Chinese Trade Driving Corruption in Africa - Wilson Gu

20
Chinese Trade Driving Corruption in Africa? Wilson Gu Introduction In order to keep up rapid economic growth and stave off domestic discontent, China has had to look for natural resources to import and new markets to export to. Africa represents major opportunities in both areas. Yet, in its pursuit of economic growth, China has been accused of a singular focus on economic growth at the expense of furthering bad governance in Africa. Bad governance comes in many shapes and sizes, not limited to corruption, human rights abuses, and wasteful spending. This differs from many Western approaches to economic development where the foreign country often places conditions on aid disbursement, like good governance or democratic reforms. Leaders of authoritarian states in Africa view these conditions as a thorn in the side, and they are gladly turning to China for economic assistance and opportunities as China has stated a “non-interventionist” policy. It is not clear if these accusations are clear and if China has a significant negative influence on African countries’ governance and institutions. This paper attempts to shed some light on this topic by providing an econometric model that will complement existing accounts and reports on China’s impact on corruption in Africa. The existing literature on China’s engagement with Africa lacks quantitative evidence. Corruption is a major obstacle to development, and as China plays a larger global role, it also has an incentive to promote sustainable growth founded on good governance. But before action can be taken, it must be determined if China’s trade and aid policies are actually exacerbating the problem of corruption in Africa. Do firms in countries that have major economic ties with China pay more bribes? What characteristics of firms in these countries lead to a higher probability of paying bribes? Four

description

basic econometric paper

Transcript of Chinese Trade Driving Corruption in Africa - Wilson Gu

  • Chinese Trade Driving Corruption in Africa? Wilson Gu

    Introduction

    In order to keep up rapid economic growth and stave off domestic discontent, China has

    had to look for natural resources to import and new markets to export to. Africa represents major

    opportunities in both areas. Yet, in its pursuit of economic growth, China has been accused of a

    singular focus on economic growth at the expense of furthering bad governance in Africa. Bad

    governance comes in many shapes and sizes, not limited to corruption, human rights abuses, and

    wasteful spending. This differs from many Western approaches to economic development where

    the foreign country often places conditions on aid disbursement, like good governance or

    democratic reforms. Leaders of authoritarian states in Africa view these conditions as a thorn in

    the side, and they are gladly turning to China for economic assistance and opportunities as China

    has stated a non-interventionist policy. It is not clear if these accusations are clear and if China

    has a significant negative influence on African countries governance and institutions.

    This paper attempts to shed some light on this topic by providing an econometric model

    that will complement existing accounts and reports on Chinas impact on corruption in Africa.

    The existing literature on Chinas engagement with Africa lacks quantitative evidence.

    Corruption is a major obstacle to development, and as China plays a larger global role, it also has

    an incentive to promote sustainable growth founded on good governance. But before action can

    be taken, it must be determined if Chinas trade and aid policies are actually exacerbating the

    problem of corruption in Africa.

    Do firms in countries that have major economic ties with China pay more bribes? What

    characteristics of firms in these countries lead to a higher probability of paying bribes? Four

  • Gu 2

    major characteristics are examined, leading to four hypotheses. 1) For firms in African countries

    that have more than 20% of their exports to or imports from China, these firms are more likely to

    pay bribes than firms in other African countries. 2) For firms that both operate in a major

    Chinese trade country and sectors that China is interested in, these firms are more likely to pay

    bribes than all other firms. 3) For firms that have high horizontal FDI (share of output produced

    by foreign firms) in sector-regions in major Chinese trade countries, these firms are more likely

    to pay bribes than other firms. 4) For firms that require an import license in major Chinese trade

    countries, these firms are more likely to pay bribes than other firms. In addition, this paper

    draws heavily from Alaimo et al., and the control rights, bargaining power, and grease the

    wheels hypotheses on determinants of bribery, all of which are tested in this paper.

    Hypothesis 1 is confirmed, as firms in countries that have major trade ties with China do

    pay more bribes. Hypothesis 2 is also confirmed but with the caveat that the data on sectors do

    not include extractive industries which tend to facilitate corruption. Hypothesis 3 is not

    confirmed, but the measurement of FDI uses microeconomic data and not macro data. It cannot

    be ruled out completely based on the results of this paper. Hypothesis 4 is not confirmed. There

    is also evidence that supports the control right hypothesis in Africa and a lack of evidence for the

    bargaining rights hypothesis, findings that corroborate those of Alaimo et al. However, the

    impact of objective courts in Africa has no significant impact on the probability of paying bribes,

    a finding that differs from Alaimo et al who find that court enforcement power lead to a

    decreased probability of paying bribes. Standard fixed effects controls include country, sector,

    and region in addition to other controls like peacefulness and country income levels.

    Literature Review

  • Gu 3

    The seminal papers on corruption are Who must pay bribes and how much? Evidence

    from a cross section of firms (Svensson 2003) and Behind the investment climate: back to

    basics determinants of corruption (Alaimo et al. 2009). Both differ from the majority of

    papers in that they use microeconomic data instead of perception indices. Svensson focuses on

    Uganda firms and the questions who pay bribes and how much. He tests the control rights

    hypothesis where firms pay bribes when faced with public officials who demand kickbacks

    when providing necessary services like public infrastructure. Results show that firms do have to

    pay bribes when dealing with these public officials, thereby answering the question who receives

    bribes. Svensson also tests a bargaining hypothesis where firms will pay bribes only if they

    are able to. He proxies the ability to pay of firms with current and expected future probability,

    and he proxies the refusal power of firms with the estimated alternative return on capital. The

    results show that the more a firm is able to pay, the less it pays. The results also show that the

    more profitable an outside option is for the firm, the fewer bribes it will pay. These two factors

    answer the question of how much do firms pay in bribes.

    Alaimo et al. takes Svenssons hypotheses and adds another one, the grease the wheels

    hypothesis, which states that firms will pay bribes if the gain from paying the bribe outweighs

    the costs of the bribe and the costs of getting caught. However, instead of Uganda, the authors

    focus on Latin America. There are four major findings. First, regulations, proxied by the degree

    of regulatory compliance, affect the probability of paying bribes, a finding that supports the

    control rights hypothesis. Second, there is not enough evidence for the bargaining position

    hypothesis. Third, domestic firms are more likely to pay bribes. Fourth, a more credible judicial

    system is associated with lower probability of paying bribes. Both of these papers provide the

    conceptual framework for identifying determinants of paying bribes in Africa. They are the

  • Gu 4

    baseline to which additional factors will be added to in order to examine Chinas economic

    actions impact on corruption and more broadly, institutions in Africa.

    Numerous articles propose deal with the impact of corruption on foreign direct

    investment and other actions of foreign economic actors (Habib and Zurawicki 2002; Egger and

    Winner 2005; Ogunmuyiwa 2012). One paper has dealt with the other direction of causality, that

    economic activity actually affects corruption. Robertson and Watson (2004) test the impact of

    changing levels of foreign direct investment on levels of corruption as measured by the

    Corruption Perceptions Index for all countries. Results show that the more rapid the rate of

    change of FDI, the higher the level of corruption. This reveals a need for similar studies that use

    microeconomic data instead of indices to measure corruption, something this paper hopes to

    achieve. The paper also proposes multiple sources of change in corruption in its literature review,

    such as abundance of natural resources, the level of innovation, government philosophy on trade,

    and cultural tendencies. The paper itself only measures FDI and some cultural factors like

    masculinity of a country. FDI is measured by using publicly available macroeconomic data.

    Because Robertson and Watson present evidence that foreign actions can influence corruption, it

    suggests that corruption in African countries could go through similar increases or decreases

    dependent on the actions of foreign countries seeking to invest or trade.

    There is much variation in the literature on whether or not Chinese economic activity has

    improved institutions and decreased corruption. An International Rivers Network report (2007)

    Chinas role in financing African infrastructure identifies a perceived propensity of Chinese

    companies to bribe abroad, and the lack of success by the Chinese government to prevent this,

    may undermine international efforts to strengthen good governance and fight corruption in

    development projects. This is also reflected in the Ethics Institute of South Africas (2014)

  • Gu 5

    Africans perceptions of Chinese businesses in Africa: a survey. For South Africa, Nigeria, and

    Kenya, 61% of respondents agree with the statement Chinese companies are involved in

    corruption when doing business in their country. It also finds negative perceptions on Chinese

    companies environmental policies, reputation, and social interactions. The China Development

    Bank has a policy of non-interference in domestic affairs when giving out loans, further

    propagating the notion that China does not care about governance in African countries as long as

    it obtains resources and markets. At the same time, Chinese companies have made numerous

    investments in transportation and infrastructure, and it is conceivable that economic growth

    could positively impact corruption (Williams 2013).

    Methodology

    This study uses the WBES new comprehensive dataset. Many of these countries data

    comes from 2007-2009, arguably before China had established a significant foothold in the

    region. Other major countries that have significant trade ties with China are missing, like Egypt

    and Sudan. Therefore, this study only deals with countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and not the

    entire continent.

    The main variables are constructed using definitions from Alaimo et al. Variable bribe is

    a dummy variable with a value of 1 if the firm paid a bribe in a variety of circumstances, from

    requesting utility services to applying for an import license. Variable foreign measures whether

    or not a firm has any foreign ownership, and variable export measures if a firm exports more

    than 50% of its direct sales. Variable govt is used to separate state-owned firms from private

    firms, because it is more common for state-owned firms to have more connections with public

    officials, thereby overstating the probability of paying bribes.

  • Gu 6

    Variables public, bank, and court are taken from Alaimo et al. as independent variables.

    Public signifies whether a firm requested public utilities or not. Bank measures a firms

    solvency which is used as a proxy for a firms ability to pay bribes. Court is an objective

    measure of courts fairness and impartiality and is used by Alaimo et al. as a measure of

    enforcement power.

    New variables in this study are as follows. Chinatrade is a dummy variable where a

    country is coded as 1 if 20% of either exports or imports go to or come from China. This data is

    taken from MITs Observatory of Economic Complicity. Trade data is used from two years

    before the dataset of the country until the year from the country. For example, if the dataset is

    Angola2010, in any year from 2008-2010 that Angola has 20% of either exports or imports with

    China, Angola will be coded as a chinatrade country. This not only matches the years of trade

    data with the year of the WBES data, but it also takes into account some lag effects of trading

    with China on corruption. Chinasector is a dummy variable where a value of 1 means the firm

    engages in one of the following sectors that China is interested in: manufacture of chemicals,

    chemical products, rubber and plastic products, other non-metallic mineral products, basic metals,

    and fabricated metal products excluding machinery and equipment. Chinasectorcountry is an

    interaction variable that multiplies chinasector by chinatrade. Horizontal FDI is measured in the

    dummy variable DVHFDI and the interaction variable ChinaFDI. In this paper, horizontal FDI

    is taken from the share of output produced by foreign firm in each region-sector. Finally, ilice

    and its interaction variable chinaimport show whether or not a firm requested an import license

    or not by country-sector. Interaction variables chinapublic, chinabank, and chinacourt are also

    included in one regression to look at the three bribery hypotheses effect in chinatrade countries.

  • Gu 7

    Fixed effects include country, region, and sector. For all regressions, import, export,

    public, bank, and court are also included. Control variables were also created to take into

    account the domestic conflict in a country (peaceful), using data from Databanks International,

    and variables were created to to control for income level of the country (lowmid and uppermid),

    using the income group classifications by the World Bank. The data for domestic conflict is not

    available for every country, so the missing countries are dropped from the regressions.

    The paper will first establish a baseline to check Alaimo et al.s variables and their effect

    on probability of paying a bribe. It will then examine each new independent variables effect on

    bribes individually. Finally, it will build a final regression model by individually adding

    interaction variables. It will also include interaction variables concerning the three bribery

    hypotheses to see how they hold in countries that trade with China. Finally, due to the number of

    observations dropped when controlling for conflict, this control is removed for an additional

    regression model that has a larger number of observations in order to see if the relationships still

    hold.

    The econometric model for this paper is:

    Pr(bribe)j,c,r,il,p = c + i + r + a + Xj,c,i,s,a + vj,c,i,s

    where j = firm; c = country; i = industry; r = region; il = income level; and p = peacefulness.

    Pr(bribe) is the probability that any firm pays bribes, and X is a set of controls aimed at testing

    the main variables: chinatrade, chinasectorcountry, and ChinaFDI.

    Results

  • Table 1. Countries in newcomprehensive.dta and % of trade with China

    Country Year

    % of

    exports

    to

    China

    % of

    imports

    from

    China Country Year

    % of

    exports

    to

    China

    % of

    imports

    from

    China Country Year

    % of

    exports

    to

    China

    % of

    imports

    from

    China

    DRC2010*** 2012 77.28% 16.35% Cameroon2009 2012 14.72% 11.19% Togo2009*** 2012 3.58% 26.30%

    Chad2009*** 2012 60.78% 24.39% Zimbabwe2011 2012 10.42% 5.65% Senegal2007 2010 1.91% 8.23%

    Angola2010*** 2012 60.78% 20.56% Rwanda2011 2012 9.23% 12.12% Ghana2007 2010 1.64% 12.84%

    Centralafricanrepublic2011*** 2012 53.70% 5.05% Rwanda2006 2009 8.88% 8.40% Uganda2006 2009 1.42% 9.03%

    Sierra Leone2009*** 2012 53.31% 14.09% Gabon2009 2012 8.50% 13.68% GuineaBissau2006 2009 1.41% 7.90%

    Congo2009*** 2012 49.35% 13.94% Tanzania2006 2009 7.97% 10.95% Nigeria2007 2010 1.23% 14.06%

    DRC2006*** 2009 42.55% 10.23% SouthAfrica2007 2010 7.57% 13.40% Cte d'Ivoire2009 2012 0.99% 8.13%

    Angola2006*** 2009 37.37% 13.39% Niger2009 2012 6.93% 18.82% Kenya2007 2010 0.78% 11.73%

    Mauritania2006*** 2009 34.69% 13.17% Madagascar2009 2012 6.63% 15.07% Burundi2006 2009 0.56% 7.14%

    Zambia2007*** 2010 31.08% 6.03% Gambia2006*** 2009 6.50% 20.24% Mauritius2009 2012 0.41% 17.75%

    BurkinaFaso2009*** 2012 29.00% 3.00% Mozambique2007 2010 5.00% 6.12% Eritrea2009 2012 0.31% 14.58%

    Benin2009*** 2012 23.15% 39.67% Mali2007 2010 4.73% 10.06% Ethiopia2011 2012 0.31% 14.58%

    Liberia2009*** 2012 20.09% 15.56% Malawi2009 2012 4.53% 18.38% CapeVerde2009 2012 0.00% 4.81%

    Mali2010 2012 16.51% 10.75%

    Guinea2006 2009 0.00% 15.02%

    *** denotes inclusion in variable chinatrade as a country that has prominent trade ties with China

  • Gu 9

    Table 2. African countries and probability of paying bribes

    Country Probability of

    paying a bribe Country

    Probability of

    paying a bribe Country

    Probability of

    paying a bribe

    Guinea2006 0.94 DRC2013 0.43 Togo2009*** 0.21

    DRC2006*** 0.94 Centralafricanrepublic

    2011*** 0.43 Uganda2013 0.20

    Mauritania2006*** 0.85 Chad2009*** 0.43 Gabon2009 0.20

    Kenya2007 0.77 Angola2010*** 0.43 Madagascar2009 0.19

    Liberia2009*** 0.69 Benin2009*** 0.39 Zimbabwe2011 0.18

    Nigeria2007 0.65 Senegal2007 0.35 Malawi2009 0.17

    GuineaBissau2006 0.62 Kenya2013 0.33 SouthAfrica2007 0.17

    Burundi2006 0.60 Cte d'Ivoire200 0.32 Zambia2013*** 0.13

    DRC2010*** 0.57 Niger2009 0.31 Namibia2006 0.13

    Tanzania2006 0.57 Congo2009*** 0.30 Tanzania2013 0.12

    Gambia2006*** 0.56 Botswana2006 0.25 BurkinaFaso2009*** 0.11

    Uganda2006 0.51 Sierra Leone2009*** 0.25 Botswana2010 0.10

    Angola2006*** 0.49 Mozambique2007 0.24 Ethiopia2011 0.08

    Cameroon2009 0.48 Rwanda2006 0.24 Rwanda2011 0.07

    Mali2007 0.48 Zambia2007 0.24 CapeVerde2009 0.05

    Ghana2007 0.44 Lesotho2009 0.23 Mauritius2009 0.05

    Swaziland2006 0.44 Mali2010 0.22 Eritrea2009 0.00

    Average 0.35

    *** denotes inclusion in variable chinatrade as a country that has prominent trade ties with China

  • Table 1 shows a list of countries and their percentages of exports to or imports from

    China. Highlighted countries receive a value of 1 for the dummy variable chinatrade. This

    variable does have some imperfections in that the trade data is only taken from one year and not

    an average of several years. Taking averages would give a better overall picture of whether or

    not a country considers China a major trade partner, because it would reduce the effect of large

    swings of trades or imports between different years. 40% of imports could be from China one

    year and decrease to 5% the next, an inaccurate measure of a countrys trade history. Time

    concerns prevented the use of this more accurate method.

    Table 2 shows a list of the African countries in the WBES surveys and the probability of

    paying a bribe by using the dummy variable bribe as defined by Alaimo et al. After a quick

    comparison with Table 1, its clear that numerous countries that have a high probability of

    paying bribes also have significant trade ties with China. However, several countries that trade

    with China have low probabilities of paying bribes, like Sierra Leone, Togo, Zambia, and

    Burkina Faso. Due to the inclusion of a control of peaceful, numerous countries were dropped in

    the majority of regressions. The remaining countries have stars.

    In Table 3, Dprobit regressions first replicate the results of Alaimo et al. Baseline

    coefficients for public, bank, and court have the same direction as the coefficients from Alaimo

    et al., and they have significance at the 1% level, too. This confirms the results of Alaimo et al.s

    paper, which finds support for the control rights hypothesis and grease the wheels hypothesis but

    no evidence for the bargaining hypothesis.

    The coefficient for variable chinatrade is positive and significant whenever regressed.

    The magnitude of this coefficient is also extremely high. Whether or not a country trades with

    China is an important determinant of if firms in that country pay bribes or not. However, that

  • Table 3. Baseline Regression Results

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    VARIABLES bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe

    chinatrade

    0.409***

    0.393*** 0.417***

    0.418*** 0.405***

    (0.140)

    (0.142) (0.139)

    (0.142) (0.141)

    chinasectorcountry

    0.156** 0.137**

    (0.064) (0.067)

    chinasector

    0.039

    (0.038)

    ChinaFDI

    -0.031

    (0.040)

    DVHFDI

    0.021

    (0.020)

    chinaimport

    -0.039 -0.003

    (0.034) (0.040)

    isector

    -0.038*

    (0.020)

    chinaexport

    0.143

    (0.116)

    public 0.157*** 0.157*** 0.158*** 0.157*** 0.157*** 0.158*** 0.159*** 0.157***

    (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013)

    bank -0.067*** -0.067*** -0.066*** -0.067*** -0.067*** -0.067*** -0.067*** -0.067***

    (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

    court -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107***

    (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013)

    medium -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.050*** -0.053***

    (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019)

    large -0.113*** -0.113*** -0.112*** -0.113*** -0.114*** -0.113*** -0.111*** -0.111***

    (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025)

    foreign -0.038** -0.038** -0.037** -0.037** -0.039** -0.037** -0.038** -0.038**

    (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018)

    export 0.013 0.013 0.015 0.014 0.011 0.015 0.018 -0.009

    (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.049)

    import 0.008 0.008 0.006 0.006 0.008 0.007 0.006 0.008

    (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)

  • Gu 12

    lowmid -0.042 -0.149 -0.042 -0.158 -0.147 -0.397*** -0.137 -0.147

    (0.156) (0.130) (0.156) (0.127) (0.130) (0.053) (0.132) (0.130)

    uppermid 0.517*** 0.414** 0.517*** 0.406* 0.175 -0.023 0.395* 0.418**

    (0.165) (0.211) (0.165) (0.211) (0.214) (0.200) (0.215) (0.209)

    peaceful 0.021 0.143 0.020 0.152 0.141 -0.261* 0.149 0.139

    (0.233) (0.162) (0.233) (0.161) (0.162) (0.142) (0.162) (0.162)

    Observations 8,749 8,749 8,749 8,749 8,749 8,748 8,748 8,749

    Robust standard errors in parentheses

    *** p

  • conclusion alone is not enough to draw any useful insight, so other variables must be included.

    Chinasectorcountry is significant and increases the probability of paying bribes. As a reminder,

    this variable interacts chinatrade with chinasector sectors that China is active in (manufacture

    of chemicals, chemical products, rubber and plastic products, other non-metallic mineral

    products, basic metals, and fabricated metal products excluding machinery and equipment). The

    direction of causality is unclear here. It is unclear whether bribes in these sectors were already

    paid before China began trading heavily with these countries or only increased (or decreased

    from an even higher level) after China started to engage in trade. It is even possible that China is

    especially attracted to sectors that have high instances of paying bribes. However, the finding

    that firms in these sectors in chinatrade countries pay more bribes holds important policy

    implications, because China has leverage in these countries which it could use to implement

    good governance. This is discussed in the policy recommendations section.

    All other potential variables FDI, import, and export - that could impact bribery are not

    significant. Even though chinatrade is related to percentage of exports and imports with China,

    the variables chinaimport and chinaexport themselves have no effect on the probability of paying

    bribes. This gives added support to the importance of the sector that firms operate in. Its not

    whether or not a firm exports or imports, but rather what that firm exports or imports. FDI is

    also not important, but this could be due to a measurement issue. This paper measures FDI using

    horizontal FDI as a summation of share of output produced by foreign firms. A better variable of

    Chinese influx of capital and investments could be ODA figures and private voluntary assistance

    data.

    Finally, the sector variable has faults, because it does not measure extractive industries

    which are linked with higher corruption. Natural resources are often owned by the government,

  • Gu 14

    and with weak institutions, these rights can easily be sold off for private gain. From a political

    perspective, natural resources also take away from the need of governments to tax its citizens.

    Without taxation, government officials can act with impunity with no accountability to anybody,

    because government revenue comes from resource rents. Therefore, by not including extractive

    industries like petroleum, the chinasectorcountry variable underestimates the magnitude of

    sectors effect on bribe probability.

    Table 4 shows the results of the full regression model. When adding variables

    individually to the model in columns 1-5, chinatrade maintains a high, positive coefficient and

    significance at the 1% level. The same goes for chinasectorcountry which is significant at the 5%

    level. In column 5, the variables chinapublic, chinabank, and chinacourt are interactions of

    chinatrade and public, bank, and court to examine the effects of the three hypotheses on bribery

    in African countries that trade with China. The control rights hypothesis holds but with less

    robust results, and the absence of evidence for the bargaining rights hypothesis continues with a

    negative coefficient on chinabank. However, chinacourt loses significance. It is expected that

    with more court enforcement, the probability of bribes should decrease as shown by the negative

    coefficients across the board for variable court. This does not hold in chinatrade countries,

    suggesting that courts do not matter in the probability of paying bribes in those countries. This

    could be due to the court systems in those countries not having significant dealings with sectors

    that China is interested in, by design or accident, as its already shown that the sector a firm is in

    affects the probability of paying a bribe.

    Due to concerns over dropped countries from including a peaceful control, column 6

    shows the results without this control. The number of observations rises from 8,748 to 20,133.

    Here, chinatrade maintains significance, but all other variables lose significance. Firms in

  • Table 4. Full Regression Model

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    VARIABLES bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe bribe

    chinatrade 0.409*** 0.392*** 0.394*** 0.417*** 0.420*** 0.418**

    (0.140) (0.142) (0.142) (0.141) (0.143) (0.182)

    chinasectorcountry

    0.156** 0.156** 0.153** 0.149** 0.035

    (0.064) (0.064) (0.064) (0.064) (0.036)

    ChinaFDI

    -0.010 -0.011 -0.014 0.016

    (0.035) (0.035) (0.036) (0.023)

    chinaimport

    -0.032 -0.039 -0.007

    (0.034) (0.034) (0.022)

    chinaexport

    0.175 0.165 0.003

    (0.116) (0.116) (0.075)

    chinapublic

    0.064* 0.030

    (0.033) (0.022)

    chinabank

    -0.069** -0.034

    (0.031) (0.021)

    chinacourt

    0.030 0.008

    (0.038) (0.022)

    public 0.157*** 0.158*** 0.158*** 0.157*** 0.145*** 0.151***

    (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.014) (0.009)

    bank -0.067*** -0.066*** -0.066*** -0.067*** -0.050*** -0.051***

    (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.016) (0.010)

    court -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.111*** -0.098***

    (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.009)

    medium -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.052*** -0.044***

    (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.012)

    large -0.113*** -0.112*** -0.112*** -0.111*** -0.110*** -0.086***

    (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.017)

    foreign -0.038** -0.037** -0.037** -0.037** -0.038** -0.027**

    (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.011)

    export 0.013 0.015 0.015 -0.009 -0.007 -0.012

    (0.045) (0.045) (0.045) (0.049) (0.049) (0.029)

    import 0.008 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.023**

    (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.011)

  • Gu 16

    lowmid -0.149 -0.157 -0.156 -0.149 -0.174 -0.549***

    (0.130) (0.127) (0.127) (0.129) (0.123) (0.037)

    uppermid 0.414** 0.405* 0.406* 0.417** 0.380* -0.239*

    (0.211) (0.211) (0.211) (0.209) (0.215) (0.123)

    peaceful 0.143 0.152 0.149 0.141 0.173

    (0.162) (0.161) (0.161) (0.161) (0.162)

    Observations 8,749 8,749 8,749 8,748 8,748 20,133

    Robust standard errors in parentheses

    *** p

  • countries that trade with China as a major partner still face a .418 higher chance of paying bribes.

    That is still very high. Because chinasectorcountry lost significance after dropping the peaceful

    control, the presence of peace or conflict in a country is shown to have an important relationship

    with the importance of firm sector as a determinant of bribes. That specific relationship, whether

    direct or indirect, is not clear from this paper.

    Policy Recommendations

    To the international community interested in African development, convince China to

    promote good governance. The data presented in this paper shows that firms in countries that

    trade heavily with China and firms that operate in sectors that China is active in face a higher

    probability of paying bribes. While causality and its direction, if causality exists at all, are still

    not proven, the existence of a correlation is important enough to at least move forward and

    emphasize the potential impact China could have on corruption. As more econometric data

    comes out, the international community should use this evidence to encourage China to

    strengthen accountability and transparency reforms in African countries. This can occur through

    bilateral channels or multilateral economic forums, like the U.S.-Africa Business Forum, Forum

    on China-Africa Cooperation, or African Economic Conference. China has the ability to do so,

    given its numerous foreign aid packages to Africa, its heavy trade relationships, and investments

    in infrastructure in Africa. The question is if China wants to change its policies. And it should,

    because reduction in corruption spurs innovation and competition, all of which will lead to long-

    term, sustainable growth that will benefit both African and Chinese firms. Stronger, more stable

  • Gu 18

    African economies are in Chinas interests, as it will continue to pursue more natural resources

    and more markets for decades to come.

    For Chinese companies that trade with Africa, encourage participation of African and

    Chinese firms in international openness and transparency initiatives like the Extractive

    Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI). Data from this paper show that sectors China trades

    with exhibit higher probabilities of paying bribes. These sectors are largely extractive industries

    and secondary businesses connected to extractive industries. EITI is an international norm that

    governments, firms, and civil society actors agree to. This norm requires firms in extractive

    industries to report taxes and other payments with the aim of improving transparency in order to

    gain accountability. Many countries in Africa have already agreed to EITI principles, even

    major Chinese trading partners like Nigeria, Chad, DRC, and Zambia. Chinese companies are in

    an especially good position to improve conditions in current African EITI countries and to bring

    more African economies to agree to these principles, due to their existing significant ties with

    African firms and government officials. This influence could be used to push for governance

    reforms that address corruption. But just like how the decision to change foreign aid policy

    ultimately lies with the Chinese government, it is up to the Chinese firms to encourage EITI

    participation.

    Summary

    This paper presents evidence that Chinese trade is connected with probabilities of paying

    bribes in Africa. It also shows that the main driver of bribery in these countries is the sector that

    a firm operates in. Therefore, three possible conclusions arise. Corruption in these sectors could

  • Gu 19

    have already been high due to the nature of extractive industries and already weak institutions,

    and these weaknesses in governance persisted after China arrived on the scene. Or, after Chinese

    firms began trading in these sectors, corruption increased due to China turning a blind eye

    towards any rent-seeking as long as China got its resources. The third possibility is that bribery

    is currently high in countries that trade with China, but it was even higher before China came.

    Without time-series data, it is difficult to prove any one of these at the correct explanation. Yet,

    given the existing literature, the first and second conclusions are most likely. These explanations

    drive the policy recommendations to bring international attention to this issue in order to

    convince China to use its influence to build good governance that prevents and punishes

    corruption, and to encourage Chinese companies and African companies to adopt international

    transparency and accountability measures like the EITI.

    Further areas of research could first examine official development assistance and private

    voluntary assistance from China. This and better measures of private sector FDI should provide

    a more comprehensive picture of the economic relationship between China and Africa, because it

    studies a dimension in addition to just trade. AidData has a dataset that uses crowdsourced

    reports to put estimates on Chinese investments and in Africa. As mentioned earlier, time-series

    or panel data could also prove helpful in establishing causality between bribery and Chinese

    economic involvement. Evidence showing Chinese actions and policies leading to higher rates

    of bribery provides much stronger support for anticorruption reforms. Whatever evidence does

    emerge, China can potentially play an important role in helping Africa develop with solid

    institutions that promote long-term, sustainable growth that can benefit all parties.

  • References

    Alaimo, V. et al. 2009b. Behind the Investment Climate: Back to BasicsDeterminants of Corruption. In

    Fajnzylber, P. et al. (Editors). Does the Investment Climate Matter? Microeconomic Foundations

    of Growth in Latin America. Washington, DC: The World Band and Palgrave Macmillan: 139-

    178 (Chapter 4).

    Bosshard, P. 2007. Chinas role in financing African infrastructure. International Rivers Network.

    Egger, P. and Winner, H. 2005. Evidence on corruption as an incentive for foreign direct investment.

    European Journal of Political Economy. 21: 932-952.

    Habib, M. and Zurawicki L. 2002. Corruption and foreign direct investment. Journal of International

    Business Studies. 33: 291-307.

    Ogunmuyiwa, M.S. 2012. An econometric analysis of the impact of corruption on FDI in Nigeria.

    Journal of African Macroeconomic Review. 2: 148-159.

    Robertson, C.J. and Watson, M. 2004. Corruption and change: the impact of foreign direct investment.

    Strategic Management Journal. 25: 385-396.

    Rossouw, G. et al. 2014. Africans perceptions of Chinese business in Africa: a survey. Ethics Institute of

    South Africa.

    Svensson, J. 2003. Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Evidence from a Cross Section of Firms. The

    Quarterly Journal of Economics. 118(1): 207-30.

    Wlliams, J. 2013. Rethinking Chinas exploitation of Africa. China Hands.