalgovernment funding was released to improve the school, whichwould not have been available had the school stayed in localauthority hands. Design of the Payment By Results (PBR) systemfor teachers was contracted in 1999 for £3 million, withoutcompetitive tendering, to a firm, Hay McBer, while a secondfirm, Cambridge Education Associates, was given the £100million five-year contract for running the system.16 (The firmemploys more than 3,000 assessors to check head teachers’assessments of their staff.)17 LEAs were not even consulted aboutoperation of the PBR scheme.

There have also been instances of permitting firms to brandeducational activities in schools. The Learning and and SkillsDevelopment Agency has funded a GNVQ pack devoted to thestudy of one firm – Legoland.18 Materials advertising Legolandare included in the packs. Less dramatically, it is already virtu-ally routine for individual IT firms to be granted monopolycontracts, heavily subsidised by public funds, to provide infor-mation technology services to schools and other public organisa-tions; the receiving organisation is then completely dependent onthat firm’s practices (and prices) as it introduces product modifi-cations which may make the initial installation redundant.

In the USA and Canada it is already commonplace for schoolsto base their teaching programmes around the image and prod-ucts of an individual corporation. In exchange for sponsorship,firms can acquire monopoly rights over access to children in theirschools, or can impose wearing of clothes bearing their logos asa form of school uniform, or even require that children watchadvertisements on their school computer screens for a certainperiod of time each day. Would central government now raiseany objections to the expansion of such practices in the UK? Does

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 49

Commercialisation or Citizenship

50

it have any concept of either the appropriate limits of the reach ofcommercialisation, or of the dangers of granting individual firmsmonopoly privileges, which conflict with the idea of the freemarket?

Contract-winning as the new core educationbusinessNon-market approaches to private sector involvement are verydominant in the new policies for commercialisation of citizen-ship services. Because the Government is not sure how tocommercialise these areas, it wants information from insiders.Because it is desperate to maximise this new role of the privatesector, it wants to make its offers to private firms as attractive aspossible. It is therefore eagerly vulnerable to intensive lobbyingby firms who see major opportunities of soft profits.

The Labour Government itself has sometimes been tough withcontractors, for example imposing penalty clauses in contracts ifthey fail to deliver improved standards in schools which theytake over. It could perhaps give greater guidance to local govern-ment staff on how to drive hard bargains in contract negotiationswith private sector firms. To date all responsibility for educatingLEAs in private-public partnerships seems to have been dele-gated to the firms themselves, who are unlikely to include thisamong their lessons.

The overall approach is courting the worst of two worlds, withboth marketisation and citizenship losing out, not this timebecause of a clash between them, but because both clash with thepractice of insider lobbying and preferred bidders. This approachruns all the risks of service deterioration of commercialisationdiscussed above, without the advantages – keen pricing, genuinechoice for ultimate consumers – which the true market can oftenbring. It carries all the disadvantages of state involvement in

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 50

The case of education

51

commercial transactions – the formation of privileged circles ofsuppliers – without the restraining hand of the public serviceethos which has been discarded in favour of a commercial one.Although the whole exercise is being carried out using the rhet-oric of free-market economics, in reality it returns us to the worldof relations between government and monopoly-holding ‘courtfavourites’ against which Adam Smith and others developedtheir initial formulations of that economics.

Government contracts within the commercialising welfarestate are very attractive. As we have already noted, they arenecessarily long-term – as much as 25 to 30 years in the case ofbuildings, such as schools. It would in fact be very difficult for,say, an LEA to contract out management of its school admissionsservices to a different firm every year or two, as the learningcurves involved in getting to know the district and its schoolswould impose considerable inefficiencies. This process makes itvery difficult to deal with dissatisfaction with the quality of aservice being offered. Also, during a seven-year period acontractor can expect to develop very close relations withpersonnel in the contracting authority, making it a highly privi-leged insider when the contract eventually comes up for renewal.

Furthermore, in its eagerness to commercialise, the govern-ment has heavily subsidised most of these developments. Forexample, government invested £1.8 million in the New Modelsprojects, most of which money went to private firms, thoughmost of the work for the experiments was carried out by LEAs.The information flow within the projects is entirely unidirec-tional. The firm learns everything it wants about how the LEAswork and about their finances; they are told nothing equivalentabout the firm operates. It is then in a good position to bid to takeover selected parts of the LEAs’ work. The firms are in effectbeing subsidised in their attempts to secure profit-makingcontracts.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 51

Commercialisation or Citizenship

52

The character of the firms which have entered the new marketis instructive. A number have emerged specifically around it.Their founders have usually been former teachers or LEA staffwho saw the chances of higher incomes by going private at atime when the Government has been cutting expenditure onadministration within public service, but subsidising higherspending on it if the same services are provided privately. Thesefirms draw almost entirely on existing LEA staff for thepersonnel with which they will replace such staff if they win acontract.

Other participants in the market are firms which have lengthyhistories in other economic sectors, and which have developededucation service branches in response to government encour-agement: for example, Arthur Andersen andPriceWaterhouseCoopers, both accountancy and managementconsultancy specialists; Group 4, security services and privateprisons specialists; W.S. Atkins, an earlier spin-off of commer-cialised local government building and other services. Serco,experienced in missile warning systems, private prisons andyoung offenders’ institutions, acquired QAA, a school inspectionfirm, in late 2000. Amey Roadstone, primarily a highwaysconstruction corporation, has linked up with Nord-Anglia, aspecialist education firm.19 These companies all have prior wide-spread experience of and success in how to win governmentcontracts of various kinds. They have highly developed lobbyingresources in Whitehall and Westminster and extensive contactswithin government. It is these attributes which have given themtheir past success in winning government contracts, and whichhave encouraged them to enter the new sector of commercialisedpublic education services, the substantive business of which isquite new to them. This is arguably the only added value whichthey bring to the education system. It is the value of theWhitehall insider, a value which is relevant to the delivery of

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 52

The case of education

53

education only because Government has decided to contract out;it is therefore not a quality which constitutes a reason forcontracting-out in the first place or which delivers anything tothe ultimate consumer of the services.

The risks inherent in this system of privileged contract insiderswill multiply as the model spreads out to individual schools. AsLEAs are weakened so that they cannot authoritatively monitorwhat is going on in schools’ contracting activities, there are virtu-ally no checks on how contract relations will be managedbetween highly skilled corporate lobbyists and voluntarygoverning bodies.

At the heart of the problem is the fact that these new educationmarkets are being fashioned by government in response to firms’requests that they be created. It is not the case that an unsatisfieddemand exists to which firms are responding; the demand isshaped to suit what the suppliers want to do, not whatconsumers want to receive. We must again remember that it isgovernment, not the citizen-consumer, who is the customer inthe commercialised welfare state.

Conclusions: Democracy, authority, citizenshipIf a service is an attribute of citizenship, it is managed throughconcepts of rights, participation and democratic authority.Fundamental to the historical operation of the British educationsystem was the role of elected councillors wielding politicalauthority; LEAs administered an area’s schools under the formalauthority of councillors. Parents could in principle make repre-sentations to councillors about the quality of services or prob-lems they had with their children’s schools; and LEA staff wereable to take firm action on such issues as individual schools’admissions practices because they acted as public authorities.

In practice the system did not always work like that; unlessparents knew how to exercise pressure, the local political system

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 53

54

could easily slip into lethargy, and this may have been particu-larly likely to occur in one-party dominated areas with loweducational expectations – a situation that characterised manyLabour towns and cities. And unless there was dynamic profes-sional leadership, LEA staff could also be inactive. But theseweaknesses are open to reform; the mechanisms exist, they onlywant energetic stimulation. The mechanisms themselves have tobe stripped away as the public education service is redefined tobecome a commercial service like any other. So long as thespecial citizenship characteristics are recognised, commercialfirms are at a disadvantage in rivalling LEAs as providers. Thisis especially the case when virtually all the staff deployed by theprivate firms are former LEA staff; all that distinguishes themfrom their colleagues remaining in the public sector is that theylack the latter's public authority. If however most of the specialattributes of public service are defined away and its activitiestranslated into commercial terms, the balance shifts radically theother way; being outside the public sector is, by a trick of defini-tion, changed from being a disadvantage to an advantage.

Because the actual delivery of education in schools was untilrecently seen as the core business, initial commercialisation wasconcentrated on authority functions. This was paradoxical, as thenormal situation is for privatised industries to be monitored bypublic regulatory authorities. In education it has been the otherway round. When Ofsted was established in 1994, it differedfrom the existing HM Inspectorate of Schools in contracting outrather than maintaining its own staff. Initially over 80 per cent ofinspection teams were provided by the staff of LEA advisory andinspection services. However, many individuals discovered thatthey could earn more money by setting up inspection consultan-cies. Today, about 75 per cent of school inspections arecontracted out to private firms, in an ‘industry’ which wasalready worth around £118 million in 1997.20

Commercialisation or Citizenship

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 54

The case of education

55

When a private firm is invited to take over an LEA’s functionsbecause the authority is deemed to have ‘failed’, the administra-tion of education in that area ceases to be a matter for localdemocracy, and does not even become one for local consumers.Instead it becomes a contractual relationship between centralgovernment and a privileged provider. Even when services for a‘failing’ authority are provided by another LEA, the principle oflocal democratic accountability is broken. Within the ‘failed’ areathe new authority providing the services has the same status as aprivate contractor; it does the work as part of a market contract,not as an element of local democracy.

When an LEA enters a commercialisation arrangement volun-tarily, the situation might seem different: the private firms aremerely contractors, agents subject to the will of their principal,which remains the legally constituted local political authority.But the political context is one in which, as we have seen, centralgovernment clearly favours the agents over the principals.Further, the fact that the LEA staff on whom the politicalauthority depends for information and advice have been put intothe position of competitors with rather than watch-dogs overcontractors, combined with the long-term nature of the contracts,make difficult any effective control of agent by principal. Thesystem is too new for us to judge how extensively chains of sub-contracting will develop, but if they do the current situation onthe privatised railways demonstrates clearly how attempts bypublic authorities to regulate become caught in the labyrinth ofcontract law and inter-firm deals.

Now, the Government rarely speaks of commercial firms alone.LEAs are also invited to consider hiving off their services to reli-gious organisations, voluntary sector partners, or even to otherLEAs who may be able to offer a more efficient service.21 Schools,like hospitals, have increasingly come to depend on volunteerhelp to overcome the staff shortages caused by their inadequate

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 55

Commercialisation or Citizenship

56

budgets of the 1980s and 1990s. However, commercial firms havefar stronger incentives to push their role and win contracts thando voluntary organisations, especially as the efforts which a firmmakes to win a contract can be offset against taxation as anacceptable business expense. Far from encouraging a growth inthe role of the voluntary sector, commercialisation is likely todrive out its existing contribution. This has already happened inthe case of careers advice services privatised during the 1980s bythe Conservatives. At first charitable organisations bid for andwon some of the contracts to replace the public service here.Gradually most have dropped away, being replaced by profit-making firms.

The provision of services by one LEA to the population ofanother raises different issues. A providing LEA cannot act as ademocratically responsible local authority in the territory ofanother. As the Government’s provisions make clear, within thatterritory the new LEA takes the form of a company, operating acommercial contract; similarly when a school takes over a poorlyperforming neighbour. This becomes another way of redefiningthe public authority role of local government as no different fromcommercial activity. The same is true for voluntary bodies; theytake on the legal form of private contractors if they take on publiceducation contracts. Another example is Connexions, the bodyestablished in 2001 to take over all supervision of the nationalcareers advice service for young people, and various special serv-ices to young people with certain problems. Its local branches,which provide services for groups of local authority areas, areestablished as limited liability companies rather than as normalpublic-service organisations. The local units already remarkablyincorporate named private firms into their formal governancestructure. As this model grows, the normal mode of deliveringlocal education services becomes that of the privileged insidercommercial firm; the firm becomes the only acceptable form of

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 56

The case of education

57

organisation; and public service becomes an anomaly within itsown heartland.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 57

Commercialisation or Citizenship

58

3| Towards a redefinition of publicservice

Challenging the hegemony of the ideology of commerciali-sation will not be easy. As the previous chapters haveshown, this is not a problem of passing fashion or venal

politicians. Extremely powerful economic forces have gatheredaround the project of bringing potentially lucrative citizenshipservices fully into the market place. In doing so they are firststripping these services of those qualities which have been partof their special value but which cannot be squeezed into themarket mould. The final stage will be the presentation of theseservices like any other good in the market to individualconsumers, so that their egalitarian, redistributive and sharedcharacter becomes entirely lost. Once this has happened, thedemocratisation of citizenship and the achievement of a statewhich worked for all people and not just privileged elites, thegreat achievement of the second half of the 20th century, willhave been reversed.

The fight back against these threats has to present an alterna-tive reform agenda. While the caricature of British health andeducation services being presented by New Labour andConservatives alike as some kind of rigidified centralisedbureaucracy of uncaring incompetents is inaccurate, it is impor-tant to recognise weaknesses which appeared in their structure

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 58

Towards a redefinition of public service

59

and practice and which require addressing if a new publicservice model is to be constructed.

Redefining public service professionalismOne of the subtlest of the conflicts over the commercialisationwave of the past two decades has been that over professionalknowledge, and it is here that the key will be found to a genuinethird way, a true alternative to both bureaucratic centralism andcommercialisation. Two kinds of such knowledge are involved.First is the professionalism of public administration itself; secondis the professionalism of the knowledge-based activities deliv-ered by the services – primarily medicine and teaching, butextending more generally to other social-service occupations,and not just the professions as conventionally understood.

The former returns us to the Victorian concept that a healthycompetitive capitalism required a state that maintained the rulesthat regulated the market system, and was neutral in its relationsto individual business interests. This model was ideal for trans-formation into the administration demanded by the social demo-cratic welfare state: not in the pockets of business lobbies, anddedicated to the delivery of impartial and therefore universaland reasonably egalitarian services. However, these very quali-ties meant a public service that was aloof, remote, not adept atcommunication. It was elitist, as its professional competencerested on the assumption that a central administrative class coulddetermine the needs of the public without much interaction otherthan that provided by the formal parliamentary process. Much ofthe unfeeling centralism of public service which Blair and hiscolleagues blame entirely on the post-war Labour Governmentsis really a residue of a pre-democratic, monarchical state withwhich social democracy compromised and turned to itspurposes. To see what a social democratic public service is likeone should look, not to the UK but to Scandinavia, where social

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 59

Commercialisation or Citizenship

60

democratic governments had far longer to develop the conceptthan the few years of Labour government that the UK had beforethe 1980s. While the Swedish and other Nordic states certainlyembodied elitist and centralising ideas, they gradually devel-oped habits of openness and transparency considerablyexceeding anything found in the UK even today. They alsodeveloped models of decentralised provision and consumerchoice within the framework of public service as far back as the1970s. It is the weakness of social democratic influence on tradi-tional models of public service that has retarded sensitivity tocitizens’ needs in the British case, not the dominance of socialdemocracy over the market. It is therefore possible to seek solu-tions to problems of remoteness and lack of choice within theterms of the social democratic model.

There has in fact been no frontal assault on the centralised char-acter of British public service during New Labour’s reforms,partly because, as noted in the first chapter, the commercialisingand privatising state needs a centralised administration, thoughministers adversely compare an alleged lack of responsiveness topublic concerns of public service with an idealised image of acustomer-friendly private sector. When services are contractedout by a public authority to private firms, the ‘customer’ is notthe consumer but the public authority concerned. Any improvedservice to ultimate consumers provided by private contractorsoccurs because their government customer stipulates that itwants such an improvement. If citizens play a part in formu-lating that stipulation it is through the political process, not themarket; government becomes aware that the voters want moreresponsive services, and in theory demands that its privateservice suppliers provide them. But if government can respondto that pressure by seeking consumer-responsiveness fromprivate firms, it could if it so chose do the same – only moredirectly – by stipulating better service from public providers.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 60

Towards a redefinition of public service

61

Public administration and public services must become moreparticipative and consultative. We already have the rudiments ofsuch an approach; government needs only to turn its attention toenhancing these: for example, the practice, started by the LabourGovernments of the 1970s, but sustained in diluted form since, ofpublic participation exercises for local planning issues. Closelyrelated were the same Governments’ Community HealthCouncils, Conservative Governments’ extensions of the partici-pative scope and powers of school governing bodies and thecurrent New Deal for Communities initiative. These and similarventures could be considerably strengthened in power and deep-ened in scope. It is often objected that vociferous middle-classgroups take more than their share of attention at such forums.That argument makes a case for community-level work to raisethe participative potential of other groups and classes, not formoving back to non-participative centralism.

Also, however, one of the main desired outcomes of a consul-tative approach to administration and service delivery is theeffect it has on the ways in which public officials and profes-sionals tackle their tasks and engage in dialogue with the public.As they gradually learn to deal with public challenge anddemands for openness, they develop ways of working which cantake such challenges in their stride rather than treat them asthreats. Even if they acquire these skills initially in relations withonly some social groups, the change in style gradually spreads tobecome a new professional norm. From there it can be trans-ferred to become an essential part of professional training andqualification.

There is considerable potential in this path. But before exam-ining it further we must examine the other characteristic of manypublic services which is a strength in need of renewal, but whichcan clash with the demand for openness and consultation: theknowledge base on which professionalism rests. This has not

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 61

Commercialisation or Citizenship

62

figured prominently in recent conflict over services. While minis-ters and private contractors caricature many characteristics ofthose who work in public service, it is more difficult to ridiculetheir knowledge. Most voters would feel uneasy if ministers andmanaging directors without professional training decided thatthey could tell surgeons how to perform operations or teachershow to educate.

But a covert attack on knowledge has been taking place.Notoriously the internal market system imposed on the NHS bythe Conservative Government did involve medically unqualifiedmanagers challenging clinical judgement, as methods of workmeasurement imitated from the management of low-skilledfactory work were imposed on medical practice as part of cost-cutting drives. Strangely, given the generally superior profes-sional status claimed by medical practitioners against schoolteachers, education has managed to sustain the model of admin-istration by persons experienced within the profession moreeffectively. Further, as we saw in the previous chapter, so far theprivate firms moving into education are depending very heavilyon recruiting both administrative and teaching staff from thosetrained for the public profession. The undermining of existingstructures of schools and LEAs takes the form mainly of allega-tions that those practising the profession are not worthy of itsideals. Indeed, the establishment by the Government of theGeneral Teaching Council, modelled even in its name as ananalogy of the General Medical Council, has been an enormousboost to the concept of the teaching profession, as well as consti-tuting an element of the New Labour approach on which afurther reconstruction of the profession could constructivelybuild.

Also useful is the fact that the insertion of strictly commercial,profit-making structures into British education is an oddity evenin the private sector. The elite parts of the historical private sector

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 62

Towards a redefinition of public service

63

of schools have always had charitable status; only a questionablefringe has taken pure commercial form. Whatever one thinksabout the entitlement of fee-paying schools to be regarded as‘charities’, this fact does indicate deeply held beliefs that there issomething anomalous about seeking to mix the profession withpure commercialism.

Disquiet at commercialisation and continuing recognition ofthe distinction between activities for profit and not for profitstrongly suggest that a defence of public services based onrespect for their knowledge is entirely feasible. There arehowever two major obstacles to advance on this front: first, muchof the agenda for public service reform requires the underminingof professional responsibility. Second, although successivegovernments can be fairly blamed for destroying professionalmorale, the professions should not automatically be trusted todevelop an appropriate new approach provided only thatgovernment would leave them alone. These problems merit closeconsideration.

The problem of government underminingThe Government has recently realised that the constant attacks ofitself and its Conservative predecessors against the public serviceprofessions has had negative effects, not only on recruitment tothe occupations concerned, but also by creating a mood of cyni-cism, which naturally reduced commitment to reform. As theGovernment’s education adviser, Michael Barber, has neatlyexpressed the point, since the 1970s education services hadmoved from a position of guidance by uninformed professionaljudgement, through one of uninformed national prescriptionduring the 1980s, to one of informed national prescription duringthe 1990s.22 What was needed for the new century was a patternof informed professional judgement replacing the nationalprescription. In similar spirit, the Prime Minister has spoken in

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 63

Commercialisation or Citizenship

64

his Fabian pamphlet, The Courage of Our Convictions, of the needfor high-quality, high-morale services.23 As he made clear, theGovernment also sees that loosening the grip of central bureau-cracy on the professions is fundamental to improving theirmorale. But the same pamphlet also demonstrates the dichoto-mous way in which he regards this issue: centralisation andneglect of the consumer is the product of the post-war OldLabour model of uniform public services; and decentralisedcustomer friendliness is an essential attribute of private firms.This enables ministers to present the introduction of privatecontractors as an automatic resolution of the problems of neglectof ‘customers’, and to ignore the contribution to centralisationand low morale being made by the proliferation of centralimposed targets and evaluations that is fundamental to their ownGovernment’s approach.

As Onora O’Neill has remarked, while targets are justified by adeclared need to restore ‘trust’ in the public service professions,they do not seem to have any such effect; because, in general,politicians are less trusted than are the professions.24 A shift inthe system of guaranteeing the quality of services from profes-sions to politicians is a shift to a system less worthy of trust. Shealso shows how Government places contradictory targets onpublic services, enabling itself to claim that it is pursuing all thegoals, while pushing resolution of the problem on to the practi-tioners. In fact, it does this in its approach to the problem ofreconstituting professionalism itself. At one level ministersdeclare their commitment to the professions and to the ethic ofpublic service, while at another they intensify further thetargeting strategy and the commercialisation which underminethese same things.

A new reform strategy for public service must include achanged approach to assessment and measurement of actualperformance, away from the stock exchange model of indica-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 64

Towards a redefinition of public service

65

torism and towards professionalism. Performance assessment byprofessionals aims at whole service appraisal, using qualifiedexpert judgement to take account of how practitioners havebalanced conflicting goals. It is also capable of assessing finepoints and nuances and not just global targets. It certainly makesuse of check lists and explicit lists of criteria of judgement, andwill use quantitative measures where these derive directly andclearly from the activity concerned, but it is not entirelydependent on these. It was the kind of model that used to befollowed by HM Inspectorate of Schools (HMI), and is in fact stillpractised by that Inspectorate in its residual but important role.While evaluation reports of this kind are serious technical docu-ments, it is also possible to produce reduced versions of, say,reports on individual schools or hospital departments which areaccessible and comprehensible to a wider public. They probablydo not lend themselves easily to use in constructing leaguetables, but given the crudity and vulnerability to manipulationand misuse of that approach, this is no bad thing.

The problem with the HMI approach to evaluation is that it isexpensive, as it requires a large number of highly skilled profes-sionals capable of assessing the work of their peers. The impactof HMI was gradually weakened over decades as governmentscut back on it; schools would be inspected too rarely for follow-up and evaluation of measures taken to address weaknesses to beeffective. The current system of appraisal by numerical indica-tors dispenses with the need for a high quality of inspectors. Thishas been particularly helpful to the privatisation process. Privatefirms bid competitively for school inspection work because theycan employ for relatively low fees retired education personnel,including of course those who have been quietly ‘pensioned off’because of unsatisfactory performance as teachers.

But great gains would compensate for the cost of high-skilledinspection, as professionals were encouraged to turn their atten-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 65

Commercialisation or Citizenship

66

tion away from playing with targets. They would see the profes-sional model of working substantively and not just rhetoricallysupported by government. And they would see an approach toachieving high standards that emerges sui generis from thespecific characteristics of the public service professions them-selves, not off-the-shelf borrowing of inappropriate businessanalogies. This would be the right starting point for a rediscoveryof the concept of high professional standards, instilled initially intraining and sustained subsequently by truly professional moni-toring, inspecting and, where necessary, disciplining.

The problem of professional arrogance If head teachers, senior LEA staff, and teachers’ trade unions andprofessional associations are firm in their insistence on high-quality performance, those seeking to undermine the system willhave little justification for external intervention. If they are slackand indulgent of weakness and poor performance, they destroythe principal ground on which they stand. This is a responsibilitywhich every individual working in the system can assume forthemselves, but a special burden rests with the wide range ofrelevant associations and unions. It is not in the interests ofteachers in general if their representative bodies protect poor-quality practice or seek to reduce pressures for high perform-ance. If we reject attempts to improve quality bypayment-by-results schemes, there is an obligation to developother, truly professional means of quality improvement.

Those involved in managing professional associations andtraining programmes must avoid an opposition-mindedness thatmeans they reject all government policies for improvement justbecause they emanate from government. It must be fully recog-nised that many initiatives by successive governments of the past20 years have contributed to a better education service: estab-lishment of a National Curriculum, more intensive inspectorial

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 66

Towards a redefinition of public service

67

work, the assertion of high standards of teaching and educationalperformance as a major national concern.

We need professions that are open, committed to dialogue andpublic participation, but proud of their special knowledge. Thereare clear tensions here. Can these really be reconciled? The morethat a profession insists on its integrity and capacity for self-disci-pline, the more it is likely to protect its mystique. Conservativemembers of the professions would probably claim that much oftheir recent trouble results from their increased openness inrecent years, their willingness to accept political, media andpublic scrutiny. The temptation to resolve this dilemma byrunning in either direction is strong. In one direction one pullsup the drawbridge again and reasserts the inscrutable characterof the profession’s knowledge, warding off all who seek to pry.The alternative extreme response is to try to duck below theparapet: to drop all claims to being anything special, to deny thatthe activity has any knowledge of particular importance. Thiswas how many in teaching, at all levels – but never medicine –responded to the first stress of demands for scrutiny and open-ness in the 1970s. It was accompanied by the challenge ofcomprehensive education, which for the first time raised publicand political expectations for the educational achievements of allchildren. Today, in a period when New Labour is toying withways of restoring selective education, it is hard to recall how,while the old 11 plus system dominated, there was little concernfor the educational performance of the bottom 65-70 per cent ofthe age range who went to secondary modern schools, few ofwhom took any measurable performance tests for the rest of theirschool careers. Or rather, all concern that was expressed took theform of the campaign to end selection. Obviously, mere changeof the system did not solve the problems of educating all thesechildren in a different way. There was considerable uncertainty,and many members of the teaching profession – which had in

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 67

Commercialisation or Citizenship

68

any case expanded massively, often with inadequate training –responded to the challenges and the new level of public concernby scaling down the claims that could be made for the educa-tional process. Curricula became undemanding, and whileteachers were often right to make education child-centred in thesense of meeting the children where they were, they often thensimply stayed there, doing little to create challenging aspirations.Far from insisting on its mystique, teaching seemed to want todeconstruct itself. The political reaction against this continuestoday.

The dilemma between an open and consultative approach onone hand and the cultivation of a high level of professionalism onthe other seems difficult, but running in either direction at theexpense of the other will be disastrous. Fortunately, this is one ofthose rare issues where, with imagination and willingness toadjust, the best of both worlds can be had: an assured and confi-dent insistence on professional competence can combine with awillingness to share special knowledge with clients, the generalpublic and the political world. This is achieved surprisinglyfrequently. For example, many a primary school head teacherhas learned how to talk openly and in detail about her work tomeetings of governors and of parents without feeling that thiscompromises her possession of special knowledge and under-standing, but also without needing to pretend that her knowl-edge and understanding are worthless. To take a differentprofession, medical practitioners are today likely to be willing totell a patient that he has a terminal cancer, and to discuss openlywith him the prognosis and helpful measures that they will taketogether to make things easier. In earlier times they hid behind awall of professional secrecy which served to spare them the needto engage in painful dialogue with a fellow human being.

If earlier generations of professional practitioners hid behindtheir mystique, it was partly because their knowledge base did

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 68

Towards a redefinition of public service

69

not live up to their claims. Until the late 19th century medicinereally had little to offer many of its patients. Teachers until aneven later date were largely ignorant of the psychology and soci-ology of the education process. Their early 21st century succes-sors have no need for such defensiveness. Their knowledge baseand set of competences will not be laid waste in the course offrank and open-hearted exchanges with clients, or discussions inparent-teacher and doctor-patient committees.

The revival of local governmentHistorically Labour has been the most consistently centralisingparty in the British state, through all its shifts between right andleft. It used to identify local government with entrenchedsquirearchies and urban bourgeois elites, and worried that localpower meant an inability to redistribute resources from richer topoorer geographical areas. During the long years of the highlycentralist Thatcher Government it really seemed that Labour,reduced to its urban strongholds, had discovered the politicalvalue of local government. This was one of the few things thatunited the urban left, struggling against deindustrialisation andthe dismantling of the welfare state, with New Labour, seekingnew radical themes that would cut associations with the state-centralising tendencies of the old Labour Party.25 Devolution toScotland, Wales and Northern Ireland, enhanced English region-alism, and anti-centralising constitutional reforms were funda-mental to the 1997 package. In reality, once the formalcommitments to the Celtic nations had been honoured, NewLabour showed itself to be as centralising as either Thatcherismor Bevanism. In the Introduction we examined reasons why thishas been a paradoxical part of the commercialisation agendaitself.

There are virtuous or vicious spirals at work here. In thevirtuous spiral, local levels of government assert strength and

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 69

Commercialisation or Citizenship

70

achieve high standards because they can attract both politiciansand professional staff of high calibre, and be equipped with theresources they need to provide a high-class service. They canattract such staff because a sympathetic central government iswilling to engage in a major and serious decentralisation ofcompetences and control over resources to prominent, wellestablished multi-purpose authorities. In such a way, bringingthe administration of many elements of the health service withingeneral local government would both increase its democraticaccountability and enhance the status of local government. Fortoo long the UK has been in precisely the reverse, vicious spiral,as stripping local government of powers has reinforced and beenreinforced by a decline in the quality of its personnel. The needsof the commercialisation agenda for even more centralisation areadding further, eventually fatal, twists to the vicious spiral.

In persuading government to shift to the virtuous spiral, onecan point to positive aspects of recent developments in bench-marking, auditing and the targeting of achievements. Althoughmuch has been said above about the negative consequences ofexcessive targeting, a more restrained and finely judged use ofthese devices can make possible a model of maximum decentral-isation accompanied by truly professional evaluation and inspec-tion to ensure that standards are maintained and a stable, limitednumber of major central policy goals met. The local and nationalprominence given today to such things as the inspection of localeducation authorities and schools’ achievements do at least showthat there can be a lively local democracy around movements forimproved standards. At present these devices have been accom-panied by rather than substituted for increasing centralisedcontrol. More logical and positively challenging to morale andcompetence would be a high level of scrutiny accompanyingradically increased autonomy – and the autonomy needs to beprofessional and concerned with actual service delivery, not just

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 70

Towards a redefinition of public service

71

the ambiguous autonomy of financial responsibility. Suchautonomy should indeed include the right to contract out non-core services if authorities so wish – provided one could haveconfidence that central government and its monitoring agencieswould be willing to take a neutral view of the performance ofsuch services.

RecommendationsFrom the above discussion flow a number of practical proposalsfor a strategy of modernising public services in a manner whichis compatible with the concept of the welfare state as a funda-mental component of social citizenship. To the extent that the‘problem’ of the welfare state is seen as one of the quality of serv-ices provided to citizens, there is no reason why these proposalsshould not be acceptable within a New Labour agenda. It is onlyif the main concerns of that agenda are a determination toprovide new profitable areas for private firms ahead ofimproving services to citizens, or to shift the burden of costs ofpublic services from collective provision to the individual user,that there is any incompatibility with these proposals.

First come a number of measures which are needed to clarifythe role of both citizenship and the market (as well as other formsof commercialisation) within the public services. The measuresare needed, not just to protect citizenship rights from beingundermined by commercialisation, but to protect the marketfrom corruption in this unavoidably politicised arena.

� While there is certainly a role for private suppliers ofmarginal and ancillary aspects of public services, extremecare must be taken about such involvement in the core busi-ness of citizenship services, since removing core businessfrom the realm of citizenship and placing it within themarket constitutes a major derogation of citizenship entitle-

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 71

Commercialisation or Citizenship

72

ment. Avoidance of distortion and residualisation must beregarded as part of the definition of high standards and effi-ciency in the delivery of services. The next step of policydevelopment must be to debate and then to define the citi-zenship core, which must then be ring-fenced from commer-cialisation.

� The importance of direct political access by citizens to issuesof service quality must be strengthened in services consid-ered essential to citizenship rights. Achieving this goal willmean maximal devolution to lower levels of government forservice delivery and minimal contracting out to privatesuppliers. Since commercialisation gives true customerstatus only to government as the principal in contractingout, it is not a response to problems of remoteness from citi-zens. Far more logical would be determined attempts toimprove the citizenship quality of public services throughmeasures for increased decentralisation and participation.

� Lobbying by private firms for the award of contracts to runpublic services in the non-core areas where they should beexpected to remain active, must be subject to strict, inde-pendent and open scrutiny. If there are to be markets, theymust be as close as possible to true markets, and not thosecorrupted by clientelistic links and cronyism. This requiresthe establishment of new monitoring procedures at bothcentral and local government levels. The only way to ensurehigh standards is to make it illegal for any firm which makesdonations of a political nature, or seconds staff to ministriesor think tanks, to be allowed to bid for public contracts.Furthermore, in the interests of providing a level playingfield among competing firms and avoiding insiderlobbying, all policy planning concerning the entry of private

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 72

Towards a redefinition of public service

73

firms into public service contracts should be carried out inconsultation with associations representing the firms in therelevant sector, not with individual enterprises.

Next comes the need to restructure the place of the publicservice professions. As with the relationship between citizenshipand the market, the needs here are two-edged. The morale ofthese professions has been desperately undermined by attacks bysuccessive governments on the public services and their funding,as well as by government determination to bring in commercialcriteria. At the same time, however, some traditional approachesof the professions to their clients need to be changed if the aimsof citizenship services are genuinely to be realised.

� There must be a revitalisation of the concept of professionalresponsibility within public service, extending through theknowledge-based services, administration itself, and allother occupations involved in public-service delivery.Government at all levels, professional institutions, andthose responsible for training and management share anobligation to work on this.

� New concepts of professional knowledge and skill mustinclude capacity for open communication and dialogue withservice users and citizens in general as fundamental compo-nents. These principles must be fundamentally embeddedin training, management and evaluation activities.

� Reinvigorated professional models of evaluating serviceperformance and dealing with poor performance mustreplace excessive and overly politicised reliance on bench-marking and targeting. But monitoring and auditing ofperformance remain fundamental.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 73

Commercialisation or Citizenship

74

Confident, communicative openness based on constantlyimproving skills, alongside centrally monitored local democracy,must be the hallmarks of a new public service. These needsextend to the profession of administration itself, which mustlearn to regard a capacity to engage in public consultation andparticipation as part of its skill, rather than as an occasionalnightmare to be avoided as much as possible. Trainingprogrammes and management systems for all groups whodeliver citizenship services need to instil and enforce capacity forand pride in both expertise and two-way communication. Theseattributes can be pitted against the greater need for secrecy thatwill always characterise the commercial sector because of firms’needs to protect their business practices from imitation bycompetitors. The more that the model of open, consultative,authoritatively monitored professionalism in public services is areality in the lives of citizens, the more likely it is that the citi-zenship welfare state, far from creeping from the historical stage,may yet experience its finest hours.

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 74

75

References

1. Series of articles on the Private Finance Initiative in the NHS, A

Pollock et al, British Medical Journal, 1999

2. Social Change in Western Europe, C Crouch, Oxford Univeristy

Press, 1999

3. Sociology at the Crossroads and Other Essays, T H Marshall, RKP,

1963

4. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,

Organizations, and States A Hirschman, Harvard University

Press, 2001

5. The Gift Relationship: from Human Blood to Social Policy, R M

Titmuss, Allen & Unwin, 1970

6. ‘The Marketization of Public Services’ by M R Freedland,

Citizenship, Markets and the State, C Crouch, K Eder and D

Tambini (ed), Clarendon Press, 2001

7. No Logo: No Space, No Choice, No Jobs, Taking Aim at the

Brand Bullies, N Klein, Flamingo, 2000

8. ‘Where the Third Way goes from Here: renewing progressive

politics’ by Tony Blair in Progressive Politics, 2003

9. ‘Called to Account’, O O’Neill, Lecture no 3 in ‘A Question of

Trust’, the BBC Reith Lectures, 2002.

10. ‘Against Privatizing Schools in the UK’ by H Brighouse, London

Review of Education, 2003

11. ‘The Price of Funny Money’ by L Dalton in What’s It All About?,

Secondary Heads Association, 2002

12 Times Educational Supplement 19 November 1999

13. ‘The Changing Role of the LEA’, Department for Education and

Skills, 2001

14. ibid.

15. Learning and Skills Act, 2000

16. Times Educational Supplement 19 November 1999

17. ‘Schools under New Labour – Getting down to Business’ Paper

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 75

Commercialisation or Citizenship

76

presented by R Hatcher at ‘Privatisierung des Bildungsbereichs’,

University of Hamburg.

18. Times Educational Supplement 13 July 2001

19. Times Educational Supplement 25 May 2001

20. Times Educational Supplement 19 December 1997

21. Letter from Secretary of State to CEOs explaining her new

‘brokerage’ concept of LEAs, 6 July 2001

22. ‘Large-Scale Education Reform in England: A Work in Progress’

by M Barber, School Development Conference, Tart University,

Estonia, 2001

23. The Courage of Our Convictions, T Blair, Fabian Society, 2002

24. ‘Called to Account’, O O’Neill, Lecture no 3 in ‘A Question of

Trust’, the BBC Reith Lectures, 2002.

25. European Cities: Social Conflicts and Governance, P Le Galès,

Oxford University Press, 2002

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 76

Other Fabian Society Publications

Coping with Post-democracyColin Crouch

‘In this stimulating pamphlet, Professor Colin Crouch makes linksbetween the decline of the state and the waning of democraticenthusiasm. When so much of the public sector has been handed overto private operators, Crouch argues, what becomes of the image ofgovernment as a task that matters? If every public function is tested byits conformity with private-sector management goals, why shouldanyone get excited about choosing between parties? If government isroutinely seen as incompetent, and the company as the only source ofexpertise, no wonder politics and democracy, in America if not yet here,are at an all-time low. This is a fate that Labour, not so long ago, wouldhave been desperate to avoid. At some stage, the Labour Party mayhave to confront the lacuna that has been created on the left.’Hugo Young, The Guardian

Colin Crouch is Professor of Sociology at the European UniversityInstitute, Florence, and External Scientific member of the Max PlanckInstitute for Society Research, Cologne

December 2000 ISBN 07163 0598 4 £6.95

Email [email protected] or call 020 7227 4900

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 77

Other Fabian Society Publications

The Courage of Our ConvictionsWhy reform of the public services is the route to socialjustice

Tony Blair

In this Fabian pamphlet the Prime Minster sets out the arguments forpublic service reform and warns that unless this is done successfully tax-funded public services could be lost altogether.

Tony Blair argues that public services are crucial to Labour’s goal ofsocial justice. Acknowledging that tension exists between national auditsand inspections and local autonomy, Blair argues that this can beovercome and sets out his four principles of reform: national standards,devolved power, professionalism and choice.

December 2002 ISBN 07163 0603 4 £6.95

Email [email protected] or call 020 7227 4900

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 78

Other Fabian Society Publications

Paying for ProgressA New Politics of Tax for Public Spending

The Commission on Taxation and Citizenship

Taxation—and the public spending it pays for—is the subject of thefiercest political controversy. Paying for Progress: A New Politics of Taxfor Public Spending offers a compelling new approach.

Reporting new research into public attitudes towards taxation, Paying forProgress argues that the public must be ‘reconnected’ to the taxes theypay and the public services which these finance. To do this it proposesthe greater use of ‘earmarked’ taxes, including a new tax to fund theNational Health Service. Setting out a new philosophy of citzenship tounderpin taxation policy, it recommends a series of reforms to meet thegoals of social inclusion and environmental protection.

Written in a lively and accessible style, Paying for Progress makes animportant contribution to political thought and policy in the first decadeof the 21st century. Providing key information on the UK tax system, itwill also be an invaluable text for students and researchers in politics,economics, public administration, law and accountancy.

‘Coherent, radical and lucid... this important book raises criticalquestions for the future of British politics’Will Hutton, Chief Executive, the Industrial Society

‘The clarity with which it explores the facts and arguments about the taxsystem make it an extremely valuable text for students and researchers.It will provide a benchmark for future work on taxation reform’Andrew Gamble, Professor of Politics, University of Sheffield

November 2000 ISBN 07163 6003 9 £9.95

Email [email protected] or call 020 7227 4900

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 79

Get ahead of Labour’s thinking — jointhe Fabian Society now for just £8.95

Members receive:

� 3 issues of our highly regarded magazine, Fabian Review

� 2 pamphlets on key political and policy ideas

� Advance notice of our headline political conferences

� Access to a nationwide network of over 70 local Fabian groups

For a membership form please ring 020 7227 4900 oremail [email protected]

‘The Fabians perform the vital function of thinking beyond the current

news agenda – and beyond current government orthodoxy. Whether it’s

on tax, public services, globalisation or the environment, they are never

afraid to ask difficult questions.’

Polly Toynbee, The Guardian

‘I am constantly impressed by the quality of the Fabians’ conferences and

meetings. The Society provides a unique forum for real people to debate

real ideas – the lifeblood of a political movement.’

Will Hutton, The Work Foundation

‘The Fabians provide a vital space for debate between pressure groups

and their members, the wider public, and political parties and

government. It’s a critical role for democracy.’

Stephen Tindale, Greenpeace UK

body.qxd 02/05/2003 12:07 Page 80

FABIA

N SO

CIETY

Com

mercia

lisatio

n o

r Citize

nsh

ipC

olin Crouch

Fabian ideas 606

Commercialisation or CitizenshipEEdduuccaattiioonn ppoolliiccyy aanndd tthhee ffuuttuurree ooff ppuubblliicc sseerrvviicceess

Colin Crouch

Commercialisation orCitizenshipEEdduuccaattiioonn ppoolliiccyy aanndd tthheeffuuttuurree ooff ppuubblliicc sseerrvviicceessColin Crouch

Fabian ideas 606

Fabian ideas 606

ISBN 0 7163 0606 9ISSN 1469 0136

£6.95

So far the argument over the role of private firms in the provision of publicservices has mainly been waged in terms of efficiency. Those in favour ofgreater involvement have focused on the improvements to service quality andthe cost-effectiveness offered by private sector providers; those opposed havequestioned the truth of these claims. Yet there is another debate about theimplications of private involvement for the character of public services whichdeserves attention.

In Commercialisation or Citizenship Colin Crouch looks at how this use of pri-vate business in public services changes the character of the services deliveredand the notions of citizenship which underpin them. He argues that publicservices were designed to provide entitlements or rights – to education, healthand social care – and that they did this through an equitable allocation ofresources on a universal basis. The role now being given to private business inthis field does not simply ignore this foundation, it actively undermines it.

Using education as his example, Crouch gives a comprehensive analysis ofprivate sector involvement showing how this threatens the citizenship basis ofeducation. He then offers a number of practical proposals for a strategy ofmodernising public services in a manner which is compatible with the conceptof the welfare state as a fundamental component of social citizenship.

Colin Crouch is Professor of Sociology at the European University Institute,Florence, and External Scientific member of the Max Planck Institute for SocietyResearch, Cologne. He is Chair of the editorial board of the PoliticalQuarterly, of which he was previously joint editor. His recent books includeIndustrial Relations and European State Traditions (1993), Are Skills theAnswer? (with David Finegold and Mari Sako, 1999), Social Change inWestern Europe (1999) and Coping with Post-Democracy (2000).

cover.qxd 12/03/2003 17:44 Page 1