CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within...

66
CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets

Transcript of CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within...

Page 1: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

CHAPTER 5:

Pollution control: targets

Page 2: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Agenda

5.1 Modelling frameworks

5.2 Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework

5.3 Pollution flows, pollution stocks and pollution damage

5.4 The efficient level of pollution

5.5 A static model of efficient flow pollution

5.6 Efficient levels of emission of stock pollutants

5.7 Pollution control where damages depend on location of emissions

5.8 Ambient pollution standards

5.9 Intertemporal analysis of stock pollution

5.10 Variable decay

5.11 Departures from convexity or concavity in functions

5.12 ‘No regrets’ policies and rebound effects

5.13 The Double Dividend hypothesis

5.14 Objectives of pollution policy

Page 3: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

5.1 Modelling frameworks

Importance for determining the target level of emissions (or pollution) of the modelling framework employed, particularly its breadth or extensiveness.

• Geographical or Political scope. • Partial equilibrium or general equilibrium analysis• Extensiveness of the system being studied: specification of the

system in which pollution-generating activities are embedded.• Constraints implied by economy–environment interactions.• Material balance principle

Page 4: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

5.2 Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework

•  Here we consider what the criterion of economic efficiency has to say about determining pollution targets.

Page 5: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Figure 5.1 Economic activity, residual flows and environmental damage

Page 6: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Pollution flows, pollution stocks and pollution damage

 • Flow-damage pollution occurs when damage results only from the

flow of residuals: that is, the rate at which they are being discharged into the environmental system.

• Stock-damage pollution describes the case in which damages depend only on the stock of the pollutant in the relevant environmental system at any point in time.

• Mixed cases are possible too.

Flow-damage pollution: D = D(M) (5.1a)

Stock-damage pollution: D = D(A) (5.1b)

Page 7: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The efficient level of pollution emissions

• There are costs and benefits of pollution emissions– Think what we might have in mind in thinking about the benefits of emissions: if a

required emissions standard is made less restrictive, the relaxation of the pollution abatement constraint allows the production of goods that could not otherwise have been made, or to produce those goods at less direct cost in terms of inputs or techniques employed.

 • With both benefits and costs, economic decisions about the

appropriate level of pollution involve the evaluation of a trade-off. • Stricter pollution targets will generate benefits but will also generate

costs• The trade off is optimized at the point where the marginal benefits

arising from reduced pollution damage fall to a level equal to the marginal benefit from avoided control costs.

Page 8: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

dM

dB

Maximised net benefits

M*

*

Emissions, M

D(M)B(M)

D(M)

B(M)

Emissions, M

Figure 5.2 Total and marginal damage and benefit functions, and the efficient level of flow pollution emissions

dM

dD

B

A

Page 9: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Efficient emissions: the case of pure flow-damage pollution

5.5 A static model of efficient flow pollution

 

• Emissions have both benefits and costs.

• We call the costs of emissions ‘damages’.

• These damages can be thought of as a negative (adverse) externality.

• For simplicity, we suppose that damage is independent of the time and the source of the emissions, and that emissions have no effect outside the economy being studied. We relax these assumptions later.

• An efficient level of emissions is one that maximises the net benefits from pollution, where net benefits are defined as pollution benefits minus pollution damages.

Page 10: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

This is now Figure 5.3

Page 11: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

• The level of emissions at which net benefits are maximised is equivalent to the outcome that would prevail if the pollution externality were fully internalised.

 • In the case of flow pollution, damage (D) is dependent only on the

magnitude of the emissions flow (M):

D = D(M) (5.2)

 • We assume:

B = B(M) (5.3)

Define:

NB = B(M) – D(M) (5.4)

Page 12: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

• Is convenient to work with marginal, rather than total, functions.

• dB/dM (or B׳(M)) is the marginal benefit of pollution

• dD/dM (or D׳(M)) is the marginal damage of pollution

• We assume for simplicity that

– total damage rises at an increasing rate with the size of the emission flow, and so the marginal damage will be increasing in M

– total benefits will rise at a decreasing rate as emissions increase (because per-unit emissions abatement costs will be more expensive at greater levels of emissions reduction). Therefore, the marginal benefit of emissions would fall as their flow increases.

Page 13: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Maximisation of net benefits

• To maximise the net benefits of economic activity, we require that the pollution flow, M, be chosen so that

which states that the net benefits of pollution can be maximised only where the marginal benefits of pollution equal the marginal damage of pollution.

Page 14: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

dM

dB

Maximised net benefits

M*

*

Emissions, M

D(M)B(M)

D(M)

B(M)

Emissions, M

Figure 5.2 Total and marginal damage and benefit functions, and the efficient level of flow pollution emissions

dM

dD

B

A

Page 15: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Efficient levels of emission of stock pollutants

Page 16: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock pollutants

• The analysis of pollution in Section 5.5 dealt with the case of flow pollution, in which pollution damage depends directly on the level of emissions.

• In doing so, it was unnecessary to distinguish between flows and stocks of the pollutant.

– First, both benefits and damages depended on emissions alone, so as far as the objective of net benefit maximisation was concerned, stocks – even if they existed – were irrelevant.

– But we also argued that stocks do not exist for pure flow pollutants (such as noise or light).

• How should the analysis change for stock pollutants, where damage depends on the stock of the pollutant?

• The flow pollution model also provides correct answers in the special (but highly unlikely) case where the pollutant stock degrades into a harmless form more-or-less instantaneously. Here the stock dimension is distinguishable from the flow only by some constant of proportionality, and so we can work just as before entirely in flow units.

• But in all other cases of stock pollutants, the flow pollution model is invalid.

Page 17: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock pollutants

• The majority of important pollution problems are associated with stock pollutants.

• Pollution stocks derive from the accumulation of emissions the life (or residence) time of which is more than merely instantaneous.

• The distinction between flows and stocks now becomes crucial for two reasons.

– First, without it understanding of the science lying behind the pollution problem is impossible.

– Second, the distinction is important for policy purposes. While the damage is associated with the pollution stock, that stock is outside the direct control of policy makers. Environmental protection agencies may, however, be able to control the rate of emission flows. Even where they cannot control such flows directly, the regulator may find it more convenient to target emissions rather than stocks. Given that what we seek to achieve depends on stocks but what is controlled or regulated are typically flows, it is necessary to understand the linkage between the two.

Page 18: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Spatial and intertemporal considerations

 

• Because stock pollutants are persistent over time and so may be transported over space, the analysis of stock pollution often necessitates taking account of space as well as time.

• It will be convenient to deal with these two dimensions separately.

• To do so, we draw a distinction between pollutants with a relatively short residence time (of the order of a day or so) and those with considerably longer lifetimes.

Page 19: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Pollution control where damages depend on location

of the emissions

Page 20: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

S1

S2

R4

R3

R2

R1

Figure 5.4 A spatially differentiated airshed

Page 21: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Pollutant dispersion and mixing

•  Mixing of a pollutant refers to the extent to which physical processes cause the pollutant to be dispersed or spread out.

• A pollutant is ‘uniformly mixing’ (UM) if physical processes operate so that the pollutant quickly becomes dispersed to the point where its spatial distribution is uniform.

– That is, the measured concentration rate of the pollutant does not vary from place to place.

– This property is satisfied, for example, by most greenhouse gases.

• By definition, the location of the emission source of a UM pollutant is irrelevant as far as the spatial distribution of pollutant concentrations is concerned.

– Irrespective of the source location, pollutant stocks become evenly distributed across the whole spatial area of interest – in our picture over the whole rectangle depicted.

– All that matters, as far as concentration rates at any receptor are concerned, is the total amount of those emissions.

Page 22: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Non UM pollutants

• Where pollutants are not uniformly mixing, location matters.

• There will not be a single relationship between emissions and concentration over all space.

• A given total value of M will in general lead to differentiated values of A across receptors.

• Moreover, if M remained constant but its source distribution changed then the spatial configuration of A would also change.

Page 23: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Non UM pollutants

• Non-uniform mixing is of importance as many types of pollution fall into this category.

• Examples include ozone accumulation in the lower atmosphere, oxides of nitrogen and sulphur in urban airsheds, particulate pollutants from diesel engines and trace metal emissions.

• Many water and ground pollutants also do not uniformly mix.

Page 24: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Non UM pollutants: policy

• An environmental protection agency may attempt to handle these spatial issues by controlling ex ante the location of pollution creators and victims.

– This approach, implemented primarily by zoning and other forms of planning control, forms a substantial part of the longer-term way of dealing with spatial aspects of pollution.

• However, now focus on the situation in which the location of polluters and people is already determined, and moving either is not a feasible option.

• Our interest must then lie in how targets for emissions from the various sources can be calculated (and, in the next chapter, on what instruments can be used).

Page 25: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Ambient pollution standards

Page 26: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The algebra of ambient pollution standards

• Suppose that there are J spatially distinct pollution ‘reception’ areas (or receptors), each being indexed by the subscript j (so j = 1, 2,..., J)

• There are N distinct pollution sources, each being indexed by the subscript i (so i = 1, 2,..., N).

• Various physical and chemical processes determine the impact on pollutant concentration in any particular receptor from any particular source.

• For simplicity, we assume that the relationships are linear. • In that case, a set of constant ‘transfer coefficients’ can be defined.

• The transfer coefficient dji describes the impact on pollutant concentration at receptor j attributable to source i.

Page 27: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The algebra (2)

• The total level, or concentration rate, of pollution at location j, Aj, will be the sum of the contributions to pollution at that location from all N emission sources. This can be written as

• (5.6)

where Mi denotes the total emissions from source i.

• A numerical example will help. In the case shown in Figure 5.4, we have N = 2 sources and J = 4 receptors. Then we have four equations corresponding to equation 5.6. These are

A1 = d11M1 + d12M2 (5.7a)

A2 = d21M1 + d22M2 (5.7b)

A3 = d31M1 + d32M2 (5.7c)

A4 = d41M1 + d42M2 (5.7d)

N

i

ijijMdA

1

Page 28: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The algebra (3)

• Collect all eight dji coefficients into a J × N matrix, D.

• Denoting the vector of emissions from the two sources as M and the vector of ambient pollution levels in the four receptors as A we have

A = DM(5.8)

Page 29: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The socially efficient level of emissions from each source

• What is the socially efficient level of emissions from each source? • It will be the set of emission levels that maximises net benefits. • Note that there are N emission sources, and so our solution will consist of N values of

Mi, one for each source.

• Benefits consist of the sum over all N sources of each firm’s pollution benefits. So we have

Page 30: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,
Page 31: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Intuition

• The emissions target (or standard) for each firm should be set so that the private marginal benefit of its emissions (the left-hand side of the equation) is equal to the marginal damage of its emissions (the right-hand side of the equation).

• Note that because the ith firm’s emissions are transferred to some or all of the receptors, the marginal damage attributable to the ith firm is obtained by summing its contribution to damage over each of the J receptors.

• An interesting property of the solution to equation set 5.13 is that not only will the efficient emission level differ from firm to firm, but also the efficient ambient pollution level will differ among receptors.

• It is easy to see why efficient emission levels should vary. Firms located at different sources have different pollution impacts: other things being equal, those sources with the highest pollution impact should emit the least.

Page 32: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Intuition• What lies behind the result that efficient levels of pollution will vary from place to

place?

• Receptors at different spatial locations will experience different pollution levels: other things being equal (including population densities), those receptors which would in an unconstrained world experience the highest pollution-stock level should have the highest efficient ambient pollution level.

• Of course, these two considerations have to be met jointly;

• NB = B - D is being maximised, and so we are searching for the best trade-off between the benefits reduction and damages reduction.

Page 33: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,
Page 34: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Intertemporal analysis of stock pollution

Page 35: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock pollutants: intertemporal

• We now consider the case of stock pollutants that have a relatively long active (i.e. damaging) lifespan but which are uniformly mixing.

• Doing so has two implications. – First, the uniformly mixing assumption implies that pollutant

concentrations will not differ from place to place, and so the spatial dimension of emissions control is no longer of direct relevance.

– Second, persistence of pollution stocks over time means that the temporal dimension is of central importance.

• As we shall see, an efficient pollution control programme will need to take account of the trajectory of emissions over time, rather than just at a single point in time.

Page 36: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock pollutants: modelling

 • The model we use to examine pollution targets is the simplest

possible one that can deal with the intertemporal choices involved.

• Damage at time t is determined by the contemporaneous stock size or concentration of the pollutant in a relevant environmental medium.

• Gross benefits depend on the flow of emissions. • Hence our damage and (gross) benefit functions have the general

forms

Dt = D(At) (5.15)

Bt = B(Mt) (5.16)

Page 37: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Emissions stock-flow relationship

• With relatively long-lived pollutants, emissions add to existing stocks and those stocks accumulate over time. However, except where pollutants are infinitely long-lived, part of the existing stock will decay or degrade into a harmless form over time.

(5.17)

• The parameter is a decay coefficient, and is a proportion that must lie in the interval zero to one.

• A pollutant for which = 0 exhibits no decay, and so the second term on the right-hand side of equation 5.17 is zero.

• This is known as a perfectly persistent pollutant. In this case, integration of equation 5.17 shows that the stock at any time is the sum of all previous emissions.

tttαAMA

Page 38: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Emissions stock-flow relationship

• More generally, we expect to find 0 < < 1, and denote this as an imperfectly persistent pollutant.

• Here, the pollutant stock decays gradually over time, being converted into relatively harmless elements or compounds.

– Greenhouse gases provide one example, but with slow or very slow rates of decay.

• The second limiting case, where = 1, implies instantaneous decay, and so the pollutant can be regarded as a flow rather than a stock pollutant.

• The specification given in equation 5.17 imposes the restriction that the parameter is constant; a constant proportion of the pollution stock decays over any given interval of time. This may be invalid in practice.

Page 39: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Emissions stock-flow relationship

•  By integrating equation 5.17 over time we obtain

• where t0 denotes the first point in time at which the pollutant in question was emitted. Thus the pollution stock level at any time t, At, depends on the entire history of emissions up to that point in time.

• Even if emissions had been at a constant level in the past and were to remain so in the future, A would not be constant throughout time, except in the very long run.

dταAMA0

ttt

t

t

Page 40: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Targets and Policies• As time periods are linked together through a stock–flow relationship, efficient

pollution targets and policies must be derived from an intertemporal analysis.

• Assume that the policy maker aims to maximise discounted net benefits over some suitable time horizon.

• For simplicity, we take the horizon to be of infinite span.

• Using t = 0 to denote the current period of time, and defining the net benefits of pollution as gross benefits minus damages (specified respectively by equations 5.15 and 5.16) the policy maker’s objective is to select Mt for t = 0 to t = ∞ to maximise

(5.18)

where r is the social (consumption) discount rate.

dteAMB rt-

0

tt

t

t

D

Page 41: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Targets and Policies 

• A complete description of efficient stock pollution will, therefore, consist not of a single number for, but a trajectory (or time path) of, emission levels through time.

• In general, this optimal trajectory will be one in which emission levels vary throughout time.

• However, in many circumstances, the trajectory will consist of two phases. One of these phases is a so-called steady state in which emissions (and concentration levels) remain constant indefinitely at some level. The other is an adjustment phase; the trajectory describes a path by which emissions (and concentrations) move from current levels to their efficient, steady-state levels. This adjustment process may be quick, or it may take place over a long period of time.

Page 42: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Optimal steady-state trajectory• Even with complete information, obtaining an optimal emissions trajectory is

technically difficult.

• Involves the calculus of optimal control, explained in Chapters 14 and 16.

• In this chapter, we consider only the efficient steady-state pollution level, in which (by definition) the pollution flow and the pollution stock are each at a constant level.

• With an unchanging stock equation 5.17 simplifies to M = A. – Intuition: for a pollutant that accumulates over time, the pollution stock can only be constant if emission

inflows to the stock (M) are equal to the amount of stock which decays each period (A).

• It then follows that in a steady state, the stock–flow relationship between A and M can be written as

A = M/ (5.19)

• In a steady state, the smaller is the value of the larger will be the pollution stock for any given level of emissions.

Page 43: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Steady-state equilibrium

• Full derivation of the steady-state solution to this problem is in Chapter 16.

• Here, we just state one major result from that solution, interpret it intuitively, and discuss some of its characteristics.

• This is a variant of the familiar marginal condition for efficiency. The marginal benefit and the marginal cost of the chosen emissions level should be equal.

• It can be read as an equality between the instantaneous value of the gross benefit of a marginal unit of pollution (the LHS of 5.20) and the present value of the damage that arises from the marginal unit of pollution (the RHS of 5.20).

• The discount factor 1/(r + ) has the effect of transforming the single period damage into its present-value equivalent.

(5.20)αr

1

dA

dD

dM

dB

Page 44: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Steady-state equilibrium

• At the level of M that satisfies equation 5.20, the value taken by the expression on each side of the equation is known as the shadow price of a unit of emission.

• It is labelled as in several of the diagrams in this chapter and will figure prominently in our discussions in the next chapter.

• Note that while the damage arising from the marginal emission takes place today and in future periods, a marginal emission today has benefits only today, and so the instantaneous value of the marginal benefit is identical to its present value. So we could also interpret equation 5.20 in terms of an equality between two present values.

Page 45: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Examination of equation 5.20 shows two very important results:

• Other things being equal, the faster is the decay rate, the higher will be the efficient level of steady-state emissions.

– Reasoning: For any given value of dD/dA, a rise in implies that the value of dB/dM would have to fall to satisfy the marginal equality. A lower value of dB/dM implies higher emissions. The greater is the rate of decay the larger is the ‘effective’ discount rate applied to the marginal stock damage term and so the smaller is its present value. A higher discount rate means we attach less weight to damages in the future, and so the emission level can be raised accordingly.

• Other things being equal, the larger is the consumption discount rate, the higher will be the efficient level of steady-state emissions.

– Reasoning: For any given value of dD/dA, a rise in r implies that the value of dB/dM would have to fall to satisfy the marginal equality. A lower value of dB/dM implies higher emissions. Intuition: The greater is the consumption discount rate r, the larger is the discount rate applied to the stock damage term and so the smaller is its present value. A higher discount rate means we attach less weight to damages in the future, and so the emission level can be raised accordingly.

(5.20)αr

1

dA

dD

dM

dB

Page 46: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

An alternative version of equation 5.20

• For the purpose of looking at some special cases of equation 5.20, it will be convenient to use an alternative version of that expression:

• Four special cases of equation 5.21 can be obtained, depending on whether r = 0 or r > 0, and on whether = 0 or > 0.

• We portray these combinations in Table 5.2.

(5.21)α

r1

dM

dB

dM

dD

Page 47: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,
Page 48: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Case A: r = 0, > 0

• In this case the pollutant is imperfectly persistent and so eventually decays to a harmless form. With r = 0, no discounting of costs and benefits is being undertaken. Equation 5.21 collapses to:

• An efficient steady-state rate of emissions for a stock pollutant requires that the contribution to benefits from a marginal unit of pollution flow be equal to the contribution to damage from a marginal unit of pollution flow.

• See Figure 5.5

(5.22)dM

dB

dM

dD

Page 49: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

r

1dM

dB

M*

*

Emissions, M

**

M**

Figure 5.5 Efficient steady-state emission level for an imperfectly persistent stock pollutant. Two cases: {r = 0 and > 0} and {r > 0 and > 0}

dM

dB

dM

dD

Page 50: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Case B: r > 0, > 0

• With r and being positive numbers, the equilibrium condition is given by equation 5.21 in unchanged form.

• The marginal equality in this case incorporates the additional term 1/(r + ) to reflect the presence of discounting at a positive rate.

• This is shown diagrammatically in Figure 5.5, with M** denoting the equilibrium emission level.

• It is instructive to compare this equilibrium with that obtained in Case A. As r increases above zero, the marginal damages function rotates clockwise about the point .

• Discounting, therefore, increases the steady-state level of emissions.

• Moreover, the larger is the discount rate, the larger is the amount by which efficient steady-state emissions rise.

Page 51: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Cases C (r > 0, = 0) and D (r = 0, = 0)

• In both Cases C and D the pollutant is perfectly persistent, and so never decays to a harmless form.

• One might guess that something unusual is happening here by noting that equation 5.21 is undefined when = 0.

• The intuition that lies behind this is straightforward. No steady state exists except for the case in which M is zero. A steady state cannot exist for any positive value of M as A would rise without bound. But then pollution damage would also rise to infinity.

• It follows that, at some point in time, the environmental protection agency (EPA) would have to require that emissions be permanently set to zero to avoid the prospect of intolerable damage.

• The pollution stock level would remain at whatever level A had risen to by that time. Pollution damage would also continue indefinitely at some constant level, but no additional damage would be generated. The zero-emissions steady-state solution turns out to be perfectly in accord with good sense.

 

Page 52: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock or concentration rate of pollutant, A

Figure 5.6 Threshold effects and irreversibilities.

Figure 5.6a A threshold effect in the decay rate/pollution stock relationship .

Variable rate of decay: one possible example

Page 53: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Stock or concentration rate of pollutant, A

Figure 5.6(b) An irreversibility combined with a threshold effect.

Page 54: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Departures from convexity or concavity in damage and abatement cost (or pollution benefit) functions

Page 55: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

• •a b

x

f(x)

Figure 5.7 A strictly convex function

Page 56: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Convex setNon convex set

Figure 5.8 Convex and non convex sets

Page 57: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

x

f(x)

A convex set

Figure 5.9 A concave function, f(x), generating a convex set defined by points lying above it

Page 58: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

x

y

I

I

T

T

P

P

Figure 5.10 (Strict) Convexity generates equilibrium with a unique set of relative prices

Page 59: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

MS Emissions, M

D

D

MD = dD/dM

MS

MD

Emissions, M

Figure 5.11 A non-convex damage function arising from pollution reaching a saturation point

Page 60: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Figure 5.12

Page 61: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Location in economic space Location in economic space

Figure 5.13 Visualising lock in

Page 62: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

The Double Dividend hypothesis

• Emission reductions programmes may create joint benefits, and that when jointness is taken into account the net welfare impacts may be substantially enhanced.

• Beginning in the 1990’s, an important literature has developed that has formalised this idea by considering environmental improvement programmes within the context of a package that also includes reform of the structure of the taxation system.

• This literature has come to be known by one of its key propositions, the Double Dividend hypothesis.

• This hypothesis arises from the possibility that the revenues from an emissions tax (or a system of permits sold by auction) could be earmarked to reduce marginal rates of other taxes in the economy.

• If those other taxes have distortionary (i.e. inefficiency-generating) effects, then reducing their rate will create efficiency gains. Thus an environmental tax with revenues ring-fenced for reducing distortionary taxes has a double benefit (or double dividend); the environment is improved and efficiency gains accrue to the economy as whole.

Page 63: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Standard methodologyWhat much of the double dividend research literature has done can be roughly

characterised as the following:

 1. Begin by identifying one environmental problem in which we are particularly interested, such as an

uncompensated pollution externality. It is this externality on which an emission tax will be levied.

2. Specify the appropriate second-best benchmark economy, making clear exactly which particular configuration of inefficiencies or distortions are assumed to prevail in that economy. For the double dividend hypothesis to be meaningful there must be at least two distortions in the economy, one being the environmental problem referred to in 1. above, and a second being a distortionary tax.

3. One distortionary tax (or other institution) is then focussed upon. The revenues from the polluting emissions tax will be recycled so as to reduce the marginal rate of this distortionary tax. In early studies, this tax was typically chosen to be a tax on labour income, but it could be any (non-lump sum) tax.

4. Solve the model of the economy for its optimal welfare maximising solution twice: once, in the benchmark case in which there is no policy intervention; second in the simulation run case in which an emissions charge is imposed on the pollution externality, and that the revenue obtained from that charge is used in its entirety to reduce the selected distortionary tax.

5. Calculate the difference in welfare between the case of no intervention - the status quo ex ante benchmark – and the case in which the emissions charge is introduced with the revenue recycled to reducing the distortionary tax.

 

Page 64: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

Objectives of pollution policy

• We conclude by returning to an issue addressed at its outset: the objectives of pollution policy.

• Throughout most of this chapter a single criterion, economic efficiency, has been adopted.

• But it would be both naïve and wrong to assume that this is, or should be, the only or even the main objective.

• Each of the following has some claim to be regarded as a goal of environmental policy, and so might be given some weight in determining pollution targets with regard to stock pollutants:

– Sustainability and ecological goals (e.g. minimum disruption to ecosystems, maintenance of biodiversity)

– Human health protection

– Public preferences

Page 65: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

t*

MH

Figure 5.14 Setting targets according to an absolute health criterion.

Emissions, M

Marginal health damage

MC

Page 66: CHAPTER 5: Pollution control: targets. Agenda 5.1 Modelling frameworks 5.2Modelling pollution within an economic efficiency framework 5.3Pollution flows,

tH*

MH*

Figure 5.15 A ‘modified efficiency’ based health standard.

Emissions, M

Marginal health damage

MC