Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

91
Chapter Six New Services, New Policies? Neo- Liberal Policy Discourse and the Broadcasting Services Act 1992 The late 1980s and early 1990s marked a transitional period in the politics of media reform in Australia. In the period prior to the late 1980s, the politics of media reform largely revolved around the scope to extend the social contract, or for greater social regulation of private broadcast media resources, particularly in the areas of public participation and accountability, Australian content requirements and children’s programming. From the late 1980s, however, new issues entered the policy domain, such as the implications of microeconomic reform and competition policy, the scope for integrating media policy into broad national cultural policy frameworks, and the 232

Transcript of Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Page 1: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Chapter Six

New Services, New Policies? Neo-Liberal Policy

Discourse and the Broadcasting Services Act 1992

The late 1980s and early 1990s marked a transitional period in the politics of

media reform in Australia. In the period prior to the late 1980s, the politics of

media reform largely revolved around the scope to extend the social contract, or

for greater social regulation of private broadcast media resources, particularly in

the areas of public participation and accountability, Australian content

requirements and children’s programming. From the late 1980s, however, new

issues entered the policy domain, such as the implications of microeconomic

reform and competition policy, the scope for integrating media policy into broad

national cultural policy frameworks, and the implications of international law and

trade agreements for domestic policy-making.

Broadcasting Policy and Microeconomic Reform

The reform of broadcasting policy in Australia was part of the

‘microeconomic reform’ agenda, identified as a priority by the third Hawke Labor

government (1987-90), with the Department of Transport and Communications

(DOTAC) being one of a number of so-called ‘super-departments’ created in this

period. DOTAC identified its purpose as being to ‘support the restructuring and

232

Page 2: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

growth of the Australian economy by accelerating change towards a transport and

communications sector which is competitive, innovative, and efficient’ (DOTAC

1988). The Department’s portfolio included a disparate range of activities, such as

aviation, road and rail transport, shipping, telecommunications, broadcasting and

spectrum management. Significantly, many of these areas had been characterised

either by monopoly public ownership, or by what Robert Horwitz (1989) has

described as ‘price-and-entry’ regulatory controls, where an industry-specific

regulator established administrative mechanisms for price-setting, and limited

competition in order to ensure stability in the provision of basic infrastructure for

other sectors of the economy.

The growing significance of microeconomic reform in Australia arose

from the perception that, in spite of the government’s significant tightening of

fiscal, monetary and incomes policies in the mid-1980s, the economy had not

restructured sufficiently to overcome balance-of payments constraints, pointing to

a need for ‘continued progress at the microeconomic level to improve efficiency

and increase supply responsiveness’ (OECD 1988: 9; cf. OECD 1990).

Microeconomic reform was defined as being ‘about making markets work better,

improving incentives, and enhancing the effectiveness of government operations’

(EPAC 1990: 3). Microeconomic reform was also bound up with public sector

reform, partly because it created pressures for the corporatisation or privatisation

of government business enterprises (GBEs), linked to changes to Commonwealth

administration associated with the growing influence of ‘new public management’

233

Page 3: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

practices and discourses derived from the private sector (Halligan et. al. 1992; cf.

Hughes 1994).

An important factor that stimulated change in broadcasting policy was the

transformation of telecommunications in the context of convergence. It became

increasingly apparent through the 1980s that telecommunications was central to

information-based economies, and that the traditional model of public monopolies

or highly regulated private providers providing broadly equitable access to a plain

old telephone service (POTS) was becoming increasingly untenable in light of

technological changes and changes in consumer demand (Westerway 1990). As a

consequence, governments throughout the world were rethinking the bases of

telecommunications regulation, as a shift towards competition, value-added

services such as mobile telephony and economy-wide expectations about the

quality of communications infrastructure took place (Collins and Murroni 1996).

The shift in policy away from restricting competition in order to achieve a series

of trade-offs between various categories of telecommunications users in the

‘public interest’, to policies designed to promote competition and network

development, would impact upon broadcasting policy in the course of the 1980s

and 1990s.

A difficulty with microeconomic reform as a general category, as Michael

Stutchbury noted, was that it ‘was as general as it was new in the Australian

policy lexicon’, and ‘could be applied to any policy measures aimed at improving

234

Page 4: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

the nuts-and-bolts efficiency of the economy in supplying goods and services’

(Stutchbury 1990: 70). Of the various portfolio areas within DOTAC, the area

with which broadcasting had its greatest affinities was telecommunications. Both

sectors involve the provision of infrastructure that is ‘not only is crucial for

commerce, but also constitutes the public realm of ideas and discussion’ (Horwitz

1989: 8); both had a history of restrictions on competition in order to achieve

policy trade offs, such as cross-subsidies to benefit rural and domestic users; and

both had experienced great change in their means of carriage and the types of

services that could be delivered as a result of digitisation and technological

convergence.

To observe the similarities between broadcasting and telecommunications

is, however, also to draw attention to their differences. First, broadcasting has not

had the same centrality to national economic performance as telecommunications,

as the latter activity is tied up with provision of a networked information

infrastructure. Second, public broadcasters such as the ABC and SBS do not have

a comparable status as GBEs to a telecommunications common carrier such as

Telecom, nor do they have such a dominant role in the sector. Broadcasting in

Australia had been an area dominated by the private sector and the logic of market

competition, mitigated by government regulation, in a way not comparable to the

public monopoly status of Telecom. Finally, much of what took place in

broadcasting regulation and broadcast media policy was difficult to fit into the

general ambit of microeconomic reform. Davis (1990) notes that generating good

235

Page 5: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

relations with media proprietors was as much a part of media policy under the

Hawke Labor government as questions of governance, and the government’s

reforms of media ownership regulations in 1987 were not particularly related to

competition policy principles. Moreover, primary responsibility for regulation

continued to rest with the Australian Broadcasting Tribunal, as an independent

statutory body whose key activities were linked more to ‘public trust’ conceptions

of media policy than microeconomic reform priorities.

DOTAC and the New Policy Discourse

A focus on the economic dimensions of broadcasting policy was not a unique

development resulting from the establishment of DOTAC. Its predecessor, the

Department of Communications, had commissioned work into economic aspects

of communications, and there had been moves to enhance competition in non-

basic telecommunications services markets since the Davidson Report

recommended greater competition in 1982 (Given and Goggin 2000). What was

unique, however, was the consistency of DOTAC’s economic focus, and its

attempts to align broadcasting policy to a whole-of-department approach which

was about ‘promoting greater industry competition to improve efficiency in a

framework where the benefits can be passed on to users’, and ‘adopting

regulatory arrangements by which competitive structures are supported … [and]

industries are able to take full advantage of technological change’ (DOTAC 1992:

iii). DOTAC was particularly concerned with the separation of structural

236

Page 6: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

regulation, or the conditions governing entry into the broadcasting sector, from

program or content regulation. It was also concerned with the development of

new broadcasting services in order to increase diversity in the broadcasting

system.

Rather than understanding ‘public interest’ regulation of broadcaster

conduct, program content and program standards as being the necessary quid pro

quo for the ownership by a few of a scarce public resource (spectrum space) and a

highly influential communications medium, it was argued that in various DOTAC

documents that concentration of ownership and broadcaster influence were the

consequence of the regulatory structure itself, as it created artificially high

barriers to entry for potential new competitors. The Review of Broadcasting

Regulation: Discussion Paper (DOTAC 1989a) indicated the change in emphasis,

and its implications for broadcasting regulation. The Review identified a series of

problems with the Broadcasting Act 1942, including: its difficulties in being

adapted for the development of new services or new delivery technologies; the

complex and inflexible nature of the legislation; the time, resources and legal

input involved in relatively minor regulatory matters; and the incapacity of the

Australian Broadcasting Tribunal to develop mechanisms to ensure regulatory

compliance, in spite of its apparently extensive discretionary powers able to be

applied in the licence renewal process. Of these, the question of new technologies

and new services had the greatest significance in the Review. It was argued that

regulation of content needed to be dealt with separately to regulation of

237

Page 7: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

technologies of delivery, since distinctions between services and their content on

the basis of their delivery technology would become less relevant in the context of

convergence. A similar set of policy emphases could also be seen in DOTAC’s

report on the introduction of pay television in Australia (DOTAC 1989b). This

report argued for a regulatory approach based upon promoting competition and

reducing barriers to entry. It was argued that the outcome of such pro-competition

policies would be the expansion of channels and services, that would produce

both greater diversity of content and consumer choice that would ‘increase the

power of the viewer to influence programming’ (DOTAC 1989b: xvii).

Observers of the Department in this period believed that it had a strongly

interventionist agenda for broadcasting policy, and that its emphasis was upon a

generic program of microeconomic reform rather than the specifics of the

broadcasting industry. Anne Britton, National Secretary of the MEAA at this

time, believed that the Broadcasting Services Act 1992 was essentially designed

‘to make the networks very happy’, and that it was also consistent with the

positions of key individuals in the Department who favoured ‘a very hands-off

broadcasting regime’.1 Christina Spurgeon, who was then a researcher with the

Communications Law Centre, recalled the personal realisation in 1990 that the

review of broadcasting legislation was not simply ‘about tidying up a

cumbersome piece of legislation’, but rather ‘about repealing the public trust

model of regulation’. 2 Jock Given noted that the clear agenda of key people in

DOTAC, combined with high turnover of Ministers in this period, enabled

238

Page 8: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

significant policy entrepreneurship where key individuals could ‘drive through

quite radical reform of the legislation … in a very short period of time’, during a

period when ‘there was not a lot of competition around for other ideas’.3 Tony

Shaw has questioned the degree to which policy bureaucrats could acquire such

control, partly because decision-making powers finally rest with the relevant

Minister, Cabinet and the Parliament, but also because of accountability processes

‘which hardly give bureaucrats much chance of influencing outcomes in a non-

transparent fashion’.4 By contrast, Anne Britton claimed that, due to the

complexity of the issues involved, ‘the bureaucrats in the Department were very

powerful’, and that Ministers at the time ‘basically delivered what the bureaucrats

in the Department of Transport and Communications dished up’.5 Such

observations are consistent with Trevor Barr’s (2000) argument that

communications policy in Australia had ceased to have a sense of strategic

thinking and national vision, instead involving the pursuit of competition as an

end in itself. It is also consistent with the critique of ‘economic rationalism’ as a

driver of public policy.

The Limits of ‘Economic Rationalism’ as an Explanatory

Framework

A common assessment of the late 1980s and early 1990s in Australia has been

that the cultural priorities of broadcasting policy were colonised by economic

priorities, and citizenship discourses were subsumed into those of consumerism

239

Page 9: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

and the market. Jo Hawke argued that, in the period from the emergence of

DOTAC in 1987 to the drafting of the Broadcasting Services Act in 1992, ‘policy

was no longer a matter of reconciling public and private interests but of

reconciling competing approaches to regulating for private interests’ (Hawke

1995: 41). Stuart Cunningham argued that the DOTAC Future Directions study

was based upon a scenario for media futures where ‘consumer sovereignty and

infrastructure provision occupy primary places over production industry

opportunities and wider social objectives’ (Cunningham 1992a: 114). Tim Dwyer

expressed similar concerns about policies for the introduction of pay television in

Australia, believing that they marked a ‘trend in communications media policy

objectives away from cultural, social, and overtly political ones and towards

industrial (or economic) ones’, whereby ‘governments and their policy

instruments are looking increasingly to ways of adjusting regulatory regimes with

an eye to securing favourable outcomes for the most influential policy players in a

changing communications environment’ (Dwyer 1990: 157).

Michael Pusey’s (1991) critique of ‘economic rationalism’ was a very

influential interpretation of the influence of economic priorities on Australian

public policy formation in the late 1980s and early 1990s. Pusey’s analysis of the

ideas and values of members of the Commonwealth Senior Executive Service

(SES) over the 1986-89 period traced changes in its composition, that saw

‘economic’ departments such as Treasury and Finance acquire greater policy

influence. Pusey associated this trend with a turning away from the historical

240

Page 10: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

priorities of a ‘nation-building state’ towards the reductionist calculus of

economic rationalism:

The state apparatus is caught within projections of reality that give

primacy to ‘the economy’, second place to the political order, and third

place to the social order. Indeed, perhaps the most central finding is that,

since the 1970s, reality has been turned upside down and society has been

recast as the object of politics … Further, society has been represented as

some sort of stubbornly resisting sludge, as a ‘generic externality’ and

even as an idealized opponent of the economy. The tail that is the economy

wags the dog that is society. (Pusey 1991: 10)

Pusey’s work drew attention to a consensus that emerged among

economists, policy-makers, federal Labor government Cabinet ministers, and

other influential policy agents (eg. journalists) about the merits of microeconomic

reform, competition policy, and free trade. It rested, however, upon some dubious

assumptions about both the Labor governments of the 1980s and 1990s, and about

government more generally. In light of the importance of the Hawke and Keating

Labor governments’ various Accords with the Australian Council of Trade

Unions (ACTU), which retained centralised and administrative systems of wage-

fixing and involved tripartite decision-making processes in areas such as industry

policy, microeconomic reform or ‘economic rationalism’ could only be seen as

one element of economic policy-making by the Labor governments of the 1980s

241

Page 11: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

and early 1990s (Keating and Dixon 1989; Schott 1991; Argy 1992). Pusey’s

claim that Australian public policy had historically possessed a ‘nation-building’

orientation was also historically contestable (Wanna 1992). In broadcasting

policy, to take one example, commitments to national culture and public

participation were of much greater significance in the 1970s and 1980s than was

the case in the 1950s and 1960s, contrary to the historical trajectory presented by

Pusey. Moreover, a commitment to a planned and coherent national cultural

policy in Australia is very much a creature of the Labor governments of the 1980s

and 1990s, particularly with the Keating government’s Creative Nation cultural

policy statement released in 1994 (DoCA 1994).

Pusey’s argument played out a familiar historical debate between

economy and society or culture as competing discourses of value. The problem

with such arguments, which go back to early nineteenth century Romantic

philosophy, and which, for theorists such as Barbara Hernstein Smith, have

argued have constitute ‘a qualifying mark of the contemporary professional

humanist’ (Smith 1988: 126), are twofold. First, the concern for social

management and the development of economy in the practice of government have

developed alongside each other, rather than in fundamental opposition. Second,

the ethical-normative and the calculative-technical dimensions of policy have

typically been developed in tandem, rather than being in basic opposition to one

1 Interview with Anne Britton, 28 September 1998. 2 Interview with Christina Spurgeon, 28 October 1997. 3 Interview with Jock Given, 18 November 1997. 4 Interview with Tony Shaw, 23 September 1998.5 Interview with Anne Britton, 28 September 1998.

242

Page 12: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

another (Burchell 1994a; Hunter 1993/4). Burchell (1994b) argued that the debate

about ‘economic rationalism’ was fatally flawed by its demand that protagonists

are ‘for’ or ‘against’ markets, or ‘for’ or ‘against’ government intervention. This

reflected a tendency to understand policies as more or less transparent

manifestations of ideologies, whereas in practice government policies typically

combine a normative dimension with a practical and technical dimension that has

been about constructing or problematising a social domain in order to render it

governable and amenable to change through the application of policy.

The Politics of ‘Labor’s Long Decade’ in Government

Implementation of the microeconomic reform agenda by Labor governments led

to an extensive debate about whether these governments had betrayed their social

democratic heritage. For critics, such as Graham Maddox (1989) and Dean

Jaensch (1989), the period marked a break with Labor traditions, as consensus

politics and the move towards becoming ‘a “catch-all” party’ (Jaensch 1989: 154)

undermined the legitimacy of the Australian Labor Party as a political alternative,

committed to the possibility of radical reforms. Claims that the Hawke-Keating

Labor governments had betrayed a Labor heritage, and were at odds with social-

democratic political priorities, were contested. Carol Johnson argued that,

historically, Labor governments have always been primarily concerned with

developing ‘a healthy capitalist economy and a humanized capitalist society’

(Johnson 1986: 1). Paul Keating himself, while Treasurer, argued that the

243

Page 13: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

government’s priorities were consistent with the Labor tradition in Australia of

being ‘a pragmatic party interested in economic progress and practical social

reform … [that] owes little or nothing to external influences, be they social

democratic, Marxist or whatever’ (Keating 1987: 174-175).

The debates about ‘economic rationalism’ and ‘Labor’s long decade’ of

political power in Australia (Beilharz 1994) were linked, and drew attention to,

wider international debates about the nature of contemporary social democratic

and Labour parties. It has been noted that such parties typically combine a moral

and normative commitment to egalitarian and democratic social change with the

strategic decisions to seek these goals through participation in existing liberal-

democratic political institutions, the development of cross-class alliances, and

acceptance of the framework of a capitalist market economy (Turner 1986;

Mathews 1989). Within an international spectrum of left-reformist political

parties, the Australian Labor Party has occupied a middle position between the

European social democratic and ‘Euro-communist’ parties, which have a stronger

historical commitment to reforming capitalism and more extensive links to the

labour movement, and ‘catch-all’ parties such as the US Democratic Party that

have had minimal ideological commitments and little inclination towards

reforming capitalism. In a number of respects the debates about ‘Labor’s long

decade’ in power were about the extent to which it was possible to use Labor’s

electoral success and labor movement links to move the party towards social

democracy (Dow et. al. 1984; Mathews 1986, 1989), or whether its electoral

244

Page 14: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

success was based upon its effacing of reformism towards becoming a ‘catch-all’

party (Jaensch 1989; Macintyre 1991).

This question cannot be addressed in isolation from Labor’s response to

precipitous deterioration in Australia’s external economic balances in the early

1980s. In the period between 1980-81 and 1985-86, Australia’s current account

deficit trebled, the economic terms of trade deteriorated by 20 per cent between

1984 and 1986, and the value of the Australian dollar (which was ‘floated’ on

international financial markets in late 1983) fall by 40 per cent against the Trade-

Weighted Index (TWI) between 1984 and 1986 (Kearney 1993). Such

developments destabilized long-standing institutional arrangements between

competing interests and marked a crisis for ‘policy settlements’ in the Australian

political economy. This decline over a five-year period was linked to a longer-

term deterioration in the relative performance of the Australian economy, as its

economic structures proved increasingly unresponsive to what Hugh Emy

described as ‘a new kind of global trading economy … characterised by an

accelerating rate of technological change and growing competition for export

markets’ (Emy 1993: 44). These developments led the then Treasurer, Paul

Keating, to issue a famous warning in 1986 that, in the absence of measures to

promote export growth, constrain spending on imports and reduce public and

private sector debt, Australia would become a ‘banana republic’.

245

Page 15: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The ‘banana republic’ crisis of the mid-1980s provides an episodic marker

of the demise of particular historic patterns of policy formation in Australia.

Richard Higgott has observed that the response of the Labor governments to the

deteriorating international situation was ‘primarily responsive rather than

resistive’ (Higgott 1991: 15), where structural adjustment was seen as providing

an opportunity for domestic policy reform towards market liberalisation, as well

as initiatives to reform international trading relations, rather than seeking to

protect the domestic economic structure from international competition (see Table

6.1):

Table 6.1

Adjustment Strategies to External Imbalances

International DomesticOffensive Create new international

trade regimeChange domestic economic structure

Australian Examples

Strengthen GATT Advance APEC Oppose

bilateralism

Industry restructuring Tariff reduction Microeconomic reform

Defensive Maintain or protect international trade regime, or extend through bilateralism or regionalism

Protect domestic economic structure

Examples Regional trade blocs

Trade sanctions

Subsidies Non-tariff barriers

Source: Higgott 1991: 25-26.

246

Page 16: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Francis Castles argued that the external crisis of the mid-1980s marked the

final nail in the coffin of the program of domestic defence, and attempts to

insulate high wage levels through high levels of tariff protection for the

manufacturing sector. Future responses to economic vulnerability would need to

pursue what Castles described as the social democratic option of domestic

compensation, where active labour market policies and a more extensive approach

to social welfare would enable the labour movement to respond proactively rather

than defensively to structural adjustment issues. The Australian Council of Trade

Unions (ACTU) came to similar conclusions in its strategic policy document,

Australia Reconstructed (ACTU 1987). Bob Catley, who was a federal Labor MP

from 1991 to 1996 as well as a Professor of Politics at the University of Adelaide,

argued that the external economic crises of the 1980s had revealed the bankruptcy

of the early 20th century political settlement that had created an unsustainable

‘dual economy’ structure, between a commodity-exporting sector oriented

towards world markets, and protected and regulated domestic industries that were

reluctant or unable to become oriented towards a more competitive economic

environment. Catley proposed that it was only a Labor government, less

encumbered by ties to particular corporate interests than its ‘pro-business’ Liberal

opponents, that could undertake ‘the task … of globalising Australian capitalism,

destroying its hybrid nature and making it internationally competitive, internally

market-driven, externally in balance with the world economy and institutionally

oriented to efficiency’ (Catley 1996: 212-213).6

247

Page 17: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

‘Advanced Liberal’ Modes of Governance

One of the difficulties with the ‘economic rationalism’ debate in Australia was the

dichotomising of markets versus government, and government failure versus

market failure. This not only produced a ‘dialogue of the deaf’ among its

participants, but also misread a significant shift within modes of governance that

was indicated by the new policy agenda of structural adjustment and

microeconomic reform in the late 1980s and early 1990s. Rather than seeing these

developments as ‘the simple translation of neoliberal ideology into practice’

(Burchell 1994b: 329), a better approach is to see them as part of a shift within

liberal forms of government, towards what has been termed neo-liberalism or

advanced liberalism.

It was observed in Chapter Two that recent work on liberal forms of

government has proposed that liberalism marks the emergence of a distinctive

ethos of government, which stresses the need to set limits to state authority in

order to govern a society, or a national space, more effectively. Liberalism is thus

not simply seen as a political ideology, but also as a form of political rationality,

or what Colin Gordon defines as ‘a system of thinking about the nature of the

practice of government (who can govern; what governing is; or who is governed),

capable of making some form of that activity thinkable and practicable both to its

practitioners and to those upon whom it is practised’ (Gordon 1991: 3). Stuart

Hall has argued that, historically, liberalism as a political ideology has

248

Page 18: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

accommodated a wide range of perspectives on policy and the role of the state,

from utilitarianism, laissez-faire economic principles and the ‘nightwatchman’

state, to social democracy, Keynesian economics and the interventionist state

(Hall 1986).

One of the distinctive features of liberal government as a form of political

rationality is that it ‘inaugurates a continual dissatisfaction with government … a

recurrent diagnosis of failure coupled with a recurrent demand to govern better’

(Rose 1996: 47). In this respect, liberal government is never simply the translation

of liberal political ideology into governmental practice; rather, there is a complex

interchange between certain normative principles of rule, a series of governmental

techniques and practices, and the self-conduct of those who are both the objects

and the subjects of government. The latter group includes not only individual

citizens, but also social and economic agents such as corporations, trade unions,

institutions of civil society, etc. The notion of ‘economic government’ thus has a

double meaning for liberalism as a political rationality: it is government informed

by economic principles and guided by the realisation of economic outcomes (e.g.

national economic growth, or improved international trade performance). But it is

also a form of government that aims to economise on the costs of realising its own

programs, by influencing the conduct of social and economic agents rather than

directing exerting its own authority (Gordon 1991; Burchell 1996). In this respect,

it is perhaps not surprising that the critique of existing regulations should be

249

Page 19: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

associated with microeconomic reform, and the development of new forms of

economy in the conduct of government.

Nikolas Rose (1996) proposed that neo-liberalism drew upon a diverse

range of critiques of ‘social government’ from across the political spectrum, and

aimed to move beyond these various ‘rhetorics of reaction’ to devising a new

series of strategies and techniques of government that ‘govern without governing

society’, and ‘govern through the regulated and accountable choices of

autonomous agents’ (Rose 1996: 61). Similarly, Graham Burchell (1996) argued

that neo-liberalism, or advanced liberalism, had two key elements. First, it

entailed a critique of so-called ‘social government’, characterised by the welfare

state and extensive regulation of markets, on the basis that such a framework is

detrimental to economic performance as it leads to excessive growth of the state

sector. Second, it has a more positive dimension, in that it calls for governmental

activism aimed at constructing the legal, institutional and cultural conditions that

will promote competition and entrepreneurial behaviour. This is what has become

known as a enterprise culture, and involved ‘the generalisation of an “enterprise

form” to all forms of conduct - to the conduct of organisations hitherto seen as

being non-economic, to the conduct of government and to the conduct of

individuals themselves’ (Burchell 1996: 28-29).

These arguments overlapped with analyses of the rise of governance,

defined as ‘the totality of institutional arrangements - including rules and rule-

250

Page 20: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

making agents- that regulate transactions inside and across the boundaries of an

economic system’ (Hollingsworth et. al. 1994: 5). Governance is a term applied

to new institutional arrangements between public, corporate and other non-

government organisations, that seek to transcend oppositions between state and

market by developing mechanisms for negotiated economic coordination, such as

interpersonal networks, associations and inter-organisational frameworks

(Hollingsworth et. al. 1994). Bob Jessop (1998) argued that these new modes of

governance and institutional self-organisation arose from the existence of

increasing interdependencies between public and private institutions, and were

aimed at ‘supplemening market exchange and government hierarchy with

institutionalized negotiations to mobilize consensus and build mutual

understanding’ between agents within particular sectoral and national institutional

sites (Jessop 1998: 34, 35).

The New Policy Discourse of Broadcasting: Diversity,

Competition and New Services

251

Page 21: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The period from the establishment of DOTAC in 1987 to the passing of the

Broadcasting Services Act 1992 saw a shift in the dominant policy discourse of

Australian broadcasting. This shift arose from developments within the Australian

broadcast media policy community itself, particularly the self-defined role of

DOTAC bureaucrats and some associated academics as ‘policy entrepreneurs’,

able to utilise their ‘outsider’ status in order to transform the Australian broadcast

media policy system. Policy transformations in this period were also shaped by

the emergence of new forms of policy discourse such as competition policy, as

well as the major technological and economic changes taking place in

broadcasting worldwide.

Diversity was a concept that was widely used in debates about broadcast

media policy reform in the period leading to the passing of the Broadcasting

Services Act. Diversity in the media has generally been considered to be an

appropriate goal of Australian media policy, although those committed to it have

not always been referring to the same thing. Diversity has been variously seen as

central to political democracy, consumer choice, national culture, cultural

pluralism and the public interest (Flew 1994). A recurrent feature of official

policy statements of the period was the perceived connection between the

promotion of new forms of broadcasting service and greater diversity in

broadcasting. In the Explanatory Memorandum to the Broadcasting Services Act,

Bob Collins, the Minister for Transport and Communications, indicated that,

under the new legislation, ‘diversity in the range of services is encouraged by a

252

Page 22: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

more open planning regime that is expected to increase the availability of

services, and by a licensing regime which is designed to accelerate the

introduction of services and encourage the introduction of the new “niche”

services’.7 This was consistent with the statement of a previous Minister, Kim

Beazley, who claimed that in the 1990s, ‘the public will be able to choose from a

whole range of services, delivered by satellite, cable or airwaves, which will

range from general appeal services down to specific interest, interactive services

… [that] will contribute to a degree of choice in information and entertainment

sources undreamt of twenty years ago’ (Beazley 1991). The Deputy Secretary of

DOTAC, Mike Hutchinson, was confident that reform of broadcasting legislation

would promote ‘a more competitive, open, regulatory regime with greater

commercial freedom for enterprises and services to respond and adjust but with

rules in place to safeguard the public interest. Such an approach would be

consistent with the Government's approach to regulation in other industries’

(Hutchinson 1990).

These views reflected a shift in the dominant understanding of how best to

achieve diversity in its various forms, away from approaches that stress diversity

within media institutions, to those that stress diversity of media service types. The

approach that saw a worldwide decline in significance during the 19080s and

1990s was what Denis McQuail (1986) termed internal diversity, or a system

where the diversity and plurality of the society and its tastes and interests are

represented within a single broadcasting organisation and its programming.

253

Page 23: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Instead, an approach had come to prevail that McQuail termed external diversity,

and Eli Noam (1991) defined as open television, where diversity in the

broadcasting system was seen as resulting from the existence of a range of media

which present different types of programming so as to appeal to distinct and

discrete sections of the audience and community.

Noam contrasted open television with what he termed the television of

privilege, a term that he used to describe regulated limited-channel television. The

implication of ‘open television’ for regulatory agencies was that a conduct

regulation approach would need to be replaced by a structural regulation

approach. The conduct regulation approach was seen as one where limits on

competition and barriers to entry existed alongside a powerful regulatory body, an

extensive framework of programming and other conduct regulations, and

sanctions for non-compliance. By contrast, the aim of a structural regulation

approach was ‘to create a regulatory environment which ensures that participants

have no choice but to act competitively’ (Noam 1991: 91). In its guide to the

Broadcasting Services Act 1992, DOTAC described the new approach as one of

‘regulation by exception’, where ‘instead of having a plethora of rules and

obligations set out … the new rules set out clear boundary conditions for different

types of service … it is only the boundaries which need to be monitored for

transgression’ (DOTAC 1993: 1-2).

254

Page 24: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The development of national competition policy in Australia post-dated

the government’s commitment to microeconomic reform, which was informing

broadcasting policy reform, but shared and extended its concern for structural

adjustment and enhancing the efficiency and dynamism of all areas of the

economy. The Hilmer Committee released its report into national competition

policy in 1993 (Report of the Independent Committee of Inquiry 1993);

subsequently, the Commonwealth, state and territory governments agreed in April

1995 to a Competition Principles Agreement (CPA), with the Competition Policy

Reform Act 1995 being passed with supporting state and territory application

legislation. National competition policy marked an important shift in legislative

approaches to competition in Australia in three respects. First, while it adopted the

competitive conduct rules found in the provisions of Part IV of the Trade

Practices Act 1974, designed to limit anti-competitive conduct by firms, it

expanded the purview of competition policy to include: reforming regulations

which unjustifiably restrict competition; reforming the structure of public

monopolies to facilitate competition; ensuring third-party access to facilities that

are essential for competition; and fostering “competitive neutrality” between

government-owned and private businesses in areas where they compete. Second,

national competition policy was premised upon the assumption that ‘the general

desirability of permitting competition was so well established that those who wish

to restrict or inhibit competition should bear the burden of why that is justified in

the public interest’ (Report of the National Committee of Inquiry 1993: 18). In the

255

Page 25: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

1995 Competition Principles Agreement, this became a guiding principle that

legislation should not restrict competition unless it can be demonstrated that:

The benefits of the restriction to the community as a whole outweigh

the costs; and

The objectives of the legislation can only be achieved by restricting

competition.

Third, national competition policy was designed to respond to a perceived

limitation of the microeconomic reform or structural adjustment process, in that it

was largely focused upon reform in the internationally traded goods and services

sectors, rather than those sectors with some degree of natural protection from

international competition. As a result, reform had largely proceeded on a sector-

by-sector basis through a diverse range of industry-specific agencies, without an

overarching national approach that presented opportunities to progress reform

more broadly and minimise the costs of industry-based regulation (Report of the

National Committee of Inquiry 1993: xviii). Competition policy had a rapid

impact upon the cognate field of telecommunications in Australia after the

passing of the Telecommunications Act 1991, with its advocates arguing that it

had achieved its goals of lowering prices to consumers (Ergas 1994; Albon 1994).

The OECD also saw competition policy as increasingly relevant to broadcasting,

as market forces played a growing role in determining the supply of broadcast

services (OECD 1993).

256

Page 26: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Shifting the burden of proof away from those calling for regulatory change

in order to increase competition to those seeking to justify restrictions upon

competition had the potential to challenge the social contract in broadcasting.

Barriers to entry for new competitors had long been the corollary of affirmative or

public interest regulations of commercial free-to-air broadcasters in the areas of

content and program standards. The continuing significance of such restrictions

was established with the government’s decision to place a moratorium on the

introduction of pay TV in 1986, and the limitation of the maximum number of

commercial broadcasters in a licence area to three under Section 28 of the

Broadcasting Services Act, subject to a review by 1997 of national benefits from

an increase in the number of services, under Section 215(2) of the Act.

The rise of new broadcast policy discourses was also closely linked to the

explosive growth in new broadcasting services worldwide, even though

trajectories of change differed across national broadcasting systems. The most

striking feature was the dramatic growth in the number of television channels and

types of broadcasting service, and particularly the growth of private broadcasting

(see Table 6.2):

Table 6.2

Growth of Television Channels in OECD Europe

Public Private Total Satellite Cable channels

1980 44 18 621990 47 84 131 38

257

Page 27: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

1995 64 180 244 262 463Source: Cairncross 1998: 69.

Such changes were driven by a combination of:

Technological changes, such as the capacity of new delivery

technologies such as broadband cable, satellite and MDS (microwave

delivery systems) to provide multichannel services across distances

without use of additional spectrum;

Economic changes, such as the willingness of consumer to subscribe to

multichannel pay services, or the scope for advertising revenue to

expand to use the new services as well as existing terrestrial

broadcasting services;

Political changes, whereby regulations were changed in order to allow

the entry of new services, often with fewer regulatory requirements on

program content than the incumbent broadcasters.

The mix of forces for change varied across countries and across

broadcasting systems. In Australia, it is apparent that technological changes were

in themselves less significant than the political context in which decisions about

the introduction of new services would be made. The most obvious case study is

that of pay television, where the first services did not commence broadcasting

until 1995, even though the technological capacity for delivery of such services

had existed since the late 1970s, and every public inquiry since 1982 had

recommended its immediate introduction (Flew and Spurgeon 2000).

258

Page 28: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The Broadcasting Services Act 1992 and its Impact: A Case Study

in Neo-Liberal Governance?

The Broadcasting Services Act 1992 was passed through Parliament, with

amendments, on 14 May 1993. The Act combined a Statement of Objectives that

aimed to codify the goals and principles of broadcasting policy, with a

commitment to ‘light touch’ regulation intended to promote greater competition,

new technologies and new services.8 It promoted differential regulation of

broadcasting services in the areas of ownership, content standards and program

standards, on the basis of their perceived ‘degree of influence’.9 The legislation

allowed automatic licence renewal for five years for commercial broadcasters

unless ‘special circumstances’ existed, and also proposed a system of ‘class

licenses’ for subscription-based and open narrowcasters. Consistent with the ‘light

touch’ and ‘degree of influence’ principles, laws regarding foreign ownership and

cross-media ownership differed between broadcasting services, with strong

controls for commercial broadcasters and less stringent controls for other

broadcasting services. The ABA would be empowered, as the ABT was, to set

program standards for children's programs and Australian content under Section

122 of the Act, but responsibility for program standards and complaints would be

devolved to industry self-regulatory bodies representing the various broadcasting

sectors, through the development of Industry Codes of Practice that would be

approved and registered by the ABA. Finally, there was a requirement under

259

Page 29: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Section 160 of the Act that the ABA perform its functions in a manner consistent

with the objects of the Act and the ‘light touch’ regulatory principle, ministerial

directions, and Australia’s international treaty obligations.

In its guide to the legislation, DOTAC stressed the extent to which the Act

was consistent with the government’s microeconomic reform agenda. DOTAC

believed that the new Act marked a move away from the closely prescriptive

approach of the Broadcasting Act 1942, providing a framework for promoting an

efficient and competitive broadcasting sector, and an Australian broadcasting

industry that could adapt to new commercial and technological realities (DOTAC

1993: 1). There is considerable commentary available on the Broadcasting

Services Act 1992 (Armstrong and Lindsay 1991; CLC/CAMLA 1991; Sinclair

1991; Davies and Spurgeon 1992; Hawke 1995). The remainder of this chapter

will therefore focus upon the extent to which the new legislation and policy

framework transformed the mode of governance of broadcasting in Australia in

the directions that DOTAC and others believed that it would.

The Impact of the Broadcasting Services Act 1992 on Media Policy

Participants

The Commercial Free-to-Air Broadcasting Industry

260

Page 30: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The commercial free-to-air broadcasting industry was the major beneficiary of

broadcasting policy reform in Australia. Policy demands that had been advocated

by FACTS and the commercial networks since the 1970s, such as an industry-

based approach to program standards, the elimination of licence renewal hearings

and greater certainty of tenure over broadcast licences, had largely been met

under the new legislation. From the point of view of the drafters of the

Broadcasting Services Act, the trade off was to be that ‘the industry’ would no

longer be the small number of commercial free-to-air broadcasters represented by

FACTS, but would instead be a more diverse and stratified grouping of

commercial broadcasters, national broadcasters, community broadcasters,

subscription broadcasters and subscription open narrowcasters. The aim was that

the degree of regulation would be commensurate with the potential influence of

the broadcaster over Australian culture, community standards and public opinion,

and that regulatory resources would be better directed to the media of greatest

potential influence. The aim was also that new types of broadcast service

providers would take advantage of the opportunities presented by new delivery

technologies to directly compete for audiences with the commercial networks, as

had been the case in many countries since the 1980s.

It is not apparent that the adoption of a ‘structural’ approach to regulation

led to the emergence of a more competitive Australian broadcasting environment.

An analysis of the economic performance of Australian commercial television

between 1986 and 1995 shows that, after the crises of ‘entrepreneurial television’

261

Page 31: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

and the impact of economic downturn in the early 1990s, the period from 1992-

1998 was one where the commercial networks were able to earn profits well

above the average across all industries in the Australian economy, as well as

continuing to accrue significant economic rents, particularly in the capital city

markets (see Table 6.3):

6 Catley’s argument that the ALP is better able to pursue policies in the overall interests of capital accumulation because of its distance from particular business interests was, interestingly, first developed by the Communist Party of Australia in the 1940s (Kuhn 1991: 62).

7 Broadcasting Services Bill 1992, Explanatory Memorandum, circulated with the authority of Senator Bob Collins, Minister for Transport and Communications, p. 9.

8 The Objectives of broadcasting Policy under Section 3 of the Broadcasting Services Act included: diversity of services; promotion of competition; diversity of control; Australian control; promotion of Australian identity, character and cultural diversity; high quality and innovative programming; fair and accurate coverage; respect for community standards; providing an effective means of addressing complaints; and protection of children.

9 The ABA was empowered to classify new services as being within six sectors including: national broadcasters; commercial broadcasters; community broadcasters; subscription broadcasters; subscription narrowcasters; open narrowcasters.

262

Page 32: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Table 6.3

Rates of Return for Australian Commercial TV 1986-95 and

Economy-Wide Indicators

Ratio of earnings (1) to tangible assets (2) in

commercial TV

Ratio of earnings (3) to total assets: all

industries

10 year bond rate

(4)

Capital cities All regional1986-87 8.6 28.0 9.6 12.81987-88 14.7 31.6 10.4 12.01988-89 8.4 33.2 11.3 13.51989-90 9.3 37.8 10.2 13.41990-91 2.1 14.5 7.4 11.21991-92 27.5 12.1 6.0 8.91992-93 24.6 12.4 7.3 7.41993-94 30.8 14.3 8.0 9.71994-95 31.0 15.3 na 9.21995-96 34.2 16.1 na 8.91996-97 30.0 14.5 na 7.11997-98 20.2 10.2 na 5.6

Sources: BTCE (1996: 78); Productivity Commission (1999: 42).

(1) Earnings are defined as earnings before interest and tax (EBIT).(2) A distinction is made in broadcasting between tangible assets, or program rights, property and equipment, and intangible assets, of which the primary one is the value of the broadcast licence itself. (3) Earnings are defined as earnings before interest and tax (EBIT).(4) As of end of financial year ie. 30 June of the end-year.

The three major commercial networks had long maintained that some

restrictions on competition, and particularly on barriers to entry, had been a

necessary condition for the realisation of ‘public interest’ objectives as part of

their social contract with regulators and the community. Such a principle was

263

Page 33: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

enshrined in Section 28 of the Broadcasting Services Act, which required that the

ABA was not to allocate more than three commercial television broadcasting

licences in a licence area prior to a review in 1997. This was despite the

requirement of national competition policy that the onus was upon those arguing

for restrictions on competition on the basis of ‘public interest’ criteria to establish

that benefits would outweigh costs, and that the restrictions were the only means

of meeting these public interest goals. As a result, there has remained a lack of

transparency in the relationship between economic protection enabling above-

average profits and the realisation of pro-social and public interest outcomes

(Hayne 1994). The major effect of the legislative changes in this period was to

make commercial broadcasters, and particularly the capital city-based networks,

more profitable and competitive in the new environment, and to reduce the degree

of external scrutiny of their conduct and performance.

Pay Television

It is almost universally agreed that the policies surrounding the introduction of

subscription broadcasting, or pay television, were one of the great areas of failure

in Australian broadcast media policy in the 1990s. ABA Deputy Chairman Gareth

Grainger admitted that the introduction of pay TV in Australia had been ‘the

single area of almost complete and glaring failure of the BSA’ (Grainger 1997:

19). In contrast to North America and most of Europe, where pay TV had been in

operation for between ten and 30 years, pay TV services did not commence in

264

Page 34: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Australia until 1995, after thirteen years of public inquiries and political delays.

Although a 1982 Australian Broadcasting Tribunal (ABT) inquiry recommended

the immediate development of cable and subscription TV services (ABT 1982),

neither the Coalition nor Labor governments adopted the recommendations, and it

was not until the 1992 reforms of broadcasting and communications laws that

adequate legislative provision was made for the development of residential

markets for pay TV services. A series of extraordinary policy and political

developments contributed to further post-1992 delays in the start-up of pay TV

services, including: a flawed allocation process for satellite-delivered pay TV

services through public auction, that was exploited by speculative bidders; the

mandating of satellite as the first delivery platform for pay TV, in order to

generate revenue for the financially troubled AUSSAT national satellite system;

and the violation of the principle of ‘technological neutrality’ that the

Broadcasting Services Act 1992 had sought to enshrine, by mandating satellite

delivery and the banning of delivery through microwave delivery systems (MDS)

(Communications Update 1992, 1993; Flew and Spurgeon 2000).

Rather than attributing the delayed introduction of pay television in

Australia to policy failure, Tom O’Regan has argued that regulators and

governments in Australia ‘have gone out of their way to protect the interests of

free-to-air broadcasters at the expense of pay TV and other new television

services in advance of their operations’ (O’Regan 1996: 70). It is apparent that

opposition to pay TV was not confined to the commercial free-to-air networks,

265

Page 35: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

but that there existed a wider climate of scepticism bordering on active hostility

towards pay TV. Pay TV was seen by its critics, which included academics,

influential members of government, and sections of the production industry, as: a

harbinger of differentiation among TV audiences based upon capacity to pay; a

purveyor of low-quality imported programming which would fragment the

programming market; and a symptom of market boosterism and technological

determinism or, as broadcaster Philip Adams put it, ‘a cure for which there is no

disease’ (quoted in Appleton 1997). A common set of assumptions was expressed

by Tim Dwyer, who drew upon a dichotomy between ‘consumer’ and

‘citizenship’ discourses as an interpretative framework for understanding pay TV

policy, to argue that ‘there have been few, if any, prominent arguments put

forward to suggest that pay TV would genuinely enhance the socio-cultural or

informational dimensions of Australia’s communications infrastructure. The

assumption has been that “more” means “better”’. (Dwyer 1995: 102)

Such arguments are perhaps less telling about pay TV than they are about

the significance of the social contract as the cornerstone of cultural and public

interest arguments for broadcast television. Ian Hayne argued that the quid pro

quo approach to broadcasting was premised upon a sustaining fiction of spectrum

scarcity as a underlying reality of service planning, rather than a consequence of

conservative spectrum planning. As a result:

266

Page 36: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

In the tradition of Catch-22 … broadcasting legislation created an

artificial scarcity of licences, which then enabled “public trustee”

arguments to rise, and which in turn led to particular schemes of regulation

supporting program restrictions and obligations. (Hayne, 1994: 9)

Pay television, as the bearer in the first instance of the shift from limited-

channel to multichannel television, would upset this logic in two key respects.

First, it would introduce real competition to commercial free-to-air television for

audiences and, to a lesser degree, advertisers. The number of households

subscribing to pay TV services in Australia has grown from 500,000 in December

1996 to 1,050,000 in June 1999, or about 15 per cent of Australian households. It

is estimated that homes with pay TV consume pay services about 46 per cent of

their total viewing time, and patterns of pay TV usage are particularly high in the

non-prime time periods, among viewers in the 5-12, 13-17 and 18-24 age groups,

and in households with children (Flew and Spurgeon 2000). While subscription

channels do not directly compete with commercial free-to-air television for total

audience share, and their advertising revenues were less than 1 per cent of those

of the commercial free-to-air sector in 1999 (Peters 1999), they are taking

significant niche audiences from the commercial free-to-air sector, and this trend

can be expected to grow significantly over time. Second, pay television promotes

greater integration of national and international programming markets,

particularly in area such as sport, documentary and infotainment programming,

where the ‘cultural discount’ of audience preferences for local as opposed to

267

Page 37: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

imported programming is lower than it is for drama (O’Regan 1996). These

structural changes arising from the introduction of pay TV are overlaid with a

tension in the policy field between older forms of social and cultural regulation

such as Australian content and program standards, and newer policy discourses of

competition policy, with the result that:

Communications and cultural policy making is driven by what are now

seen as two relatively separate and separable governmental ends whose

conflict and shape is to be pragmatically determined. (O’Regan, 1996: 71)

Public Interest and Advocacy Groups

The Broadcasting Services Act, and its approach to questions of regulation and

policy formation, had significant adverse implications for public interest and

advocacy groups involved in Australian broadcasting policy. If the 1970s marked

the growth of a public participation discourse in broadcasting, with the early

inquiries of the ABT being a high-water mark in public accountability for

commercial broadcasters, and the 1980s saw the institutionalisation and

professionalisation of participation by organised interest groups and policy

activists, the 1990s would see the bases for such participation significantly

challenged, and the capacity for interventions in the policy and regulatory process

altered in significant ways. What was particularly under challenge was the notion

that such groups had a right to involvement in the policy process on behalf of the

268

Page 38: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

wider community of media audiences, on the basis of the ‘public trust’ nature of

broadcasting licences.

The ‘public trust’ conception of broadcasting licences had sustained the

active involvement of public interest and advocacy groups in the policy-making

process in three related ways. First, it supported the proposition that the public as

citizens had an interest in commercial broadcasting over and above their interest

as individual audience members in watching or not watching particular programs.

Insofar as the broadcasting audience is highly atomised, the role for interest

groups seeking to represent broad community interests or those of particular

sections of the audience (e.g. children) was legitimated. Second, the claim that the

public as citizens had an interest in processes of policy formation as well as

outcomes, which was established in the 1970s through the Senate Standing

Committee’s inquiry into Australian broadcasting, the Green Report, and the ABT

Self-Regulation Inquiry, entailed a commitment to open and transparent processes

of decision-making. Finally, recognition of the unequal resources of the

broadcasters compared with other interest groups had led to a commitment to

institutional pluralism, manifesting itself in the ABT playing an active role in

promoting and assisting the involvement of community-based and public interest

groups to participate in the broadcasting policy process.

Such propositions were always open to challenge, and became

increasingly contested from the late 1980s on. Former Communications Minister

269

Page 39: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

Graham Richardson has provided a colorful critique of the claim that the public

are interested in such open processes on the basis of the ‘public interest’:

It depends on where you are coming from: should everything be done by

open public hearing process? It’s always been put to me, ‘Ah, it’s in the

public interest’. Well, I will take you for a walk down the shopping centre

of any place in the western suburbs. Go up to the first hundred people and

ask what are the issues facing this country. We won’t find one that tells us

the ABA must have public hearings. Not one! Who’s interested in it? A

very small, elite clique who claim to represent the people out there but

who could not give a stuff. (Richardson 1992: 129)

Even those advocating public processes would acknowledge the possibility that

the wider community was not in fact particularly interested in getting involved.

Anne Britton has observed that while she believes that ‘dropping the licence

renewal process has been quite instrumental in shutting the public out of a

response to the activities of networks’, she would acknowledge that:

If you looked around at who was involved in the licence renewal process

in the 1980s, it was the unions, consumer associations, public interest

organisations. It was hardly people stampeding the doors of the ABT to

have a say in how broadcasting ran … The reality … and it’s a depressing

scenario in some ways, is that most public movements are not that big.

270

Page 40: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The notion of there being a great cross-section of the public involved is

nonsense. There are three or four individuals who are going to run a whole

range of campaigns. I don’t think we should necessarily beat ourselves up

over that.10

Suspicions that the ‘public interest’ was not being adequately represented

though such processes fed into the concern that both the broadcasting legislation

and the ABT had become excessively legalistic, and that the costs of ensuring

regulatory compliance by broadcasters through public licence renewal hearings

had come to significantly outweigh the benefits for the wider community of such

processes. There was also the issue of who was involved in such processes, and to

what ends. Industry representatives such as Tony Branigan (FACTS) have

expressed concern with government-funded organisations such as the AFC and

the FFC being involved as lobbyists in the policy process,11 while Jock Given

(CLC) observed dangers in ‘an easy equation between the production industry and

what we would see as the public interest’.12 From the perspective of public choice

theory, such conduct was seen as an instance of sectional interests and bureaucrats

deploying ‘public interest’ rhetoric for their own economic or other ends,

capturing concentrated benefits at the expense of unorganised interests, and

expanding the ‘political market’ in broadcasting to the detriment of consumer

choice (Self 1993). This literature also asserts that such interest-group coalitions

are more likely to emerge when there are regulatory constraints on competition,

10 Interview with Anne Britton, 28 September 1998. 11 Interview with Tony Branigan, 13 November 199712 Interview with Jock Given, 18 November 1997.

271

Page 41: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

and the absence of a direct market relationship between consumers and service

providers.

Regulatory Agencies: The Australian Broadcasting Authority

The Australian Broadcasting Authority had a very different regulatory remit to the

Australian Broadcasting Tribunal that it replaced. The ABA was designed to be

less procedure-bound in its conduct, and was expected to use the resource savings

arising from devolution of program standards functions, and the ending of licence

renewal hearings, to play a more proactive role in researching current and future

media issues. While industry representatives such as Tony Branigan of FACTS

found their relationship with the ABA to be ‘far less suspicious and formal’ than

that with the ABT,13 Anne Britton of the MEAA expressed concern that rejection

of the ABT’s more ‘hands-on’ approach had led to a more ‘closed door’ approach

to regulation, and that the ABA has been a ‘reluctant watchdog’.14

In a personal assessment of the Broadcasting Services Act and the ABA’s

performance after five years, Deputy Chairman Gareth Grainger believed that the

major improvements had been in those areas where the ABA had been permitted

greater policy flexibility and the scope to develop ‘partnership’ arrangements with

other relevant stakeholders. These included the development of a co-regulatory

approach with industry organisations in the area of program standards and

13 Interview with Tony Branigan, 13 November 1997.14 Interview with Anne Britton, 28 September 1998.

272

Page 42: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

complaints procedures, research into audience and community views towards

broadcast media, and the capacity for informal but ongoing processes of public

and industry consultation as a basis for informing ABA policies and reviews

(Grainger 1997). Such arrangements exemplify the new modes of governance

based upon networks and negotiated coordination, to build workable and mutually

beneficial relationships based upon trust and shared understanding.

Critics have argued that such informality comes at a cost in terms of the

scope for public participation and understanding of regulatory processes. Holly

Raiche’s study of ABA investigations into control of broadcasting licenses found

that the ABA’s ‘informal’ processes to test for control have meant that ‘the public

must take on faith that the ABA’s investigations were as full and accurate as

possible and that the correct conclusions on control were reached’ (Raiche 1997:

18). Similar criticisms were raised by Chadwick et. al. (1995), who argued that in

the areas of planning and technology, ownership and control and codes of

practice, the ABA had been unable to resist political interference. They believed

that the ABA’s lack of independence and transparency had arisen from procedural

and substantive flaws with the Broadcasting Services Act, and the ways in which

it qualified public interest criteria by criteria of economic efficiency, with a

resulting tendency to be ‘supine, self-censoring [and] always anticipating the

wishes of its political masters or captured by those it oversees’ (Chadwick et. al.,

1995: 71). Osmond Borthwick, from the ABA, responded by arguing that the

ABA had used its discretionary powers effectively to provide information and

273

Page 43: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

enable public involvement, and was open and accountable in its procedures

(Borthwick, 1995). This response does, however, miss Raiche’s and Chadwick et.

al.’s principal point, which is that there was no longer an implied right of public

participation enshrined in legislation that guarantees broadcast property, as was

the case under the ‘public trust’ conception of broadcast licences. As a result, the

question of a public interest in broadcasting policy is one of ‘the values which are

to guide decision-making by whatever regulator emerges’ (Chadwick et. al. 1995:

75), and whether they choose to include public interest and advocacy groups in

their deliberative procedures.

Codes of Practice and Co-Regulation

A major development for the broadcasting industry was the need to develop

Codes of Practice, under Section 123 of the Broadcasting Services Act 1992.

These Codes of Practice needed to address the question of program standards,

would involve the development of industry-based mechanisms for the handling

of complaints, and were to be registered with the Australian Broadcasting

Authority. For the most part, industry and regulatory agency representatives

have viewed this experience positively, believing that this co-regulatory

approach (defined in this way since the industry-based codes and complaints

procedures are subject to ABA review, and generally developed in consultation

with the ABA) has generated a process for addressing program standards and

complaints that is not only more efficient for the stations, but more efficient and

274

Page 44: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

effective for the public. Tony Branigan, the Chair of FACTS, believed that the

need to develop a Commercial Television Code of Practice, administered by

FACTS, ‘has been beneficial for the stations, as it has forced stations to become

a lot more professional in how they handle complaints … They’ve been forced

to become more accountable [because] our Code of Practice has been generated

within the industry rather than being imposed on stations’.15 Sally Stockbridge,

Senior Classifications Officer for Channel Ten, Sydney, and former Board

member of the Office of Film and Literature Classification, concurred with this

view, believing that from the station’s point of view, getting an ‘immediate

response’ from viewers provides an ‘ongoing gauge’ of matters of public

concern which can influence programming.16 From the regulator’s perspective,

Debra Richards, former Director of Program Standards at the ABA, believed

that the co-regulatory approach has been more effective in terms of the use of

ABA resources, as well as well as ensuring greater responsiveness on the part of

broadcasters to public complaints.17

Analysts of new modes of governance such as co-regulation, such as Bob

Jessop, believe that there is a ‘tendency to highlight success and downplay

failure’ with these new arrangements (Jessop 1998: 40). Yet it was noted in

Chapter Two that policy failure is an endemic feature of the policy process, in

the sense that policy-makers have only an incomplete, partial and contingent

capacity to represent and control the objects of their policy discourse. This 15 Interview with Tony Branigan, 13 November 1997. 16 Interview with Sally Stockbridge, Senior Classifications Officer, Channel Ten, Sydney,

18 November 1997. 17 Interview with Debra Richards, 19 November 1997.

275

Page 45: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

tendency to policy failure is accentuated by both elements of consumer

sovereignty in relation to media products and services, as well as by citizens’

expectation of a right to representation and involvement in policy processes

which have social and cultural significance.

Such dangers became manifest in Australia in 1999 when a serious crisis

of co-regulatory governance emerged in commercial radio. This centred around

allegations that high-profile announcers such as John Laws, Alan Jones,

Howard Sattler and Jeremy Cordeaux had breached the Commercial Radio

Code of Practice, by accepting payment from leading companies and industry

associations in exchange for favourable editorial comment on their programs,

and that their radio stations were thus in breach of their licence obligations

(ABA 1999a; ABA 1999b). The ABA investigated these deals, particularly

those surrounding Laws and Jones on radio station 2UE, on the basis of the

requirements, under the Objects of the Broadcasting Services Act 1992 that it is

required to ‘encourage providers of commercial broadcasting services to be

responsive to the need for fair and accurate coverage of matters of public

interest’ (s. 3 (g)), and ‘to encourage providers of broadcasting services to

respect community standards in the provision of program material (s. 3 (h)). The

ABA found that Laws and Jones had contravened the Commercial Radio Codes

of Practice, administered by the Federation of Australian Radio Broadcasters

(FARB), on 90 occasions. It found that Clause 2.2(d) of the FARB Code, which

requires that ‘In the presentation and preparation of a news and current affairs

276

Page 46: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

program, a licensee must ensure that viewpoints are not misrepresented, and

material is not presented in a misleading manner by giving wrong or improper

emphasis … or by withholding relevant available facts’, had been breached on

60 occasions, and Clause 3.1(a), which requires that ‘Advertisements broadcast

by a licensee must not be presented as news programs or other programs’, had

been breached on 30 occasions. It recommended that 2UE be required to make

on-air as well as off-air disclosures of relevant commercial agreements as a

condition of its broadcast radio licence, and to ensure that paid advertisements

were readily distinguishable for other program matter (ABA 2000).

The ABA’s ‘cash-for-comment’ inquiry presented starkly the question

of whether an industry body such as the Federation of Australian Radio

Broadcasters (FARB), as well as the ABA, were willing to address public

concerns about the conduct of individual stations and broadcasters, and were

willing to prosecute those found to have been in breach of the Industry Code of

Practice. It was the raising of these allegations on the ABC television program

Media Watch in July 1999 which triggered the ABA’s inquiry, but the issues

had been raised in a number of quarters, including the Media Watch program, as

early as 1994, without action being taken by the ABA. Moreover, the principal

announcers involved - John Laws and Alan Jones - continue to broadcast their

high-rating programs, and the sanctions imposed upon radio station 2UE, such

as requirements for on-air disclosure of prior commercial arrangements by

announcers in relevant announcements, and the keeping of a register of such

277

Page 47: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

commercial agreements by the radio station that is available for public viewing,

were seem by many as inadequate punishments for the quite blatant use of the

public airwaves to promote undeclared sponsors’ interests by these announcers

in the guise of commentary.18 The dangers of co-regulation, such as the potential

for closure of public discourse, lack of public accountability and regulatory

capture, were raised in a fairly stark fashion by this inquiry, and its wider

ramifications for broadcast media policy remain a matter of contention.

Program Classification

One of the most politically contentious areas of media content regulation is

censorship and content classification. Part of the reason why this area has been

subject to particularly intense debate is because discourses of citizenship,

particularly those associated with freedom, participation and the ‘public interest’

can be aligned to both pro- and anti-censorship debating positions, and possess no

necessary correspondence to a particular political orientation. It is an area where,

in contrast to positions taken in debate cultures around public participation, the

left-progressive position has tended to favour ‘passive’ rather than ‘active’

citizenship, or the setting of clear boundaries between individuals and the state.

While direct censorship, in the form of suppression or prohibition of programs,

18 An indication of the power of the two presenters in their home market of Sydney was provided by Michael Gordon-Smith, ABA Board member and Chair of the Inquiry from 8 November 1999, in a presentation to staff and students at the Queensland University of Technology, Brisbane on 16 May 2000. He pointed out that the ABA sought a Queens Counsel to represent it who was based outside of Sydney, since they could not guarantee that a Sydney QC would be willing to prosecute a case against the two individuals, given their connections with powerful people from all sectors in Sydney.

278

Page 48: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

has not been a strong characteristic of government policies towards broadcast

television in Australia, program classification and program modification have

been characteristic forms of content regulation.19

The development of classificatory norms for broadcast television, such as

restrictions on the time of the day or evening in which programs with particular

features (eg. sex, violence, nudity, adult language and themes), have been based

on a sliding scale approach to content regulation. Classifications are linked to the

presumed ‘moral competencies’ of various audiences, most particularly adults as

compared with children, and the ‘publicness’ of the media of distribution, and

access is regulated on the basis of the age of the audience member, the time of the

broadcast or the nature of the exhibition venue. Such an approach is consistent

with a liberal model of media content regulation, which not only entails setting

limits to state regulation of individual conduct, but also typically involves the

establishment of a series of governmental procedures for content regulation. Such

procedures include: establishment of an ‘arm’s length’ relationship between

regulators and government; development of calculative and evaluative norms to

both media content and ‘community standards’; and policy mechanisms that can

render the various normative principles associated with the distribution of media

19 Collins and Murroni have noted that one of the problems with debates about media censorship is their tendency to conflate four relatively distinct forms of regulating access to materials: suppression or prohibition; restriction of circulation to certain types of audience and not others (eg. adults and not children); restriction of circulation to certain media or places of viewing (eg. films unable to be shown on television, or materials restricted to ‘adults only’ bookshops or cinemas); and deletion of particular images, words, scenes etc. from an overall media product, whether in its original released form or in subsequent releases (eg. ‘R’-rated films modified for broadcast television). This is connected to a tendency to presume that suppression, rather than restriction or selective deletion, is the characteristic form of state regulation over media content. (Collins and Murroni 1996: 98-99).

279

Page 49: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

content (freedom of speech and expression, protection of children, respect for

community standards, and consumer choice) into programs of action to be

administered by independent experts (Bertrand 1978; Stockbridge 1996; Flew

1998).

The Broadcasting Services Act had two principal implications for the area

of program classification. First, in line with the move towards industry self-

regulation, responsibility for developing program classification standards would

be devolved from regulatory authorities to industry bodies, who would develop

standards as part of their Codes of Practice in a co-regulatory framework with the

ABA. In developing program classification standards, the industry bodies would

be required to take into account both the Objects and Section 123 of the

Broadcasting Services Act, the classificatory standards for other media

administered by the Office of Film and Literature Classification (OFLC), and the

outcomes of consultation with the community as well as with the ABA about

these standards. The other key element of the new legislation was that, in line

with the concept of a sliding scale of regulation based upon the ‘degree of

influence’ of different broadcast media upon community views, material which

may require modification in order to be shown on broadcast media would be able

to be shown without modification on those media identified as being more

directly ‘media of choice’, such as subscription broadcasting or pay TV. Under

Section 100(2) of the Broadcasting Services Act, subscription television

broadcasting licensees were required to comply with a Code of Practice

280

Page 50: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

applicable to the licensee, as well as with the film classification system

administered by the OFLC.

As a first ‘test case’ of the new regulatory regime, the question of whether

‘R’ rated material would be permitted on pay TV quickly became caught up in

what Sally Stockbridge has described as the ‘crisis of content regulation’ in

Australia (Stockbridge 1996: 137; cf. Spurgeon 1994). The development of new

media, greater media diversity, global media distribution networks, and changes

in the relationship between content distributors and users would seem to imply a

reduced capacity for regulators to control or restrict access to media content. For

some observers, such as former British Board of Film Classification member

Julian Wood, these developments require a change in regulatory practices,

towards ‘letting go’ of content controls, and instead adopting a role of informing

and educating media audiences and users (Wood 1997: 13). For others such as the

Senate Select Committee on Community Standards Relevant to the Supply of

Services Utilising Electronic Technologies, and prominent individual members

such as the independent Tasmanian Senator Brian Harradine, such an approach

would reinforce a decline in moral authority in society, and would be contrary to

what they perceive as a majority community concern about violent and sexually

explicit material in the media. As a result, they simply refused to accept findings

such as those from a joint ABA/OFLC research on community attitudes in 1993,

which found that 82 per cent of respondents believed that adults should have the

option of watching R-rated material on pay TV. Instead, they successfully lobbied

281

Page 51: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

for amendments to the Broadcasting Services Act which had the effect of ensuring

that a ban on such material on pay TV would be put in place.20 Similarly, the

FACTS Code of Practice has twice been amended, in 1993 and 1997, in response

to government pressures to move the earliest time for screening of material rated

‘MA’ back from 8.30 p.m. to 9.00 p.m., and then from 9.00 p.m. to 9.30 p.m.

The failure to institute a more liberal regulatory regime for program

content on pay TV in Australia, and the debates surrounding program

classification more generally, point to two perennial questions arising from liberal

modes of governance. These are the balance between individual freedoms and the

achievement of economy in the practice of government on the one hand, and the

sense of moral guardianship towards a community implied in the ‘shepherding’

role of the modern state on the other. This question of balance is an instance of

what Nikolas Rose has termed the ‘recurrent dilemma of liberal government: the

fear of not governing enough versus the fear of governing too much’ (Rose 1993:

292). One approach would accept that a consequence of media proliferation,

globalisation, decentralisation and the fragmentation of audiences, would be

further movement away from the ‘prohibition model’ of media content regulation,

and a pluralistic understanding of the notion of community standards in a

culturally diverse society. Such an approach is consistent with the policy

20 The amended clause of the Act requires that ‘the licensee will ensure that access to programs classified “R” by the Office of Film and Literature Classification is restricted by disabling devices acceptable to the ABA but will not broadcast such an “R” classified program until the ABA has completed extensive, Australia-wide qualitative and quantitative research on community standards of taste and decency in relation to classifications for pay television and on what levels of violence and depiction of sex should be allowed, and the ABA has recommended, and the parliament has, by resolution of each House, approved, the broadcast of such programs’ (clause 10(1), Schedule 2, part 6).

282

Page 52: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

directions indicated by the Broadcasting Services Act, towards greater consumer

choice, responsible industry self-regulation and ‘regulation by exception’.

By contrast, the Senate Committee’s approach, and the dominant policy

approach since 1996, has been to call for greater regulation of problematic media

content in light to these trends in media distribution and consumption. This points

to what Christina Spurgeon has described as a ‘paradox of the “information

economy”’, where ‘uncompromising pastoral concern for the moral management

of populations has come into direct political conflict with national economic

strategy as residential markets for information-based services continue to

develop’ (Spurgeon 1999: 52). Although this latter approach appears backward-

looking in light of economic and technological globalisation, there is nonetheless

some need for caution in dismissing these arguments. Such arguments draw upon

recognisable citizenship discourses, most notably those of community, security,

social responsibility and public accountability, and promote a notion of ‘active

citizenship’, or ongoing participation in community activities on a moral-

normative basis. In considering the persistence of such arguments, there is a need

to acknowledge the extent to which the liberalisation of censorship has also

involved its governmentalisation, where moral arguments are subsumed within

bureaucratic processes as part of a conscious desire to ‘de-dramatise’ potentially

contentious aspects of social life. This is done through a process of subjecting

conflicting normative principles to the calculative and administrative logics of

social administration that are ‘neither transparent to public scrutiny nor

283

Page 53: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

immediately amenable to popular will’ (Meredyth 1997: 276; cf. Donzelot 1993;

Flew 1998).

Conclusion

The late 1980s and early 1990s saw a major shift in thinking about

broadcast media policy. The drivers of such changes included: new policy

discourses that stressed diversity and consumer choice; the growing significance

of economic discourses associated with ‘neo-liberal’ modes of governance; and

the utilisation of delivery technologies such as cable, satellite and the Internet to

provide new multichannel, user-pays and interactive services. These changes also

pointed to a shift in the role of state agencies, from being the public interest

watchdogs of the uses of private power and the brokers of outcomes between

competing interests, to becoming the animators of change, the facilitators of

industry self-regulation and the promoters of competitive market behaviour.

While some have seen such outcomes as a manifestation of a misguided

‘economic rationalism’, it has bee argued in this chapter that these developments

marked a confluence between ‘advanced liberal’ modes of governance based upon

‘responsible self-regulation’ and negotiated coordination between public and

private sectors, and the ‘revisionist’ social-democratic agenda of the Hawke and

Keating Labor governments to promote an Australian economy and society that

was more outward-looking and change-oriented, in the face of recurrent structural

crises in the economy.

284

Page 54: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

The apotheosis of these changes was meant to be the Broadcasting

Services Act 1992. While the rhetoric of those promoting the new legislation and

that of its critics saw the new legislation as the harbinger of a neo-liberal policy

environment, in practice the legislative changes led largely to the strengthening of

the economic position of the incumbent broadcast networks, and a weakening of

the capacity of public interest and advocacy groups to exercise countervailing

power to the broadcasters. While the Australian Broadcasting Authority was

largely positive about these developments, problems emerged in broadcast media

policy in the 1990s that the new policy framework dealt with in ways that were at

odds with both ‘public trust’ expectations from the community as citizens about

broadcasting regulation, and with the notions of freedom, competition and

autonomy championed by neo-liberal discourses.

It was observed in this chapter that that, in contrast to the neo-liberal

rhetoric that accompanied the legislative changes, the policy framework largely

consolidated the political and economic power of the commercial broadcasting

networks and, to the extent that challenges emerged to such power emerged from

prospective new entrants or from critics of the networks, the authority of

regulatory agencies was largely used to defend the status quo. What became

apparent was that the decline of ‘public trust’ discourse as a basis for regulation

had an immediate and negative impact upon the capacity of public interest and

advocacy groups to involve themselves in the policy process, whereas the

285

Page 55: Chapter Six_PhD_Terry Flew

intention to promote new technologies and greater competition had little impact

upon the commercial free-to-air broadcasters, as seen in the protracted difficulties

in introducing pay television into Australia. Moreover, the extent to which the

new legislation led to broadcast media policy moving away from direct

government intervention and towards effective self-government is debatable. In

areas such as complaints, self-regulatory mechanisms developed quickly,

although the ‘cash-for-comment’ scandal that emerged in Australian commercial

radio in 1999 pointed to some major limitations in the process. In other areas,

most notably program classification standards, the ‘light touch’ and self-

regulatory intentions of the Broadcasting Services Act towards the media were

largely negated by a continuing tendency for other elements of government to

seek reinforcement of their rights and capability to engage in moral management

of the population, through their ability to shape laws governing the availability of

media content to consumers. The logic of the social contract - that restrictions on

competition were a necessary trade off for content regulations - also remained

largely intact over the course of the 1990s in Australia, as the Productivity

Commission would ruefully observe in its inquiry into broadcasting in 2000.

286