CH04 Consumption and Saving

download CH04 Consumption and Saving

of 64

Transcript of CH04 Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    1/64

    Chapter 4

    Consumption,Saving, and

    Investment

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    2/64

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    3/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-3

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    The importance of consumption and saving

    Desired consumption: consumption amount desired byhouseholds

    Desired national saving: level of national saving whenconsumption is at its desired level, Sd= Y- Cd- G (4.1)

    The consumption and saving decision of an individualA person can consume less than current income (saving is

    positive)A person can consume more than current income (saving is

    negative)

    Trade-off between current consumption and futureconsumptionThe price of 1 unit of current consumption is 1 + runits of

    future consumption, where ris the real interest rateConsumption-smoothing motive: the desire to have a

    relatively even pattern of consumption over time

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    4/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-4

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Effect of changes in current incomeIncrease in current income: both consumption

    and saving increase (vice versa for decrease incurrent income)

    Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) =fraction of additional current income consumedin current period; between 0 and 1

    Aggregate level: When current income (Y)

    rises, Cd

    rises, but not by as much as Y, so Sd

    rises

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    5/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-5

    Figure 4.1(a) The index of consumer sentiment,January 1987December 1994

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    6/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-6

    Figure 4.1(b) Total consumption expenditures andconsumption expenditures on durable goods, 19871994

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    7/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-7

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Effect of changes in expected futureincomeHigher expected future income leads to more

    consumption today, so saving falls

    Application: consumer sentiment and the199091 recession; sharp contraction inconsumer sentiment in 1990 led to fall inconsumer spending

    Effect of changes in wealth

    Increase in wealth raises current consumption,so lowers current saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    8/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-8

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Effect of changes in real interest rateIncreased real interest rate has two opposing

    effectsSubstitution effect: Positive effect on saving, since

    rate of return is higher; greater reward for savingelicits more saving

    Income effectFor a saver: Negative effect on saving, since it takes less

    saving to obtain a given amount in the future (targetsaving)

    For a borrower: Positive effect on saving, since the higherreal interest rate means a loss of wealth

    Empirical studies have mixed results; probably a

    slight increase in aggregate saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    9/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-9

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Taxes and the real return to savingExpected after-tax real interest rate:

    ra-t = (1 - t)i- e (4.2)

    Simple examples: i= 5%, e = 2%; ift= 30%, ra-t

    = 1.5%; ift= 20%, ra-t= 2%

    In touch with the macroeconomy: interest ratesDiscusses different interest rates, default risk, term

    structure (yield curve), and tax statusSince interest rates often move together, we frequently

    refer to the interest rate

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    10/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-10

    Table 4.1 Calculating After-Tax Interest Rates

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    11/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-11

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Fiscal policyAffects desired consumption through changes in current

    and expected future income

    Directly affects desired national saving, Sd = Y- Cd - G

    Government purchases (temporary increase)HigherG financed by higher current taxes reduces after-tax

    income, lowering desired consumption

    Even true if financed by higher future taxes, if people realizehow future incomes are affected

    Since Cddeclines less than G rises, national saving (Sd= Y-Cd - G) declines

    So government purchases reduce both desired consumptionand desired national saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    12/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-12

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    TaxesLump-sum tax cut today, financed by higher future

    taxes

    Decline in future income may offset increase incurrent income; desired consumption could rise or fall

    Ricardian equivalence proposition If future income loss exactly offsets current income gain,

    no change in consumption

    Tax change affects only the timing of taxes, not their

    ultimate amount (present value) In practice, people may not see that future taxes will rise if

    taxes are cut today; then a tax cut leads to increaseddesired consumption and reduced desired national saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    13/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-13

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    14/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-14

    4.1 Consumption and Saving

    Application: a Ricardian tax cut?The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconstruction

    Act (EGTRRA) of 2001 gave rebate checks to taxpayersand cut tax rates substantially

    From the first quarter to the third quarter, government

    saving fell $245 billion (at an annual rate) but privatesaving increased $212 billion, so national savingdeclined only $33 billion, a result consistent withRicardian equivalence

    Most consumers saved their tax rebates and did notspend them

    As a result, the tax rebate and tax cut did not stimulatemuch additional spending by households

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    15/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-15

    Application A Ricardian Tax Cut?

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    16/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-16

    4.2 Investment

    Why is investment important?

    Investment fluctuates sharply over the business cycle,so we need to understand investment to understand thebusiness cycle

    Investment plays a crucial role in economic growth

    The desired capital stockDesired capital stock is the amount of capital that allows

    firms to earn the largest expected profitDesired capital stock depends on costs and benefits of

    additional capitalSince investment becomes capital stock with a lag, thebenefit of investment is the future marginal product ofcapital (MPKf)

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    17/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-17

    4.2 Investment

    The user cost of capital

    Example of Kyle's Bakery: cost of capital, depreciation rate,and expected real interest rate

    User cost of capital = real cost of using a unit of capital for aspecified period of time

    uc= rpK+ dpK= (r+ d)pK (4.3)

    Determining the desired capital stock (Fig. 4.2)Desired capital stock is the level of capital stock at which MPKf

    = ucMPKf falls as Krises due to diminishing marginal productivityucdoesn't vary with K, so is a horizontal line

    IfMPKf> uc, profits rise as Kis added (marginal benefits >marginal costs)

    IfMPKf< uc, profits rise as Kis reduced (marginal benefits replacement cost, then firmshould invest more

    Tobins q = capitals market value divided by itsreplacement costIfq < 1, don't invest

    Ifq > 1, invest more

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    24/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-24

    4.2 Investment

    Stock price times number of shares equals firms market

    value, which equals value of firms capitalFormula: q = V/ (pKK), where Vis stock market value of firm,

    Kis firms capital,pK is price of new capital

    SopKKis the replacement cost of firms capital stock

    Stock market boom raises V, causing q to rise, increasing

    investmentData show general tendency of investment to rise when

    stock market rises; but relationship isnt strong becausemany other things change at same time

    This theory is similar to text discussionHigherMPKf increases future earnings of firm, so VrisesA falling real interest rate also raises Vas people buy stocks

    instead of bonds

    A decrease in the cost of capital,pK, raises q

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    25/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-25

    Figure 4.4 An increase in the expectedfuture MPK raises the desired capital stock

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    26/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-26

    4.2 Investment

    From the desired capital stock to investment

    The capital stock changes from two opposing channelsNew capital increases the capital stock; this is gross investmentThe capital stock depreciates, which reduces the capital stockNet investment = gross investment (I) minus depreciation:

    Kt+1 - Kt = It - dKt (4.5), where net investment equals the change in the capital stock

    Fig. 4.5 shows gross and net investment for the United StatesRewriting (4.5) gives It= Kt+1 - Kt+ dKt

    If firms can change their capital stocks in one period, then the desiredcapital stock (K*) = Kt+1, so It = K*- Kt + dKt (4.6)

    Thus investment has two partsDesired net increase in the capital stock over the year (K*- Kt)

    Investment needed to replace depreciated capital (dKt)Lags and investment

    Some capital can be constructed easily, but other capital may takeyears to put in place

    So investment needed to reach the desired capital stock may bespread out over several years

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    27/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-27

    Figure 4.5 Gross and net investment, 19292002

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    28/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-28

    4.2 Investment

    Investment in inventories and housingMarginal product of capital and user cost also

    apply, as with equipment and structures

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    29/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-29

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    30/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-30

    4.3 Goods Market Equilibrium

    The real interest rate adjusts to bring the goods

    market into equilibriumgoods market equilibrium condition : Y

    = Cd + Id+ G (4.7)Differs from income-expenditure identity, as goods

    market equilibrium condition need not hold; undesiredgoods may be produced, so goods market won't be inequilibrium

    Alternative representation: sinceSd= Y- Cd - G, Sd= Id (4.9)

    The saving-investment diagramPlot Sd vs. Id (Key Diagram 3; Fig. 4.6)Equilibrium where Sd = Id

    How to reach equilibrium? Adjustment ofr

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    31/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-31

    Key Diagram 3 The saving investment diagram

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    32/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-32

    Figure 4.6 Goods market equilibrium

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    33/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-33

    Table 4.3 Components of AggregateDemand for Goods (An Example)

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    34/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-34

    4.3 Goods Market Equilibrium

    Shifts of the saving curveSaving curve shifts right due to a rise in current output,

    a fall in expected future output, a fall in wealth, a fall ingovernment purchases, a rise in taxes (unless Ricardianequivalence holds, in which case tax changes have noeffect)

    Example: Temporary increase in governmentpurchases shifts S leftResult of lower savings: higherr, causing crowding out

    ofI

    Shifts of the investment curveInvestment curve shifts right due to a fall in the effective

    tax rate or a rise in expected future marginal productivityof capitalResult of increased investment: higherr, higherS and I

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    35/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-35

    Figure 4.7 A decline in desired saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    36/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-36

    Figure 4.8 An increase in desired investment

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    37/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-37

    4.3 Goods Market Equilibrium

    Application: Macroeconomic consequences of the

    boom and bust in stock pricesSharp changes in stock prices affect consumption

    spending (a wealth effect) and capital investment (viaTobins q)

    Consumption and the 1987 crashWhen the stock market crashed in 1987, wealth declined by

    about $1 trillionConsumption fell somewhat less than might be expected, and

    it wasnt enough to cause a recession

    There was a temporary decline in confidence about the future,but it was quickly reversedThe small response may have been because there had been a

    large run-up in stock prices between December 1986 andAugust 1987, so the crash mostly erased this run-up

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    38/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-38

    Figure 4.9 Real U.S. stock prices and theratio of consumption to GDP, 19872002

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    39/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-39

    4.3 Goods Market Equilibrium

    Consumption and the rise in stock market wealth in the

    1990sStock prices more than tripled in real termsBut consumption was not strongly affected by the runup in

    stock prices

    Consumption and the decline in stock prices in the early

    2000sIn the early 2000s, wealth in stocks declined by about $5

    trillionBut consumption spending increased as a share of GDP in

    that period

    Investment and Tobins qInvestment and Tobins q were not closely correlated following

    the 1987 crash in stock pricesBut the relationship has been tighter in the 1990s and early

    2000s, as theory suggests

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    40/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-40

    Figure 4.10 Investment and Tobins q, 19872002

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    41/64

    Appendix 4A

    A Formal Modelof Consumption

    and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    42/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-42

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    How much can the consumer afford? The budget constraint (BC)Current income y; future income yf; initial wealth a

    Choice variables: af= wealth at beginning of future period; c=current consumption; cf= future consumption

    af = (y+ a - c)(1 + r), so cf = (y+ a - c)(1 + r) + yf (4.A.1) the BC

    The budget lineGraph budget line in (c, cf) space (Fig. 4.A.1)

    Slope of line = -(1 + r) Present values

    Present value is the value of payments to be made in the future interms of today's dollars or goods

    Example: At an interest rate of 10%, $12,000 today invested for

    one year is worth $13,200 ($12,000

    1.10); so the present valueof $13,200 in one year is $12,000General formula: Present value = future value / (1 + i), where

    amounts are in dollar terms and iis the nominal interest rateAlternatively, if amounts are in real terms, use the real interest rate

    rinstead of the nominal interest rate i

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    43/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-43

    Figure 4.A.1 The budget line

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    44/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-44

    Present value and the budget constraintPresent value of lifetime resources: PVLR= y+ yf/(1+r) + a (4.A.2)

    Present value of lifetime consumption: PVLC= c+ cf

    /(1+r) (4.A.3)The budget constraint means PVLC= PVLRc+ cf/(1+r) = y+ yf/(1+r) + aHorizontal intercept of budget line is c= PVLR, cf= 0

    What does the consumer want? Consumer preferences Utility = a persons satisfaction or well-being (indifference curve, IC) Graph a persons preference for current vs. future consumption using ICAn IC shows combinations ofcand cf that give the same utility (Fig. 4.A.2)A person is equally happy at any point on an IC Three important properties of ICs

    Slope downward from left to right: Less consumption in one period

    requires more consumption in the other period to keep utility unchangedICs that are farther up and to the right represent higher levels of utility,

    because more consumption is preferred to lessICs are bowed toward the origin, because people have a consumption-

    smoothing motive, they prefer consuming equal amounts in each periodrather than consuming a lot one period and little the other period

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    45/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-45

    Figure 4.A.2 Indifference curves

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    46/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-46

    The optimal level of consumption Optimal consumption point is where the budget line is tangent to an IC (Fig.

    4.A.3)

    Thats the highest IC that its possible to reachAll other points on the budget line are on lower ICs The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and

    Saving The effect on consumption of a change in income (current or future) or

    wealth depends only on how the change affects the PVLRAn increase in current income (Fig. 4.A.4)

    Increases PVLR, so shifts budget line out parallel to old budget line If there is a consumption-smoothing motive, both current and future

    consumption will increase Then both consumption and saving rise because of the rise in current

    incomeAn increase in future income

    Same outward shift in budget line as an increase in current income

    Again, with consumption smoothing, both current and future consumptionincrease Now saving declines, since current income is unchanged and current

    consumption increasesAn increase in wealth

    Same parallel shift in budget line, so both current and future consumptionrise

    Again, saving declines, since crises and yis unchanged

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    47/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-47

    Figure 4.A.3 The optimal consumptioncombination

    Fi 4 A 4

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    48/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-48

    Figure 4.A.4 An increase in income or wealth

    A di 4 A A F l M d l f C ti d S i

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    49/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-49

    The permanent income theoryDifferent types of changes in income

    Temporary increase in income: yrises and yf is unchanged

    Permanent increase in income: Both yand yf rise

    Permanent income increase causes bigger increase in PVLRthan atemporary income increase

    So current consumption will rise more with a permanent income

    increaseSo saving from a permanent increase in income is less than from

    a temporary increase in income

    This distinction between permanent and temporary income changeswas made by Milton Friedman in the 1950s and is known as the

    permanent income theoryPermanent changes in income lead to much larger changes in

    consumption

    Thus permanent income changes are mostly consumed, whiletemporary income changes are mostly saved

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    A di 4 A A F l M d l f C ti d S i

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    50/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-50

    Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-CycleModel

    Life-cycle model was developed by Franco Modigliani andassociates in the 1950sLooks at patterns of income, consumption, and saving over an

    individuals lifetimeTypical consumers income and saving pattern shown in Fig. 4.A.5Real income steadily rises over time until near retirement; at retirement,

    income drops sharplyLifetime pattern of consumption is much smoother than the income

    pattern In reality, consumption varies somewhat by age For example, when raising children, household consumption is

    higher than average

    The model can easily be modified to handle this and othervariationsSaving has the following lifetime pattern

    Saving is low or negative early in working lifeMaximum saving occurs when income is highest (ages 50 to 60)Dissaving occurs in retirement

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Fi 4 A 5 Lif l ti

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    51/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-51

    Figure 4.A.5 Life-cycle consumption,income, and saving

    Fi 4 A 5 Lif l ti

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    52/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-52

    Figure 4.A.5 Life-cycle consumption,income, and saving (contd)

    A di 4 A A F l M d l f C ti d S i

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    53/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-53

    Bequests and savingWhat effect does a bequest motive (a desire to leave an

    inheritance) have on saving?Simply consume less and save more than without a bequest

    motive

    Ricardian equivalence

    We can use the two-period model to examine Ricardianequivalence

    The two-period model shows that consumption is changedonly if the PVLRchanges

    Suppose the government reduces taxes by 100 in the current

    period, the interest rate is 10%, and taxes will be increased by110 in the future period

    Then the PVLRis unchanged, and thus there is no change inconsumption

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    54/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-54

    Excess sensitivity and borrowing constraintsGenerally, theories about consumption, including the

    permanent income theory, have been supported bylooking at real-world dataBut some researchers have found that the data show

    that the impact of an income or wealth change isdifferent than that implied by a change in the PVLRThere seems to be excess sensitivity of consumption to

    changes in current incomeThis could be due to short-sighted behavior

    Or it could be due to borrowing constraintsBorrowing constraints mean people cant borrow as

    much as they want. Lenders may worry that a consumerwont pay back the loan, so they won't lend

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    55/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-55

    If a person wouldnt borrow anyway, the

    borrowing constraint is said to be nonbindingBut if a person wants to borrow and cant,

    the borrowing constraint is bindingA consumer with a binding borrowing constraint

    spends all income and wealth on consumptionSo an increase in income or wealth will be entirely

    spent on consumptionThis causes consumption to be excessively

    sensitive to current income changesHow prevalent are borrowing constraints?

    Perhaps 20% to 50% of the U.S. populationfaces binding borrowing constraints

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    56/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-56

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    The Real Interest Rate and theConsumption-Saving Decision

    The real interest rate and the budget line(Fig. 4.A.6)When the real interest rate rises, one point

    on the old budget line is also on the newbudget line: the no-borrowing, no-lending

    pointSlope of new budget line is steeper

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    57/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-57

    The substitution effect

    A higher real interest rate makes future consumptioncheaper relative to current consumption

    Increasing future consumption and reducing currentconsumption increases saving

    Suppose a person is at the no-borrowing, no-lending pointwhen the real interest rate rises (Fig. 4.A.7)

    An increase in the real interest rate unambiguouslyleads the person to increase future consumptionand decrease current consumption

    The increase in saving, equal to the decrease incurrent consumption, represents the substitutioneffect

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Figure 4 A 6 The effect of an increase in

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    58/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-58

    Figure 4.A.6 The effect of an increase inthe real interest rate on the budget line

    Figure 4 A 7 The substitution effect of an

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    59/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-59

    Figure 4.A.7 The substitution effect of anincrease in the real interest rate

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    60/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-60

    The income effectIf a person is planning to consume at the no-borrowing, no-lending point, then a rise in thereal interest rate leads just to a substitution

    effectBut if a person is planning to consume at a

    different point than the no-borrowing, no-lending point, there is also an income effect

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    61/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-61

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    The intuition of the income effect

    If the person originally planned to be a lender, therise in the real interest rate gives the person moreincome in the future period; the income effectworks in the opposite direction of the substitution

    effect, since more future income increases currentconsumption

    If the person originally planned to be a borrower,the rise in the real interest rate gives the person

    less income in the future period; the income effectworks in the same direction as the substitutioneffect, since less future income reduces currentconsumption further

    Appendix 4 A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    62/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-62

    The income and substitution effects together

    Split the change in the budget line into two parts(Fig. 4.A.8)A budget line with the same slope as the new budget

    line, but going through the original consumption point(BLint)

    The substitution effect is shown by the change frombudget line BL1 to budget line BLint, with theconsumption point changing from point D to point P

    The income effect is shown by the change from

    budget line BLint to budget line BL2, with consumptionpoint changing from point Pto point Q

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    63/64

    Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 4-63

    Appendix 4.A: A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

    The substitution effect decreases current

    consumption, but the income effect increases currentconsumption; so saving may increase or decrease

    Both effects increase future consumption

    For a borrower, both effects decrease current

    consumption, so saving definitely increases but theeffect on future consumption is ambiguous

    The effect on aggregate saving of a rise in the realinterest rate is ambiguous theoretically

    Empirical research suggests that savingincreases

    But the effect is small

    Figure 4 A 8 An increase in the real interest rate with

  • 8/2/2019 CH04 Consumption and Saving

    64/64

    Figure 4.A.8 An increase in the real interest rate withboth an income effect and a substitution effect