Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer...

57
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Transcript of Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer...

Page 1: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Page 2: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 2©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

When government controls price, some people are better off May be able to buy a good at a lower price

But what is the effect on society as a whole? Is total welfare higher or lower and by how

much?

A way to measure gains and losses from government policies is needed

Page 3: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 3©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

Between 0 and Q0 producers receive

a net gain from selling each product--

producer surplus.

ConsumerSurplus

Quantity

Price

S

D

Q0

5

9

Between 0 and Q0

consumer A receives a net gain from buying

the product-- consumer surplus.

ProducerSurplus

3

QD QS

Page 4: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 4©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

To determine the welfare effect of a governmental policy, we can measure the gain or loss in consumer and producer surplus

Welfare Effects Gains and losses to producers and

consumers

Page 5: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 5©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

When price is held too low, the quantity demanded increases and quantity supplied decreases

Some consumers are worse off because they can no longer buy the good Decrease in consumer surplus

Some consumers are better off because they can buy it at a lower price Increase in consumer surplus

Page 6: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 6©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

Producers sell less at a lower priceSome producers are no longer in the

marketBoth of these producer groups lose and

producer surplus decreasesThe economy as a whole is worse off

since surplus that used to belong to producers or consumers is simply gone

Page 7: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 7©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The loss to producers is the sum of

rectangle A and triangle C

B

A C

Consumers that can buy the good gain A

Price Control and Surplus Changes

Quantity

Price

S

D

P0

Q0

Pmax

Q1 Q2

Consumers that cannot buy, lose B

Triangles B and C are losses to society – dead weight loss

Page 8: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 8©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Price Controls and Welfare Effects

The total loss is equal to area B + CThe deadweight loss is the inefficiency

of the price controls – the total loss in surplus (consumer plus producer)

If demand is sufficiently inelastic, losses to consumers may be fairly large This can have effects in political decisions

Page 9: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 9©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

B

APmax

C

Q1

With inelastic demand, triangle B can be larger

than rectangle A and consumers suffer net

losses from price controls.

S

D

Price Controls With Inelastic Demand

Quantity

Price

P0

Q2

Page 10: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 10©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Efficiency ofa Competitive Market

In the evaluation of markets, we often talk about whether it reaches economic efficiency Maximization of aggregate consumer and

producer surplus

Policies such as price controls that cause dead weight losses in society are said to impose an efficiency cost on the economy

Page 11: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 11©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Efficiency ofa Competitive Market

If efficiency is the goal, then you can argue that leaving markets alone is the answer

However, sometimes market failures occur Prices fail to provide proper signals to

consumers and producers Leads to inefficient unregulated competitive

market

Page 12: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 12©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Types of Market Failures

1. Externalities Costs or benefits that are not reflected in market

supply and demand (e.g. pollution) Costs or benefits are experienced by a third party

not involved in transaction

2. Lack of Information Imperfect information prevents consumers from

making utility-maximizing decisions

Government intervention may be desirable in these cases

Page 13: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 13©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

BA

C

Price Control and Surplus Changes

Quantity

Price

S

D

P0

Q0

Pmin

Q1 Q2

When price is regulated to be no lower than Pmin, the

deadweight loss given by triangles B and C

results.

Page 14: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 14©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

The 1984 National Organ Transplantation Act prohibits the sale of organs for transplantation

What has been the impact of the Act?We can measure this using the supply

and demand for kidneys from estimated data Supply: QS = 8,000 + 0.2P Demand: QD = 16,000 - 0.2P

Page 15: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 15©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

Since the sale of organs is not allowed, the amount available depends on the amount donated Supply of donated kidneys is limited to 8,000

The welfare effect of this supply constraint can be analyzed using consumer and producer surplus in the kidney market

Page 16: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 16©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

Suppliers: Those who supply them are not paid the

market price, estimated at $20,000Loss of surplus equal to area A = $160 million

Some who would donate for the equilibrium price do not donate in the current market

Loss of surplus equal to area C = $40 million Total ‘producer’ loss of A + C = $200 million

Page 17: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 17©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

Recipients: Since they do not have to pay for the kidney,

they gain rectangle A ($160 million) since price is $0

Those who cannot obtain a kidney lose surplus equal to triangle B ($40 million)

Net increase in surplus of recipients of $160 - $40 = $120 million

Dead Weight Loss of C + B = $80 million

Page 18: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 18©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

Other Inefficiency Costs Allocation is not necessarily to those who

value the kidneys the most Price may increase to $40,000, the

equilibrium price, with hospitals getting the price

Page 19: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 19©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

D

A and D measure the total value of

kidneys when supply is constrained.

A

C

The loss to suppliersis seen in areas A & C.

The Market for Kidneys

Quantity

Price

4,0000

$10,000

$30,000

$40,000

8,000

S’

B

If kidneys are zero cost, consumer gain would be A minus B.

S

D

12,000

$20,000

Page 20: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 20©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Market for Human Kidneys

Arguments in favor of prohibiting the sale of organs:

1. Imperfect information about donor’s health and screening

2. Unfair to allocate according to the ability to pay Holding price below equilibrium will create

shortages Organs versus artificial substitutes

Page 21: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 21©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Minimum Prices

Periodically, government policy seeks to raise prices above market-clearing levels Minimum wage law Regulation of airlines Agricultural policies

We will investigate this by looking at the minimum wage legislation

Page 22: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 22©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

BA

The change in producersurplus will be

A - C - D. Producersmay be worse off.

C

D

Minimum Prices

Quantity

Price

S

D

P0

Q0Q3 Q2

Pmin

If producers produce Q2, the amount Q2 - Q3

will go unsold.

D measures total cost of increased

production not sold.

Page 23: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 23©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

B

The deadweight lossis given by

triangles B and C.

C

A

L1 L2

Unemployment

wmin

Firms are not allowed topay less than wmin. This

results in unemployment.

S

D

w0

L0

The Minimum Wage

L

w

A is gain to workers who find jobs at

higher wage.

Page 24: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 24©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Price Supports

Much of agricultural policy is based on a system of price supports Prices set by government above free-market

level and maintained by governmental purchases of excess supply

Page 25: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 25©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Price Supports

What are the impacts on consumers, producers and the federal budget?

Consumers Quantity demanded falls and quantity

supplied increases Government buys surplus Consumers must pay higher price for the

good Loss in consumer surplus equal to A+B

Page 26: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 26©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Price Supports

Producers Gain since they are selling more at a higher

price Producer surplus increases by A+B+D

Government Cost of buying the surplus, which is funded

by taxes, so indirect cost on consumers Cost to government = (Q2-Q1)PS

Page 27: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 27©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Price Supports

Government may be able to “dump” some of the goods in the foreign markets Hurts domestic producers that government is trying to

help in the first place

Total welfare effect of policy

CS + PS – Govt. cost = D – (Q2-Q1)PS

Society is worse off overallLess costly to simply give farmers the money

Page 28: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 28©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

B

DA

To maintain a price Ps

the government buys quantity Qg .

D + Qg

Qg

Price Supports

Quantity

PriceS

D

P0

Q0

Ps

Q2Q1

E

Net Loss to society is E + B.

Page 29: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 29©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Production Quotas

The government can also cause the price of a good to rise by reducing supply Limitations of taxi medallions in New York

City Limitation of required liquor licenses for

restaurants

Page 30: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 30©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

BA

•CS reduced by A + B•Change in PS = A - C•Deadweight loss = BC

C

Supply Restrictions

Quantity

Price

D

P0

Q0

S

S’

PS

Q1

•Supply restricted to Q1

•Supply shifts to S’ & Q1

Page 31: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 31©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Import Quotas and Tariffs

Many countries use import quotas and tariffs to keep the domestic price of a product above world levels Import quotas: Limit on the quantity of a good

that can be imported Tariff: Tax on an imported good

This allows domestic producers to enjoy higher profits

Cost to consumers is high

Page 32: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Import Quotas and Tariffs

With lower world price, domestic consumers have incentive to purchase from abroad Domestic price falls to world price and

imports equal difference between quantity supplied and quantity demanded

Domestic industry might convince government to protect industry by eliminating imports Quota of zero or high tariff

Page 33: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 33©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

QS QD

PW

AB C

Quota of zero pushes domestic price to P0 and

imports go to zero.

Import Tariff to Eliminate Imports

Quantity

Price

Q0

D

P0

S

In a free market, the domestic price equals the

world price PW.

Imports

Loss to consumers is A+B+C.

Gain to producers is A.Dead weight loss: B +C.

Page 34: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 34©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Import Tariff (General Case)

The increase in price can be achieved by a tariff

QS increases and QD decreases

Area A is the gain to domestic producers

The loss to consumers is A + B + C + D

DWL = B + C Government Revenue is D

= tariff * imports

DCB

QS QDQ’S Q’D

AP*

Pw

Q

P

D

S

Page 35: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 35©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Import Quota (General Case)

If a quota is used, rectangle D becomes part of the profits to foreign producers

Consumers lose A+B+C+D

Producers gain ANet domestic loss is

B + C + D

DCB

QS QDQ’S Q’D

AP*

Pw

Q

P

D

S

Page 36: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 36©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Sugar Quota Example

The world price of sugar has been as low as 4 cents per pound, while in the U.S. the price has been 20-25 cents per pound

Sugar quotas have protected the sugar industry but driven up prices

Domestic producers have been better off and so have some foreign producers that have quota rights

Consumers are worse off

Page 37: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 37©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Sugar Quota Example

The Impact of a Sugar Quota in 2001 US production = 17.4 billion pounds US consumption = 20.4 billion pounds US price = 21.5 cents/pound World price = 8.3 cents/pound Price elasticity of US supply = 1.5 Price elasticity of US demand = –0.3

Page 38: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 38©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Impact of Sugar Quota

The data can be used to fit the US supply and demand curves QS = -8.70 + 1.21P QD = 26.53 - 0.29P This situation led to little domestic supply and

most domestic consumption coming from large imports

Government restricted imports to 3 billion pounds raising price to 21.5 cents/pound

Page 39: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 39©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Sugar Quota in 1997

C

D

B

AThe cost of the quotas

to consumers was A + B + C + D = $2.4b.

The gain to producers was area A = $1b.

SUS DUSPrice(cents/lb.)

4

8

11

16

20

PW = 8.3 before quota

PUS = 21.5 after quota

Quantity(billions of pounds)24.21.4 17.4 20.4

Page 40: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 40©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy

The government wants to impose a $1.00 tax on movies. It can do it two ways: Make the producers pay $1.00 for each

movie ticket they sell Make consumers pay $1.00 when they buy

each movie

In which option are consumers paying more?

Page 41: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 41©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy

The burden of a tax (or the benefit of a subsidy) falls partly on the consumer and partly on the producer

How the burden is split between the parties depends on the relative elasticities of demand and supply

Page 42: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 42©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Effects of a Specific Tax

For simplicity we will consider a specific tax on a good Tax of a particular amount per unit sold Federal and state taxes on gas and

cigarettes

For our example, consider a specific tax of $t per widget sold

Page 43: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 43©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

•Buyers lose A + B

Incidence of a Specific Tax

D

S

B

D

A

C

Quantity

Price

P0

Q0Q1

PS price producers get

Pb price buyers pay

Tax = $1.00 •Government gains A

+ D in tax revenue.

•Sellers lose D + C

•The deadweightloss is B + C.

Page 44: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 44©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Effect of an OutputTax on Industry Output

Price($ per

unit ofoutput)

Output

DD

P1

SS1

Q1

P2

Q2

SS2 = S1 + t

t

Tax shifts S1 to S2 andoutput falls to Q2. Price

increases to P2.

Page 45: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 45©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Incidence of a Specific Tax

Four conditions that must be satisfied after the tax is in place:

1. Quantity sold and buyer’s price, Pb, must be on the demand curve Buyers only concerned with what they must

pay

2. Quantity sold and seller’s price, PS, must be on the supply curve Sellers only concerned with what they receive

Page 46: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 46©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Incidence of a Specific Tax

Four conditions that must be satisfied after the tax is in place (cont.):

3. QD = QS

4. Difference between what consumers pay and what buyers receive is the tax

If we know the demand and supply curves as well as the tax, we can solve for PB, PS, QD and QS

Page 47: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 47©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Incidence of a Specific Tax

In the previous example, the tax was shared almost equally by consumers and producers

If demand is relatively inelastic, however, burden of tax will fall mostly on buyers Cigarettes

If supply is relatively inelastic, the burden of tax will fall mostly on sellers

Page 48: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Impact of Elasticities on Tax Burdens

Quantity Quantity

Price Price

S

D S

D

Q0

P0 P0

Q0Q1

Pb

PS

t

Q1

Pb

PS

t

Burden on Buyer Burden on Seller

Page 49: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 49©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy

We can calculate the percentage of a tax borne by consumers using pass-through fraction ES/(ES - Ed) Tells fraction of tax “passed through” to

consumers through higher prices For example, when demand is perfectly

inelastic (Ed = 0), the pass-through fraction is 1 – consumers bear 100% of tax

Page 50: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 50©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Effects of a Tax or Subsidy

A subsidy can be analyzed in much the same way as a tax Payment reducing the buyer’s price below

the seller’s price

It can be treated as a negative taxThe seller’s price exceeds the buyer’s

priceQuantity increases

Page 51: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 51©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

D

S

Effects of a Subsidy

Quantity

Price

P0

Q0 Q1

PS

Pb

Like a tax, the benefitof a subsidy is split

between buyers and sellers, depending

upon the elasticities ofsupply and demand.

Subsidy

Page 52: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 52©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Effects of a Subsidy

The benefit of the subsidy accrues mostly to buyers if ED /ES is small

The benefit of the subsidy accrues mostly to sellers if ED /ES is large

As with a tax, using supply and demand curves, and the size of the subsidy, one can solve for resulting prices and quantities

Page 53: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 53©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

A Tax on Gasoline

We can measure the effects of a tax by looking at an example of a gasoline tax

The goal of a large gasoline tax is to: Raise government revenue Reduce oil consumption and reduce US

dependence on oil imports

We will consider a gas tax in the market during mid-1990’s

Page 54: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 54©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

A Tax on Gasoline

Measuring the Impact of a 50 Cent Gasoline Tax Intermediate-run EP of demand = -0.5

QD = 150 - 50P

EP of supply = 0.4QS = 60 + 40P

QS = QD at $1 and 100 billion gallons per year (bg/yr)

Page 55: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 55©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

A Tax on Gasoline

With a 50 cent tax:

QD = QS

150 - 50Pb = 60 + 40PS

150 - 50(PS+ 0.50) = 60 + 40PS

PS = .72

Pb = PS + 0.50 = $1.22

QD = QS = 89 bg/yr

Page 56: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 56©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

A Tax on Gasoline

With a 50 cent tax: Q falls by 11% Price to consumers increases by 22 cents

per gallon Producers receive about 28 cents per gallon

less Both producers and consumers were

opposed to the tax Government revenue would be significant at

$44.5 billion per year

Page 57: Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,

Chapter 9 57©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

CD

A

The Impact of a 50 Cent Gasoline Tax

Quantity (billiongallons per year)

Price($ pergallon)

50 150100

P0 = 1.00

Pb = 1.22

PS = .72

89

11

The buyer pays 22 cents of the tax, and

the producer pays 28 cents.

SD

60

$0.50 Tax

Consumer Loss = A + B

Producer Loss = C + D

Government revenue = A + D = 0.50(89) = $44.5 billion.

B