Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz -...

66
Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers

Transcript of Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz -...

Page 1: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Chapter 13Social Security

Jonathan GruberPublic Finance and Public Policy

Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers

Page 2: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Introduction

Social Security is a federal program that taxes workers to provide income support for the elderly.

Over the next 75 years, the program has promised $3.7 trillion more in benefit payments than it plans to collect in taxes from workers.

Page 3: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Introduction

There are many directions that Social Security reform could go in, but little progress has been made.

Reforming the program is difficult because it is the single largest income source of the elderly; thus reform suggestions may bring withering political attacks.

Social Security is also the largest social insurance program in the U.S. By making payroll tax payments to Social

Security, workers purchase insurance against earnings loss when they die or retire.

Page 4: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Introduction

This lesson reviews institutional features of Social Security, and provides economic motivations for government intervention.

It then examines behavioral responses, such as crowding out of saving and encouraging early retirement.

Lastly, we examine potential reforms.

Page 5: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

WHAT IS SOCIAL SECURITY AND HOW DOES IT WORK?

Social Security began in 1935, during the height of the Great Depression. The main motivation was to provide a means of support for this unfortunate generation of elderly.

Basic structure is that workers (and employers) pay a payroll tax, and the money is used to pay benefits to the current generation of elderly.

Page 6: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

There are numerous details to Social Security.

Social Security is financed through the FICA tax, which totals 12.4% of gross earnings up to $87,900 in 2004.

An individual can collect Social Security as early as age 62, assuming he has paid into the system through the payroll tax for 10 years.

Page 7: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

When eligible, the Social Security claimant receives an annuity payment, a payment that lasts until the recipient’s death.

The payment is a function of average indexed monthly earnings, or AIME. Earnings are calculated from the 35

highest years of earnings. If the claimant worked less than 35 years, those years are treated as “0”.

They are indexed for inflation.

Page 8: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

Social Security benefits are then calculated as a redistributive function of past earnings.

Low earners get higher relative payments, but lower absolute payments.

Figure 1Figure 1 illustrates the current relationship between earnings and benefits.

Page 9: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Figure 1

$5,892$3,689

$1,000 $2,000 $3,000 $4,000 $5,000 $6,000 $7,000 $8,000

$0

Soc

ial S

ecur

ity B

enef

its (

PIA

)

$0

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (AIME)

Social Security Benefits as a Function of Earnings90

¢/$

32¢/$

15¢/$

0¢/$$1,865.89

$1,535.44

$550.80

$612

Workers who have monthly earnings less than $612 receive 90¢ in

benefits for every $1 of earnings.

Thus, a worker earning exactly $612 per month would get 0.90*$612, or

$550.80 in monthly benefits.The x-axis measures real monthly earnings,

known as AIME.The y-axis measures

Social Security benefits taken at the “normal”

retirement age.

This is the relationship

between earnings and benefits.

For the next $3,077 in monthly earnings beyond the initial $612,

workers receive only 32¢ in benefits per dollar earnings.

Thus, the total benefit from earning $3,689 per month is $1535.44, which

equals 0.90*$612 + 0.32*$3,077.

For the next $2,203 in monthly earnings, benefits increase by just 15¢ for every dollar of earnings.

The corresponding benefit for someone earning $5,892 (or more)

per month is $1865.89.

For AIME above $5,892, no benefits are paid because this corresponds to the level where no payroll taxes are

paid.

Page 10: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

The benefit formula is a redistributive function of past earnings because: Workers who earn more get higher benefits But the benefits do not rise at nearly as fast as

earnings. The replacement rate is the ratio of benefits

received to earnings prior to the entitling event. For the average earner, the Social Security

replacement rate is 40%. For low earners, it is closer to 60%. For high earners, it is closer to 20%.

Page 11: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

How are Social Security benefits paid out? Individuals can receive their Primary Insurance

Amount (PIA) starting at age 65, which is the Full Benefits Age (FBA).

One can collect benefits as early as 62, the Early Entitlement Age (EEA).

The FBA is rising to age 67; almost all college students would need to wait until 67 to collect the PIA.

If one collects benefits before their FBA, the benefits are actuarially reduced. The reduction accounts for differing years of collecting benefits and the time value of money.

There is a delayed retirement credit (DRC) for those who wait to collect Social Security after the FBA.

Page 12: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

For beneficiaries between 62 and 64, there is an earnings test of $11,640, meaning any $1 earnings beyond that point reduces Social Security benefits by 50¢.

This is not exactly a tax, however, because the benefits are returned later with interest.

Page 13: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Program Details

Spouses of claimants are also entitled to receive benefits. The family’s total benefit would be equal to:

Where SSBEN is the total benefit collected from Social Security, PIA is the primary insurance amount, and the subscripts H and W denote the husband and wife’s PIAs.

For example, a wife with a low level of earnings may have her benefit determined by her husband’s PIA.

SSBEN PIA PIA PIA PIAH W H W m a x , . , .1 5 1 5

Page 14: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

How does Social Security work over time? In contrast to private pension plans,

which are funded, Social Security has typically been unfunded.

This means that taxes collected from a current worker go directly to current retirees.

This is referred to as a “Pay-As-You-Go” system.

Page 15: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

There is no guarantee with a pay-as-you-go system that future benefits will be paid out in the way one might expect: The system could go bankrupt. Future generations could refuse to pay

to finance the system.

Page 16: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

Unlike private pension plans, which are backed by the actual assets of the plan, the promises of Social Security are backed by the policies of the government.

Because of the large fiscal imbalance in Social Security, nearly ¾ of young people today believe that the system will not provide them with significant income in retirement.

Page 17: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

In reality, Social Security is not a completely unfunded system; some of today’s payroll contributions go into the Social Security Trust Fund to help pay for future retirees.

Yet, the trust fund is projected to run out of money by 2042, at which point Social Security becomes a completely unfunded system.

The unfunded nature of Social Security creates redistribution across generations.

See Table 1Table 1.

Page 18: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Table 1

Social Security in a Two-Period WorldPeriod Number

of young

workers

Earnings per young worker

Taxes paid per

young worker

Total taxes paid

Number of old

retirees

Benefits to old

retirees

Taxes paid by

old retirees

Rate of return

1 100 $20,000

0 0 0 0 --- ---

2 105 $21,000

$2,100 $220,500

100 $2,205 0 ∞

3 110 $22,050

$2,205 $242,550

105 $2,310 $2,100 10%

4 115 $23,153

$2,315 $266,225

110 $2,420 $2,205 10%

5 121 $24,310

0 0 115 0 $2,315 -∞

Individuals live for two periods, and then die. They are young in the first

period, and old in the second.

When they are young, they work and pay a tax to support Social

Security.

When they are old, the collect Social Security.

The population grows over time, in this case by 5% per period.

Real wages are assumed to rise at 5% as well, due to increased

productivity.There is no Social Security program in year 1. The young do not have to pay

Social Security taxes.Social Security is started as an

unfunded program in year 2, with a 10% payroll tax on the current young.

The taxes collected are $220,500; $2,100 per person x 105 young people. This is divided among the 100 elderly.

Because the elderly did not pay into the system, yet they collect benefits,

their rate of return is infinite.

The initial generation (elderly who did not pay) is the big winner from the

unfunded system.

In year 3, the elderly are those who were young and paying taxes in year 2.

Recall they paid in $2,100 each.

They now receive $2,310 in benefits, 10% more than they paid in.

This return comes from higher total tax collections due to wage growth

and population growth.

If population and wage growth are high, the rate of return to “middle

generations” can be large.

Now imagine that in year 5, the young workers scrap the system. They pay no

taxes.

The elderly in year 5 (who were young in year 4) suffer as a consequence. They paid

into the system but got nothing out of it.

Page 19: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

This example illustrates several points. The return to “middle generations”

depends on the rates of population and wage growth.

Unfunded Social Security carries with it a legacy debt, the debt incurred by the government because early generations received much more in benefits than they paid in taxes.

Page 20: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Work Over Time?

The example shows how Social Security redistributes across generations: The first generation received a large

windfall. The middle generations got a rate of

return determined by wage and population growth.

The final generation was the big loser.

Page 21: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

How does Social Security redistribute in practice? We compute Social Security Wealth (SSW), the

expected PDV of Social Security benefits over a person’s lifetime, minus the PDV of payroll taxes.

This involves several steps: Calculate the entire future stream of benefits that

the person expects to receive before he or she dies, accounting for mortality. Use a discount rate to compute PDV of benefits.

Calculate the entire future stream of payroll taxes. Compute the PDV of taxes.

Take the difference between the two to get SSW. Table 2Table 2 shows the results.

Page 22: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Table 2

Redistribution under Social Security for a Single Male

Earnings Level Retirees turn 65 in 1960

Retirees turn 65 in 1995

Retirees turn 65 in

2030

Low earner $26,100 $12,500 -$4,100

Average earner $36,500 -$5,100 -$56,200

High earner $36,800 -$37,100 -$248,500

Moving across the columns examines successively younger generations.

Younger generations have lower SSW than older

generations.

Moving down the rows looks at higher earners.

Higher earners have lower SSW.

Page 23: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

The redistribution to the oldest generation occurs for the kinds of reasons we saw in the previous table. They did not pay into the system for

much of their working lives, but received benefits over their whole retirement.

In addition, not only was there population growth and wage growth, but also growth in the actual payroll tax rate.

Page 24: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

For more recent retirees (the 1995 cohort), Social Security has generally become a losing proposition. They paid into the system for their

entire working lives. The growth in the payroll tax rate has

slowed. There has been a significant slowdown

in wage growth and population growth.

Page 25: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

For future retirees (the 2030 cohort), the outcome is the worst of all. Payroll taxes are not rising at all. Wage and population growth are slow.

Page 26: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

In addition, the system has shifted from one that favors the rich in earlier generations to one that favors the poor.

The reason is for this change is that higher-income earners pay more money into the system through payroll taxes; but when the returns to Social Security are low, the higher-income earner has more money of his or her own in an underperforming asset.

Page 27: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

How Does Social Security Redistribute in Practice?

Finally, Social Security redistributes in other ways. It pays an annuity until death; therefore groups

with shorter life expectancies (men, the poor, minorities, smokers) tend to lose under such a system.

It provides survivorship benefits; this redistributes toward married couples relative to single individuals.

It adjusts the benefit level by 50% for married households with a single earner; this redistributes toward single-earner married households.

It generally redistributes from the rich to the poor, even with adjustments for life expectancy.

Page 28: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING BENEFITS OF SOCIAL SECURITY:

Rationales for Social Security

On the surface, it is not clear why there is government involvement in Social Security, since retirement is an anticipated event that is largely an individual decision.

There are a number of rationales for government involvement, however.

Page 29: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Rationales for Social Security

First, there may be market failures in the annuities market that Social Security solves. This market is subject to adverse

selection, where the “high risks” are the ones who live a long time.

Finkelstein and Poterba (2004) find compelling evidence for such adverse selection.

Page 30: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Rationales for Social Security

Second, paternalism comes into play: policymakers believe that individuals won’t save enough for their own retirement. In 1991, for example, the median

American aged 51-61 had $107,000 in future Social Security wealth, but only $16,000 in private pension wealth and $3,000 in other personal retirement assets.

Page 31: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

Regardless of the reason, Social Security’s existence is motivated by consumption smoothing.

The question then becomes does it? The existing evidence shows that it

does help smooth consumption.

Page 32: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

The evidence comes in several forms: Private savings behavior Consumption at retirement Living standards of the elderly

Page 33: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

Existing research suggests that each $1 of Social Security wealth crowds out 30¢ to 40¢ of private savings. This is important, but not full crowd-out. Assessing the evidence in the U.S. is

difficult because Social Security is a nationally uniform program, which makes it difficult to find good treatment and control groups.

Other countries, such as Italy and the U.K., have had changes that lend credence to the magnitude of crowding out.

Page 34: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

Another approach is to look directly at consumption. A model with diminishing marginal utility would imply smooth consumption over time. Bernheim, Skinner, and Weinberg

(2001) found that consumption falls more than 30% when individuals retire.

This finding is consistent with only a partial crowding-out of private savings by the Social Security system.

Page 35: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

A third piece of evidence examines the poverty rates of the elderly.

The poverty rate is defined as: The number of elderly with income less

than the poverty threshold divided by the total number of elderly.

Figure 2Figure 2 shows the results.

Page 36: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Elderly Poverty Rate and SS Over Time

0

8

16

24

32

40

1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001

Year

Po

ve

rty

Ra

te f

or

65

+ (

%)

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

SS

Sp

en

din

g (%

of G

DP

)

SS Spending

Elderly Poverty RateWhile Social Security spending has gone up.

The fraction of elderly living in poverty has fallen

dramatically over time.

Figure 2

Page 37: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Does Social Security Smooth Consumption?

The decline in poverty rates for the elderly during the 1960s and 1970s coincided with the time when the Social Security program grew the fastest.

Engelhardt and Gruber (2004) analyze how poverty fell for birth cohorts that benefited from expansion in Social Security, relative to those that did not, and conclude that Social Security can explain the entire time trend reduction in poverty among the elderly over this period.

Page 38: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

SOCIAL SECURITY AND RETIREMENT:

Theory The design of Social Security naturally

leads to the issue of whether it encourages early retirement.

Social Security may encourage early retirement through: Implicit taxation, acting as a

“substitution effect.” Redistribution, acting as an “income

effect.”

Page 39: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Theory

The “implicit tax” takes account of the fact that a worker at the early entitlement age can choose to work another year.

If so, SSW changes because: One more year of payroll taxes is paid. One year of Social Security benefits is given up. The benefit level goes up because of actuarial

adjustment. The year of work usually replaces a low earnings

year with a high earnings year. Higher implicit taxes should lead to earlier

retirement. The redistributive effects were discussed early, and

act as an income effect.

Page 40: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

There are three sources of evidence that suggest Social Security encourages retirement: Time series evidence The retirement hazard rate International comparisons

Page 41: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

Figure 3Figure 3 illustrates time series evidence. It shows the labor force participation of males, plotted against Social Security spending.

The time series for females is clouded by the general upward trend in female labor force participation since World War II.

Page 42: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Figure 3

Elderly Labor Force Participation and SS Over Time

10

12

14

16

18

20

22

1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001

Year

Lab

or

Fo

rce

Par

tici

pat

ion

Rat

e (%

of

65+

in

lab

or

forc

e)

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

SS

Sp

end

ing

(% o

f GD

P)

SS Spending

Labor Force Participation

While Social Security spending has gone up.

The fraction of elderly men who are working has fallen

dramatically.

Page 43: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

The second piece of evidence comes from examining the age pattern at retirement.

The retirement hazard rate is the percentage of working people who retire at a given age.

Figure 4Figure 4 shows the results.

Page 44: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

Age

Ret

irem

ent

Haz

ard

Rat

e

SS EEASS FBA

55 60 65 7062

The hazard rate again spikes at 65, the FBA.

The hazard rate falls at ages 63 and 64.

The hazard rate is less than 10% through age 61.

The hazard rate spikes up at age 62, which is also

the early entitlement age.

Figure 4

Page 45: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

The hazard rates in Figure 4Figure 4 are suggestive, but not necessarily conclusive about the impact of Social Security.

Figure 5Figure 5 shows similar hazard rates in 1960 (before the EEA), 1970, and 1980.

Page 46: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Ret

irem

ent

Haz

ard

Rat

e

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

Age

55 65 70

1960

1970

1980

62

SS EEA

SS FBA

There was no spike in the hazard rate in 1960, before the EEA was introduced.

The spike grew slowly over time, after the EEA was

introduced.

Figure 5

Page 47: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

A third type of evidence, and perhaps most compelling, is to make international comparisons.

There are spikes in other countries too, at the EEA and FBA, even when those ages differ from that in the United States.

Figure 6Figure 6 shows retirement patterns in France.

Page 48: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

50 55 60 65 70

0

0.1

Ret

irem

ent

Haz

ard

Rat

e

Age

-0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7 SS EEA & FBA

There is an enormous spike in the hazard rate in France at age 60, which is both the EEA and FBA.

60% of those working when they turn 60 retire during the next year.

Moreover, when the “age 60” retirement age was not an option in France, the hazard rate was 10%.

Figure 6

Page 49: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Evidence

Figure 7Figure 7 shows evidence from Germany, which lowered its retirement age in the early 1970s.

Page 50: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992

EEA Introduced in 1973

Year

Mea

n R

etire

men

t A

geGermany lowered the early

retirement age from 65 to 60 in 1973.

Within 7 years, the average age at which individuals retire had fallen

from 63 to 58.

Figure 7

Page 51: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Implicit Social SecurityImplicit Social Securitytaxes and retirement taxes and retirement

behaviorbehavior Finally, Gruber and Wise (1999)

present data from a series of counties on the implicit tax rates from Social Security and the decision not to work.

The results show a strong positive relationship between retirement rates and tax rates.

Figure 8Figure 8 shows their results.

Applicati

Applicati

onon

Page 52: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Figure 8

20

-0.5 0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5

30

40

50

60

70

Disincentive to work

Non

wor

king

Eld

erly

R2 = 0.82

Japan

US

Canada

Sweden

Spain

UK

France

Germany

Belgium

Italy

NetherlandsIn nations like the United States, Sweden, and especially Japan,

there is little implicit tax.

These countries also have higher percentages of elderly working.

Other countries, like the Netherlands, Belgium, France, and

Italy, have high taxes.

They also have lower percentages of elderly working.

The horizontal axis measures the “implicit tax” to working at older

ages.

For example, the measure takes into account the extra payroll taxes

paid by working another year.

It also takes into account any upward adjustments to benefit levels for delaying retirement.

And it accounts for the fact that average earnings tend to be higher

by delaying retirement.

Page 53: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Implicit Social SecurityImplicit Social Securitytaxes and retirement taxes and retirement

behaviorbehavior In summary, the evidence suggests that

Social Security systems that penalize work beyond the retirement age have led to increased retirements.

Applicati

Applicati

onon

Page 54: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM

The Social Security system, in its current form, is unsustainable.

The number of elderly that need to be supported by workers continues to grow over time.

See Figure 9Figure 9.

Page 55: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Ratio of Elderly to Working Age Population

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Year

Nu

mb

er o

f el

der

ly p

er 1

00 w

ork

ing

ag

e p

eop

le

The number of elderly, relative to workers,

has grown over time.

By 2025, there will be a larger share of

elderly in the U.S. than there are in Florida

currently.

Figure 9

Page 56: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM

Also, over the next 75 years, the PDV of the program’s obligations exceed the PDV of the taxes it will collect by $3.7 trillion.

Three factors cause this imbalance: Improvements in life expectancy A reduction in birth rates The growth in wages has slowed

dramatically.

Page 57: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Reform Round I: The Greenspan Commission

With impending financial problems, the Greenspan Commission in 1983 recommended a number of changes that took place: Speeding up increases in the payroll

tax. Cutting benefits.

These policy changes staved off Social Security’s financing problems to some extent, but did not solve them.

Page 58: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Incremental Reforms

There are a number of approaches that build on the current system: Raise payroll taxes further: An increase from

12.4% to 14.3% solves financing problems for the next 75 years; raising it to 15.9% solves it forever.

Extend the base of taxable wages: Some workers are not covered by Social Security, and would represent a net gain in the financial position of the program.

Raise the retirement age: The FBA has not moved up in lock-step with life expectancy.

Page 59: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Incremental Reforms

Lower benefits: Lower rates at which the AIME is translated into the PIA. Alternatively, the government could adjust the indexation rate.

Means-test the program: Another possibility would be to tax benefits for higher income households.

Page 60: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

In addition to the “incremental reforms” discussed, there are some more fundamental reforms that have been posed as a solution to Social Security’s financial imbalance: Invest the trust fund in stocks Privatization

Page 61: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

Investing the trust fund in stocks–100% of the assets of the Social Security Trust Fund are held in bonds.

A slow investment of the trust fund in the stock market could lead to a higher rate of return and cover half of the projected 75-year deficit. This runs into the problem that politicians

may simply take these higher returns and use them for government spending.

Also, there is concern the government might abuse its position to manipulate capital markets for its own good.

Page 62: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

A more radical alternative is privatization–allowing individuals to invest their payroll taxes in various assets through individually controlled accounts. The capital would then truly be “off-

budget” to politicians, unlike the Social Security Trust Fund.

It would also respect consumer sovereignty with respect to investment decisions.

Page 63: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

The transition to such a system is the most difficult problem–how do we let individuals save money for their own retirement, while at the same time supporting the existing generation of retirees?

Once the need to pay back this legacy debt is accounted for, a privatized Social Security system would not provide a higher rate of return.

Page 64: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

Such a privatized system could also have higher administrative costs; the current system’s costs are only 0.19% of the program’s asset balances.

For example, the administrative costs of the U.K. and Chile, two countries with privatized systems, are more than 100 basis points higher, which over the course of many years substantially lowers wealth levels.

Page 65: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Fundamental Reforms

A final issue with privatization is that policy makers may not want to respect consumer sovereignty with respect to retirement savings.

In private 401(k) accounts, for example, company stock makes up 1/6th of aggregate assets. This option almost never makes sense.

Page 66: Chapter 13 Social Security Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.

Recap of Social Security

What is Social Security and how does it work?

Consumption smoothing benefits of Social Security

Social Security and Retirement Social Security Reform