Cities Theory Crash Course

38
Urban Economics Crash Course By Charles-Albert Ramsay Dawson College Economics Department Westmount, Qc. © 2012 The following lecture notes explain why cities exist, and why most of our economic activity is linked to city work. The lectures are based on a shortlist of seminal texts from Alfred Marshall, and Jane Jacobs. The lectures do not cover an exhaustive review of urban economics literature, and they are not a complete course in Urban Economics. These lectures were presented as a subtopic in the course Advanced Studies in Economics (Fall 2012). Diagrams and Summary Tables were created by the author as pedagogical tools for the student. Any errors are my sole responsibility. Contents 1. Agglomeration Economies ....................................................................................................... 2 2. Hub Cities and Transport Costs ............................................................................................... 6 3. Jacobs’ Urban Economics ...................................................................................................... 10 4. City Instabilities ..................................................................................................................... 15 5. Jacobs’ Spectrum of Regions ................................................................................................. 20 6. Innovation in Jacobs’ Agglomerations ................................................................................... 29 7. Appendices ............................................................................................................................. 32

description

This is a group of lectures on urban economic topics

Transcript of Cities Theory Crash Course

Page 1: Cities Theory Crash Course

Urban Economics Crash Course

By Charles-Albert Ramsay

Dawson College

Economics Department

Westmount, Qc.

© 2012

The following lecture notes explain why cities exist, and why

most of our economic activity is linked to city work.

The lectures are based on a shortlist of seminal texts from Alfred

Marshall, and Jane Jacobs.

The lectures do not cover an exhaustive review of urban

economics literature, and they are not a complete course in

Urban Economics. These lectures were presented as a subtopic

in the course Advanced Studies in Economics (Fall 2012).

Diagrams and Summary Tables were created by the author as

pedagogical tools for the student. Any errors are my sole

responsibility.

Contents 1. Agglomeration Economies ....................................................................................................... 2

2. Hub Cities and Transport Costs ............................................................................................... 6

3. Jacobs’ Urban Economics ...................................................................................................... 10

4. City Instabilities ..................................................................................................................... 15

5. Jacobs’ Spectrum of Regions ................................................................................................. 20

6. Innovation in Jacobs’ Agglomerations ................................................................................... 29

7. Appendices ............................................................................................................................. 32

Page 2: Cities Theory Crash Course

1. Agglomeration Economies

- Why Should I Care?

Production tends to locate in cities, which are an inescapable reality of

economic life since their inception 10,000 years ago. This leads to

many problems such as pollution, and traffic. Understanding how

cities work helps understand everything else.

- This Lecture Has 2 Parts

Economies of Agglomeration

Problems Created by Cities

- What are Agglomeration Economies?

Producers can save money by locating in the same area as other

companies. This is similar to economies of scale, but in this case the

companies don’t necessarily produce more.

Economies of Agglomeration

Alfred Marshall (1920) proposed three reasons why producers can

save money when locating their plants near those of other companies.

A) Shared pool of labour

B) Input sharing

C) Knowledge spillovers

These three reasons are still used today to explain why cities exist.

The first reason has to do with the lower cost of acquiring labour in

the city, where companies can “share” labour. For example, aerospace

companies would benefit from being in Montreal because the city

already hires many specialists in this field. The city will probably train

more people in this field, so it will be possible to hire young recruits,

or even poach some older workers from competitors.

Second, producers would benefit from a larger market for raw

materials. Since Montreal produces airplanes, it is easy to find inputs

such as aluminium and specialized electronics in Montreal. This

attracts even more aerospace companies. Cities often offer a hub of

transportation networks, ports, airports, highways, which reduce the

transportation costs of inputs and outputs.

Third, producers can learn from one another in the city. Some

companies really do not want this, as their need for secrecy is

important. They would rather isolate themselves. Most companies

Page 3: Cities Theory Crash Course

would probably benefit from this. These knowledge spillovers happen

in many ways, by hiring an employee from a competitor, by having

access to local experts and scientists, through specialized local media,

or by word-of-mouth.

These three advantages create “economies of scale” which can be

beneficial to even small organizations that don’t have a large scale of

production. It allows small companies to reduce their costs as if they

were a big company.

Cities have taken this ball and have run with it. Today, most people on

earth live in large cities. Economies are wealthier and more urban than

ever. Urban economies are also more innovative. In Quebec, three

quarters of patent activity is attributed to the Greater Montreal area,

which only represents half of Quebec’s population.

What can non-urban economies do? It seems they have had to focus

on offering low-cost inputs such as labour, or natural resources. When

so endowed, think of potash in Saskatchewan, or cheap labour in

China, these may prosper. However, their lack of diversity will leave

these economies vulnerable to foreign demand shocks.

Problems Created by Cities

Cities also create many problems. Successful cities grow sometimes

uncontrollably, creating havoc for its citizens. Traffic, pollution, and

crime, are just some of the problems that can become unbearable in

large cities.

Scarcity of food, and energy, are also major problems. Montreal could

probably never be able to produce all the food Montrealers need to eat

and thrive. And once all the wood on the island has been cut to build

houses, where will the energy come from to heat them for the next

decades and centuries?

One solution cities come up with is to import materials, food, and

other products, from the hinterland, and other cities, to satisfy its

wants and needs. This builds the economy of neighboring regions.

Another solution cities are likely to use is to invent new ways of

dealing with its problems. Cities have (probably) invented things like:

Corn, a more productive food plant.

Tractors, a more productive earth moving technology.

Sewers and Aqueducts, more effective water management.

Electricity, a cleaner and more convenient energy source.

Cars, Trains, Planes: faster, cleaner, and more productive than

horse and buggy.

Page 4: Cities Theory Crash Course

Many authors such as Jacobs (1969) argue that a city’s ability to

invent, and innovate, and solve urban problems is the key to constant

economic development and growth. What helps a city solve problems?

There is no one answer to this. Diverse and inventive cities have been

dubbed Jacobs’ agglomerations. Jacobs believes cities should try to

master all the elements of the urban ecology, which are:

Good markets, the right kind of urban planning, strong science, a

propensity to reinvest profits, a propensity to invest productively, a

diverse industrial base, openness to new ideas, and the ability to

reverse-engineer key imports.

Cities can constantly create new problems, which can be salutary in

the sense that these problems create opportunities to generate new

solutions. These new solutions can spur new industries and fuel

economic development and growth.

However, cities can become vulnerable to these problems and fail.

Many, many, cities have fallen in history due to inadequate economic

growth and crushing social problems such as pollution and crime.

- Think Piece

Think of one thing you love about city life, and one thing you despise.

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

- Wrap-Up

Cities exist because of three advantages they bring together, which

rural locations cannot offer, these create savings for companies, that

we call economies of agglomeration.

Marshall (1920) identified these three advantages as being a shared

labour pool, a shared pool of other inputs such as materials and

specialized services, and knowledge spillovers between firms.

Cities also create problems which can become opportunities for future

growth. Cities have invented technologies such as corn and electricity,

which have solved important urban problems such as scarcity of food

and energy.

To be innovative, cities should favour a mix of economic and political

factors. Cities often fail when problems are left unsolved.

Page 5: Cities Theory Crash Course

- Cheat Sheet with Memory Helper

Economic Agglomeration: A place where producers locate next

to each other, even with competitors.

Agglomeration Economies: Three advantages that cities can offer

companies to reduce their costs.

- References and Further Reading

Jacobs, J. (1969). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of Economics. London: MacMillan.

Page 6: Cities Theory Crash Course

2. Hub Cities and Transport Costs

- Why Should I Care?

- This Lecture Has 2 Parts

Transport Costs

a. Theory

Criticism

- What is a Hub City?

Cities are usually transportation hubs. Places where boats and trucks,

meet planes and any other mode of transportation. Producers who

locate near these hubs reduce transportation costs, as long as

congestion is not too important.

Transport Costs

Jacobs (1970) argues that cities, being where the consumer market is,

are natural locations for producers. However, cities can become

congested, which seems inefficient for producers who leave to lower

density locations.

Jacobs argues the issue is more complex than this. She argues that

cities also reduce the transport costs of inputs to production. Inputs

are diverse, and may need to be imported from a variety of locations.

Being centrally located, and endowed of transportation hubs, cities

reduce the overall transportation cost of gathering these inputs.

The key to understanding what this means is to consider the diversity

and variety of inputs that go into the production of even simple

products.

Page 7: Cities Theory Crash Course

a. Input Location-Transport Cost Theory

Definitions

a. Four resources are located in isolated regions.

b. The resources are used to produce 1 product.

c. The four regions are equidistant from each other.

d. Roads link the four regions together in all directions.

e. The manufacturer must produce in 1 location only.

Assumptions

a. The manufacturer prefers to reduce all transportation costs.

b. There are no tax breaks at any locations.

c. The roads are flat, and uncongested.

Predictions

a. Manufacturing will locate at E (hub location).

Interpretation

Imagine a simple economy where 1 good is produced, such as an

office chair. The product is made with four inputs. Each input is

located in a different region. Wood is in the North. Plastic wheels are

in the South. Labour is West. Leather is East.

If there are six roads (straight lines) that link these regions, the hub of

those regions will naturally be chosen as the manufacturing and

assembly site, as it reduces the overall transportation costs of the

inputs. The manufacturer has to locate next to a road. There are thus

five possible locations (A, B, C, D, and E).

Assuming the transport costs are equivalent between the inputs, the

cheapest production location is E.

Input Location-Transport Cost Diagram

Wood

Leather Labour

Wheels

A

B

C

D

E

Page 8: Cities Theory Crash Course

Criticism

You may object that companies must also consider the transportation

costs of the final good to the market.

In this case most of the chairs would be sent West, and some to the

other three regions. The final location decision might be E, or

somewhere between C and E.

You may also object that a company would not locate in an

unpopulated area. This is reasonable.

However, as E becomes the natural location of production, labour will

migrate to E, and a settlement will form. We can postulate that other

manufacturing activities would also migrate to E because of

agglomeration economies discussed earlier. This would create a

positive feedback loop for the E location.

- In-Class Activity

Imagine you are the CEO of Bombardier, Inc. You wish to produce

medium-sized commercial airplanes. Consider the following elements

and their transport costs.

Aluminium (for wings) from Saguenay by Boat

Electronics (for navigation) from Britain by Boat

Landing Gear (wheels) from Montreal by Truck

Wood (for furniture) from Worldwide by Boat

Final Plane to New York City flown by client

Draw a map, and decide where in Quebec you would locate your

manufacturing plant, as you try to reduce the total transportation costs

of production and delivery?

Is there missing information you would need to make the best

decision?

- Think Piece

The transport cost model argues that big cities are actually cheaper

production locations than small cities because their “central” location

decreases transportation costs. Would you argue this argument

counters the higher costs associated to big city congestion and delays

in delivery?

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

Page 9: Cities Theory Crash Course

- Wrap-Up

Companies are always trying to reduce their production costs. Holding

labour, land, and capital costs constant, transportation costs are an

important factor in the location decision of producers.

All else equal, producers will choose to locate in the city, or region,

that minimizes their transportation costs. Jacobs argues that one must

consider the transportation costs of bringing inputs to the factory, and

the costs of distributing outputs to market.

According to Jacobs, cities do both. First, cities are central locations

relative to the diversity of natural and capital resources that are needed

for production. Cities also provide a local pool of labour. Second,

cities are markets in themselves for the products, so they also reduce

the distribution costs.

According to a simple model, the hub – even uninhabited and not

endowed of resources – will become the natural production location

because it reduces the overall transportation costs.

- References and Further Reading

Jacobs, J. (1970). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Page 10: Cities Theory Crash Course

3. Jacobs’ Urban Economics

- Why Should I Care?

Cities are the heart and lungs of the economic system. But they are

hard to understand because we don’t have specific data to analyse

their core economic functions. There is however a radical theory

which does help to understand cities, innovation, and prosperity.

- This Lecture Has 3 Parts

Import Replacement

Diversity Feedback

Measurement

- What is Jacobs’ Urban Economics?

After explaining how urban neighborhoods should be designed in her

landmark 1959 book The Death and Life of Great American Cities,

Jane Jacobs wrote a formal theory on how city economies work as a

system, in her next book, The Economy of Cities, published in 1969.

The theory holds on one key concept. A self-reinforcing feedback she

called the “import-replacement cycle”, which she has observed the

world over, and which she documents using historical examples.

Import Replacement

Jacobs refers to trade (exports and imports) between cities, as opposed

to most economists who refer to trade between nations.

In a nut-shell, the idea of import-replacement is quite simple. Instead

of consuming imports, city entrepreneurs will produce locally what

was once imported from another city or region.

Why do this?

Import replacements are usually better suited to the local market,

provide appreciated variety to consumers, reduce transport costs, and

are not subject to tariffs.

First, some imports may not be well-suited to the local market. For

example, American magazines are less appealing to Québécois readers

Page 11: Cities Theory Crash Course

for linguistic and cultural reasons. It is reasonable to see an

opportunity for a local magazine market in Quebec.

Second, consumers have a preference for variety in consumption.

Imports contribute to diversifying their basket of goods. Better yet, a

replaced import is often modified to suit local preferences. Consumers

now have more choices.

Third, imports may be overly expensive due to transport costs. For

example, Asian-built cars are more expensive in Canada than cars

built in Detroit, USA, or Oshawa, Ontario, because they need to be

shipped half way around the world.

Finally, import tariffs increase the price of foreign products. For

example, Canada imposes a tariff on European cars. Locals may find it

interesting to produce because consumers appreciate lower prices.

How does this work?

Before the import-replacement process begins, an economy must be

able to afford the imports in the first place. Jacobs argues most

forward cities had started as successful supply regions. The export

revenue generated the capital needed to import consumption goods.

Let’s run through a hypothetical example from a cattle supply region

we will call Cattaliana.

Cattle exports generate capital for Cattaliana economy

Wine imports are ordered and consumed in Cattaliana

Local cowboy breaks away from cattle ranch to launch winery

5% of the wine imports are replaced by local wine

Wine is “new work”, creates local jobs

Wine is sold locally at first.

Cattaliana starts to export wine to neighboring settlements

Wine exports generate capital for Cattaliana economy

Imports of shoes, umbrellas, and books are ordered

We see the cycle has the potential to be self-reinforcing. Local

entrepreneurs may copy the first “breakaway entrepreneur”, and start

to replace shoe imports with local production.

Of course, if local economic agents are content with their supply

region status, they may not engage in import-replacement.

Page 12: Cities Theory Crash Course

Diversity Feedback

It’s important to note that import-replacement automatically increases

the industrial diversity of the city. This has five positive effects on the

economy.

First, diversity of local production reduces costs for most producers

of old work. The city economy grows in scale, and scope. This means

there are more inputs available locally, more specialized tools,

machines, materials, knowledge, etc, which benefit producers in

general.

Second, workers are not the same. Each worker has individual

strengths, preferences, interests and training. A greater diversity of

local production therefore increases labour productivity by allowing

a better allocation of labour according to individual strengths.

Third, diversity of local production also increases innovation

opportunities, as different industries learn from each other. The

transmission of knowledge is more important when different

industries share the same banks, schools, and other specialized

services.

Fourth, the export revenue generated by import-replacement brings a

following of new and fresh imports. Remember that consumers prefer

variety. When sailing in far away places, shippers often pick up a wide

range of foreign goods which may find a market back home.

Thus, the new import wave will bring a variety of novel wares. This

means there can be a multiplier effect to import-replacement. As

export revenue grows, so does the quantity, and variety of imports.

Hence, the opportunities to replace these imports multiply with each

round of import-replacement.

Finally, industrial diversity reduces economic volatility. Industry

cycles are smoothed over as their relative weight within the local

system is reduced. A foreign demand shock for cattle in Cattaliana

won’t be as hard to take if the economy also produces wine and shoes.

Measurement

How can one observe the import-replacement phenomenon?

It is difficult. Ready-made available data for city economies is not the

first priority of government agencies such as Statistics Canada.

But there are three ways of doing it.

First, an anthropological-type study using fieldwork can be useful. By

travelling in the city, interviewing entrepreneurs and bankers, one will

Page 13: Cities Theory Crash Course

be able to identify new work activities, and try to link them to

previous imports.

The researcher will look for activity in the core, but also to see if any

workshops, or factories, have migrated to the city region, which

includes suburban residential areas, and the immediate hinterland of

the city.

Second, one may have access to Export-Import data from a statistical

agency that represents a metropolitan area. According to Jacobs’

theory, bursts in exports would precede increases in imports. Imports

would grow in both quantity and variety. These bursts in imports

would then be followed by bursts of new-work exports.

Exports and Imports would be constantly catching up, and passing,

each other, as both grow continuously. A trade deficit (X<M) would

be associated to slow growth overall. But this is not a bad thing as the

city recharges its batteries with fresh ideas from new imports.

A trade surplus (X>M) would be associated to a growth spurt, fuelled

by new work as old imports are replaced.

A third measurement of this phenomenon would be to break down

GDP figures by industry to try to see the apparition of new work in the

data. This is difficult as new work, which is truly innovative, is often

poorly categorised by statisticians, and lumped in to “other”

categories. Another difficulty is the absence of detailed industry

breakdowns for scarce “metropolitan” GDP data.

- In-Class Activity

Draw a 3-part flow chart depicting the evolution of contemporary

Chinese cities. Use the following elements.

Supply Region: Rice

Import replacement 1: Toys

Import replacement 2: Televisions

Import replacement 3: Automobiles

- Think Piece

What would David Ricardo say about this theory?

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

Page 14: Cities Theory Crash Course

- Wrap-Up

Economic growth according to Jacobs is due to the replacement of

imports as local production. This is added to old work, and generates a

positive feedback of economic prosperity and increased trade.

The cycle is directly related to trade with other regions and cities.

Jacobs believes a built-in correction mechanism leads to the inevitable

decline of cities, which opens up room for the rise of other cities.

Import-replacement automatically increases the industrial diversity of

the city. This has five positive effects on the economy.

The phenomenon is difficult to observe empirically. One must use

field work, interviews, or data mining (GDP and trade data), to verify

if this actually happens. City-states may have more relevant

macroeconomic data, than nation-states.

- References and Further Reading

Jacobs, J. (1970). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Page 15: Cities Theory Crash Course

4. City Instabilities

- Why Should I Care?

Cities are the heart and lungs of the economic system. But they have

their weaknesses. Inherent built-in instabilities will eventually bring

down even the world’s most powerful cities.

- This Lecture Has 6 Parts

Congestion and Pollution

Labour Reducing Process Innovations

Obsolescence

Old-Work Transplants

Non-productive Capital Outflows

National Currencies

- What is a City Instability?

Instability is a built-in mechanism that will cause disruptions in a

system’s path. For Jacobs, instabilities are built-in forces that will hurt

an economy’s capacity to innovate and grow.

Congestion, Pollution, and Crime

These instabilities are the easiest to understand. As cities grow, they

become congested, which increases transportation costs. The

congestion can also lead to pollution.

In older cities, overcrowding led to water pollution and poor

sanitation. Nowadays, brine water is treated, but congested roads lead

to air pollution.

Economic agglomeration and population overcrowding can lead to

increased crime levels. This is an important stress factor on cities, and

may accelerate a decrease in economic activity into an irreversible

decline.

Page 16: Cities Theory Crash Course

Labour Reducing Process Innovations

Being innovators, city economies also lead to improvements in

production processes. Not only do cities invent new products, they

also get old work done more efficiently. This is one of the negative

aspects of Schumpeter’s “Creative Destruction”.

Cities tend to invent machines, robots, automated technologies,

electronics, etc., that reduce the number of workers needed. These

technologically unemployed workers create a problem for the city. If

they are left idle they will need resources which could be invested to

grow the city instead.

Obsolescence

Another aspect of Creative Destruction is the generally inevitable

obsolescence of what we produce. Good are replaced on the market by

a newer product. For example, the type writer is no longer being

produced as the new substitute of personal computers has made it

obsolete.

Cities that produce obsolete goods will feel the brunt of this drastic

change in the economy.

Old-Work Transplants

An important aspect of Jacobs’ theory is that rural work is

transplanted city work. When city work becomes mature, the work is

tempted to leave the city to reduce its production costs.

City Regions and Transplant Regions will benefit from the arrival of

this work. But the city core may lose out if it does not find new work

for its idle labour.

Non-productive Capital Outflows

City economies are not independent of social, political, and cultural

phenomena. Jacobs’ argues that cities may be negatively affected by

non-productive capital outflows if they are part of larger nation-state

countries, or worse, federations of nations.

The higher-order government, whether central, or federal, will impose

income, corporate, and consumption taxes on the population, wherever

it is located. The strong cities will end up paying most of the levies,

but may not be enjoying most of this spending.

On top of that, governments are not always good at investing money

productively. A productive investment is an expenditure that generates

a higher return. Economically, production investments will generate

more production and work.

Page 17: Cities Theory Crash Course

Now we must note that State functions such as the justice system,

including contract, real estate, and patent tribunals, are crucial to the

existence of market economies.

Jacobs argues that governments tend to prefer “largesse” expenditures,

aimed at redistributing wealth across the land. As much as these

programmes are sound on a moral level, they do tend to transfer funds

from the city to benefit poorer, more backward regions.

Government regulations of crucial “club good” industries, can also be

detrimental to larger cities. For example, price regulation imposes

“national” prices to letter postage services, airfare, train service,

telephone companies, and television distribution companies.

One example, the Canadian government granted a monopoly to the

Bell Telephone Co. at the turn of the 1900’s. In exchange for this, Bell

was expected to service all of Canada, including rural areas, at no

exchange charge to the consumer. Urban dwellers ended up paying

higher prices on telephone services, to subsidize rural Canadians.

Jacobs argues that lower prices in Montreal and Toronto, would have

left money in these cities, which – maybe – could have found more

productive uses.

National Currencies

When Jacobs realized the importance of city trade for the creation of

new work, she then realized that a city currency can greatly enhance

the trade feedback. A city currency will smooth over business cycles,

especially if they are related to trade.

When a city has a trade deficit (X<M), it could fall into a recession.

However, a free floating city currency would depreciate before

production levels are affected. This will bolster the foreign price of

city export goods, without affecting local prices and wages.

Foreign demand for the city currency would be perfectly aligned with

that city’s exports. The feedback information of the exchange rate

with other currencies would be perfectly useful information for the

city economy.

Inversely, when a city has a trade surplus (X>M), it could go into

overheating, which generates inflation. On strong foreign demand for

city exports, the city currency will appreciate, making the exports

even more expensive. This will have two effects.

First, exports sales will slow down, reducing inflationary pressures

from shortages on factor markets, such as the job market, or the steel

market.

Page 18: Cities Theory Crash Course

Second, the city’s purchasing power for imports will rise. This will

fuel a new round of importing, which – hopefully – will in turn feed a

new round of import replacements.

Some city-states still exist. And they are some of the fastest growing

economies in the world. Singapore is a fast growing city-state that has

insisted on using a local city currency.

Few economies still use city currencies. Most states have

“nationalized” currency printing under a central bank. According to

Jacobs, this has concentrated the currency trade information feedback

on the largest, incumbent cities, of their nation. Hence, many countries

now have only one major city (ex: Paris, France).

Another problem with national currencies is that it may exacerbate a

disconnect between an important supply region and a metropolis. In

Canada, the exchange rate is very high because of the strong demand

for Alberta oil.

This is hurting the urban areas, whose economies are not based on

natural resources, but on manufacturing and services.

Nowadays, a city currency in Montreal would probably be worth less

than the Canadian dollar, to help it sell exports, and bolster its

economy. A regional currency in the West would still be strong, with

no negative impact on the Alberta resource economy.

Until the past century however, Jacobs (1985) argues most currencies

in human history were city currencies. Imperial currencies have

existed but many empires tolerated and encouraged city currencies

within their military realm.

The European Union did not follow Jacobs` advice when they created

a continental currency in 2000. The eliminated their national

currencies to merge them into the Euro. Advantages of a Currency

Bloc include lower transaction costs across borders, no more exchange

rate risk, and increased political integration mitigating the future

possibilities of war in Europe. This project was a long-time coming,

being a dream of German and French leaders for centuries, such as

Napoleon.

- Think Piece

Montreal used to be top-dog in Canada. Now it’s n.2 since political

instability sent so many headquarters to Toronto in the 1980’s. On top

of that, Canada is one huge federation that sucks money out of cities

to spread over its immense territory. Add to that the Canadian

currency which is too strong for Montreal’s manufacturing industries.

Page 19: Cities Theory Crash Course

Would a city currency for the Greater Montreal Area be beneficial to

its economy? What are drawbacks?

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

- Wrap-Up

Import-replacing cities have built-in destruction mechanisms that will

slow its growth and reverse that into a decline.

First, agglomerations lead to congestion, crime, and pollution. If these

problems are not addressed, they may lead to the decline of the city.

Second, cities improve technology and processes, which usually

reduces the need for labour. New jobs must be created or else the city

will decline.

Third, city work may become obsolete, as competitive substitutes are

invented in other cities.

Fourth, cities cannot stop producers from relocating in lower-cost

locations. New work must be created to fill the gaps left by the exodus

of old work.

Fifth, cities are subject to taxes from higher-order governments who

may use the money in non-productive ways. The money is often spent

in “largesse” efforts towards other less wealthy regions.

Sixth, national currencies tend to counter the “natural” trade cycle of

import-replacing cities. This reduces the growth of the city, and the

influx of imports, which hinders future growth.

- References and Further Reading

Jacobs, J. (1970). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Jacobs, J. (1985). Cities and the Wealth of Nations. Vintage.

Page 20: Cities Theory Crash Course

5. Jacobs’ Spectrum of Regions

- Why Should I Care?

Some economies are regional, and some are cities. Some regions are

thriving and others are not. Some cities are thriving, and others are

not. Jacobs provides five categories of regional economies to explain

where the wealth is, and where it is not.

- This Lecture Has 5 Parts

The Forward City

The City Region

The Supply Region

The Transplant Region

The Backward City

- What is a Spectrum of Economic Regions?

A spectrum is an axis that follows one variable. In this case, we will

compare cities according to their capacity to be dynamic economies,

capable of innovation and adaptation.

Jacobs (1970, 1985) theory explains how city-economies adapt to each

other, in relation to geography, trade, government, and business

forces. She presents five types of economic regions: The Forward

City, the City Region, the Supply Region, the Transplant Region, and

the Backward City.

In this text, these categories are aligned from one extreme to another,

from the most dynamic (forward city) to the least dynamic (backward

city).

Jacobs categories of economies is constructed from her own theory of

economic growth, which is grounded in her visits of cities across the

globe, economic history, anthropology, and a critical evaluation of

macro-economics.

The five categories are differentiated according to variables such as

density, industrial diversity, resource endowment, company size, the

Page 21: Cities Theory Crash Course

import-replacement function, product innovation, process innovation,

employment, price levels, and immigration patterns.

The Forward City

A “Jacobs Agglomeration” is a city which is diverse, growing, and

inventive. It is an inductive conclusion based on several criteria. Such

a city tends to create opportunity for migrants and youth, tends to

invent new products and industries, and tends to be very open to trade

and science.

We will call these economies “Forward Cities” for their unique

capacity to constantly innovate, generate new products, and adapt

smoothly to changing trade patterns. This quality is what makes

Forward Cities the economic heart and lung of the rest of the system,

and provides technology improvements, and prosperity to many other

economies.

NOTE – Jacobs never used the terms Jacobs’ Agglomeration, or

Forward City. She used the term “import-replacing city”.

Economic literature now uses the term Jacobs’ agglomeration and the

term “forward city” is original to this text. It serves to illustrate the

economic development quality of these cities, and to differentiate them

from “backward cities”, since they are opposites on the Jacobs

spectrum of economic regions.

Forward Cities can be large or small. But they do grow rapidly at

some point in time. Most of them are now quite large, and are thus

often dubbed as a “metropolis”, or “economic capital”.

Jacobs identifies Detroit, of 1910, as an example of a forward city.

The density of Detroit at the time was relatively high, compared to

smaller rural settlements of that period. The city was then bustling

with hundreds of car design and manufacturing companies, a new

industry that was in a phase of rapid development and expansion.

The industrial diversity of the city was growing at the time, as Detroit

was replacing German automobile imports, into local production.

As most forward cities, the geographic location of Detroit did not

confer any particular resource endowments such as minerals or oil. As

the name of city indicates, the city was a natural location for a

maritime port, although set well inside the North-American continent;

a natural link between Great Lakes waterway. The city was also at the

hub of road transportation between the US Midwest and southern

Ontario.

Economic history literature indicates that 1910 Detroit hosted a

variety of small and medium sized automobile companies. It came to

be known as “Motor City” for this reason. Of the hundreds of

Page 22: Cities Theory Crash Course

carmakers, the industry eventually consolidated into three large

multinationals (GM, Ford and Chrysler) whose headquarters are still

in Detroit.

According to Jacobs, Detroit’s growth is due to its “import-

replacement”. Detroit did not invent the automobile, which was a

German invention. However, Detroit was the birthplace of this

industry in North America, and greatly contributed to the refinement

and improvement of both the product, and its production process.

This led to a strong demand for labour, high employment in the city.

This attracted people to the city, whose population grew.

The exports of cars enabled the city to import many higher-order

goods, and the wider variety of local production helped keep overall

prices low. The price of cars themselves was continuously decreasing,

as the technology, and processes improved, and as scale increased.

Instabilities associated to forward cities are:

o Unaddressed congestion, pollution, crime

o Eventual loss of work to lower cost regions

o Obsolescence

o Capital withdrawals from nation-state policy

o National currency

Risk factors associated to forward cities are:

o To gradually stop import-replacing.

o To stop indigenous innovation.

What can governments do to help these economies?

o Provide positive feedback mechanisms such as city currency.

o Avoid non-productive capital outflows by nation-state.

o Invest in productive investments such as new

products, and science.

o Encourage Breakaway Entrepreneurship.

o Address pressing problems of urban life. Solutions may

become opportunity to invent new industries.

The City Region

Growing cities have a direct impact on their surrounding areas, often

rural, and sparsely populated at first. Analysts now speak of “Greater

Detroit Area”, or of Metropolitan Areas, which include “Outer

Suburban Rings”.

Once the metropolis grows outside its initial borders, these areas

become engaged in the intricate network of the city economy. Their

Page 23: Cities Theory Crash Course

production diversifies as old-work is transplanted outside the now

congested core city. City regions directly benefit from the

inventiveness of the core city, without having to deal with the

congestion and pollution.

The density increases, but remains low. The industrial diversity can be

very high, surprising to many. The structure of this economy remains

diverse in production, scale, and scope.

The area does not need any particular natural resource endowment,

other than land to build factories, houses and office space.

The area is indirectly engaged in import-replacement, but this is due to

its integration with the city economy.

City Regions can be product innovators, or not. This is because

producers transplant production here to save on costs, not out of a

creative need to constantly invent new products.

Thus, these producers are very much interested in cost-saving process

innovations, especially labour-saving technology.

The level of employment is high and growing, which attracts

migration from other regions, further out from the city.

Price levels tend to be low, as cost-saving measures, and diversity of

local production, are the norm.

Instabilities include:

o The eventual loss of work to lower-cost regions

o A reduction in arrival of new work from a decline of the city

o Obsolescence

o Capital withdrawals from nation-state policy

o National currency

Policy prescriptions:

o Agree to what is best for core city.

o Invest in cost-cutting process innovation.

The Supply Region

Many Supply Regions – also known as resource economies – are quite

wealthy, as they are usually endowed with a highly demanded natural

resource.

But Jacobs argues they are inherently fragile, and lack a capacity to

adapt to changes in trade patterns. She qualifies them of being

Page 24: Cities Theory Crash Course

“backward” economies, along with Transplant Regions, and Backward

Cities.

An example of a Supply Region near Detroit is the Ohio iron ore

region, which saw the rise of the Cleveland Cliffs mining company.

Naturally endowed with a key mineral for making steel, widely used

in making automobiles, the rise of the Detroit economy created what

Jacobs calls a solvent market for Ohio’s iron ore, and steel foundered

in Cleveland. The mining area of Cleveland Cliffs is not a densely

populated area, and its economy is highly concentrated in iron ore

mining. Without the iron ore, one can wonder how much economic

activity would take place there.

The mining industry is typically consolidated, made up of a few large

companies. They are content in supplying other regions and do not

engage in import-replacement. Generally, they are not known for

product innovation.

Supply regions are focussed on reducing production costs, and

improving processes. The job market can grow at first, but usually is

very stable or declining as labour-reducing technology is introduced.

Prices can be high as most consumer goods need to be imported.

However in this case, Ohio mines are relatively close to important

cities such as Detroit and Cleveland, so prices here would be relatively

low.

Migrants would be attracted to the area when the mines are being

constructed, but immigration would be halted after their normal

operations level-off.

Supply regions that are struggling often find a way to receive funds

from wealthier supply regions, or from wealthier forward cities. In

Canada, the federal government transfers equalization payments to

poor provinces, which are generated from taxes collected in wealthy

provinces such as Alberta (wealthy supply region), or Ontario

(Toronto is wealthy forward city). These capital injections may not be

economically productive, as they can generate a disposition of

dependence toward wealthy areas. Politically, the transfers may be

argued to be moral. But many economists believe these transfers

contribute to keep poor regions in poverty.

Another structural problem that supply regions may face is if they are

part of a currency union with other supply regions specialized in

different industries. The exchange rate will follow the trends of the

industries with the largest trade volume, and these patterns may not

help the smaller supply regions. For example, Alberta’s oil patch

dictates fluctuations in the Canadian exchange rate. However, the oil

industry cycle may not match the cycle for coal, which is the main

mineral export of Nova Scotia. The Canadian dollar may be hurting

the Maritime economy more than it helps.

Page 25: Cities Theory Crash Course

Instabilities:

o Capital injections from nation-state policy

o National currency disconnect

Risk factors are:

o A sudden drop in “foreign” demand

o New competition from lower cost region

o Introduction of a new substitute good which reduces demand

o Introduction of a new production substitute which clears

population

o National currency

Policy prescriptions:

o Diversify industrial base to reduce foreign demand risk.

o Constantly invest in cost-cutting process innovation.

o Avoid monopsony power on local labour that discourages

breakaway entrepreneurship.

The Transplant Region

This type of economic region is similar to the Supply Region in many

ways. However, its inception occurs differently.

The Transplant Region is brought to life by the transfer of work from

a congested city to a lower-cost production area. Its role is to supply

cities and other regions with a specialized product.

However, its economic raison d’être has nothing to do with natural

resources. It can be anywhere on earth, as long as transport and labour

costs are lower than in the city.

Under the umbrella of the Detroit automobile industry, a city such as

Flint, Michigan, is a perfect example of a Transplant Region, also

known as a “company town”.

Flint is where General Motors was created in 1908, an automobile

consolidator that swallowed Buick and Chevrolet, along with dozens

of other Detroit-based carmakers.

GM had decided to set up in Flint to avoid the high costs of the then-

bustling Detroit. The city was less than two hours away, so GM could

bring workers over to this specialized area and continue to benefit

from knowledge spillovers from the Detroit economy.

As most Transplant Regions, the city never diversified out of car

making. GM eventually built its headquarters in Detroit, but Flint

remained a key manufacturing location for a long time. However,

Page 26: Cities Theory Crash Course

lower cost locations appeared over the last century and eventually,

Flint lost one plant after the other. Finally, in 1999, GM decided to

shut its last plant in Flint, which made large Buick sedans that had

gone out of fashion with SUV craving consumers.

The density of Transplant Regions is usually low, on purpose, to

reduce overall costs of living, wages and transportation.

At first, the absence of industrial diversity is not a problem, as this

large, single-company, transplant comes “out of nowhere”. It is seen

as a “godsend” by local townspeople of a previously poor region.

However, over time, the region may lose this work as the factory is

transplanted again, to an even-lower cost region.

A Transplant Region usually does not engage in import-replacement

because the local employer is alone, very large, and dominates the

political and economic culture of the region. This kind of monopoly

on the labour market is called a monopsony, and research indicates

they tend to discourage breakaway entrepreneurship and any form of

competition for local labour.

The factory’s strategic management decisions are not made locally,

they come from a head quarter located outside the region. In this case,

GM’s Flint plants would follow orders from Detroit. Local initiative is

limited to process innovations, and product innovations are not

expected. If foreign demand is strong, the transplant region will enjoy

growing demand for labour, and worker migration toward the region.

Risk factors are the same as for supply regions.

The Backward City

To be dubbed “backward” is insulting. Jacobs actually writes that

most cities in the world, and throughout history, have a backward

economy. The good news is that a Backward City can evolve into a

more forward economy.

Most people would say a backward economy is in decline, or is non-

competitive. They may be shielded from other, more competitive

economies, by subsidies, import tariffs, or other barriers to trade.

Modern-day Detroit has definitely become a backward economy. Its

population is declining, neighborhoods are abandoned, and houses are

boarded up. Poverty and crime tend to be rampant, and especially

difficult to live with, in high density cities in decline.

The size of companies tends to vary within the city. In the case of a

declining city, many large companies have probably left, leaving a

gaping hole in the fabric of the economy. In the case of stagnant small

towns, companies are generally small and not growing.

Page 27: Cities Theory Crash Course

This city is not import-replacing. It is not inventing new products. It

probably is not very good at process innovations either. Because of all

this, consumption goods need to be imported at a high price, and the

non-competitive local producers output is overly expensive.

A note: Jacobs insists that price levels must be considered as relative

to local wages. A foreigner travelling to a stagnant city may find

prices are lower than what he is accustomed to at home. But that does

not mean the locals can afford these prices.

Jobs are scarce and population is declining. Survival depends more

and more on the local stock of natural resources and less and less on

trade and productive investment.

The risk for this type of regional economy is that things get worse

before they get better. A population exodus can relieve the city of the

strain of providing for everyone. Remittance from expatriated workers

may become the only capital inflow to the city.

Jacobs recommends that these cities avoid direct competition with

large dynamic economies. They should start to construct a local

symbiotic network of workshops and small factories that replace low-

technology imports. This new production usually can be sold to other,

neighboring backward economies.

- In-Class Activity

Associate each city to an economic category. Work in groups.

Use the internet if possible.

Montreal 1985 Montreal 2007

Magog Laval

Val d’Or Saint-Jérôme

Kingsey Falls Valcourt

Toronto Markham

Sudbury Gaspé

- Think Piece

Think of your home town and think of a place you could establish

yourself in the near future. Associate them to an economic category.

Where would you probably enjoy the most prosperity?

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

Page 28: Cities Theory Crash Course

- Wrap-Up

Economies can be analyzed under five categories, according to their

ability to grow, evolve, and adapt to changing conditions.

The Forward City is the strongest economic category. These are

import-replacing cities where employment is high, and prices are low.

They are usually very diverse economic systems, where symbiotic

networks of small and large companies interact.

The City Region is the immediate neighbor of the Forward City,

where overflow production is located. Many factories are transplanted

here as the core becomes congested and expensive. Employment here

is high and prices low.

The Supply Region is a resource-based economy. Local consumption

goods are imported, using funds from specialized export work.

Employment may be high, but usually dwindles, and prices are high as

well.

The Transplant Region is manufacturing-based (or services) town

where mature city work was transplanted to reduce land, and labour

costs. Employment can be high, but this economy is vulnerable to

foreign demand shocks.

The Backward City is a declining economy, which may in the past

have been a successful supply region, or transplant region.

Employment is low and declining. Prices are high and rising.

- References and Further Reading

Jacobs, J. (1970). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Jacobs, J. (1985). Cities and the Wealth of Nations. Vintage.

Page 29: Cities Theory Crash Course

6. Innovation in Jacobs’ Agglomerations

- Why Should I Care?

Jacobs’ agglomerations don’t just replace imports, they also nurture

product and process innovations. This is the key to understanding the

geography of Schumpeter’s Creative Destruction.

- This Lecture Has 2 Parts

City Inventions

Diversity trumps Specialization

- What is Innovation in Jacobs’ Agglomerations?

Jacobs (1970) argues that cities are natural environments for economic

change because imports come through the cities. This is because cities

are located around ports and other transport hubs. Cities can afford to

import new and innovative goods from foreign economies with the

money earned from their exports.

But who invents the new things others will import?

Cities, answers Jacobs.

City Inventions

Jacobs theorizes cities invented almost everything that came to a

market. Even agriculture and farming technologies.

Consider the previous example of office chairs. A share of the

production will eventually be exported from E-City as foreigners

become aware of the existence of the product. This export, brings in

extra money to E-City, who can use it to import goods from abroad,

which are not produced locally. Let’s assume E-City imports fancy

dinner chairs from abroad.

Most economists would believe this trade is a good thing and these

economies should specialize in the fields where they hold a relative

comparative advantage. This is the Ricardo view.

Jacobs argues most cities don’t behave this way.

Page 30: Cities Theory Crash Course

Jacobs argues that cities copy each other, to everyone’s benefit. E-City

has got wood, leather and plastics. It can use “reverse-engineering” to

copy the imported good and produce it locally. The import becomes a

knowledge spillover between economies.

Further, the added local production also increases money stocks in E-

City, which enable its citizens to import more fancy products. This is a

positive feedback loop directly related to trade.

Trade brings in new ideas to cities that often copy the imported

products and thus increase their local production levels. Furthermore,

Jacobs argues that cities use imports as inspiration. These imports fuel

innovation.

Consider the imported dinner chair example. Not only will E-City

start producing dinner chairs. But E-City might also invent a whole

type of chair, inspired by the fabrics, the assembly techniques, and the

overall design of the imported good.

As producers act on the profit incentive, and as consumers love new,

different, and better products, market-oriented cities become the

natural location for inventive companies. The trade cycle generates a

second positive feedback loop of invention and innovation.

Diversity Trumps Specialization

Most Jacobs’ agglomerations are typically very diversified economies.

Think of Tokyo, Montreal, Singapore, Shanghai, New York, San

Francisco, Mexico City, etc…

These kinds of cities are now considered to be the engines of

economic growth by modern macroeconomists.

But this observable fact flies in the face of orthodox economic theory

which argues that Ricardian comparative advantage should lead to

economic specialization and increased production.

What does diversity mean?

Industrial diversity refers to the variety of goods and services which

are produced in a city, a region, or a metropolitan area.

Some cities such as Montreal are very diverse. Our metropolis

produces a variety of final goods such as transformed food products,

chemicals, airplanes, pharmaceuticals, refined petroleum, cardboard,

etc. Montreal also produces a variety of services such as TV, radio and

print media, finance, insurance, law council, accounting, health, and

education.

Page 31: Cities Theory Crash Course

Diversity has two main advantages, according to Jacobs (1970). First,

it reduces vulnerabilities to foreign trends.

Second, and more importantly, diversity increases innovation

because science and technology spill over different industries with

greater ease when these industries share the same city.

Solutions to technical problems can be useful in very different

industries. For example, the clothing industry has come up with

Velcro technology used in shoes and other garments. This technology

has proven to be very useful in wide array of industries, such as

aerospace. Surprisingly, wings are attached to the fuselage of some

planes with hard-pressed Velcro-type technology.

Jacobs’ point is that in a diverse city, very different industries can

learn from each other. In diverse cities, technology and knowledge

will spillover more quickly from one industry to another. Economists

have dubbed this phenomenon cross-industry knowledge spillovers.

In the end, you can ask yourself if diverse cities are wealthier than

specialized regions. They can be. Studies show that Jacobs

agglomerations typically grow at a more steady and constant pace,

which over time trumps the typically rocky path of high-flying

resource economies.

- Think Piece

The 2008-09 recession was much harder on Toronto, than it was on

Montreal. Toronto’s economy is specialized in the automobile

industry, which was the focal point of the economic slowdown.

Borrowing from the idea of “resilience” in psychology, would you

argue that politicians and policymakers should focus on making their

economies as “resilient” as possible?

Submit 1 page essay in-class.

- Wrap-Up

Jacobs agglomerations are more dynamic economies in the sense that

they are more diverse and innovative than others.

Jacobs argues that trade will increase the strength of the hub city, as

imports offer opportunity for new ideas. Cities often copy imports and

produce them locally, adding to the local production level.

Jacobs also argues that trade fuels the innovative nature of companies

in cities, because that is where the imports are first seen by nationals.

Urban producers use imports as inspiration to invent new products.

Page 32: Cities Theory Crash Course

Jacobs agglomerations tend to be more diverse because they invent

new industries that add to previous activities. Jacobs argues this

diversity is enviable because A) it protects the economy from violent

foreign demand cycles, and B) it leads to cross-industry knowledge

spillovers which generates more innovation and economic

development.

Specialized economies can be very wealthy, but studies show their

economic cycles to be more pronounced and overall generate less

prosperity than diverse cities.

- Cheat Sheet with Memory Helper

Hub City: A city located on a transportation hub,

such as a crossroads of highways or

railways, a deep water port, or a major

airport, or all of the above.

Company Town: An economy dominated by a large

employer, such as a mine, or a

manufacturing plant.

Cross-industry Spillover: The phenomenon of one industry

adopting technology designed in a

very different industry.

- References and Further Reading

Hall, P. (1966) The World Cities. McGraw-Hill.

Jacobs, J. (1970). The Economy of Cities. Vintage.

Jacobs, J. (1984). Cities and the Wealth of Nations. Vintage.

7. Appendices

The Jacobs Summary Table, and the Import-Replacement Diagram are

on the next five pages.

If trade is the fuel of innovation.

Does free trade

make innovation free?

Page 33: Cities Theory Crash Course

TYPES OF ECONOMIES Forward Cities City Regions Supply Regions Transplant Regions Backward Cities

MONIKERS METROPOLIS METRO OUTER RINGS,

SUBURBS, HINTERLAND RESOURCE ECONOMY COMPANY TOWN CITY IN DECLINE

EXAMPLES DETROIT 1900 GREATER DETROIT;

WINDSOR, ON CLEVELAND CLIFFS

STEEL FLINT, MICHIGAN DETROIT 2010

DENSITY HIGH LOW LOW LOW EITHER

INDUSTRIAL DIVERSITY HIGH HIGH LOW LOW LOW

RESOURCE ENDOWMENT

NOT NECESSARY NOT NECESSARY MANDATORY LABOUR IS SUFFICIENT BECOMES MANDATORY

IMPORT-REPLACING YES MAYBE NO NO NO

SIZE OF WORKPLACES VARIETY FROM SMALL

TO LARGE VARIETY FROM SMALL

TO LARGE LARGE LARGE

VARIETY FROM SMALL TO LARGE

JOBS HIGH HIGH EITHER EITHER LOW

PRICES LOW LOW HIGH HIGH HIGH

IMMIGRATION INCOMING INCOMING EITHER EITHER OUTCOMING

Page 34: Cities Theory Crash Course

TYPES OF ECONOMIES Forward Cities City Regions Supply Regions Transplant Regions Backward Cities

PRODUCT INNOVATOR YES EITHER NO NO NO

PROCESS INNOVATOR EITHER YES EITHER EITHER NO

INSTABILITIES

creative destruction, nation-state capital outflows, congestion, pollution

capital outflows dependency money, monopsony power

dependency money, monopsony power

dependency money

RISK FACTORS

To gradually stop import-replacing, or to stop indigenous innovation.

That "old-work" is lost to transplant regions. That newer "old work" stops flowing from the core city.

Foreign demand shock. New consumer substitute shock. Introduction of a new production substitute which clears population. New competition from lower cost region

Foreign demand shock. New consumer substitute shock. Introduction of a new production substitute which clears population. New competition from lower cost region

It can't get worse. It can only get better.

POLICY PRESCRIPTIONS

Avoid non-productive capital outflows by nation-state.

Agree to what is best for core city.

Diversify industrial base to reduce foreign demand risk.

Diversify industrial base to reduce foreign demand risk.

Start replacing "simple" imports to sell to neighboring backward cities.

Invest in productive investments such as new products, and science.

Invest in cost-cutting process innovation.

Invest in cost-cutting process innovation.

Invest in cost-cutting process innovation.

Encourage Breakaway Entrepreneurship Solve urban problems.

Avoid monopsony power.

Avoid monopsony power.

Page 35: Cities Theory Crash Course

Beaver pelts exported to France

Money comes in

Montreal, New France

France makes

beaver felt hats

PARIS,

FRANCE

Money is sent back for clothes

French Fashion exported to Montreal

STEP 1 - NORMAL TWO-WAY TRADE

Montrealers hunt

beavers for pelts

Page 36: Cities Theory Crash Course

Beaver pelts exported to France

Montreal, New France

PARIS,

FRANCE

Less money is sent

back for clothes

Less French Fashion exported to Montreal

STEP 2 – IMPORT IS REPLACED

Montreal skins

Beavers for pelts

New

workshop

makes clothes

Some of the

clothes money

diverted to local

producer

Advantages:

No transport costs, no shipping delays.

Custom work is possible.

Create local jobs.

Generate demand for neighboring supply

cities (textiles, buttons).

Page 37: Cities Theory Crash Course

Montreal, New France

STEP 3 – EXPORT TO OTHER CITIES

Clothing

workshop

PARIS,

FRANCE

Beaver pelt

trade

Trois-Rivières,

New France Montreal fashions are now exported to neighboring cities such

as Trois-Rivières.

This trade nurtures a second wave of export-funded imports to

Montreal, which may come from Paris, or any other city in its

trading circles.

The import-replacement cycle can thus start all-over again with

whatever Montrealers decide to import, and produce locally.

Page 38: Cities Theory Crash Course