Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and...

42
Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 1 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review 1 2 Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigation 3 4 5 Coordinating Lead Authors 6 R.J.T. Klein (Netherlands), S. Huq (Bangladesh) 7 8 Lead Authors 9 F. Denton (Senegal), T.E. Downing (UK), R.G. Richels (USA), J.B. Robinson (Canada), F.L. Toth 10 (IAEA / Hungary) 11 12 Contributing Authors 13 B. Biagini (GEF / Italy), S. Burch (Canada) 14 15 Review Editors 16 M. Grubb (UK), U. Safriel (Israel), A. Allali (Morocco) 17 18 19 Contents 20 21 Executive Summary 2 22 23 18.1 Introduction 2 24 18.1.1 Background and Rationale 3 25 18.1.2 Structure of the chapter 4 26 27 18.2 Summary of relevant knowledge in IPCC TAR 5 28 29 18.3 Decision-making on inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 7 30 18.3.1 Objectives, decision processes 7 31 18.3.2 Spatial and temporal scale issues in decision-making 12 32 18.3.3 Stakeholder roles, risk and decision-making 13 33 18.3.4 Response capacity and development pathways 14 34 18.3.5 Adaptation, mitigation and sustainable development 18 35 36 18.4 Inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 20 37 18.4.1 Trade-offs and synergies 20 38 18.4.2 Climate policy and institutions 27 39 40 18.5 Elements for effective implementation 30 41 18.5.1 Identifying and evaluating inter-relationships 31 42 18.5.2 Financing and institutions 31 43 18.5.3 Relevance to policy and development 33 44 45 18.6 Information needs 33 46 47 References 36 48

Transcript of Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and...

Page 1: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 1 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review 1 2

Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigation 3 4 5 Coordinating Lead Authors 6 R.J.T. Klein (Netherlands), S. Huq (Bangladesh) 7 8 Lead Authors 9 F. Denton (Senegal), T.E. Downing (UK), R.G. Richels (USA), J.B. Robinson (Canada), F.L. Toth 10 (IAEA / Hungary) 11 12 Contributing Authors 13 B. Biagini (GEF / Italy), S. Burch (Canada) 14 15 Review Editors 16 M. Grubb (UK), U. Safriel (Israel), A. Allali (Morocco) 17 18 19 Contents 20 21 Executive Summary 2 22 23 18.1 Introduction 2 24 18.1.1 Background and Rationale 3 25

18.1.2 Structure of the chapter 4 26 27 18.2 Summary of relevant knowledge in IPCC TAR 5 28 29 18.3 Decision-making on inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 7 30

18.3.1 Objectives, decision processes 7 31 18.3.2 Spatial and temporal scale issues in decision-making 12 32 18.3.3 Stakeholder roles, risk and decision-making 13 33 18.3.4 Response capacity and development pathways 14 34 18.3.5 Adaptation, mitigation and sustainable development 18 35

36 18.4 Inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 20 37

18.4.1 Trade-offs and synergies 20 38 18.4.2 Climate policy and institutions 27 39

40 18.5 Elements for effective implementation 30 41

18.5.1 Identifying and evaluating inter-relationships 31 42 18.5.2 Financing and institutions 31 43 18.5.3 Relevance to policy and development 33 44

45 18.6 Information needs 33 46 47 References 36 48

Page 2: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 2 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Executive summary 1 2 This chapter identifies inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation in climate policy, and 3 assesses their significance and potential for climate policy. The six key messages of this chapter 4 are as follows: 5 6 · On a global scale, climate policy is not about choosing between mitigation or 7

adaptation to climate change. Adaptation is a necessity, because no mitigation effort will 8 prevent climate change from happening in the next few decades. On the other hand, reliance 9 on adaptation alone could eventually lead to a magnitude of climate change to which 10 effective adaptation will be possible only at very high social and economic costs. 11

12 · Whilst there are many differences between adaptation and mitigation, the two options 13

are inter-related in at least three ways. First, both options contribute to preventing 14 dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system, thus creating the possibility 15 of exploring trade-offs and synergies. Second, both adaptation and mitigation are subject of 16 international climate policy negotiations and the same global institutions are involved in 17 facilitating their implementation in developing countries. Third, the capacities of society to 18 mitigate and to adapt are both strongly linked to development pathways, in particular on a 19 local scale. 20

21 · Analysis of the inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation may promote the 22

effective implementation of climate policy. Meeting multiple objectives (e.g., by 23 developing synergies between adaptation and mitigation) can increase the cost-effectiveness 24 of options and make them more attractive to potential funders and other stakeholders. 25 However, an exclusive focus on synergies may lead to essential options without synergetic 26 effects being overlooked. 27

28 · A preliminary analysis of options that have both adaptive and mitigative effects 29

suggests that their potential to benefit climate policy would be limited. Whilst many 30 options exist that have such synergetic effects, it is unclear whether these effects are 31 serendipitous and whether their benefits justify policy intervention. 32

33 · One way of promoting both adaptation and mitigation would be to enhance society’s 34

response capacity. This would facilitate the effective implementation of both options, as 35 well as their mainstreaming into ongoing and future sectoral planning and development. 36 However, little empirical information is available on what determines response capacity and 37 on how it can best be enhanced. 38

39 · Insufficient information is available to evaluate the overall costs and benefits of 40

pursuing inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation. To provide decision-41 makers with unambiguous guidance on the desirability of inter-relationships requires 42 empirical research on, among other things, trade-offs and synergies, the link between 43 response capacity and development pathways, and the role of institutions in promoting both 44 adaptation and mitigation. 45

46 47 18.1 Introduction 48 49 The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) identifies two options 50

Page 3: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 3 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

to address climate change: mitigation of climate change by reducing greenhouse gas emissions 1 and enhancing sinks, and adaptation to the impacts of climate change. Most industrialised 2 countries have committed themselves, as signatories to the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol, to 3 stabilising greenhouse gas emissions at 1990 levels by the year 2000 and to reducing their overall 4 greenhouse gas emissions by at least 5% compared to 1990 by the period 2008–2012 (an 5 assessment of current efforts aimed at mitigating climate change is presented by Working Group 6 III). However, because of the lag times in the global climate system, no mitigation effort, no 7 matter how rigorous and relentless, is going to prevent climate change from happening in the next 8 few decades (see relevant chapters in Working Group I). In fact, the first impacts of climate 9 change are already being observed (see Chapter 1). 10 11 Adaptation is therefore a necessity (Parry et al., 1998). Chapter 17 presents examples of 12 adaptations to climate change that are currently being observed but concludes that there are limits 13 to effective adaptation. Even if these limits were to be removed, however, reliance on adaptation 14 alone could well lead to a magnitude of climate change in the long run to which effective 15 adaptation is only possible at very high social and economic costs (as, for example, shown for sea-16 level rise in Europe by Lonsdale et al., 2005; Poumadère et al., 2005; Olsthoorn et al., 2005). It is 17 therefore no longer a question of whether to mitigate climate change or to adapt to it. Both 18 mitigation and adaptation have become essential in reducing the risks of climate change. 19 20 21 18.1.1 Background and rationale 22 23 The level of climate change impacts, and whether or not this level is dangerous (cf. Article 2 of 24 the UNFCCC), is determined by both mitigation and adaptation efforts. Nonetheless, discussions 25 on mitigation and adaptation have been rather unconnected in both climate research and climate 26 policy, involving largely different communities of scholars and negotiators. Only recently 27 policymakers have expressed an interest in exploring inter-relationships between adaptation and 28 mitigation beyond integrated assessment modelling, which has in turn triggered an increased 29 research effort. In particular, the link between the two climate response options vis-à-vis 30 development is becoming a focus for policy and research. 31 32 Traditionally, the focus of climate policy has been on energy policy, with little attention being 33 given to enhancing sinks or to adaptation. As energy supply relies predominantly on fossil fuels 34 (the main source of anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions), energy policy has been the logical 35 entry point for mitigation. This policy focus was reflected in the IPCC Second Assessment Report 36 (SAR). Since the publication of the SAR, the international climate policy community has become 37 aware that energy policy alone will not suffice in the quest to control climate change and limit its 38 impacts. Climate policy is being expanded from energy policy to consider a wide range of options 39 aimed at sequestering carbon in vegetation, oceans and geological formations, and at reducing the 40 vulnerability of sectors and communities to the impacts of climate change by means of adaptation. 41 Consequently, the IPCC Third Assessment Report (TAR) provided a more balanced treatment of 42 mitigation and adaptation, illustrating the increased interest in adaptation. 43 44 Recognising the finitude of funds and the consequent need to explore trade-offs between the long-45 term global benefits of mitigation and the immediate local benefits of adaptation, the question has 46 now arisen as to exactly how much adaptation and mitigation would be optimal, when and in 47 which combination (GAIM Task Force, 2002). In addition to exploring trade-offs, opportunities 48 are being sought to develop synergies between adaptation and mitigation. Synergies in climate 49 policy are created when measures that control atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations also 50

Page 4: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 4 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

reduce adverse effects of climate change, or vice versa. 1 2 The amount of literature that deals explicitly with inter-relationships between adaptation and 3 mitigation is still small. Yet it is also very diverse: there is no consensus in the literature as to 4 whether exploring and exploiting inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation is 5 desirable (cf. Venema and Cisse, 2004; Klein et al., 2005). The small size of the literature and the 6 lack of consensus pose a challenge to policymakers and academics alike. As a possible first step in 7 addressing this challenge, this chapter does not only assess the available literature on inter-8 relationships between adaptation and mitigation; it also presents an analytical framework with 9 which such assessment can be done consistently and in line with earlier climate policy analysis. 10 11 12 18.1.2 Structure of the chapter 13 14 Box 18.1 summarises the differences, similarities and complementarities between adaptation and 15 mitigation. This chapter then uses this information as the starting point for assessing to what 16 extent adaptation and mitigation are related, and if and how any such inter-relationships could be 17 exploited in climate policy. The chapter is structured as follows. Section 18.2 summarises the 18 knowledge relevant to this chapter that was presented in the IPCC Third Assessment Report 19 (TAR). Section 18.3 then frames the challenge to climate policy of deciding when, how much and 20 how to adapt and mitigate as a decision-theoretical problem, based on which Section 18.4 21 describes and assesses three categories of inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation: 22 (i) trade-offs and synergies, (ii) climate policy and institutions, and (iii) response capacity. Section 23 18.5 then assesses the literature for elements for effective implementation of climate policy that 24 relies on inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation. Section 18.6 outlines information 25 needs of climate policy and priorities for research. 26 27 28 Box 18.1: Differences, similarities and complementarities between adaptation and mitigation 29 30 IPCC TAR used the following definitions: mitigation is any “anthropogenic intervention to reduce 31 the sources or enhance the sinks of greenhouse gases” (IPCC, 2001a: 379), whereas “[A]daptation 32 to climate change refers to adjustment in natural or human systems in response to actual or 33 expected climatic stimuli or their effects, which moderates harm or exploits beneficial 34 opportunities” (IPCC, 2001a: 365). 35 36 There are a number of important differences between mitigation and adaptation. Given the global 37 nature of climate change, meaningful mitigation actions need to involve several countries (a 38 sufficient number of major greenhouse gas emitters to foreclose leakage), whereas adaptation 39 activities largely take place at local, regional or national levels. Adaptation rarely expands beyond 40 national boundaries, although some adaptation strategies might result in spillovers over national 41 boundaries (e.g., by changing international commodity prices in agricultural or forest product 42 markets). The costs of mitigation arise locally (economic spillovers are possible) while its benefits 43 are dispersed globally (ancillary benefits might be realised at the local/regional level). Both the 44 costs and benefits of adaptation accrue predominantly locally (with the possibility of spillovers to 45 other regions and to other actors, for example in flood protection or coastal zones). The benefits of 46 mitigation spread over decades to centuries (disregarding possible near-term ancillary benefits) 47 while the benefits of most adaptation efforts can be realised within years and over decades. 48 Correspondingly, there is a long delay between paying for the mitigation costs and realising their 49 benefits from smaller climate change while the time span between outlays and returns of 50

Page 5: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 5 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

adaptation is much shorter. These asymmetries imply that mitigation is driven by international 1 agreements and ensuing national public policies (sometimes supplemented by community-based 2 initiatives), whereas the bulk of adaptation actions are driven by the affected private actors and 3 communities, possibly assisted by public policies. This also entails that mitigation policies require 4 rigorous implementation measures while adaptation is largely fostered by the self-interest of the 5 affected agents. Finally, mitigation is by necessity based on information available today whereas 6 adaptation strategies can benefit from improving information about climate change and its impacts 7 over the coming years and decades. 8 9 There are a number of linkages between mitigation and adaptation at different levels of decision-10 making. Mitigation efforts can foster adaptive capacity if they eliminate market failures and 11 distortions as well as perverse subsidies that prevent actors to make decisions on the basis of the 12 true social costs of the available options. However, mitigation expenditures imply diverting social 13 or private resources and reduce the funds available for adaptation, especially if they accrue to 14 social groups adversely affected by climate change (e.g., agriculture in many regions). Similarly, 15 the implications of adaptation activities can be both positive and negative for mitigation 16 endeavours. For example, if afforestation is part of a regional adaptation strategy, it also makes a 17 positive contribution to mitigation. In contrast, if adaptation actions imply increased energy use 18 from carbon emitting sources (e.g., indoor heating and cooling, irrigation and alike), this would 19 affect mitigation efforts negatively. 20 21 Mitigation and adaptation are connected in the local and national policy portfolios and their 22 relative importance depends on local priorities and preferred approaches in combination with 23 international responsibilities. 24 25 26 27 18.2 Summary of relevant knowledge in IPCC TAR 28 29 Compared to the SAR, two of the Working Groups preparing the IPCC TAR were restructured. 30 The scope assigned to Working Group II was limited to impacts of climate change on sectors and 31 regions and to issues of vulnerability and adaptation, while Working Group III was commissioned 32 to assess the technological, economic, social and political aspects of mitigation. Whereas there 33 were concerted efforts to assess linkages of both mitigation and adaptation to sustainable 34 development (see Chapter 20), there was little room to consider the direct relationships between 35 these two domains. The integration of results and the development of policy-oriented synthesis 36 were therefore difficult (Toth, 2003). 37 38 The attempt to establish the foundations of the Synthesis Report (IPCC, 2001a) in the final 39 chapters of Working Groups II and III produced limited results. Chapter 19 in Working Group II 40 presented “Reasons for concern about projected climate change impacts” in a summary figure that 41 outlines the risks associated with different magnitudes of warming, expressed in terms of the 42 increase in global mean temperature. Largely based on integrated assessment models (IAMs), 43 Chapter 10 in WG III summarised the costs of stabilising CO2 concentrations at different levels. 44 These two summaries are difficult to compare because the questions as to what radiative forcing 45 and climate sensitivity parameters should be used to bridge the concentration-temperature gap 46 remains unanswered. Moreover, many statements in the two working group reports were 47 themselves distilled from a large number of reviewed studies. Yet the generic assumptions 48 underlying the methods, the specific assumptions of the applications, the selected baseline values 49 for the scenarios, and many other postulations implicit in the parameterisation of mitigation and 50

Page 6: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 6 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

adaptation assessments were largely ignored or remained hidden in the Synthesis Report. 1 2 Nonetheless, the TAR presented new concepts for addressing inter-relationships between 3 adaptation and mitigation. Local adaptive and mitigative capacities vary significantly across 4 regions and over time. Superficially they appear to be strongly correlated because they share the 5 same list of determinants. However, aggregate representation across nations or social groups of 6 both mitigation and adaptation is misleading because the capacity to reduce emissions of 7 greenhouse gases and the ability to adapt to it can deviate significantly. As the TAR pointed out: 8 “one country can easily display high adaptive capacity and low mitigative capacity simultaneously 9 (or vice versa)” (IPCC, 2001b: 107; see also Yohe, 2001). In a wealthy nation the damages may 10 fall on a small but influential social group and the costs of adaptation can be distributed across the 11 entire population through the tax system. Yet in the same country, another small group might be 12 hurt by mitigation policies without the possibility to spread this burden. In addition to the 13 conceptual deliberations, the TAR discussed inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 14 at two levels: at the aggregated, global and national levels and in the context of economic sectors 15 and specific projects. 16 17 The WGII report pointed out that “Adaptation is a necessary strategy at all scales to complement 18 climate change mitigation efforts” (IPCC 2001c: 6) but also elaborates the complex relationships 19 between the two domains at various levels. Some relationships are synergistic while others are of 20 trade-off nature. The report noted the arguments in the literature about the trade-off between 21 adaptation and mitigation because resources committed to one are not available for the other but 22 notes that this is “debatable in practice because the people who bear emission reduction costs or 23 benefits often are different from those who pay for and benefit from adaptation measures” (IPCC 24 2001c: 94). From the dynamic perspective, “climatic changes today still are relatively small, thus 25 there is little need for adaptation, although there is considerable need for mitigation to avoid more 26 severe future damages. By this logic, it is more prudent to invest the bulk of the resources for 27 climate policy in mitigation, rather than adaptation (IPCC 2001c: 94). Yet, as WGIII noted, one 28 should bear in mind the intergenerational trade-offs. The impacts of today’s climate change 29 investments on future generations’ opportunities should also be considered. Investments might 30 enhance the capacity of future generations to adapt to climate change, but at the same time they 31 may displace investments that could create other opportunities for future generations (IPCC 32 2001b: 484). 33 34 WGIII Chapter 10 outlined the iterative process in which nations balance their own mitigation 35 burden against their own adaptation and damage costs. “The need for, extent and costs of 36 adaptation measures in any region will be determined by the magnitude and nature of the regional 37 climate change driven by shifts in global climate. How global climate change unfolds will be 38 determined by the total amount of greenhouse gas emissions that, in turn, reflects nations’ 39 willingness to undertake mitigation measures. Moreover, balancing mitigation and adaptation 40 efforts largely depends on how mitigation costs are related to net damages (primary or gross 41 damage minus damage averted through adaptation plus costs of adaptation). Both mitigation costs 42 and net damages, in turn, depend on some crucial baseline assumptions: economic development 43 and baseline emissions largely determine emission reduction costs, while development and 44 institutions influence vulnerability and adaptive capacity” (IPCC 2001b: 604). 45 46 Discussions of inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation are sparser at the 47 sector/project level. Some chapters in WGII noted the mitigation linkages when discussing climate 48 change impacts and adaptation in selected sectors, primarily those related to land-use, agriculture 49 and forestry. WGII Chapter 5 noted that “[A]fforestation in agroforestry projects designed to 50

Page 7: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 7 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

mitigate climate change may provide important initial steps towards adaptation” (IPCC 2001c: 1 296). Chapter 8 emphasised sustainable forestry, agriculture and wetlands practices that yield 2 benefits in watershed management and flood/mudflow control but involve trade-offs such as 3 wetlands restoration helping to protect against flooding and coastal erosion, but producing 4 methane release. 5 6 WGII Chapter 12 observed the complexities in land management in Australia and New Zeeland 7 “where control of land degradation through farm and plantation forestry is being considered as a 8 major option, partly for its benefits in controlling salinisation and waterlogging and possibly as a 9 new economic option with the advent of incentives for carbon storage as a greenhouse mitigation 10 measure (IPCC 2001c: 608). Chapter 15 mentioned soil conservation practices (e.g., no tillage, 11 increased forage production, higher cropping frequency) implemented as mitigation strategies in 12 North America (IPCC 2001c: 756). It observed that the Kyoto Protocol mentions human-induced 13 land-use changes and forestry activities (afforestation, reforestation, deforestation) as sinks of 14 greenhouse gases for which sequestration credits can be claimed and that agricultural sinks may 15 be considered in the future. The market emerging in North America to enhance carbon 16 sequestration leads to land management decisions with diverse effects. The negative consequences 17 of reduced tillage implemented to enhance soil carbon sequestration include the increased use of 18 pesticides for disease, insect and weed management; capturing carbon in labile forms that are 19 vulnerable to rapid oxidation if the system is changed; and reduced yields and cropping 20 management options and increased risk for farmers. The beneficial consequences of reduced 21 tillage (especially no-till) are reduced input costs (e.g., fuel) for farmers; increased soil moisture 22 and hence reductions in crop water stress in dry areas; reduction in soil erosion; and improved soil 23 quality (IPCC 2001c: 758). 24 25 In chapters dealing with other sectors affected by climate change impacts and mitigation, less 26 attention was paid to their linkages. WGII Chapter 8 mentioned energy end-use efficiency in 27 buildings having both mitigation and adaptation benefits as improved insulation and equipment 28 efficiency can reduce the vulnerability of structures to extreme temperature episodes and 29 emissions. An example of the remote causalities between mitigation and adaptation across space 30 and time was provided by Chapter 17. Small island states are recognised to be vulnerable to 31 climate change and tourism is a major source of income for many of them. While over the long 32 term, milder winters in their current markets could reduce the appeal of these islands as tourist 33 destinations, they could be even more severely harmed by increased airline fares “if greenhouse 34 gas mitigation measures (e.g., levies and emission charges) were to result in higher costs to 35 airlines servicing routes between the main markets and small island states” (IPCC 2001c: 862). 36 37 Finally, WGII Chapter 8 drew attention to a linkage between adaptation and mitigation in the 38 Kyoto Protocol that establishes a surcharge on mitigation projects implemented as Clean 39 Development Mechanisms. “One key issue is the size of the “set-aside” from CDM projects that is 40 dedicated to funding adaptation. If this set-aside is too large, it will make otherwise viable 41 mitigation projects uneconomic and serve as a disincentive to undertake projects. This would be 42 counterproductive to the creation of a viable source of funding for adaptation” (IPCC 2001c: 444). 43 44 45 18.3 Decision-making on inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 46 47 18.3.1 Objectives, decision processes 48 49 Climate change is one of the most complex issues facing humankind. Experts still debate both the 50

Page 8: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 8 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

magnitude and timing of the problem. Uncertainties exist in our understanding of the greenhouse 1 effect, its likely consequences, and the efficacy of various countermeasures. Yet, uncertainty need 2 not lead to paralysis. A portfolio of actions is available for reducing the risks of climate change. 3 Each needs to be evaluated on its individual and collective merits. Policymakers need to decide 4 what constitutes the right mix of near-term actions in the face of the many long-term uncertainties. 5 Among the actions under consideration are investments in (i) mitigation: actions that eliminate or 6 reduce greenhouse gas emissions, or remove greenhouse gases from the atmosphere; (ii) 7 adaptation: actions that help human and natural systems to adjust to climate change should it 8 occur; (iii) technology: R&D to enhance mitigative and adaptive capacity; and (iv) research: 9 continued research to reduce uncertainties about how much change will occur, at what rate and 10 what effects it will have. 11 12 The list of options suggests a multitude of possible decision-makers both spatially and temporally. 13 Mitigation is being debated by the UNFCCC and its subsidiary bodies. It is also being discussed 14 independently by member states. And more recently, there has been a great deal of activity taking 15 place at the grassroots level. Adaptation decisions embrace both the public and private sector. 16 With proactive adaptation, decisions often involve large construction projects in the hands of 17 public sector decision-makers. With reactive adaptation, decisions are often localised, involving 18 many private sector agents. Decisions related to technology development, demonstration, and 19 diffusion are similarly diffuse, involving both the developers and users of technology. The same 20 applies to scientific research. 21 22 It is difficult and perhaps counterproductive to explore the payoffs from various types of 23 investments without a conceptual framework for thinking about their interactions. Decision 24 analysis provides one such framework. It allows for the systematic evaluation of near-term options 25 in light of the careful consideration of the potential consequences. The next several decades will 26 require a series of decisions on how best to reduce the risks from climate change. There will no 27 doubt be opportunities for learning and midcourse corrections. The immediate challenge facing 28 policy makers is what actions make sense today in the face of the many long-term uncertainties. 29 30 Figure 18.1 provides a caricature of the climate policy “decision tree”. In the language of decision 31 analysis, the squares represent points at which decisions are made, the circles represent the 32 reduction of uncertainty in the outcomes, and the arrows indicate the wide range of possible 33 decisions and outcomes. The diagram is by no means exhaustive. Nor do we intend to search for 34 the optimal set of near-term decisions. Such a quest is beyond the scope of this chapter. Indeed, it 35 is questionable whether such an analysis is even possible given the diversity of decisions required 36 at the international, domestic, and local levels. 37 38 The first decision node summarises some of today’s investment options. How much should we 39 invest in mitigation? In adaptation? In expanding mitigative and adaptive capacity? And in 40 research to reduce scientific uncertainty? Once we act, we have an opportunity to learn and make 41 mid-course corrections. The outcome nodes represent some of the types of learning that will occur 42 between now and the next set of decisions. The outcomes are uncertain; the uncertainty may not 43 be resolved but there will be new information which may influence future actions. Hence, the 44 expression “act, then learn, and then act again” (Beltratti, 1996). 45 46 47

Page 9: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 9 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 Figure 18.1: The dynamic nature of the climate policy process. The squares are decision nodes, 37 with arrows indicating the wide range of actions. The circles are outcome nodes, with wide range 38 of potential consequences. 39 40 41 The outcome nodes reflect uncertainty in the consequences of the decision nodes. How effective is 42 each action in meeting its respective goal and what have we learned to facilitate the achievement 43 of future goals? For example, are countries achieving their mitigation targets? What have we 44 learned about the ability of existing institutions to implement reductions mandated at the 45 international, domestic, and local level? What are the marginal and total costs of implementation 46 and the impact on market and non-market systems? What will be the population and their 47 economic status in 2050, 2100? What is the significance of increasing life spans? Will there be 48 shortfalls in the size and capacity of the workforce? Presumably we will also learn more about the 49 likelihood, nature, and magnitude of climate change and its consequences in the future. 50

Page 10: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 10 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 The issue of development paths is particularly complex. Climate change mitigation and adaptation 2 will both be affected by, and have impacts on, broader socio-economic policies and trends, such as 3 those related to development, sustainability and equity. In the present context, it is unclear 4 whether development should be characterised as a decision node, an uncertainty node, or both. 5 Given the focus of this chapter, we treat development paths as a critical uncertainty, recognising 6 the inherent interactions between decisions related to mitigation and adaptation and those related 7 to development. 8 9 Figure 18.2 shows schematically how decisions on climate policy relate to development paths. 10 Particular climate policy decisions, and the climate policy decision problem itself, are rooted in 11 the larger context of response capacity and development paths. Thus the act-learn-act-again 12 framework is connected to a larger set of policy decisions that are not driven by climate policy. 13 Ideally, those connections would be explicit and the act-learn-act-again framework would be 14 expanded to include, insofar as possible, explicit consideration of those larger contextual factors. 15 In some cases this might involve only an explicit consideration of the implications of climate 16 policy measures for sustainable development. In others it might extend to the development of a 17 sustainable development policy framework in which climate goals are embedded. In either case, 18 the decision framework connects climate policy to the larger world of sustainable development 19 analysis and policy. 20 21

22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 Figure 18.2: Climate policy decision-making and development paths framing climate policy 38 decision making. Climate policy decisions (the rectangular panels of decision nodes) connect to 39 underlying socio-economic and technological development paths (the branching streams). The 40 development path frames and constrains response capacity—indicated by the squares with a blend 41 of mitigation (red) and adaptive (blue) capacity. Climate policy choices (the square nodes) may 42 not be related to development policy, either at the international scale (above the path) or local 43 actors who are unlikely to influence development pathways (below the path). Climate responses 44 may occur at key junctures. The outcomes of these branch-decisions, sometimes called tipping 45 points, is represented by the circular nodes, also shaded according to the balance of mitigative or 46 adaptive capacity. As the path unfolds, different mitigation and adaptation options may be 47 available and the success of their outcomes may change. 48 49 50

Page 11: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 11 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 Box 18.2: Mitigation Policy 2 3 Programs and specific interventions that might reduce either the rate at which the radiative 4 balance is changing or the ultimate level at equilibrium, assuming one is reached. Mitigation 5 policies include not only interventions designed to reduce the emission of greenhouse gases but 6 also actions such as reforestation (or reducing deforestation), removal of radiatively active gases 7 from the atmosphere, and altering the earth’s albedo in ways that affect the earth’s radiative 8 balance. 9 10 The US National Academies of Science 11 12 13 14 15 Box 18.3: Cost-Effectiveness Analysis, Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Tolerable Windows 16 Approach 17 18 The ultimate goal of the UNFCCC is “the stabilisation of greenhouse gas concentrations in the 19 atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate 20 system.” Mitigation costs are of secondary importance. The Convention states that “policies and 21 measures to deal with climate change should be cost-effective so as to ensure global benefits at the 22 lowest possible costs.” In other words, once a maximum safe level of concentrations has been 23 determined, the goal is to identify a “least-cost” way for meeting the objective subject to the 24 constraint. 25 26 Most (but certainly not all) economists would argue that cost-effectiveness analysis, while useful, 27 does not go far enough. Policy makers need to consider both the costs of policies and what they 28 might achieve in terms of reducing environmental damages. Unfortunately, our ability to conduct 29 such analysis at the present time is limited due to problems with quantifying and valuing impacts. 30 31 In cost-benefit analysis, the goal is to minimise the sum of mitigation costs and damages. By 32 introducing damages into the calculation, one can explore assumptions about the effects of 33 adaptation on impacts and hence the extent to which adaptation can reduce damages. However, to 34 date, there have been relatively few attempts to simultaneously treat mitigation and adaptation as 35 decision variables. Indeed, most analysis of the benefits of adaptation have assumed a given level 36 of mitigation (either implicitly or explicitly) and then examined the consequences of alternative 37 adaptation decisions. Unlike the mitigation analysis, adaptation analysis has been bottom-up by 38 necessity. That is, it is conducted at a much smaller level of aggregation. 39 40 Consistent with the decision tree framework (Figure 18.1), cost-effectiveness and cost-benefit 41 analyses are not only deterministic, but also probabilistic. This adds a powerful dimension to the 42 analysis in that it allows for the consideration of uncertainty, particularly the occurrence of low 43 probability, high consequence events. Outcomes are identified for key uncertainties and 44 probabilities are assigned to each. For example in one multi-model study of optimal hedging 45 strategies, probabilities were assigned to temperature change and impacts. As with the 46 deterministic analysis, the focus was on a single investment category – the optimal near-term 47 mitigation. 48 49 The tolerable windows approach (TWA) combines aspects of cost-effectiveness and cost-benefit 50

Page 12: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 12 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

analysis. It is based on the premise that decisions about the limits to unacceptable climate change 1 impacts and costs are normative judgements based on the values and perceptions of social actors 2 and derives fields or corridors of long-term CO2 emissions. For any specific cost-impact 3 combination, if the corridor exists, it contains all emission paths that prevent surpassing the 4 impact limit without exceeding the cost limit any time during the time horizon (typically 100 to 5 200 years). If such a corridor does not exist, willingness to pay for mitigation, willingness to 6 tolerate higher impacts or a combination of the two is required to find at least one feasible 7 pathway. Probabilistic versions of the TWA model are not available as yet but it is possible to 8 conduct standard uncertainty analyses. This includes exploring sequential decision-making when 9 an emission path is prescribed for a given period and the model computes its implications for the 10 long-term emission corridor. The TWA therefore takes explicit social decisions about acceptable 11 impacts and costs and produces a domain of feasible mitigation strategies but leaves the actual 12 choice within this domain to decision-makers who can consider factors and goals not included in 13 the model. 14 15 16 17 Although we have presented examples of how actual analyses fit into the decision tree framework, 18 the main purpose of the framework is to provide a structure for thinking about an extremely 19 complex problem. Although convenient for purposes of economic analysis, outcomes do not have 20 to be expressed in a common unit. Nor is cost-effectiveness or cost-benefit analysis the only way 21 to evaluate specific investments. Indeed, it is not even necessary to agree with the present 22 structuring of the decision problem. What is necessary is to recognise the interrelationship of what 23 might initially appear to be a group of unrelated and disconnected decisions and begin to think 24 about how to take advantage of their synergies and trade-offs. 25 26 27 18.3.2 Spatial and temporal scale issues in decision-making 28 29 Climate change decision-making – acting, learning, then acting – is not a once-and-for-all event. 30 Rather it is a process that is likely to take place over decades if not centuries. Furthermore, it does 31 not occur at discrete intervals but is driven by the pace of social, economic, scientific and political 32 processes. Decisions are taken at different spatial and social scales, and by a variety of actors (see 33 Section 18.3.3). 34 35 The nature of the decisions changes over time. For example, mitigation choices may initially 36 begin with easy measures such as adoption of low-cost supply and demand-side options in the 37 energy sector. Through successful investment in research and development, a host of low-cost 38 alternatives should become available in the energy sector allowing for a transition to low-carbon-39 venting pathways. Given the current composition of the energy sector, this is unlikely to happen 40 overnight but through a series of decisions over time. Initially, adaptation decisions are likely to 41 address current climatic risks (e.g., drought early-warning systems) and be anticipatory or 42 proactive (e.g., land-use regulations). With increasing climate change, autonomous or reactive 43 actions (e.g., purchasing air conditioning) are likely to increase. 44 45 Decision-making on inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation takes place at more 46 than one spatial and institutional scale, implying different actors and objectives (see Section 47 18.3.3). A common decision-making hierarchy is from policy to implementation. Policy refers to 48 the agenda setting and regulatory role of policymaking bodies (e.g., a new law on renewable 49 energy). Strategic planning refers to the translation of policy into action through programmes 50

Page 13: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 13 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

(e.g., guidance for urban planning on energy efficiency). Operational implementation is within the 1 remit of specific actors with direct effects on sectoral and regional activities (e.g., decisions to 2 purchase air conditioning). The latter two categories are consistent with the common division 3 between strategies and measures in the UNFCCC documents. 4 5 These decision-making scales are often congruent with spatial scales, although many decisions 6 span more than one spatial scale. Within a policy framework, at a highly aggregated, international 7 scale, mitigation and adaptation are often seen as substitutes: the more mitigation is undertaken, 8 the less adaptation is necessary and vice versa. Resources devoted to mitigation might impede 9 socio-economic development and reduce investments in adaptive capacity and adaptation projects. 10 11 National and sub-national decision-making is often a mixture of policy and strategic planning. The 12 mitigation-adaptation trade-off is problematic at this scale because the effectiveness of mitigation 13 outlays in terms of averted climate change depends on the mitigation efforts of other major 14 greenhouse gas emitters. Thus, the magnitude of necessary adaptation is disconnected from an 15 individual country’s mitigation. A national policy example of synergies might be a new water law 16 that requires metered use, enabling water companies to adjust their charges in anticipation of 17 scarcity and conserve energy through demand-side measures. This policy would then be 18 implemented in strategic plans by water companies and environment agencies at a sub-national 19 level. 20 21 At the operational scale of specific projects, there may be trade-offs or synergies between 22 adaptation and mitigation. However, the majority of projects are unlikely to have strong inter-23 linkages. Section 18.4.1 summarises the insights from recent work on these issues, including 24 examples such as community afforestation to support sustainable livelihoods. 25 26 The linkages between adaptation and mitigation also link across scales (Cash and Moser, 2000; 27 Rosenberg and Scott, 1996). A policy framework is often seen as essential in driving strategic 28 investment and operational projects (e.g., Grubb, 2003, Grubb et al., 2002 for technological 29 innovation). Or, operational experience is seen as a precursor to developing sound strategies and 30 policies (BP?). In many cases the results of action at one scale have implications at another scale 31 (e.g., local adaptation decisions that increase greenhouse gas emissions, or national carbon taxes 32 that change local resource use). 33 34 35 18.3.3 Stakeholder roles, risk and decision-making 36 37 In the act-then-learn characterisation of decision-making, the roles of various stakeholders 38 embrace different aspects of mitigation-adaptation linkages. Stakeholders may be characterised 39 according to their constitution (public or private), level of decision-making (policy, strategic 40 planning or operational implementation), geographic scale (local, national or international) and 41 networks (single actor, stakeholder regime or institution). In addition, decision-making may be 42 motivated by climatic risks or climate change (e.g., climate-driven, climate-sensitive, climate-43 related) and the domain of action might cover mitigation only, mitigation-adaptation linked, or 44 adaptation only. 45 46 Stakeholders are exposed to a variety of risks, including financial, regulatory, strategic, 47 operational, or to their reputations, physical assets, life and livelihoods (e.g., Institute for Risk 48 Management, 2002). Risk is commonly defined as the probability of a consequence, while 49 uncertainty is often taken to represent structural and behavioural factors that are not readily 50

Page 14: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 14 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

captured in probability distributions (e.g., Stainforth et al., 2005, Tol, 2003). Stakeholder decision 1 making includes awareness and perception of climate change issues, negotiation, bargaining and 2 social norms (Clark et al., 2001), analytical frameworks (see Section 18.3.1), and information and 3 monitoring systems. Faced with the deep uncertainty of climate change, stakeholders may adopt a 4 precautionary approach with the intention of stimulating technological (if not social) change. For 5 instance, estimates of the social cost of carbon, one measure of the benefits of mitigation, are 6 sensitive to the choice of decision framework (including equity weighting, risk aversion, 7 sustainability considerations, and discount rates for future damages) (Downing et al., 2005, Tol, 8 2004). 9 10 Relatively few public or corporate decision-makers have direct responsibility for both adaptation 11 and mitigation. For example, adaptation might reside in a ministry of environment while 12 mitigation policy is led by a trade or economic ministry. However, criteria relating to either 13 mitigation or adaptation, or both, are increasingly common in decision-making. For example, local 14 development plans might screen housing developments according to energy use, water 15 requirements and preservation of green belt. Development agencies have begun to screen their 16 projects for relevance to mitigation and adaptation (e.g., Burton and Van Aalst, 1999; Klein, 2001; 17 Eriksen and Næss, 2003). 18 19 Many stakeholders embrace concerns related to mitigation (e.g., energy efficiency) and adaptation 20 (e.g., sustainable communities, poverty reduction) through environmental policies and not 21 necessarily climate change per se. Preliminary work by Nagai and Hepburn (2005) suggests that 22 there may be a trade off between cost-effective emission reductions and the achievement of other 23 sustainable development objectives --- in other words, more expensive projects per emission 24 reduction unit tend to contribute more to sustainable development then cheaper projects. 25 26 27 18.3.4 Response capacity and development pathways 28 29 As outlined in the IPCC TAR (Working Group II, Ch.18 and Working Group III, Ch. 1)1 and 30 discussed at more length in Chapter 17 of this volume and Chapter 12 of the Working Group III 31 report, the ability to implement specific adaptation and mitigation measures is dependent upon the 32 existence and nature of adaptive and mitigative capacity, which make such measures possible and 33 affects their extent and effectiveness. In that sense, specific adaptation and mitigation measures 34 are rooted in their respective capacities. 35 36 Adaptive capacity has been defined in the Third Assessment Report (Working Group II, Ch.18.1) 37 as “the potential, capability, or ability of a system to adapt to climate change stimuli or their 38 effects or impacts.” In a parallel way mitigative capacity has been defined in the Third 39 Assessment Report (Working Group III, Ch. 1.5) as the “ability to diminish the intensity of the 40 natural (and other) stresses to which it might be exposed.” Clearly these two categories are closely 41 related, though in accordance with the differences between adaptation and mitigation measures 42 discussed in section 18.1 above, the capacities also differ somewhat. In particular, since 43 adaptation measures tend to be both more geographically dispersed and smaller in scale than 44 mitigation measures (Dang et al., 2003), adaptive capacities refer to a slightly broader and more 45 general set of capabilities than mitigative capacities. Despite these minor differences, however, 46 adaptive and mitigative capacities are driven by similar sets of factors. As such, the term response 47

1 For discussions on adaptive capacity, see Working Group II, Chapter 18.1, 18.5 and 18.6. For the introduction of the concept of mitigative capacity, see Working Group III, Chapter 1.5.

Page 15: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 15 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

capacity may be used to describe the ability of humans to manage both the generation of 1 greenhouse gases and the associated consequences (Tompkins and Adger, 2003). 2 3 Little work has yet been done in identifying the determinants of response capacity. With regard to 4 mitigative capacity, Yohe (2001) has suggested the following list of determinants: 5 6 • range of viable technological options for reducing emissions 7 • range of viable policy instruments with which the country might effect the adoption of these 8

options 9 • structure of critical institutions and the derivative allocation of decision-making authority 10 • availability and distribution of resources required to underwrite their adoption and the 11

associated, broadly defined opportunity cost of devoting those resources to mitigation 12 • stock of human capital, including education and personal security 13 • stock of social capital, including the definition of property rights 14 • country’s access to risk-spreading processes (e.g., insurance, options and futures markets, 15

etc.) 16 • ability of decision makers to manage information, the processes by which these decision 17

makers determine which information is credible and the credibility of the decision makers 18 themselves 19

20 Yohe suggests a similar set of determinants for adaptive capacity, but adds the availability of 21 resources and their distribution across the population. Recent research has sought to offer 22 empirical evidence that demonstrates the relative influence of each of these determinants on actual 23 adaptation (Yohe and Tol, 2002).2 These determinants of both adaptive and mitigative capacity 24 expand on those identified in the Third Assessment Report and agree closely with those offered by 25 (Moss et al., 2001) and (Adger et al., 2004). The linkages between adaptive and mitigative 26 capacity are demonstrated by the striking similarities between these sets of determinants, which 27 show that both the ability to adapt and the ability to mitigate depend on a mix of social, 28 biophysical and technological constraints (Tompkins and Adger, 2003). Recent research has 29 pointed to the necessity of broadening these lists of determinants to include important factors such 30 as socio-political aspirations (Haddad, 2005), risk perception and perceived adaptive capacity 31 (Grothmann and Patt, 2005). 32 33 These discussions of determinants indicate the close connection that exists between response 34 capacities and the underlying socio-economic and technological development paths that give rise 35 to those capacities. In important respects, the determinants listed above are important 36 characteristics of such development paths. Those development paths, in turn, underpin the 37 baseline and stabilisation emission scenarios that will be discussed in Chapter 3 of Working 38 Group III and used to estimate emissions, climate change and associated climate change impacts3. 39 That is, the determinants of response capacity can be expected to vary across the underlying 40 emission scenarios reviewed in this Fourth Assessment Report. Different underlying scenarios 41 imply different levels and types of response capacities, and thus different likely or even possible 42 levels of adaptation and mitigation. 43 44 2 See WGII Chapter 17.3 for a more detailed discussion of adaptive capacity. 3 The climate change and climate change impact scenarios assessed in the Fourth Assessment Report will be primarily based on the SRES family of emission scenarios, which define a spectrum of different development paths, each with associated socio-economic and technological conditions and driving forces. Each family of emission scenarios will therefore give rise to a different set of response capacities.

Page 16: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 16 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

This situation is summed up in Figure 18.3, which shows adaptation and mitigation measures as 1 being rooted in adaptive and mitigative capacity. The adaptive and mitigative capacities are in 2 turn contained within, and strongly affected by, the nature of the development path in which they 3 exist. The figure also illustrates that adaptation, mitigation and their respective capacities overlap 4 substantially but are not identical4. 5 6

7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Figure 18.3: Adaptation and mitigation are made possible through response capacity, which in 21 turn is deeply rooted in the underlying socio-economic and technological development path which 22 gives rise to these capacities. Different development paths imply different response capacities. 23 24 25 The concept of development paths is discussed at more length in chapter 12 of the Working Group 26 III report. Here it is sufficient to think of a development path as the complex array of 27 technological, economic, social, institutional and cultural characteristics that define an integrated 28 trajectory of the interaction between human and natural systems over time at a particular scale. 29 Such technological and socio-economic development pathways find their most common 30 expression in the form of integrated scenarios (Swart et al., 2004). 31 32 In the climate change context, the TAR noted that “[c]limate change is thus a potentially critical 33 factor in the larger process of society’s adaptive response to changing historical conditions 34 through its choice of developmental paths” (Banuri et al., 2001). Later in the same volume, the 35 following typology of critical components of development paths is presented (Toth et al., 2001): 36 37 • Technological patterns of natural resource use, production of goods and services and final 38

consumption 39 • Structural changes in the production system 40 • Spatial distribution patterns of population and economic activities 41 • Behavioural patterns that determine the evolution of lifestyles 42

43 The importance of the connection shown in Figure 18.3 among measures, capacities and 44 development paths is threefold. First, as pointed out in the Third Assessment Report, a full 45 analysis of the potential for adaptation or mitigation policies must also include some consideration 46 of the capacities in which these policies are rooted. This is increasingly being reflected in the 47

4 That is, as discussed in Section 18.4, there can be trade-offs or synergies among specific adaptation and mitigation measures.

DevelopmentPath

A – adaptive measures M – mitigative measures AC – adaptive capacity MC – mitigative capacity

MA

Response Capacity

A M

Page 17: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 17 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

literature being assessed in other chapters of this assessment5. Second, such an analysis of 1 response capacities should in turn encompass the nature and potential variability of the underlying 2 development paths that strongly affect the nature and extent of those capacities. This suggests the 3 desirability of an integrated analysis of climate policy options that assesses the linkages among 4 policy options, response capacities and their determinants, and underlying development paths6. As 5 yet this type of assessment is in its infancy. 6 7 Third, the linkages between climate policy measures and development paths described here 8 suggest a potential disconnection between the degree of adaptation and/or mitigation that is 9 possible and that may be desired in a given situation. On the one hand, the development path will 10 determine the response capacity of the scenario. On the other, the development path will strongly 11 influence the levels of greenhouse gas emissions, the associated climate change, the likely degree 12 of climate change impacts and thus the desired mitigation and/or adaptation in that scenario (Metz 13 et al., 2002; Nakicenovic, 2000; Swart et al., 2003). 14 15 However, there is no particular reason that the response capacity and the desired levels of 16 mitigation and/or adaptation will change in compatible ways. As a result, particular development 17 paths might give rise to levels of desired mitigation and adaptation that are at odds with the degree 18 of adaptive and mitigative capacity available. For example, particular development path scenarios 19 that give rise to very high emissions might also be associated with a slower growth, or even a 20 decline, in the determinants of response capacity. Such might be the case in scenarios with high 21 degrees of military activity or a collapse of international cooperation. In such cases, climate 22 change impacts could increase, even as response capacity declines. 23 24 The various possible connections among desired adaptation and/or mitigation and adaptive and 25 mitigative capacity are shown schematically in Figure 18.3. That figure shows the directions of 26 emissions, impacts and response capacity associated with four notional scenarios that represent 27 different development pathways. It can be seen that in all four scenarios, increases or decreases in 28 emissions lead to corresponding increases or decreases in climate change impacts (and therefore in 29 required adaptation and/or mitigation). In the case of scenarios 1 and 4, these changes in impacts 30 are associated with corresponding changes in response capacity. All move in the same direction. 31 But in the cases of the scenarios 2 and 3, increases or decreases in impacts are associated with the 32 opposite effect on response capacity. In scenario 2, the need for climate policy responses 33 increases, while desired response capacity goes down: a very undesirable outcome. In scenario 3 34 the fortunate result is that the capacity for response increases while the need declines. 35 36

37

5 On adaptive capacity, see especially chapters 17 of this volume. On mitigative capacity, see the discussions in chapter 12 of the WGIII report. Each of the regional and sectoral chapters in Working Group II, and sectoral chapters in Working Group III will also discuss adaptive or mitigative capacity as relevant to their region/sector. 6 Such an integrated assessment approach was proposed in the Synthesis Report of the IPCC’s Third Assessment Report (Watson 2002)

Page 18: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 18 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Figure 18.3: Linkages between response capacity and the need for adaptation and mitigation. 10 While the need for mitigation and adaptation will rise and fall with the level of climate change 11 impacts and associated level of emissions, in a given development path scenario, response 12 capacity may or may not change accordingly. In scenarios 1 and 4, response capacity changes in 13 the same direction as changes in desired adaptation or mitigation, while in scenarios 2 and 3, 14 response capacity changes in the opposite direction. In scenario 2, shown in red, the need for 15 adaptation and/or mitigation increases, while response capacity declines, a highly undesirable 16 outcome. 17 18 19 Of course the notional scenarios that are shown in Figure 18.3 represent only a simplified 20 schematic outline of the various logical possibilities among these factors. Much more work is 21 needed to determine whether any of these outcomes are empirically feasible and to assess the 22 complexities (such as the differences between adaptive and mitigative responses and capacities in 23 particular situations) that are not shown in the figure. 24 25 26 18.3.5 Adaptation, mitigation and sustainable development 27 28 The linkages among climate policy, response capacities and development paths suggested in the 29 previous section help to understand the nature of the relationship between climate policy and 30 sustainable development. There is a small but growing literature on the nature of this relationship 31 (Banuri, 2001; Beg et al., 2002; Cohen et al., 1998; Markandya et al., 2002; Metz et al., 2002; 32 Munasinghe et al., 2000; Najam et al., 2003; Robinson et al., 2001; Schneider et al., 2000; Smit et 33 al., 2001; Swart et al., 2003; Wilbanks, 2003). Much of this literature emphasises the degree to 34 which climate change policies can have effects, sometimes called ancillary benefits or co-benefits, 35 which will contribute to the sustainable development goals of the jurisdiction in question. This 36 amounts to viewing sustainable development through a climate change lens. It leads to a strong 37 focus on integrating sustainable development goals and consequences into the climate policy 38 framework and on assessing the scope for such ancillary benefits. For instance, reductions in 39 greenhouse gas emissions might reduce the incidence of death and illness due to air pollution and 40 benefit ecosystem integrity – both of which are elements of sustainable development. The 41 challenge then becomes ensuring that actions taken to address environmental problems don’t 42 obstruct regional and local development (Beg et al., 2002). A variety of case studies demonstrate 43 that regional and local development can in fact be enhanced by projects that contribute to 44 adaptation and mitigation. Urban food growing in two UK cities, for instance, has resulted in 45 reduced crime rates, improved biodiversity and reduced transport-based emissions (Howe and 46 Wheeler, 1999). Similarly, agro-ecological initiatives in Latin America have helped to preserve 47 the natural resource base while empowering rural communities (Altieri, 1999). 48 49 An alternative approach is based on the finding in the Third Assessment Report that it will be 50

Page 19: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 19 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

extremely difficult and expensive to achieve stabilisation targets below 650 ppm from baseline 1 scenarios that embody high emission development paths. Conversely, low emission baseline 2 scenarios may go a long way toward achieving low stabilisation levels even before climate policy 3 is include in the scenario (Morita et al., 2001). This recognition leads to an approach to the 4 linkages between climate policy and sustainable development—equivalent to viewing climate 5 change through a sustainable development lens—that emphasises the need to study how best to 6 achieve low emission development paths (Metz et al., 2002; Robinson et al., 2003; Swart et al., 7 2003). 8 9 It has further been argued that sustainable development might decrease the vulnerability of 10 developing countries to climate change impacts (McCarthy et al., 2001), thereby having 11 implications for the necessary amount of both adaptation and mitigation efforts. For instance, 12 economic development and institution building in low-lying, highly populated coastal regions may 13 help to increase preparedness to sea level rise and decrease vulnerability to weather variability 14 (McLean et al., 2001). Similarly, investments in public health training programmes, sanitation 15 systems and disease vector control would both enhance general health and decrease vulnerability 16 to the future effects of climate change (McMichael et al., 2001). Framing the debate as a 17 development problem rather than an environmental one helps to address the special vulnerability 18 of developing nations to climate change while acknowledging that the driving forces for emissions 19 are linked to the underlying development path (Metz et al., 2002).7 20 21 Both approaches to linking climate change to sustainable development suggest the desirability of 22 integrating climate policy measures with the goals and attributes of sustainable development. This 23 suggests an additional reason to focus on the inter-relationships between adaptation, mitigation, 24 response capacity and development paths that are indicated in Figures 18.2 and 18.3. If climate 25 policy and sustainable development are to be pursued in an integrated way, then it will become 26 important not simply to evaluate specific policy options that might accomplish both goals, but also 27 to explore the determinants of response capacity that underlie those options and their connections 28 to underlying socio-economic and technological development paths. 29 30 There is general agreement that sustainable development involves a comprehensive and integrated 31 approach to economic, social and environmental processes (Munasinghe, 1992; Banuri et al., 32 1994; Pezzoli, 1998; Najam et al., 2003). However, early work tended to emphasise the 33 environmental and economic aspects of sustainable development, overlooking the need for social, 34 political or cultural change (Barnett, 2001; Lehtonen, 2004; Robinson, 2004) . More recently, the 35 importance of social, political and cultural factors – for example, poverty, social equity, 36 governance – has increasingly been recognised (Lehtonen, 2004) to the point that social 37 development8 is now given equal status as one of the ‘three pillars’ of sustainable development. 38 This is evidenced by the convening of the World Summit on Social Development in 1995 and in 39 the fact that the Millennium Summit in 2000 highlighted poverty as fundamental in bringing 40 balance to the overemphasis on the environmental aspects of sustainability. The environment-41 poverty nexus is now well recognised and the linkage between sustainable development and 42 achievement of the Millennium Development Goals (United Nations, 2000) has been clearly 43 articulated (Jahan and Umana, 2003). In order to achieve real progress in relation to the 44 Millennium Development Goals, different countries will settle for different solutions (Dalal-45 7 Of course it is important also to acknowledge that climate change policy cannot be considered a substitute for sustainable development policy even though it is determined by similar underlying socio-economic choices (Najam et al., 2003). 8 taken here to include also political and cultural concerns

Page 20: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 20 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Clayton, 2003), and these development trajectories will have important implications for the 1 mitigation of climate change. 2 3 In attempting to follow more sustainable development paths, many developing nations experience 4 unique challenges, such as famine, war, social, health and governance issues (Koonjul 2004). As a 5 result, past economic gains in some regions have come at the expense of environmental stability 6 (Kulindwa 2002), highlighting the lack of exploitation of potential synergies between sustainable 7 development and environmental policies. Technology, institutions, economics and socio-8 psychological factors, which are all elements of both response capacity and development paths, 9 affect the ability of nations to build capacity and implement sustainable development, adaptation 10 and mitigation measures (Nederveen et al., 2003). 11 12 13 18.4 Inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation 14 15 18.4.1 Trade-offs and synergies 16 17 Analysts working on global-scale climate analyses remain divided in their formulation of the 18 adaptation-mitigation linkages. Some consider them as substitutes and seek the optimal policy in 19 cost-benefit frameworks while others emphasise the diversity of impacts (with little scope for 20 adaptation in some sectors) and the asymmetry of social actors who need to mitigate versus those 21 who need to adapt. 22 23 As an example of new results from global cost-benefit analyses, Nordhaus (2001) estimates the 24 economic impact of the Kyoto-Bonn Accord with the RICE-2001 model. He finds that without the 25 US participation the resulting emission path remains below the efficient reduction policy (that 26 balances estimated costs and benefits of emission reductions) whereas the original Kyoto Protocol 27 implied higher than efficient abatement. Among the many recent applications of another cost-28 benefit model, FUND is adopted to demonstrate an interesting trade-off between mitigation and 29 adaptation (Tol and Dowlatabadi, 2001). Taking malaria as a climate-related disease, the authors 30 observe that people with an annual income of USD 3,000 or more do not die of malaria and all 31 world regions surpass this threshold by 2085 in most IPCC IS92 scenarios. Progressively more 32 ambitious emissions reductions in OECD countries gradually decrease the cumulative malaria 33 mortality if one considers only the impact side, i.e., the biophysical effects of climate change 34 mitigation on malaria prevalence. However, if the economic effects of mitigation efforts (the 35 slower rate of economic growth) are also taken into account then, according to the FUND model, 36 the malaria-mortality improvements due to slower global warming will be gradually eliminated 37 and eventually surpassed by the losses due to the reduced rate of income growth. Cost-benefit 38 models are recognised by many as sources of guidance on the magnitude and rate of optimal 39 climate policy while others criticise them for ignoring the sectoral (economic and social), spatial 40 and temporal distances between those who need to mitigate versus those who need to adapt to 41 climate change. 42 43 The Tolerable Windows Approach (TWA) adapts a different approach to integrating mitigation 44 and impact/adaptation concerns. The ICLIPS (Integrated Assessment of Climate Protection 45 Strategies) model identifies fields of long-term greenhouse gas emission paths that prevent rates 46 and magnitudes of climate change generating what is considered to be unacceptable regional or 47 sectoral impacts without imposing intolerable mitigation costs on societies. This “relaxed” cost-48 benefit framework can be used to explore trade-offs between climate change or impact constraints 49 and mitigation cost limits in terms of the existence and size of long-term emission fields. For any 50

Page 21: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 21 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

given impact constraint, increasing the acceptable consumption loss due to climate protection 1 expenditures increases the emission field and allows higher near-term emissions but involves 2 higher mitigation rates and costs in later decades. Conversely, for any given mitigation cost limit, 3 increasing the tolerated level of climate impact also enlarges the emission field and allows higher 4 near-term emissions (Toth et al., 2002; 2003a,b). This formulation allows the exploration of side-5 payments for enhancing adaptation in order to tolerate impacts from larger climate change. The 6 TWA is helpful in exploring the feasibility and implications of crucial social decisions (acceptable 7 impacts and mitigation costs) but, unlike CBA, it cannot provide an optimal policy. 8 9 Cost-effectiveness analyses (CEAs) depict a rather remote relationship between mitigation and 10 adaptation. They implicitly assume that some sort of a global climate change target can be agreed 11 upon that would keep all climate change impacts at the level that can be managed via adaptation 12 or taken as “acceptable losses”. Global CEAs have proliferated since TAR. In addition to 13 exploring least-cost strategies to stabilise CO2 concentrations, CEAs are also adopted to 14 stabilising radiative forcing and global mean temperature. The stabilisation literature is assessed in 15 WGIII Chapter 3. 16 17 Looking into the details of specific adaptation and mitigation activities at less aggregated scales 18 reveals diverse linkages. The four types include mitigation projects fostering or hindering 19 adaptation (land-use related activities) and adaptation projects fostering or hindering mitigation 20 (i.e., reducing or increasing greenhouse gas emissions). 21 22 Afforestation, reforestation and forest conservation have been advocated for decades as essential 23 mitigation options. Recent studies, however, reveal a more differentiated picture. Based on an 24 extensive survey of dissolved carbon in the Amazonian river system, Mayorga et al. (2005) 25 suggest that a small and rapidly cycling pool of organic carbon accounts for the large carbon 26 fluxes from land to water to atmosphere in the humid tropics. This means that the absorbed CO2 is 27 released in about five years. Another study finds that in arid and semi-arid regions afforestation 28 massively reduces water yields (UK FRP 2005). This has direct and wide-ranging negative 29 implications for adaptation options in several sectors like agriculture (irrigation), power 30 generation (cooling towers), and ecosystem protection (minimum flow to sustain ecosystems in 31 rivers, wetlands and on the banks). Afforestation and reforestation may also have negative impacts 32 on biodiversity, as shown by Caparros and Jacquemont (2003), due to the over-plantation of fast-33 growing alien species. These studies demonstrate the intricate relationships between climate 34 change mitigation, adaptation, and also linkages to other environmental concerns like water 35 resources and biodiversity with profound policy implications. The land-use and forestry mitigation 36 options in the Marrakech Accord may alter land allocation to the detriment of the poor in regions 37 where land is scarce, may reduce water yields and distort water allocation in water-stress regions, 38 and may negatively affect biodiversity. All three implications reduce the scope for adaptation to 39 climate change (excluding effective but more expensive options due to increased land rents, 40 precluding forms and magnitudes of irrigation due to higher water prices, etc.). 41 42 While the implications of some mitigation strategies for adaptation and other development and 43 environment concerns have been recognised recently, the effects of adaptation on greenhouse 44 emissions (energy use, land conversion, agronomic techniques like increased use of fertilisers and 45 pesticides, water storage and diversion, coastal protection) have been known much longer but 46 have remained largely unexplored. For example, many adaptation options are known to involve 47 increased energy use and hence interfere with mitigation efforts if the energy is supplied from 48 carbon-emitting sources. Yet it is not straightforward to separate the adaptation effects from those 49 of other drivers in regional or national energy demand projections. For the USA state of Maryland, 50

Page 22: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 22 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Ruth and Lin (forthcoming) find that at least in the medium term up to 2025, climate change 1 contributes relatively little to changes in the energy demand. Nonetheless, the climate share varies 2 with geographical conditions (changes in heating and cooling degree days), economic (income) 3 and resource (relative costs of fossil and other energy sources) endowments, technologies, 4 institutions and other factors. Such “mitigation rebound” effects of adaptation are likely to be 5 minor in most countries and regions but more in-depth studies are needed to estimate their 6 magnitude over the long term. 7 8 Examples of inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation are shown in Figure 18.4 and 9 Table 18.1. On the local and operational scale, there are many projects concerned with energy 10 efficiency, solar energy or forest management. Individual responses to heat waves or water 11 shortages are related to adaptation more than mitigation. Community action is often key, scaling 12 up to sustainable livelihoods. The examples are typically aimed at development and resource 13 management and may have only weak links to national strategies or policies. Climate change is 14 often given as a context of the action, but is not the main purpose. 15 16 A diverse cluster of actions are more strategic in nature. Typical examples include tourism and 17 conflicts over water use as well as energy use (including long distance flights), spatial planning 18 and building design in urban areas, natural resource conservation and links to sustainable 19 livelihoods, and rural enterprises. These programmes tend to be driven by development and 20 adaptation aims, but have significant roles in mitigation. Some actions, such as linking CDM to 21 poverty reduction and land use planning, are more driven by mitigation policies and strategies, 22 with a concern for adaptation synergies. 23 24 Synergies and trade-offs at the broader policy level are diverse. There are many examples of 25 analyses of inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation (e.g., in global comparisons of 26 costs and benefits, linking climate policy to global change and development pathways, and 27 synergies with other multi-lateral agreements). However, there are fewer examples of explicit 28 policy linkages (e.g., through integrated programmes, regulations, or economic instruments). The 29 UNFCCC negotiations cover mitigation and adaptation, but in different forums. The CDM 30 surcharge and some of the climate funds are specific examples of linkages. Spanning policy and 31 strategic planning, capacity building is a critical link (e.g., the National Capacity Self Assessment 32 exercises). Insurance has a role in both adaptation and as investment for mitigation. Trade regimes 33 affect global and local development. 34 35 The outcomes of mitigation policies (such as carbon taxes and increased fuel prices) could have 36 significant operational effects on adaptation, altering present and possibly desirable resource use. 37 Geoengineering is a special case of large scale mitigation efforts that could influence resource use, 38 impacts and adaptation. An example of an adaptation policy (in the sense of regulation and legal 39 frameworks) that might affect negotiations over mitigation is the prospect of liability for climate 40 impacts. In a less legal framework, concerns over large-scale and abrupt climate change impacts 41 plays a role in awareness of the potential risks and motivations for urgent mitigation strategies. 42 Ecological feedbacks have been reported that could exacerbate climate change; to the extent that 43 these are influenced by human actions and adaptation they are included in this table. 44 45 Recent studies have begun to address many of these linkages in detail: 46 47 Afforestation, reforestation and forest conservation: Based on an extensive survey of dissolved 48 carbon in the Amazonian river system, Mayorga et al. (2005) suggest that a small and rapidly 49 cycling pool of organic carbon accounts for the large carbon fluxes from land to water to 50

Page 23: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 23 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

atmosphere in the humid tropics. This means that the absorbed CO2 is released in about five years. 1 Another study finds that in arid and semi-arid regions afforestation reduces water yields (UK FRP 2 2005). This has direct and wide-ranging negative implications for adaptation options in several 3 sectors like agriculture (irrigation), power generation (cooling towers) and ecosystem protection 4 (minimum flow to sustain ecosystems in rivers, wetlands and on the banks). 5 6 Land use and biodiversity: Afforestation and reforestation may have negative impacts on 7 biodiversity (Caparros and Jacquemont 2003), due to the over-planting of fast-growing alien 8 species. The land-use and forestry mitigation options in the Marrakech Accords may alter land 9 allocation to the detriment of the poor in regions where land is scarce, reduce water yields and 10 distort water allocation in water-stress regions and negatively affect biodiversity. 11 12 Effects of adaptation on greenhouse gas emissions: The requirements of adaptation projects (e.g., 13 energy use, land, fertilisers and pesticides, water, coastal protection) have remained largely 14 unexplored. For example, many adaptation options are known to involve increased energy use and 15 hence interfere with mitigation efforts if the energy is supplied from carbon-emitting sources. Yet 16 it is not straightforward to separate the adaptation effects from those of other drivers in regional or 17 national energy demand projections. For the USA state of Maryland, Ruth and Lin (forthcoming) 18 find that at least in the medium term up to 2025, climate change contributes relatively little to 19 changes in the energy demand. Nonetheless, the climate share varies with geographical conditions 20 (changes in heating and cooling degree days), economic (income) and resource (relative costs of 21 fossil and other energy sources) endowments, technologies, institutions and other factors. Such 22 “mitigation rebound” effects of adaptation are likely to be minor in most countries and regions but 23 more in-depth studies are needed to estimate their magnitude over the long term. 24 25 Health effects: Tol and Dowlatabadi (2001) observe that people with an annual income of USD 26 3,000 or more do not die of malaria. All world regions are expected to surpass this threshold by 27 2085 in most IPCC IS92 scenarios. Progressively more ambitious emissions reductions in OECD 28 countries gradually decrease the cumulative malaria mortality if one considers only the impact 29 side, that is, the biophysical effects of climate change mitigation on malaria prevalence. However, 30 if the economic effects of mitigation efforts (the slower rate of economic growth) are also taken 31 into account then, the FUND model shows improvements in mortality from malaria due to slower 32 global warming will be gradually eliminated and eventually surpassed by the losses due to the 33 reduced rate of income growth. 34 35 36

Page 24: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 24 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 Figure 18.4: Clusters of inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation. Note: the ellipses 22 are located in a rough fashion in order to be readable. Many actions would span across at least 23 two levels. For example, the CDM is a negotiated policy that is implemented as a national or 24 corporate strategy resulting in operational projects. 25 26 27

A

DA

PTA

TIO

N

Ope

ratio

nal

Stra

tegi

c

Pol

icy

Local energy use

Community water, land

use, forestry & energy

Individual responses to hazards

Natural resource/

sustainable livelihoods

Urban planning,building design

& recycling

CDM: land use & energy

Global costs & benefits

Global change & development

pathways

Tourism use of energy and water

Watershed planning

Rural enterprises &

energy efficiency

MEAs UNFCCC negotiations &

funds

National capacity building

Carbon taxes, energy prices

& resource use

Impacts liability & mitigation targets

Awareness of impacts and

motivation for mitigation

Operational Strategic Policy MITIGATION

Resource cost of

adaptation

Health benefits of mitigation

Ecological feedbacks

Trade liberalization

Insurance

Geoengineering

Page 25: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do

Not

Cite

– D

o N

ot Q

uote

IP

CC

WG

II F

ourt

h A

sses

smen

t Rep

ort –

Dra

ft fo

r E

xper

t Rev

iew

Dea

dlin

e fo

r su

bmis

sion

of c

omm

ents

: 4 N

ov 2

005

25

C

hapt

er 1

8 –

Ada

ptat

ion-

Miti

gatio

n Ta

ble

18.1

: Exa

mpl

es o

f clu

ster

s of i

nter

-rel

atio

nshi

ps b

etw

een

clim

ate

chan

ge a

dapt

atio

n an

d m

itiga

tion.

1

2

Typ

e of

link

age

Des

crip

tion

Exa

mpl

es

Ref

eren

ces

Loc

al e

nerg

y us

e fo

r de

velo

pmen

t G

reen

hous

e ga

s em

issi

ons a

re re

duce

d as

pe

ople

switc

h to

rene

wab

le e

nerg

y / m

ore

effic

ient

ene

rgy

usag

es fo

r dev

elop

men

t and

po

verty

redu

ctio

n ob

ject

ives

Rur

al e

lect

rific

atio

n an

d re

new

able

s, m

icro

hy

drop

ower

, sol

ar, e

ffic

ient

stov

es

Cha

krab

arti

and

Cha

krab

arti

(200

2), A

l M

alki

, et a

l. (1

998)

, Ven

ema

and

Cis

se

(200

4), G

EF (2

005)

, GEF

(200

5), C

ida

(200

5)

Indi

vidu

al r

espo

nses

to c

limat

ic

haza

rds

Res

pons

es to

clim

atic

haz

ards

incr

ease

s or

redu

ces e

nerg

y co

nsum

ptio

n an

d gr

eenh

ouse

ga

s em

issi

ons

Hea

t wav

es st

imul

ate

purc

hase

and

use

of a

ir-co

nditi

oner

s, w

ater

cris

es le

ad to

con

serv

ing

wat

er a

nd e

nerg

y

Smith

et a

l. (2

002)

, WH

O (2

004)

Com

mun

ity w

ater

, lan

d us

e,

fore

stry

and

ene

rgy

Com

mun

ities

use

thei

r res

ourc

es m

ore

effe

ctiv

ely

to a

dapt

to c

limat

e ch

ange

, with

an

cilla

ry b

enef

its fo

r miti

gatio

n an

d v.

v.

Padd

y ric

e, w

ater

dem

and

and

met

hane

, cl

imat

e ris

ks in

Tan

zani

a, G

EF sm

all g

rant

s, Fi

nnis

h te

chno

logy

pro

gram

me,

fuel

woo

d in

th

e H

imal

ayas

, com

mun

ity fo

rest

ry in

Mex

ico

Ber

gkam

p et

al.

(200

3), P

aavo

la (2

004)

, Eb

rahi

mia

n (2

003)

, Leh

tilaa

et a

l. (2

005)

, Si

ngh

et a

l. (2

003)

, Pra

sad

et a

l. (2

001)

, K

loos

ter a

nd M

aser

a (2

000)

Nat

ural

res

ourc

es a

nd su

stai

nabl

e liv

elih

oods

N

atur

al re

sour

ces a

re m

anag

ed, p

rovi

ding

pr

otec

tion

to c

omm

uniti

es fr

om c

limat

ic e

vent

s B

ioen

ergy

in A

ustra

lian

fore

sts,

sust

aina

ble

livel

ihoo

ds (e

.g.,

Suda

n), m

angr

ove

prot

ectio

n (e

.g.,

Vie

tnam

)

Fung

et a

l. (2

002)

, IU

CN

et a

l. (2

004)

Tou

rism

use

of e

nerg

y an

d w

ater

To

uris

m is

rela

ted

to c

limat

e an

d tra

vel c

osts

, lo

cal d

eman

d fo

r ene

rgy

and

wat

er m

ay st

rain

lo

cal r

esou

rces

Hot

el h

eat p

umps

, wat

er su

pply

in M

allo

rca,

tra

vel c

osts

and

em

issi

ons i

n N

ew Z

eala

nd

Cha

n an

d La

m (2

003)

, Ess

ex e

t al.

(200

4),

Bec

ken

(200

2), B

ecke

n an

d Si

mm

ons

(200

2), C

eron

and

Dub

ois (

2005

) W

ater

shed

pla

nnin

g W

ater

reso

urce

and

haz

ard

plan

ning

, im

plic

atio

ns fo

r hyd

roel

ectri

c po

wer

R

esto

ratio

n in

Mah

aras

htra

, gla

cial

lake

s in

Nep

al, m

icro

-hyd

ropo

wer

in th

e Ph

ilipp

ines

IU

CN

et a

l. (2

003)

, Ala

m a

nd M

urry

(2

005)

, GEF

(200

5), m

ata

and

Bud

hoor

am

(200

5)

CM

D: l

and

use,

ene

rgy

use

Enco

urag

e co

mm

uniti

es to

use

rene

wab

le

ener

gy in

stea

d of

foss

il fu

els.

Ren

ewab

le te

chno

logy

, for

est u

se, c

omm

unity

en

ergy

pla

nnin

g B

arua

(200

1), F

earn

side

(199

9), K

uzm

a an

d D

obro

vlny

(200

4)

Car

bon

taxe

s, en

ergy

pri

ces a

nd

reso

urce

use

Ef

fect

of m

itiga

tion

on re

sour

ce u

se a

t an

oper

atio

nal l

evel

Fo

od se

curit

y, h

ouse

hold

wel

fare

R

osen

berg

and

Sco

tt (1

996)

, Tie

zzi (

2005

)

Res

ourc

e co

st o

f ada

ptat

ion

Inve

stm

ent i

n in

fras

truct

ure

with

sign

ifica

nt

reso

urce

cos

ts a

nd u

se o

f gre

enho

use

gase

s R

oad

plan

ning

in th

e Pa

cific

Ed

y (2

004)

Hea

lth b

enef

its o

f miti

gatio

n M

itiga

tion

can

redu

ce e

nviro

nmen

tal h

ealth

st

ress

es

Impr

oved

air

qual

ity

Cifu

ente

s et a

l. (2

001)

, Alc

amo

et a

l. (2

002)

U

rban

pla

nnin

g. B

uild

ing

desi

gn

and

recy

clin

g

Urb

an p

lann

ing

and

ener

gy b

alan

ce li

nk

miti

gatio

n an

d ad

apta

tion,

Inte

llige

nt b

uild

ing

Urb

an fo

od p

rodu

ctio

n, re

cycl

ing,

hea

t isl

and

miti

gatio

n H

owe

and

Whe

eler

(199

9), H

olla

nd

(199

9), E

stes

et a

l. (1

999)

, Sai

lor (

2002

),

Page 26: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do

Not

Cite

– D

o N

ot Q

uote

IP

CC

WG

II F

ourt

h A

sses

smen

t Rep

ort –

Dra

ft fo

r E

xper

t Rev

iew

Dea

dlin

e fo

r su

bmis

sion

of c

omm

ents

: 4 N

ov 2

005

26

C

hapt

er 1

8 –

Ada

ptat

ion-

Miti

gatio

n

desi

gns c

an re

duce

the

ener

gy n

eede

d to

pr

ovid

e he

at a

nd li

ghtin

g H

erto

n et

al.

(200

3), M

ills (

2003

)

Aw

aren

ess o

f im

pact

s and

m

otiv

atio

n fo

r m

itiga

tion

Perc

eptio

n of

dan

gero

us c

limat

e ch

ange

m

otiv

ates

miti

gatio

n ac

tion

Reg

iona

l and

stak

ehol

der a

sses

smen

ts

Ker

r and

Alle

n (2

001)

Mul

ti-la

tera

l Env

iron

men

tal

Agr

eem

ents

La

nd c

over

and

bio

dive

rsity

man

agem

ent l

inks

to

bot

h m

itiga

tion

and

adap

tatio

n La

nd c

over

in G

erm

an o

ffic

ial d

evel

opm

ent

assi

stan

ce

Kle

in (2

001)

Eco

logi

cal f

eedb

acks

Ec

olog

ical

impa

cts,

ofte

n w

ith so

me

hum

an

elem

ent,

driv

ing

furth

er re

leas

es o

f gre

enho

use

gase

s

Dro

ught

and

fire

s in

Euro

pe, p

erm

afro

st a

nd

met

hane

in R

ussi

a

Impa

cts l

iabi

lity

and

miti

gatio

n ta

rget

s Le

gal i

mpl

icat

ions

of f

utur

e cl

imat

e im

pact

s lin

ked

to m

itiga

tion

targ

ets a

nd m

otiv

atio

n G

loba

l ass

essm

ents

To

l and

Ver

heye

n (2

001)

Nat

iona

l cap

acity

bui

ldin

g In

crea

se th

e ab

ility

of a

nat

ion

to re

spon

d to

cl

imat

e ch

ange

N

atio

nal C

apac

ity S

elf A

sses

smen

ts, v

ario

us

proj

ects

such

as C

3D, C

limat

e an

d D

evel

opm

ent

Mur

ray

and

Huq

(200

5)cl

imat

e po

licy

pape

r

Glo

bal c

hang

e an

d de

velo

pmen

t pa

thw

ays

Scen

ario

s and

pla

nnin

g to

mai

nstre

am c

limat

e ch

ange

in d

evel

opm

ent

Glo

bal s

cena

rios g

roup

, mai

nstre

amin

g,

deve

lopm

ent a

genc

ies s

cree

ning

tool

s, sy

nerg

ies i

n V

ietn

am

Mun

asin

ghe

and

Swar

t (20

05),

Ras

kin

et

al.,

Rob

inso

n an

d H

erbe

rt (2

001)

, Ber

g et

al

. (20

02),

Dan

g et

al.

(200

3), S

war

t et a

l. (2

003)

, Wilb

anks

(200

3), D

avid

son

et a

l. (2

003)

T

rade

libe

ralis

atio

n In

crea

sed

econ

omic

eff

icie

ncy

by re

duci

ng

trade

bar

riers

to e

nhan

ce a

dapt

atio

n ca

paci

ty,

whi

le in

crea

sing

tran

spor

t

Ope

ning

Eur

opea

n m

arke

ts to

agr

icul

tura

l ex

ports

from

Afr

ica,

glo

balis

atio

n an

d ec

onom

ic re

stru

ctur

ing

Obr

ien,

New

Eco

nom

ic F

ound

atio

n

Insu

ranc

e

Insu

ranc

e is

a m

echa

nism

to sp

read

risk

s as

wel

l as a

maj

or in

vest

or w

ith a

role

in

miti

gatio

n

Ris

k m

anag

emen

t, fin

ance

D

lugo

leck

i and

Key

khah

(200

3)

Geo

engi

neer

ing

Larg

e sc

ale

miti

gatio

n ef

forts

So

lar r

adia

tion

refle

ctor

s, de

ep o

cean

or

geol

ogic

al c

arbo

n st

orag

e, fe

rtilis

atio

n of

the

ocea

ns

Dow

lata

badi

, Bus

sele

r et a

l. (2

004)

Glo

bal c

osts

and

ben

efits

A

naly

ses o

f opt

imal

bal

ance

s of a

dapt

atio

n an

d m

itiga

tion,

usi

ng a

var

iety

of g

loba

l met

hods

Ef

ficie

ncy

and

equi

ty, c

ost-b

enef

it, to

lera

ble

win

dow

s To

l (20

01, 2

003,

200

5), D

owni

ng e

t al.

(200

5)

UN

FCC

C n

egot

iatio

ns a

nd fu

nds

Allo

catio

n of

reso

urce

s and

dev

elop

men

t of

fram

ewor

ks

Spec

ial C

limat

e Fu

nd

Page 27: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 27 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

18.4.2 Climate policy and institutions 1 2 The ultimate objective of the UNFCCC, as stated in Article 2, is 3 4

“to achieve ... stabilisation of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a 5 level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system 6 … within a time-frame sufficient to allow ecosystems to adapt naturally to climate 7 change, to ensure that food production is not threatened and to enable economic 8 development to proceed in a sustainable manner.” 9

10 At first sight, this objective refers only to mitigation: reducing greenhouse gas emissions such that 11 atmospheric concentrations are stabilised. The Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC, agreed in 1997 12 and effective since 16 February 2005, requires Annex I parties (i.e., the developed-country 13 signatories) to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions by an average of 5.2% compared to 1990 14 levels by the first Commitment Period of 2008 to 2012. Major greenhouse gas emitting countries 15 have already established national (and in the case of the European Union, Europe-wide) 16 regulations and policies for reducing greenhouse gas emissions from industrial and domestic 17 sources. Australia and the United States of America have initiated alternative policies for reducing 18 their greenhouse gas emissions, including the Asia-Pacific Partnership on Clean Development and 19 Climate, agreed in Vientiane, Laos, in July 2005. This partnership allows Australia, China, India, 20 Japan, South Korea and the United States of America to set their goals for reducing greenhouse 21 gas emissions individually, but without enforcement mechanism. 22 23 Developing countries do not have to meet emission-reduction targets under the Kyoto Protocol, 24 yet a number of countries have put in place mitigation policies. These include the development of 25 wind energy in India and the establishment of targets for renewable energy development in China 26 (refs.). In addition, the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) under the Kyoto Protocol, which 27 enables non-Annex I Parties to implement mitigation projects with funding from Annex I Parties, 28 has spawned a large number of projects that enable developing countries to make contributions to 29 reducing greenhouse gas emissions. Through their obligations under the Montreal Protocol on 30 Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer, developing countries have already reduced their 31 emissions of greenhouse gases that are also ozone-depleting substances, such as CFCs. 32 33 In spite of these mitigation efforts, the stabilisation level at which dangerous anthropogenic 34 interference with the climate system can still be prevented does not only depend on greenhouse 35 gas emission reduction (or sink enhancement). It also depends on the degree to which adaptation 36 can be expected to be effective in addressing the consequences of climate change. In other words, 37 the higher the ability of ecosystems and society to adapt to potential impacts, the higher the level 38 at which atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations can be stabilised before anthropogenic 39 interference with the climate system becomes dangerous (see also Chapter 19). Adaptation can 40 thus complement mitigation in meeting the ultimate objective of the UNFCCC. 41 42 In parallel with the progress made on mitigation, adaptation is beginning to receive the attention 43 that many adaptation scholars have been advocating, both in the academic arena and in climate 44 policy (e.g., Burton, 1994, 2000; Pielke, 1998). Until recently, adaptation was contained in a 45 single COP decision (decision 11/CP.1), which set out three stages of adaptation that some believe 46 were drafted in a manner to enable further decisions on adaptation to be delayed (Burton et al., 47 2002). Additional decisions have since been taken, most importantly decisions 5/CP.7, 6/CP.7 and 48 28/CP.7, the latter introducing the opportunity for least-developed countries (LDCs) to prepare 49 National Adaptation Programmes of Action (NAPAs). As stated in Decision 28/CP.7: 50

Page 28: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 28 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 “The rationale for developing NAPAs rests on the low adaptive capacity of LDCs, 2 which renders them in need of immediate and urgent support to start adapting to 3 current and projected adverse effects of climate change. Activities proposed through 4 NAPAs would be those whose further delay could increase vulnerability or lead to 5 increased costs at a later stage.” 6

7 The increasing importance of adaptation to international climate policy was also reflected in the 8 establishment of four funds that can be used to support adaptation activities: the Strategic Priority 9 Piloting an Operational Approach to Adaptation, the Adaptation Fund, the Least-Developed 10 Countries Fund and the Special Climate Change Fund (see Section 18.5.2). 11 12 The introduction of the NAPAs and the four funds reflects the increased recognition that climate 13 change poses a threat to development issues such as water supply, food security, human health, 14 natural resource management and protection against natural hazards. This recognition has moved 15 adaptation from being the “handmaiden to impacts research in the mitigation context” (Burton et 16 al., 2002) to an activity that is considered crucial within the broader context of sustainable 17 development. The link between adaptation and sustainable development is particularly relevant 18 when seeking to enhance the capacity of countries and communities to adapt to climate change, 19 which is often limited by lack of resources, poor institutions and inadequate infrastructure, 20 amongst other things (Smith et al., 2003; see Section 18.3.4). 21 22 The term “mainstreaming” has emerged to describe the integration of policies and measures to 23 address climate change into ongoing development activities. Mainstreaming aims at ensuring the 24 long-term sustainability of investments, as well as at reducing the sensitivity of development 25 activities to both today’s and tomorrow’s climate. Mainstreaming is seen as making more efficient 26 and effective use of financial and human resources than designing, implementing and managing 27 climate policy separately from ongoing activities. By its very nature, energy-based mitigation 28 (e.g., fuel switch and energy conservation) can be effective only when mainstreamed into energy 29 policy. For adaptation, however, this link has not appeared as self-evident until recently. 30 Mainstreaming is based on the premise that human vulnerability to climate change is reduced not 31 only when climate change is mitigated or when successful adaptation to the impacts takes place, 32 but also when the living conditions for those experiencing the impacts are improved (Huq and 33 Reid, 2004). 34 35 The incorporation of development concerns into climate policy and the subsequent emergence of 36 mainstreaming as the preferred process of implementing adaptation (Sperling, 2003) demonstrate 37 that climate policy involves more than decision-making on adaptation and mitigation. Klein et al. 38 (2005) described three current roles of climate policy: (i) to control the atmospheric 39 concentrations of greenhouse gases (ii) to prepare for and reduce the adverse impacts of climate 40 change and take advantage of opportunities, and (iii) to address development and equity issues. 41 Although climate change is not the primary reason for poverty and inequality in the world, 42 addressing these issues is seen as a prerequisite for successful adaptation and mitigation in many 43 developing countries (Sperling, 2003). 44 45 In addition to the three current roles of climate policy, a fourth role could be identified: to 46 facilitate the successful integration and implementation of adaptation and mitigation in sectoral 47 and development policies (Klein et al., 2005). This requires the building of response capacity, 48 both on the macro and the micro-scale, as well as creating mechanisms and incentives for 49 mainstreaming. It would not require developing synergies between mitigation and adaptation per 50

Page 29: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 29 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

se, but rather between building adaptive and mitigative capacity, and thus with development (see 1 Section 18.3.4). With this new role of climate policy comes the awareness of the importance to 2 involve a greater range of actors in the implementation of adaptation and mitigation, including 3 sectoral, sub-national and local actors (see Section 18.3.3). This is reflected in the respective roles 4 of institutions at these levels. 5 6 Institutions tend to be the locus of power enactment, influence and negotiation (North, 1990). 7 Some analysts have focused on institutional architecture and adaptive capacity (Adger 2000). (The 8 complexity of decisions relating to climate means that non-climate institutions would be a logical 9 resource for drawing support, exploiting synergies, building capacity and raising awareness on 10 climate impacts. The trouble is that climate policy has largely evolved in a separate cluster with 11 little interaction between the scientific and development world. Equally, organisations such as the 12 World Trade Organisation (WTO) should also be concerned with climate change and its impacts 13 (Newell, 2004). It is becoming increasingly clear that the wide array of decision-making required 14 can not be reached under the UNFCCC umbrella alone and both regional and international 15 grouping with similar interests in climate prevention should also be vehicles to channel effective 16 decision making. Multilateral development institutions do offer an opportunity to coherently 17 formulate policies and build synergies. In areas where environmental causes and consequences 18 have the same origins and where countries share the same ideals of human and sustainable 19 development, regional co-operation could create “win-win” opportunities in both economic 20 integration and addressing the adverse effects of climate change (Denton et al., 2002). 21 22 Getting development institutions to incorporate climate change and environmental concerns, 23 especially in the African context, calls for a paradigm shift as environmental issues tend to be 24 divorced from development and usually relegated to ministries with little financial and political 25 clout such as the environment ministry. 26 27 The implementation of adaptation strategies would, to a large extent, depend on local stewardship, 28 but both governments and regional organisations such as the Permanent Interstate Authority on 29 Drought and Desertification (CILSS) and the West Africa Economic and Monetary Union 30 (UEMOA) could help or hinder such efforts. Whilst such formal structures may help build 31 consensus on adaptation and/or mitigation, it is important, especially in the context of the West 32 African Sahel, to focus on societal pressure groups and the indigenous and innovative practices 33 that communities have crafted to build resilience to climate extremes and change. Water 34 management institutions in Africa have extensive knowledge on water issues but often they suffer 35 from limited capacity and tend not to use climate change adaptation or mitigation as a template for 36 their development projects. Yet it is certain that the development of irrigation systems in the 37 Senegal River, for instance, could help reinvigorate agricultural productivity, but this should be 38 done with vulnerability of climate variability in mind to increase the resilience of farmers and 39 pastoralists who depend on the river as their main livelihood. 40 41 Organisations such as UEMOA who are actively engaged in energy development to address the 42 perennial problem of energy poverty in the continent should also focus on how to exploit 43 mechanisms such as the Clean Development Mechanisms in order to mitigate against present and 44 future emissions, especially with the use of renewables. UEMOA countries (i.e., Benin, Burkina 45 Faso, Cote d’Ivoire, Niger, Senegal and Togo) are vulnerable to drought and desertification and 46 while mitigation may not be their main concern it does offer opportunities to reduce negative 47 impacts that are pervasive in deforestation and land use change. Institutional arrangements are a 48 viable option for mainstreaming climate change into development and regional objectives and thus 49 build synergy through the formulation of coherent policies. 50

Page 30: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 30 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 Perhaps due to their contextual experiences, the countries in UEMOA have developed a National 2 Action Plan as part of their commitment to the United Nations Convention to Combat 3 Desertification but similar reflexes need to be created and strengthened vis-à-vis the UNFCCC. 4 Both adaptation and mitigation efforts could be enhanced through institutional frameworks. 5 However, because climate change tends to be perceived as remote and secondary, institutions that 6 deal with this issue tend to be under-resourced and under-staffed with few individuals specialised 7 in issues ranging from biodiversity to climate change. Without the relevant capacity and resources, 8 regional and non-climate institutions, particularly those in developing countries, may not be able 9 to grasp the wide ranging complex issues that are inherent to climate policy. 10 11 Organisation such as the World Trade Organisation and the European Union could, through 12 specific mechanisms, integrate environmental policy into their economic rationales. The 13 agricultural sector, particularly industrial agriculture and the use of strong fertiliser accounts for 14 the production of emissions such as methane and nitrous oxide. Ironically whilst many 15 governments under the UNFCCC are advocating a less-fossil fuel dependent pathway, they are 16 also taking on agricultural trade policies that would amount to vast increases in energy demands 17 of both agricultural production and distributions systems (Shrybman, 2000). However, this may 18 not be a key issue in some of the least Developed Countries where consumption of energy in still 19 low, since agriculture in rural areas tends to be predicated on animal and human energy with few 20 mechanised agricultural practices. The tendency in agriculture is toward human power and animal 21 traction and this is likely to continue in the foreseeable future (Karekezi et al., 2002). However, it 22 is an entirely different story for industrialised nations who could use certain mechanisms such as 23 the WTO Agreement on Agriculture and the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) as advocacy and 24 implementing tools on mitigation policies. Climate abatement in the face of the many contentious 25 issues surrounding globalisation, subsidies and equity within the WTO seems to be a non-issue – 26 at least for the moment – especially since analysts are not adopting critical lenses to the combined 27 impacts of globalisation and pervasive subsidies. 28 29 Consequently, alongside the need to use existing mechanisms within the WTO to integrate climate 30 and economic considerations, there is also a considerable need to address contradictions between 31 policies relevant to the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions and agricultural trade policies. 32 Energy remains a quintessential input in agro-processing, transportation and packaging, and the 33 combined effect of increases in energy consumption in the agricultural sector and impacts of 34 agricultural trade policies are not thought through within the broad parameters of climate change. 35 Other sectors such as forestry need to be looked at within specific mechanisms of the EU from an 36 environmental/climate perspective. The main legislative mechanism that deals with forests tends 37 to be linked to the CAP. Policies within the CAP offer some support for agricultural and 38 silvicultural activities that could help increase carbon sequestration. A recent addition to the EU’s 39 effort is the establishment of a Working Group on Forest Sinks within the European Climate 40 Change Programme (ECPP). Such actions need to be encouraged as they have the ability to help 41 implement some of the key objectives of the protocol. 42 43 44 18.5 Elements for effective implementation 45 46 This section will address the question of the apparent gap between response capacity and actual 47 adaptive and mitigative behaviour. Although the adaptive and mitigative capacity literature does 48 not claim that building capacity will necessarily lead to improved responses to the climate change 49 risk, little work has been done to explicate the widely noted variation in response to climate 50

Page 31: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 31 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

change among communities with similar capacities. It is apparent, therefore, that capacity is a 1 necessary, but not sufficient, condition for action. Risk perception, socio-political aspirations, 2 institutional structure and historical culture, for instance, may help to explain part of the variation 3 in action among groups with similar levels of response capacity. 4 5 6 18.5.1 Identifying and evaluating inter-relationships 7 8 9 18.5.2 Financing and institutions 10 11 12 13 Box 18.4: The role of the GEF on climate change adaptation and mitigation 14 15 The Global Environment Facility (GEF) is a multilateral fund with the mandate to finance the 16 incremental costs of activities that produce global environmental benefits in the areas of 17 biodiversity, climate change, international waters, land degradation and persistent organic 18 pollutants. GEF operations started in the early 1990s. The GEF was made the financial mechanism 19 of the UNFCCC in 1992 and operates through three implementing agencies (UNEP, UNDP and 20 the World Bank) and seven executing agencies, including regional development banks. 21 22 Since its inception, the GEF has allocated $4.5 billion in total, supplemented by more than $14 23 billion in co-financing, for more than 1,400 projects in 140 developing countries and countries 24 with economies in transition. The share for climate change is about $1.6 billion (1991-2003) 25 (GEF, 2003). 26 27 The GEF operational strategy states that “The overall strategic thrust of GEF-financed climate 28 change activities is to support sustainable measures that minimise climate change damage by 29 reducing the risk, or the adverse effects, of climate change. The GEF will finance agreed and 30 eligible enabling, adaptation and mitigation activities in eligible recipient countries.” (GEF, 1994). 31 The operational strategy proposes a mix of short- and long-term measures to reduce greenhouse 32 gas emissions and enhance sinks, and also includes a plan for adaptation interventions. During its 33 first decade of operations, however, the GEF climate change portfolio focused primarily on 34 mitigation. 35 36 Several operational programmes define the GEF climate change programme and focus on 37 removing barriers to cost-effective energy efficiency and renewable energy; commercialising 38 promising new technologies (e.g., fuel cells); and, more recently, sustainable transportation 39 (Eberhard and Tokle, 2004). Adaptation was initially supported only in the context of national 40 communications. New trends in the climate change mitigation portfolio include: 41 42 • For energy efficiency: a renewed commitment to market transformation for the diffusion of 43

energy-efficient technologies in the industry and building sectors 44 • For renewable energy: focus on on-grid, off-grid, rural energy programmes and renewable 45

energy for productive uses 46 • For sustainable transport: a departure from a technology-focused (fuel-cell buses, etc.) 47

approach in favour of a more integrated approach to sustainable mobility, including modal 48 shift, non-motorised transport, bus-rapt transit and other policy-related interventions 49

50

Page 32: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 32 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

UNFCCC guidance to the GEF on adaptation evolved from an initial staged approach starting 1 with support for studies and vulnerability assessments (Stage I) and capacity building (Stage II), 2 rapidly evolving towards concrete project implementation. Further guidance to the GEF with 3 respect to adaptation was provided by UNFCCC COP-7, COP-9 and COP-10. Adaptation 4 activities will be supported through four different funds: 5 6 • The Strategic Priority Piloting an Operational Approach to Adaptation (SPA), supported 7

under the GEF trust fund (which includes support for projects that combine mitigation and 8 adaptation interventions) 9

• The Least-Developed Country Fund (LDCF), designed to support the development and 10 implementation of National Adaptation Plans of Action (NAPAs) for the 48 least-developed 11 countries 12

• The Special Climate Change Fund (SCCF), established to addresses special needs of 13 developing countries in the ambit of climate change, and whose top priority is adaptation 14

• The Adaptation Fund (AF), established after the entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol, 15 which directs that 2% of the share of the proceeds from CDM projects be placed in a fund 16 for adaptation 17

18 The LDCF, SCCF and AF create opportunities for the GEF to finance activities closely integrated 19 with mainstream development in several traditional sectors, including water, agriculture and 20 coastal planning. The SPA, on the other hand, provides a concrete opportunity to test integration 21 among GEF focal areas and multilateral environmental agreements on the ground, including 22 projects that combine adaptation and mitigation. Adaptation projects will address both current 23 variability and extremes and climate change. 24 25 The implementation of adaptation projects imposes an additional cost to vulnerable countries in 26 achieving their development goals. The additional cost of meeting adaptation needs will be 27 supported by the GEF through the four funds listed above. Baseline activities that would be 28 implemented in the absence of climate change are expected to be covered by existing budget lines, 29 through government, bilateral aid, private sector, NGO resources, World Bank loans or other 30 multilateral sources. The expected outcome of this approach is that adaptation funding will be 31 closely connected to mainstream development planning and investment, and that the traditional 32 development sectors (e.g., water and agriculture) will become the focus for GEF adaptation 33 projects. 34 35 The evolution of GEF funding for climate change over time is shown in Figures 18.5 and Table 36 18.2. 37

38 Figure 18.5: Number of GEF climate change projects in work programme (Eberhard and Tokle, 39 2004). 40 41

0

50

100

150

200

250

1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003

Cum

ulat

ive

(Num

ber o

f pro

ject

s)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Annu

al (N

umbe

r of

pro

ject

s)

Annual Cumulative

Page 33: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 33 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

1 Table 18.2: GEF resources allocated for climate change by country. 2

Rank Country

Total Approved Allocations

(US$ Million)

GEF Funds (US$

Million) Total

including pipeline

Total CO2 Megaton Emissions

(2000)

1 China 312.16 438.21 2,790.5 2 India 129.61 134.84 1,070.9 3 Mexico 117.08 173.48 424.0 4 Brazil 82.31 93.81 307.5 5 Philippines 63.75 66.88 77.5 6 Poland 54.39 68.19 301.3 7 Morocco 47.76 47.76 36.5 8 Uganda 32.53 32.53 1.5 9 Tunisia 28.66 29.66 18.4 10 Indonesia 27.74 29.74 269.6 11 Thailand 19.71 19.71 198.6 12 Cuba 19.08 19.08 30.9 13 Croatia 18.47 18.47 19.6 14 Vietnam 17.41 39.66 57.5 15 Sri Lanka 15.64 16.39 10.2 16 Chile 15.55 15.55 59.5 17 Peru 15.24 15.24 29.5 18 Lithuania 13.95 13.95 11.9 19 Romania 12.31 12.64 86.3 20 Russia 12.18 37.18 1,435.1

3 4 Looking ahead, three issues are expected to reshape the GEF portfolio in the years to come: 5 • The expanding role for adaptation, including making the adaptation fund operational 6 • The impact of the Resource Allocation Framework directing funding based on greenhouse 7

gas emission reduction and other measures of impact; a shift toward larger emitters 8 • Exploration of synergies between the GEF and the CDM and other sources of carbon 9

finance 10 11 12 13 18.5.3 Relevance to policy and development 14 15 16 18.6 Information needs 17 18 The information needs for understanding inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation, 19 with the implications for research priorities, related to decision frameworks, trade-offs and 20 synergies, institutions and implementation. 21 22 Decision frameworks relating adaptation and mitigation (separately or conjointly) should be tested 23

Page 34: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 34 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

against the roles and responsibilities of stakeholders at all levels of action. Global optimising 1 models may influence some decisions, while experience at the project level is important to others. 2 Hybrid approaches to integrated assessments across scales (top down and bottom up) should be 3 further developed (Wilbanks and Kates, 2003). 4 5 Representations of risk and uncertainties need to be related to decision frameworks and processes 6 (Kasperson and Kasperson, 2005). Climate risk, current and future, is only one aspect of 7 adaptation-mitigation decision-making; the relative importance and effect of other drivers needs to 8 be understood. 9 10 Research on actual trade-offs and synergies, grounded in case studies and sectoral assessments, is 11 at an early stage. The extent to which adaptation-mitigation links are substantial and urgent is still 12 a gap. Many analysts suggest the links are either serendipitous (e.g., outside the domain of project 13 planning) or modest in terms of either conflicts or co-benefits. If the urgent priority for adaptation 14 is risk management among vulnerable livelihoods, the implications for greenhouse gas emissions 15 are likely to be quite small. 16 17 At a global or international level, a socially, economically and environmentally justifiable (or 18 optimal) mix of mitigation, adaptation and development remains a research need. The extent to 19 which a global optimum is consistent with national or local mixes of strategies, or indeed 20 achievable, requires a concerted effort. The distributional effects would be an important factor is 21 evaluating tolerable or optimal climate policies. Understanding of the social cost of carbon, 22 linking to risk assessment, is fragmentary. 23 24 Unintended effects of mitigation for adaptation and vice versa are poorly documented although 25 many links have been suggested, including market failures such as perverse subsidies. The ability 26 of institutions to mediate such unintended effects may be key (e.g., Cash and Moser, 2000). The 27 necessity of links between public policy and private action, from global negotiations to local 28 levels and across sectors remain problematic. 29 30 At the pragmatic level of project design, many technical uncertainties will need resolution in order 31 to demonstrate effective linkages. Examples from agro-forestry include: 32 33

• Resilience of tree-based production systems to increased inter-annual climate variability. 34 There are reasons to think that deep-rooted tree-based production systems are more 35 resilient to inter-annual variability because their root systems explore a larger volume of 36 soil and often attain the water table. Maintenance of permanent vegetation cover improves 37 and sustains hydrologic function of the soil, which should improve the situation in both 38 drought and wet years. This is particularly pertinent to fragile (erodable) soils. 39

• Ability of agro-forestry systems to maintain production in the face of long-term climate 40 change. With a longer lifespan than annual cropping systems, up front investments are 41 often higher. As such the returns on investment are often maximised several years after the 42 establishment. Thus for agroforestry systems, where future options for farmers are limited 43 by choices made at the time of establishment, the long-term sustainability issue in the face 44 of climate change needs careful consideration. 45

• Carbon sequestration potential of agro-forestry systems. Of particular concern are the N2O 46 emissions (e.g., shade coffee systems, improved fallow systems). Below-ground carbon 47 sequestration in no-till agroforestry systems should be high. 48

49 Progress in implementing adaptation-mitigation programmes and projects is gathering pace. 50

Page 35: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 35 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Collecting the current experience and building a solid information base for future action is a 1 priority. The development of a broad-spectrum of response capacity needs to be effective in order 2 to seize opportunities and overcome constraints on implementation in sectoral policies. Effective 3 institutional development, use of financial instruments, participatory planning and risk 4 management strategies are areas for learning from the emerging experience (Klein et al., 2005). 5 Protocols for action should be compared. 6 7 The literature on the extent to which adaptation would affect different groups of societies is 8 relatively scant. Climate mitigation in the forest and energy sectors are likely to affect women and 9 men differently, drawing upon inferences from studies of environmental degradation and energy 10 poverty. Mitigation action through the Clean Development Mechanism could also help or hinder 11 women’s access to energy and energy technologies but, to date, little has been done on cross 12 gender analyses and the degrees of vulnerability, resilience and response capacity. Adaptation 13 strategies would be relevant in climate sensitive sectors such as water and agriculture and women 14 tend to assume the bulk of the responsibility of water management in both productive and non-15 productive uses and they provide the active labour force in agriculture. Adaptation strategies such 16 as irrigation, use of crop resistant species in agriculture, water storage, etc. could generate new 17 opportunities for women but this assertion need to be backed with empirical work. 18 19 20

Page 36: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 36 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

References 1 2 Adger, W. N. (2000). Institutional adaptation to environmental risk under the transition in 3

Vietnam. Annals of the Association of American Geographers. Oxford, Blackwells 4 Publishers. 90: pp. 735-738. 5

Adger, W. N. (2001). "Scales of Governance and Environmental Justice for Adaptation and 6 Mitigation of Climate Change." Journal of International Development 13: 921-931. 7

Adger, W. N., N. Brooks, et al. (2004). New Indicators of Vulnerability and Adaptive Capacity. 8 Technical Report 7. Norwich, UK, Tyndall Centre for Climate Research. 9

AfDB, ADB, et al. (2003). Poverty and Climate Change—Reducing the Vulnerability of the Poor 10 through Adaptation. Interagency. S. (ed.). Washington, DC, USA: xii+43 pp. 11

Al Malki, A., M. Al Amri, et al. (1998). "Experimental Study of Using Renewable Energy in the 12 Rural Areas of Oman." Renewable Energy 13(4): 319 - 324. 13

Alam, M. and L. A. Murry (2005). Gatekeeper Series: Facing up to Climate Change in South Asia 14 - Reducing the risk of GLOFs in Nepal. Winnipeg, Canada, IISD. 15

Alcamo, J., P. Mayerhofer, et al. (2002). "An integrated assessment of regional air pollution and 16 climate change in Europe: findings of the AIR-CLIM project." Environmental Science & 17 Policy 5(4): 257-273. 18

Altieri, M. A. (1999). "Applying Agroecology to enhance the productivity of Peasant farming 19 systems in Latin America." Environment, Development and Sustainability 1(3-4): 197-217. 20

Banuri, T., G. Hyden, et al. (1994). Sustainable Human Development: From Concept to 21 Operation., United Nations Development Programme, New York. 22

Banuri, T., G. Hyden, et al. (1999). Sustainable Human Development: From Concept to 23 Operation. New York, United Nations Development Programme. 24

Banuri, T. and J. Weyant (2001). Setting the Stage: Climate Change and Sustainable 25 Development. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation, Report of Working Group III, 26 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Metz, Bert, O. Davidson, R. Swart and J. Pan, 27 Cambridge University Press. 28

Barnett, J. (2001). The Meaning of Environmental Seruirity, Ecological Politics and Policy in the 29 New security Era. London, Zed Books, London. 30

Barua, D. C. (2001). "Strategy for Promotions and Development of Renewable Technologies in 31 Bangladesh: Experience from Garmeen Shakti." Renewable Energy 22(1-3): 205 - 210. 32

Becken, S. (2002). "Analysing International Tourist Flows to Estimate Energy use Associated 33 with Air Travel." Journal of Sustainable Tourism 10(2): 114 - 131. 34

Becken, S. and D. Simmons (2002). "Understanding Energy Consumption Patterns of Tourist 35 Attractions and Activities in New Zealand." Tourism Management 23(4): 343 - 354. 36

Becken, S., D. Simmons, et al. (2003). "Energy use associated with different travel choices." 37 Tourism Management 24(3): 267-278. 38

Beg, N., J. Corfee Morlot, et al. (2002). "Linkages between climate change and sustainable 39 development." Climate Policy 2(2-3): pp. 129-144. 40

Beltratti, A. (1996). Models of Economic Growth with Environmental Assets. Economics, Energy 41 and Environment, Springer Science. 42

Bergkamp, G., B. Orlando, et al. (2003). Change: Adaptation of water resources management to 43 climate change. Gland, Switzerland and Cambridge, UK, IUCN and Water & Nature 44 Initiative. 45

Bhandari, P. M. (No date). Examining adaptation and mitigation opportunities in the context of 46 the integrated watershed management programme of the Government of India. New Delhi, 47 The Energy and Resources Institute (TERI). 48

Bharwani, S., M. Bithell, et al. (2005). "Multi-agent modelling of climate outlooks and food 49 security on a community garden scheme in Limpopo, South Africa." Philosophical 50

Page 37: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 37 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

transactions of the Royal Society Forthcoming. 1 Boulahya, M., M. S. Cerda, et al. (2002). Climate, Communications, And Innovative 2

Technologies: Potential Impacts and Sustainability of New Radio and Internet Linkages in 3 Rural African Communities. Dar es Slaam, Tanzania - UNESCO Conference of Ministers of 4 Education of African Member States, Commonwealth of Learning UNESCO (BREDA). 5

Brooks, N., W. Neil Adger, et al. (2005). "The determinants of vulnerability and adaptive capacity 6 at the national level and the implications for adaptation." Global Environmental Change 15: 7 151 - 163. 8

Brotoisworo, E. (2004). ADB Technical Assistance to the Pacific: A Risk-based approach to 9 adaptation. 2nd AIACC Regional Workshop for Asia and the Pacific, Manila, Philippines. 10

Burton, I. (1994). "Deconstructing adaptation. and reconstructing." Delta 5(1): 14-15. 11 Burton, I. (2000). Adaptation to climate change and variability in the context of sustainable 12

development. In: Climate Change and Development. L. Gomez-Echeverri, Yale School of 13 Forestry and Environmental Studies, New Haven, CT, USA: pp. 153–173. 14

Burton, I., S. Huq, et al. (2002). "From impacts assessment to adaptation priorities: the shaping of 15 adaptation policy." Climate Policy, 2(2-3). 16

Busseler, K. O., J. E. Andrews, et al. (2004). "The Effects of Iron Fertilization on Carbon 17 Sequestration in the Southern Ocean." Science 304(5669): 414 - 417. 18

Caparros, A. and F. Jacquemont (2003). "Conflict between biodiversity and carbon sequestration 19 programs: economic and legal implications." Ecological Economics 46: 143 - 157. 20

Cash, D. W. and S. C. Moser (2000). " Linking global and local scales: 21 designing dynamic 22 assessment and management processes." Global Environmental Change 10(109-120). 23 Catrinus, J. J. and M. Munasinghe (1998). Climate Change Policy: Facts, Issues and Analyses, 24

Cambridge University Press: pp 83-121. 25 Ceron, J. P. and G. Dubois (2005). "More mobility means more impact on climate change: 26

prospects for household leisure mobility in France." Belgeo 2005(1-2): 103-120. 27 Chakrabarti, S. and S. Chakrabarti (2002). "Rural Electrification Programme with Solar Energy in 28

Remote Region - a case study in an island." Energy Policy 30(1): 33 - 42. 29 Chan, W. W. and J. C. Lam (2003). "Energy-saving supporting tourism Sustainability: A Case 30

study of Hotel Swimming Pool Heat Pump." Journal Of Sustainable Tourism 11(1): 74-83. 31 Cifuentes, A. L., V. H. Borja-Aburto, et al. (2001). "Hidden health benefits of greenhouse gas 32

mitigation." Science 293. 33 Cohen, S., D. Demeritt, et al. (1998). "Climate Change and sustainable development: Towards 34

dialogue." Global Environmental Change 8(4): 341-373. 35 Dalal-Clayton, B. (2003). The MDGs and sustainable development: the need for a strategic 36

approach. London, IIED: 73-91. 37 Dang, H., A. Michaelowa, et al. (2003). "Synergy of adaptation and mitigation strategies in the 38

context of sustainable development: the case of Vietnam." Climate Policy 3S1: S81-S96. 39 Denton, F., Y. Sokona, et al. (2002). Climate change and sustainable development strategies in the 40

making: what should west African countries expect? Climate and Development. Paris, 41 OECD. 42

Dlugolecki, A. and M. Keykhah (2003). "Climate Change and the Insurance Sector - Its Role in 43 Adaptation and Mitigation." The Journal of Corporate Environmental Strategy and Practice 44 (GMI)(39). 45

Dowlatabadi, H. (2005). On integration of policies for climate and global change. Vancouver 46 British Columbia, Institute for Resources Environment and Sustainability & Liu Institute for 47 Global Issues: In preparation. 48

Downing, T. E., D. Anthoff, et al. (2005). Scoping uncertainity in the social cost of carbon Final 49 project report. Social Cost of Carbon A Closer Look at Uncertainty (SCCU). Oxford:SEI, 50

Page 38: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 38 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Defra. 1 Dubois, G. and J. P. Ceron (2005). Greenhouse gas emissions from tourism under the light of 2

equity issues. Tourism, recreation and climate change. C. M. Hall. Otago, New Zealand, 3 Clevedon: Channel View publications. 4

Ebrahimian, E. (2003). Community Action to Address Climate Change: Case Studies Linking 5 Sustainable Energy Use with Improved Livelihoods. New York, GEF Small Grants 6 Programme, United Nations Development Programme: 144. 7

Environmental Agency UK (2004). Suffolk Estuarine Strategies Alde and Ore Estuary Strategy. 8 Suffolk, Environmentat Agency UK. 9

Essex, S., M. Kent, et al. (2004). "Tourism Development in Mallorca: Is water supply a 10 constraint?" Journal Of Sustainable Tourism 12(1): 4-28. 11

Estes, M. G. J., V. Gorsevski, et al. (1999). The Urban Heat Island Phenonenon and Potential 12 Mitigation Strategies. Arizona State Univeristy, APA National Planning. 13

Fearnside, P. M. (1999). "Forests and Global Warming Mitigation in Brazil - Opportunities in the 14 Brazilian Forest Sector for Responses to Global Warming Under the 'Clean Development 15 Mechanism'." Biomass and Bioenergy 16(3): 171 - 189. 16

Fearnside, P. M. (2004). "Do Hydroelectric Dams Mitigate Global Warming? The case of Brazil's 17 Curua-una Dam." Mitigation and Adaptationg for Global Warming (in press). 18

Finan, T. J. and D. R. Nelson (2001). "Making rain, making roads, making do: Public and private 19 adaptations to drought in Ceara, Northeast Brazil." Climate Research 19(2): 97 -108. 20

FRP, U. (2005). From the Mountain to the Tap: How Land Use and Water Management Can Work 21 for the Rural Poor. UK FRP, London., United Kingdom Forestry Research Programme. 22

Fung, P. Y. H., M. U. F. Kirschbaum, et al. (2002). "The Potential for Bioenergy Production from 23 Australian Forests, its contridution to national greenhouse targets and recent develoments in 24 conversion processes." Biomass and Bioenergy 22(4): 223 - 236. 25

Goklany, M. (2005). "A Climate Policy for the Short and Medium Term: Stabilization or 26 Adaptation?" Energy and Environment 16(3 & 4). 27

Gössling, S. (2002). "Global environmental consequences of tourism." Global Environmental 28 Change 12(4): 283-302 12(4): 283-302. 29

Gössling, S., C. Borgström-Hansson, et al. (2002). "Ecological Footprint Analysis as a Tool to 30 Assess Tourism Sustainability." Ecological Economics 43(2-3): 199-211. 31

Gössling, S., P. Peeters, et al. (2005). "The Eco-efficiency of Tourism." Ecological Economics 32 online-publication available at www.elsevier.com. 33

Govindasamy, B., K. Caldeira, et al. (2003). "Geoengineering Earth's radiation balance to mitigate 34 climate change from a quadrupling of CO2." Global and Planetary Change 37(1-2): 157-168. 35

Grothmann, T. and A. Patt (2005). "Adaptive capacity and human cognition: The process of 36 individual adaptation to climate change." Global Environmental Change online publication 37 available at www.sciencedirect.com. 38

Haddad, B. (2005). "Ranking the adaptive capacity of nations to climate change when socio-39 political goals are explicit." Global Environmental Change 15(165-176). 40

Hertin, J., F. Berkhout, et al. (2003). "Climate change and the UK house building sector: 41 perceptions, impacts and adaptive capacity." Building research & Information 31(3-4): 278 - 42 290. 43

Holland, L. (1999). "Horse-power: Urban domestic recycling and the development of sustainable 44 local commmunity structures." Sustainable Development 7(1): 47-53. 45

Howe, J. and P. Wheeler (1999). "Urban food Growing: The experience of two UK cities." 46 Sustainable Development 7(1): 13-24. 47

Huq, S. and H. Reid (2004). "Mainstreaming adaptation in development." IDS Bulletin 35(3): 15-48 21. 49

IIED, Lead, et al. (2005). Ckunate Change and development consultation on key research issues: 50

Page 39: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 39 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Scoping Paper & Activities Review. London, IIED: 84. 1 IPCC (1995). Economic and social dimensions of climate change - contribution of working group 2

III to the second assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change: 59-74. 3 IRM, AIRMIC, et al. (2002). A Risk Management Standard. London, AIRMIC, IRM, ALARM: 4

17. 5 IUCN, IISD, et al. (2004). Sustainable Livelihoods & Climate Change Adaptation. New York, 6

IUCN, IISD, SEI-B, Intercooperation. 7 IUCN, SEI-B, et al. (2003). Livelihoods and Climate Change - Watershed Restoration and 8

Development in Maharashtra State, India. Gland, Switzerland, IUCM, SEI-B, IISD, SDC. 9 Jaeger, C. C. (2005). Climate Change: Combining Mitigation and Adaptation. Climate Policy for 10

the 21st Century Meeting the Long-Term Challenge of Global Warming. D. Michel. 11 Baltimore, Maryland, Johns Hopkins University–SAIS: 406. 12

Jahan, S. and A. Umana (2003). "The environment-poverty nexus." Development Policy Journal 13 3: 53-70. 14

Karekezi, S. and W. Kithyoma (2002). "Renewable energy strategies for rural Africa: is a PV-led 15 renewable energy strategy the right approach for providing modern energy services to the 16 rural poor of sub-Saharan Africa?" Energy Policy 30: 1082. 17

Kasperson, J. X. and R. E. Kasperson (2005). Volume I: Publics, Risk Communication & the 18 Social Amplification of Risk. London, Earthscan. 19

Kasperson, J. X. and R. E. Kasperson (2005). Volume II: Risk Analysis, Corporations & the 20 Globalization of Risk. London, Earthscan. 21

Kellomaki, S., H. Peltola, et al. (2005). Management of European Forests under Changing 22 Climatic Conditions. Chapter 9: European Mitigation and Adaptation Potentials: 23 Conclusions and Recommendations. 24

Kerr, A. and S. Allen (2001). Climate Change: North Atlantic Comparisons. Edinburgh, 25 University of Edinburgh. 26

Klein, R. (2001). Adaptation to climate change in German Official Development Assistance - An 27 Inventory of Activities and Opportunties, with a Special Focus on Africa. Eschborn, 28 Germany, Deutsche Desellschaft fur Technische Zusammenarbelt: pp 44. 29

Klein, R. J. T., E. L. Schipper, et al. (2005). "Integrating mitigation and adaptation into climate 30 and development policy: three research questions." Environmental Science and Policy, in 31 press. 32

Klooster, D. and O. Masera (2000). "Community forest management in Mexico." Global 33 Environmental Change 10(4): 259 - 272. 34

Koonjul, J. (2004). "special case of Small Island States for sustainable development." Natural 35 Resources Forum(28): 155-156. 36

Kulindwa, K. (2002). "Economic reforms and the prospect for sustainable development in 37 Tanzania." Development Southern Africa 19(3): 389-404. 38

Kuzma, J. and L. Dobrovolny (2004). The Global Climate and Economic Development. 39 Minnesota, A consensus report from the Humphrey Institute workshop series on “Climate 40 Change and Sustainable Development: Paths to Progress”. 41

Lehtilaa, A., I. Savolainenb, et al. (2005). "The role of technology development in greenhouse gas 42 emissions reduction: The case of Finland." Energy: International Energy Workshop 30(14): 43 2738 - 2758. 44

Lehtonen, M. (2004). "The environmental-social interface of sustainable development: 45 capabilities, social capital, institutions." Ecological Economics 49(2): 199-214. 46

Markandya, A. (2002). Climate Change and Sustainable Development, Earthscan Publications, 47 London. 48

Markandya, A. and K. Halsneas (2000). Climate Change and its Linkages with development, 49 equity and sustainability, Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. 50

Page 40: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 40 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Mata, J. M. and J. Budhooram (2005). "Complementarity between Mitigation and Adaptation: The 1 Water Sector." Global Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies Journal (in preparation). 2

Mayers, J. and S. Bass (2004). Policy That Works for Forests and People: Real Prospects for 3 Governance and livelihoods. Sterling, Virginia., Earthscan. 4

Mayorga, E., A. K. Aufdenkampe, et al. (2005). "Young organic matter as a source of carbon 5 dioxide outgassing from Amazonian rivers." Nature 436: 538-541. 6

McCarthy, J., O. Canziani, et al. (2001). Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Vulnerability and 7 Adaptation. Cambridge, United Kingdom, Cambridge University Press. 8

McLean, R. F., T. A., et al. (2002). Coastal Zones and Marine Ecosystems. 9 McLean, R. F., A. Tsyban, et al. (2001). Coastal zones and marine ecosystems. In: Climate 10

Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge 11 University Press. 12

McMichael, A., A. Githeko, et al. (2001). Human Health. 13 Metz, B., B. M., et al. (2002). "Towards an equitable global climate regime: compatibility with 14

Article 2 of the Climate Change Convention and the link with sustainable development." 15 Climate Policy 2: 211-230. 16

Michaelson, J. (1998). "Geoengineering: A climate change Manhattan project." Stanford 17 Environmental Law Journal 73: 74-140. 18

Mills, E. (2003). "Climate Change, insurance and the building sector: technological synergisms 19 between adaptation and mitigation." Building research & Information 31(3-4): 257 - 277. 20

Mills, E. (2004). "The Insurance market place as a Nexus for Catalyzing synergisms between 21 Climate Change Mitigation and Adaptation." Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for 22 Global Change (MITI) (submitted). 23

Morita, T., R. J., et al. (2001). Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications., 24 Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 25

Moss, R., A. Brenkert, et al. (2001). Vulnerability to climate change: A Quantitative Approach. P. 26 f. t. U. D. o. Energy., Pacific Northwest National Lab (PNNL-SA-33642). 27

Munasinghe, M. (1992). Environmental Economics and Sustainable Development. Washington 28 DC, World Bank. 29

Munasinghe, M. and S. R. (2005). Primer on Climate Change and Sustainable Development. 30 Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. 31

Najam, A., A. Rahman, et al. (2003). "Integrating sustainable development into the Fourth 32 Assessment Report of the IPCC." Climate Policy 3S1: S9-S17. 33

Nakicenovic, N. and e. al. (2000). Special Report on Emissions Scenarios. Report of 34 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. London, Cambridge University Press. 35

Nederveen, A., J. Konings, et al. (2003). "Globalization, international transport and the global 36 environment: Technological innovation, policy making and the reduction of transport 37 emissions." Transportation Planning and Technology 26(1): 41-67. 38

Newell, P. (2004). "Climate Change and Development: A tale of two crises." Climate Change and 39 Development 35(3): 120. 40

Nordhaus, W. D. (2001). "Global Warming Economics." Science 294: 1283 - 1284. 41 North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, 42

Cambridge University Press. 43 O'Brien, Karen, et al. (2004). "Mapping vulnerability to multiple stressors: Climate change and 44

globalization in India." Global Environmental Change 14: 303-313. 45 Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, B. and L. A. Barclay (2004). "Human capital systems of innovation in 46

African development." African Development Review 16(1): 115-139. 47 Paavola, J. (2004). Livelihoods, Vulnerability and Adaptation to Climate Change in the Morogoro 48

Region, Tanzania. Norwich, University of East Anglia: 15. 49 Pezzoli, K. (1997). "Sustainable development: a transdisciplinary overview of the literature." 50

Page 41: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 41 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 40(5): 549-574. 1 Pezzoli, K. (1997). "Sustainable Development: A Transdisciplinary Overview of the Literature." 2

Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 40(5): 549-574. 3 Pielke, J. R. A. (1998). "Rethinking the role of adaptation in climate policy." Global 4

Environmental Change 8(2): 159-170. 5 Prasad, R., S. Maithal, et al. (2001). "Renewable Energy Technologies for Fuelwood Conservation 6

in the Indian Himalayan Region." Sustainable Development 2(9): 103. 7 Rayner, S. (1998). Human Choice and Climate Change, Battelle Press: Columbus. 8 Rehman, I. H. and H. D. Venema (No date). Decentralized Renewable Energy and the Climate 9

Change Mitigation-Adaptation Nexus. New Delhi, India, Energy and Resources Institute 10 (TERI). 11

Robinson, J. (2004). "Squaring the circle? Some thoughts on the idea of sustainable development." 12 Ecological Economics 48: 369-384. 13

Robinson, J., M. Bradley, et al. (2003). Climate change and sustainable development: Realizing 14 the opportunity at the world climate change conference Moscow. 15

Robinson, J. and D. Herbert (2001). "Integrating climate change and sustainable development." 16 International Journal of Global Environmental Issues 1(2): 130-149. 17

Rosenberg, N. J. and M. J. Scott (1996). Implications of Policies to Prevent Climate Change for 18 Future Food Security. Climate Change and World Food Security. T. E. Downing. Oxford, 19 UK, Springer: 551-589. 20

Ruth, M. and A.-C. Lin (2005). "Regional energy demand and adaptations to climate change: 21 Methodology and application to the state of Maryland, USA." Energy Policy, in press. 22

Sailor, D. J. (2002). Urban Heat Islands: Opportunities and Challenges for Mitigation and 23 Adaptation. Toronto - North American Urban Heat Island Summit, Portland State 24 University. 25

Schneider, S. H., W. Easterlig, et al. (2000). "Adaptation: Sensitivity to natural variability, agent 26 assumptions and dynamic climate changes." Climatic Change 45(1): 203-221. 27

Shrybman, S. 28 Shrybman, S. (2000). Trade, agriculture, and climate change: how agricultural trade policies fuel 29

climate change? Minneapolis, Institute for Agriculture and Trade policy. 30 Simms, A., J. Magrath, et al. (2004). Up in Smoke. London, New Economics Foundation. 31 Singh, S. N., A. Verman, et al. (2003). "Investigating options for attenuating methan emissions 32

from Indian Rice fields." Environmental International 29(5): 547 - 553. 33 Smit, B., O. Pilifosova, et al. (2001). Adaptation to Climate Change in the Context of Sustainable 34

Development and Equity. Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. J. 35 McCarthy, O. Canziani, N. Leary, D. Dokken and K. E. White. Cambridge, Cambridge 36 University Press. 37

Smith, J. B., R. J. T. Klein, et al. (2003). Climate Change, Adaptive Capacity and Development. 38 London, UK, Imperial College Press. 39

Srivastava, L. and T. Heller (2003). Integrating sustainable development and climate change in 40 AR4., Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. 41

Stainforth, D. A., T. Aina, et al. (2005). "Uncertainty in predictions of the climate response to 42 rising levels of greenhouse gases." Nature 433(27): 403-405. 43

Strachan, N., H. Zerriffi, et al. (2003). System implications of distributed generation. Critical 44 infrastructures - state of the art in research and applications. W. Thiessen. Boston, Dortecht, 45 London, Kluwer Academic Publications. 65. 46

Swart, R., J. Robinson, et al. (2003). "Climate change and sustainable development: expanding the 47 options." Climate Policy 3(S1): S19-S40. 48

Tiezzi, S. (2005). "The welfare effects and the distributive impact of carbon taxation on Italian 49 households." Energy Policy 33(12): 1597-1612. 50

Page 42: Chapter 18 – Inter-Relationships between Adaptation and Mitigationensembles-eu.metoffice.com/IPCC/rev_archive/FOD/Ch18_FOD.pdf · 2007. 12. 19. · Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote

Do Not Cite – Do Not Quote IPCC WGII Fourth Assessment Report – Draft for Expert Review

Deadline for submission of comments: 4 Nov 2005 42 Chapter 18 – Adaptation-Mitigation

Tol, R. S. J. (2003). "Is the uncertainty about climate change too large for expected cost-benefit 1 analysis?" Climatic Change 56(3): 265-289. 2

Tol, R. S. J. (2004). The marginal damage cost of carbon dioxide emissions: An assessment of the 3 uncertainties. Hamburg, Centre for Marine and Climate Research, University of Hamburg. 4

Tol, R. S. J. (2005). The double trade off between Adaptation and Mitigation for sea level rise: An 5 Application of FUND. Hamburg, Germany, Research Unit Sustainability and Global 6 Change. 7

Tol, R. S. J., M. Bohn, et al. (2005). "Adaptation to five meters of sea level rise." Climatic Change 8 (submitted). 9

Tol, R. S. J. and H. Dowlatabadi (2001). "Vector-Borne Diseases, Climate Change, and Economic 10 Growth." Int. Assess. 2: 173 - 181. 11

Tol, R. S. J. and R. Verheyen (2001). Liability and compensation for Climate Change Damages - 12 A Legal and Economic Assessment, Research Unit Sustainability and Global Change FNU-13 9, Centre for Marine and Climate Research, Hamburg University. 14

Tompkins, E. and W. N. Adger (2003). Defining response capacity to enhance climate change 15 policy. Working Paper 39. Norwich, Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research. 16

Tompkins, E. and L. Hurlston (2003). Report to the Cayman Islands' Government. Adaptation 17 lessons learned from responding to tropical cyclones by the Cayman Islands' Government, 18 1988 - 2002. Norwich, Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research. 19

Toth, F. L., T. Bruckner, et al. (2003a). "Integrated assessment of long-term climate policies: Part 20 1 - Model presentation." Climatic Change 56(1-2): 37-56. 21

Toth, F. L., T. Bruckner, et al. (2003b). "Integrated assessment of long-term climate policies: Part 22 2 - Model results and uncertainty analysis." Climatic Change 56(1-2): 57-72. 23

Toth, F. L., T. Bruckner, et al. (2002). "Exploring Options for Global Climate Policy in an Inverse 24 Integrated Assessment Framework." Environment 44(5): 23-34. 25

United Nations (2000). United Nations Millennium Declaration. Resolution adopted by the 26 General Assembly, 55th Session, 18 September. A/RES/55/22, United Nations. 27

Venema, H. D. and M. Cisse (2004). Seeing the Light - Adapting to Climate Change with 28 decentralized renewable energy in developing countries. Winnipeg, Canada, IISD. 29

Watson, R. (2002). Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report, Third Assessment Report of the 30 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. London., Cambridge University Press. 31

Weiss, C. (1986). Research and policy-making: a limited partnership. The Use and Abuse of 32 Social Science. F. Heller. London, Sage. 33

Wilbanks, T. (2003). "Integrating climate change and sustainable development in a place-based 34 context." Climate Policy 3(S1): S147-S154. 35

Wilbanks, T., P. Leiby, et al. (2003). Toward an Integrated analysis of Mitigation and adaptation: 36 Some preliminary findings. Oak Ridge, Tennessee, USA, Oak Ridge National Laboratory. 37

World Health Organization Europe (2004). Energy, sustainable development and health. 38 Budapest, Hungary, World Health Organization Europe. 39

Yohe, G. (2001). "Mitigative capacity: the mirror image of adaptive capacity on the emissions 40 side." Climatic Change 49(3): 247-262. 41

Yohe, G. and R. S. J. Tol (2002). " Indicators for social and economic coping capacity: Moving 42 toward a working definition of adaptive capacity." Global Environmental Change 12: 25-40. 43

44