Chapter 4 Note

download Chapter 4 Note

of 5

Transcript of Chapter 4 Note

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    1/9

    1 Supplement to Chapter 4 in Galor.

    This note goes through the mathematical models of the chapter. These relate to three

    of the main hypotheses of the demographic transition. These are (1) The demographic

    transition was caused by increases in income; (2) the demographic transition was caused

    by declines in mortality; (3) the increased demand for human capital. These three are

    covered in the following. The note is best read in conjunction with Galor’s book.

    1.1 The rise in income per capita: non-robustness result

    The central hypothesis is that the decline in fertility observed in the late 19th century

    was caused by increased income due to the industrialization. The following model shows

    that this result is not theoretically robust. Consider a consumer who obtains utility from

    consumption (c) and surving children  (n):

    u =    ln n + (1  ) ln c

    The constraint is:

    c = (1 n) y;

    where    is the time cost associated with raising a child and  y  is the income earned if 

    all time is spent on working.

    The utility function can be written:

    u   =     ln n + (1  )ln((1 n) y)

    u   =     ln n + (1  )ln(1 n) + (1  ) ln y

    Di¤erentiating the utility function wrt to  n  gives:

    1

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    2/9

     1

    n + (1  )

      1

    1 n ( ) = 0

     1

    n

      = (1  )   

    1 n  (1 n) = (1  ) n

      n   =   n n

    n   =   

     

    The number of children is unrelated to income in this model. Thus, theoretically

    we would not expect that the opportunity cost of children (related to income growth)

    necessarily plays a role in the timing of the fertility decline.

    1.2 The decline in Infant and Child Mortality

    This hypothesis suggests that the decline in infant and child mortality that preceded the

    fertility decline is a plausible explanation of the onset of the demographic transition. The

    hypothesis can be illustrated in the framework of the previous sections by making the

    number of surviving children a function of the probability of surviving infancy    and the

    number of children the household will bear nb

    :

    n =  nb:

    Let utility maximization problem be the same as in the previous subsection. Therefore,

    the solution for n  is:

    n =  

      :

    The actual number of children is then:

    nb =   

      :

    It is seen that an increase in    leads to a lower number of children being born. In the

    absence of uncertainty, there is, however, no e¤ect on the surviving number of children.

    2

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    3/9

    Thus, the central prediction is that higher mortality rates (lower  ) leads to higher fertility

    rates, whereas the number of surviving children is unchanged.

    1.3 The rise in demand for Human Capital

    The second phase of industrialization witnessed a signi…cant increase in the demand for

    human capital. The increased demand for human capital led families to invest in the

    education of their children according to this hypothesis. Thus, the argument is that the

    increased demand for human capital led to a quantity-quality trade-o¤.

    The idea can be illustrated by considering the following utility maximization problem:

    u = (1  ) ln c +   ln n +   ln h;

    where h  is the level of human capital of each child, and 0  <  0):  The following

    assumptions are made:

    3

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    4/9

    lime!0

    he(e; g) =   1:

    lime!1

    he(e; g) = 0

    h(0; g)   >   0:

    The e¤ect of  g is an obsolence is e¤ect. Technological change means that some education

    is made obsolete. Further heg(e; g) >  0.

    The utility maximization problem can be rewritten as:

    maxe;n u   = (1  )ln((1 n ( 

    q

    +  

    e

    e) y) +   ln n +   ln h (e; g) =(1  ) ln y + (1  ) ln(1 n ( q +  ee)) +   ln n +   ln h (e; g) :

    The …rst order conditions become:

    @u

    @n  = (1  )

      1

    1 n ( q +  ee) ( ( q +  ee)) +  

    1

    n = 0:

    @u

    @e  =    

      1

    h (e; g)he(e; g)

      1  

    1 n ( q +  ee)n e = 0:

    The solution for n  is:

    n =   

     q +  ee:

    Now the second condition can be rewritten:

       1

    h (e; g)he(e; g) =

      1  

    1 n ( q +  ee)n e:

    By substituting the solution for n into this expression, we get:

    4

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    5/9

       1

    h (e; g)he(e; g) =

      1  

    1     q+ ee

     ( q +  ee)

     

     q +  ee e

       1

    h (e; g)

    he(e; g) =  1  

    1  

     

     q

    +  e

    e

     e

       1

    h (e; g)he(e; g) =

      1

     q +  ee e

     eh (e; g) =   he(e; g) ( q +  ee) :

    It can be established generally that an optimal solution for  e  and n  exists:

    e   =   e(g ; ;  q;  e):

    n   =     q +  ee(g ; ;  e;  q)

    :

    To establish this we de…ne the implicit function as determined by the necessary …rst

    order condition:

    G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)  eh (e; g) he(e; g) ( q +  ee) = 0

    The assumptions on  he(e; g) implies that:

    lime!0

    G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)   <   0

    lime!1

    G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)   >   0

    This follows from the fact that as  e ! 0,he  ! 1 (and h(0; g) >  0). Further, as e!1,

    h (e; g)  will converge at a positive value (if strictly increasing, it will go towards in…nity)

    and he(e; g) converges to 0.

    Further, we can establish that:

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @e  =    ehe (e; g) hee(e; g) ( 

    q +  ee)  ehe(e; g)

    = (1  )  ehe (e; g) hee (e; g) ( q +  ee) >  0:

    5

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    6/9

    Since 0  <  0  will make  G(:) = 0:

    Given this we can now sign how this value of  e  responds to the other parameters in

    the model by simply using the implicit function theorem. Recall that the average product

    of a strictly, increasing and concave function decreases with the value of the independent

    variable. In our case, this means:

    @ he

    @e  =

     ehe h (e; g)

    e2  ehe:

    This is used to establish the sign of the derivative wrt   e below:

    We next obtain the following derivates and their signs:

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @g

      =  ehg (e; g) heg (e; g) ( q +  ee) <  0

    Since hg   0:

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @   = he(e; g) ( 

    q +  ee) <  0

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @ q  = he(e; g) <  0:

    6

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    7/9

    Notice that there is a    q too much in Galor’s formula on page 138 compared to the

    above formula for   @G(g;; q ; e)

    @ q  :

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @ e  = h (e; g) he (e; g) e > 0:

    Which uses h(e; g) > ehe: > ehe  since 0  <  0

    @e

    @   =

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @   =

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @e  > 0

    @e@ q

      = @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @ q  =@G (e; g ; ;  

    q;  e)@e

      > 0

    @e

    @ e  =

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @ e  =

    @G (e; g ; ;  q;  e)

    @e 

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    8/9

    n =   

     q +  ee(g ; ;  e;  q)

    This can be di¤erentiated partially with respect to the four variables:

    @n

    @g  =

     e @e@g

    [ q +  ee(g ; ;  e;  q)]2 

  • 8/20/2019 Chapter 4 Note

    9/9

    Where we make the assumption that  g    ĝ  =   2 

    (1) which ensures  e    0:   It is easily

    seen that this function is increasing in  g   the rate of technological growth, and that  n   is

    decreasing in e  and hence  g :

    References

    [1] Lagerlöf, N.-P., 2006. The Galor-Weil model revisited: a quantitative exercise. Review

    of Economic Dynamics 9(1), 116-142.

    9