Breen Cooke

download Breen Cooke

of 39

Transcript of Breen Cooke

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    1/39

    The Persistence of the Gendered Division of Domestic Labour

    Richard Breen Lynn Prince Cooke Nuffield College Nuffield College

    Oxford OX1 1NF, UK Oxford OX1 1NF, UK

    +44 (0) 1865 278 538 phone +44 (0) 1865 280 370 phone

    +44 (0) 1865 278 621 fax

    [email protected] [email protected]

    Total word count (excluding this page): 9,385

    December 2004

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    2/39

    1

    The Persistence of the Gendered Division of Domestic Labour

    Abstract

    Why has the gendered division of domestic labour proved so resistant to change

    despite the growth in married womens labour force participation? We develop a

    game theoretic model of marriage to show that womens individual levels of relative

    economic autonomy are not in themselves sufficient to bring about an aggregate shift

    in the division of domestic labour. Using data for 22 countries from the 1994

    International Social Survey Programme, we show that what is required is that there

    be a greater proportion of economically autonomous women within the society as a

    whole, together with a sufficiently large proportion of men who, if faced with an

    economically autonomous woman, would rather participate in domestic tasks than

    endure marital breakdown. These results suggest that until we see greater gender

    material equality for the majority of women in a society and an evolution in mens

    gender ideology, the gendered division of domestic labour will persist.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    3/39

    2

    The Persistence of the Gendered Division of Domestic Labour

    Introduction

    Womens increasing labour force participation was expected to lead to a

    revolution in the gendered division of labour under which men are breadwinners and

    women spend their time in unpaid domestic activities, depending on their husband

    for economic support. Social exchange, bargaining and contract models predicted

    that womens greater labour force participation would enable them to negotiate more

    equal sharing of unpaid work (Blau, 1960; Blood and Wolfe, 1960; England and

    Farkas, 1986). The revolution in the gendered division of labour, however, stalled at

    the door of most households (Hochschild, 1989): while womens labour force

    participation continues to rise across countries, the increase in mens share of

    domestic work and childcare has been modest, remaining about one third of the time

    contribution of women (Blossfeld and Drobnic, 2001; Gershuny, 2000).

    Berk (1985) suggests that the persistence of womens responsibility for the

    domestic sphere arises because couples do gender. Couples do gender to

    legitimate social arrangements based on gender category (West and Zimmerman,

    1987). Hochschild (1989) argues that where mens beliefs about relative gender

    power are threatened by wives earning power, couples seek a balance by having the

    breadwinning wife do more domestic tasks regardless of the logic of the

    pocketbook. Empirical support for this conjecture has been found in the United

    States (Brines, 1994) and Australia (Bittman et al., 2003): as wives become the

    primary breadwinners, they do more of the domestic tasks to reinforce traditional

    gender identities.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    4/39

    3

    The division of labour is part of the on-going negotiation process of marriage

    and can affect marital outcomes. Some models of the family contend that increases

    in womens labour force participation result in greater marital instability because of

    womens decreasing need for mens economic production (Becker, 1981, 1985) or

    increasing competition for occupational status (Parsons, 1953). Empirical evidence

    of the direct relationship between womens employment and marital instability,

    however, is mixed (Brines and Joyner, 1999; Bumpass, Martin, and Sweet, 1991;

    Hoffman and Duncan, 1995; Ruggles, 1997; South, 2001), or effects are contingent

    on other factors (Aberg, 2003; Schoen et al., 2002; South and Lloyd, 1995).

    In contrast, Oppenheimer (1988, 1997) argues that womens employment is

    now desirable for family economic flexibility. Sweeney (2002) found evidence that

    employed women in the U.S. are more likely to marry than unemployed women.

    Similarly, Moffitt (2000) reports that U.S. marriage rates have been declining at a

    faster rate among the least-educated women. In contrast, the greater income

    associated with more highly-educated, dual-career couples appears to off-set any

    negative effects of more educated womens economic independence (Moffitt, 2000).

    An oversight in these analyses of the effects of the changing division of paid

    labour on marriage is that none of them controls for possible effects of shifts in the

    division of unpaid, domestic labour. More than two decades ago, Huber and Spitze

    (1980) found that employed wives thoughts of divorce decrease with husbands

    increasing housework contribution. More recent evidence reveals that husbands

    greater domestic contribution increases the likelihood of second births in Germany

    (Cooke, 2004) and Hungary and Sweden (Olh, 2003). Yet if husbands greater

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    5/39

    4

    domestic participation is beneficial for family outcomes, the question remains of why

    we do not see a greater shift in the division of domestic labour.

    In this paper we use game theory to model the conditions under which the

    aggregate gendered division of domestic labour is expected to change through a

    process of marriage selection and differential marital stability. To the best of our

    knowledge this is the first sociological application of game theory to family

    bargaining, although several economists have applied it in this way (Chen and

    Wooley, 2001; Lundberg and Pollak, 1993, 1994; Manser and Brown, 1980;

    McElroy and Horney, 1981). While most of the paper is devoted to development of

    the model, we also include a preliminary empirical test of it using data from the 1994

    International Social Survey Programme.

    Game Theory and the Family

    Although applications of formal game theory to the family are absent from

    sociology, there is a sociological tradition of viewing family outcomes as a function

    of relative bargaining power. Relative bargaining power is determined by resources

    that individuals can call upon within marriage and the attractiveness of possible

    alternatives to the marriage. Economic resources are a primary source of bargaining

    power (Blood and Wolfe, 1960; Weber, 1958), so the gendered division of labour

    reinforces superior male bargaining power within the family (England, 1993).

    Because of persistent gender wage differentials (Blau and Kahn, 1996; Blau et al.,

    2002), mens relative economic strength is likely to be maintained even when women

    are employed. Confining womens activities to the sphere of the home also reduces

    their bargaining strength because it increases their investment in marriage-specific

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    6/39

    5

    capital, such as children, that is not readily transportable to a new relationship

    (England and Farkas, 1986; England and Kilbourne, 1990). Consequently, the more

    extreme the gendered division of labour, the more important maintaining the

    marriage is for women than men. This enables men to negotiate solutions more

    favorable to themselves in terms of family expenditures, leisure time, and their

    assistance with the amount or type of domestic tasks (Blau et al., 2002).

    Game theory makes explicit the interdependency of the players in negotiating

    the division of labour. Each player has a set of possible strategies, the payoffs to

    which depend on the actions taken by all players. The first economic applications of

    game theory to the family modeled marriage as a cooperative game in which binding,

    costlessly enforceable agreements are possible (Manser and Brown, 1980; McElroy

    and Horney, 1981). In these models the threat point is divorce and it is assumed that

    an individuals threat point can change as exogenous factors change (Manser and

    Brown, 1980). The family instability resulting from womens labour force

    participation predicted by the neoclassical economic and functionalist sociological

    models is one solution within this game: as womens economic independence

    increases, they are more likely to quit a marriage. Yet this quit only occurs if a

    woman is unable to negotiate her own personal best outcome in the family, a process

    not modeled within the neoclassical and functionalist theories.

    Lundberg and Pollak (1993, 1994) argue that, because there are mutual

    benefits, such as shared living economies and enjoyment of children, the threat point

    in non-cooperative games is not divorce but a reversion to traditional gender roles.

    Men will focus on the breadwinner role, while women will assume responsibility for

    the domestic sphere. Without help from her partner, however, this results in an

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    7/39

    6

    under-production of the family goodeither children or a well-maintained home

    since women will only take on what they can manage on their own (Lundberg and

    Pollak, 1993). This non-cooperative model accounts for the observed decline in

    hours spent in housework (Gershuny, 2000) and in fertility as women increase their

    labour force participation (see Lehrer and Nerlove, 1986 for a review).

    Applications of game theory to the family have for the most part been

    theoretical. Empirical tests have assessed the effect of laws (Gray, 1998) or policies

    (Phipps and Burton, 1995) on womens labour force participation, and the effect of

    transfers on family expenditures (Lundberg et al., 1997). None of these models or

    evidence sheds light on why the gendered division of domestic labour is so resistant

    to change as womens labour force participation increases over time. To do so, we

    apply game theory to the consequences of partner selection for marital decision-

    making.

    Courtship and the Marriage Game

    The marriage market requires decision-making under uncertainty (Beckeret

    al., 1977). The greater diversity of possible female (and to a lesser extent, male)

    roles has increased the uncertainty, and new characteristics of men and women

    become important in determining the quality of a marriage. Until World War II, the

    gendered division of labour was the norm, although at best it was an ideal applicable

    to white, middle-class households during specific historical periods. Married black

    women in the United States and working class women more generally have

    historically had high labour force participation rates (Blau et al., 2002; Goldin,

    1990). But these transgressions from the norm did not alter widely held beliefs about

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    8/39

    7

    mens and womens ideal-typical roles. Under the male breadwinner norm a mans

    potential earnings were a primary consideration in a womans marriage decision.

    There is evidence that the rise in wages following World War II induced

    more middle-class married women to enter the labour market, but subsequent

    generations of women increasingly expect to work as a matter of right (Goldin,

    1990). Oppenheimer (1988, 1997) argues that as mens employment has become

    more precarious, the desirability of female employment increases. The increasing

    desirability of womens employment should in turn increase the likelihood that men

    assume more domestic tasks to facilitate this employment, and that women prefer

    men who do. Thus, mens willingness to participate in domestic tasks becomes a

    new aspect that needs to be ascertained prior to committing to a marriage. Not only

    is this information important to women intending to work throughout marriage and

    desiring more egalitarian marital roles, but it now also needs to be explicit among

    those women and men desiring the traditional gendered division of labour.

    We model this uncertainty by assuming that there are three types of men and

    of women, defined by their preferences over outcomes shaped by the actions taken

    by each in determining the domestic division of labour. The assumption of three

    types is surely a simplification, but it accords with Hochschilds (1989) qualitative

    groupings and womens relative distribution of preferences for paid versus domestic

    work suggested by Hakim (2000). A players type is private information: each

    player knows his or her own type and also the distribution in the population of types

    of the other gender, but needs to rely on information provided by the potential

    partner to determine that persons type. This greater uncertainty means that there is

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    9/39

    8

    more information to be gleaned during the courtship process, but in the game that we

    present it is only aftermarriage that a partners true type is revealed.

    Figure 1 illustrates the extended form of the game, which shows the choices

    facing each player at each move of the game (represented by squares) and the

    outcomes of their actions (represented by nodes). Each outcome has a perceived

    payoff for the woman and the man. The woman makes the initial decision of whether

    to marry (Yes) or not (No). If the woman chooses not to marry she receives payoff

    S, for remaining single, and the man receives payoff B, for remaining a bachelor. If

    she marries, it is then the husbands move, in that he can participate in domestic tasks

    (cooperate), in which case the couple receives the payoff (C,C), or he chooses not to

    participate (defect). If the husband defects, then the woman must decide whether to

    remain in the marriage (Remain) and accept payoff R, or Divorce and receive payoff

    D. The husbands payoffs here are M and P, respectively.

    [Figure 1 about here]

    The game is an extension of the trust game (e.g. Gibbons, 1997) in which

    women take the role of truster. This reflects the fact that women still retain the

    primary responsibility for childcare and domestic work in marriage if the man

    decides not to participate. In other words, marriage requires that the woman trusts her

    husband to cooperate and this, in turn, gives him (the trustee) the option to defect.

    Types differ in their ranking of the payoffs. Female types differ in the

    relative traditionalism of their gender ideology and their ability to be economically

    autonomous. Economic autonomy is shaped by policies affecting womens access to

    education and employment, her relative earnings within waged work, public and

    private transfers in the event of divorce, and other policies that affect womens

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    10/39

    9

    ability to establish autonomous households (Orloff, 1993). Because of mens

    historical high level of labour market participation, their types differ mainly in

    gender ideology, although they are also responsive to variations in the costs of

    divorce, as shown by Nixons (1997) evidence for the United States that stronger

    child support enforcement reduces the incidence of marital breakup.

    The first type of woman, Traditional, has the most traditional gender

    ideology and would expect to assume the majority of domestic tasks even under

    those economic circumstances when she might have to work. She has not invested

    heavily in human capital and thus has poor economic alternatives to marriage. Her

    payoffs are ranked C>R>S>D: that is, she prefers to remain married to being

    divorced or to not marrying regardless of her husbands participation in domestic

    tasks.1

    The second type of woman, Transitional, has payoffs ordered C>S>R>D. She

    has an alternative to marriage but has no outside option once in one. The typical

    example of the Transitionaltype, represented by the majority of women since World

    War II, is someone who works full-time when single, but after marriage stays at

    home with pre-school children, returning to employment, often on a part-time basis,

    as the children grow up (Blau et al., 2002; England and Farkas, 1986; Hakim, 2000).

    Part-time employment allows a woman to balance family and economic demands

    (Blossfeld and Hakim, 1997; Hakim, 2000), but this entails lower investment in

    human capital, leaving a woman economically vulnerable in the event of a divorce.

    Consequently, once married, if she is employed, she will work the double-shift of

    paid and unpaid labour if her husband chooses not to participate because the

    alternative of divorce is not economically feasible.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    11/39

    10

    The third type of woman,Autonomous, has payoffs ranked C>S>D>R. She

    has both an alternative to marriage and viable outside options after she marries. She

    has the most egalitarian gender ideology and either a career or access to other means

    of support that minimize the importance of her partners relative earnings. In

    economic termsAutonomous women have the greatest bargaining power among the

    three types of women.

    Considered as players in an extended trust game, Traditionalwomen must

    always trust; Transitionalwomen have the option of not trusting; andAutonomous

    women have both this option and an outside option, which can force two of the three

    male types discussed below to honour her trust.

    The three male types are as follows.Hardliners have preferences ordered

    M>B>P>C. They would prefer to see their marriage end in divorce or separation

    rather than contribute in any substantive way to domestic work and childcare,

    although they prefer not to marry than to marry and separate. They prefer the

    traditional division of labour in terms of their own role as sole breadwinner and will

    not alter their behaviour even if their female partners find it necessary to work.

    Adjusterspreferences are ordered M>C>B>P. They prefer not to do unpaid

    domestic work but would rather do so than lose the marital family through divorce.

    Thus they will contribute to domestic tasks if the womans outside alternatives to

    marriage are sufficiently attractive to threaten divorce. But, as withHardliners, they

    prefer not to marry than to marry and ultimately divorce. The third male type,

    Cooperator, is comprised of that small proportion whom Hochschild (1989) found

    willingly participate fully in unpaid domestic tasks; their preferences are C>M>B>P.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    12/39

    11

    Given the three types of each gender, if couples knew each others type

    before marrying, there would be nine possible subgame perfect equilibria of the

    game (shown in Table 1). Traditionalwomen would always marry and remain

    married regardless of the mans type; Transitionalwomen would marry

    Cooperators, but decline to marryHardliners orAdjusters because both these types

    of men defect when paired with a Transitionalwoman; andAutonomous women

    have sufficient bargaining power to have cooperative marriages with eitherAdjusters

    orCooperators and would never marry aHardliner, because no matter who a

    Hardlinermarries, he will always defect.

    [Table 1 about here]

    Under these subgame perfect equilibria, becauseAutonomous women always

    enjoy marriages in which the husband cooperates, an increase in the proportion of

    women of this type should lead to an increase in the proportion of all marriages that

    are cooperative. This is what the bargaining models predict because they implicitly

    assume womens greater economic autonomy results in mens greater participation in

    domestic tasks. As the proportion of employed married women continues to

    increase, male Cooperators,being preferred by both Transitionaland Autonomous

    women, would be more likely to marry than any other type. As noted by Hochschild

    (1989), the first child creates a crisis in the division of domestic labour, so it could be

    expected that TransitionalandAutonomous women married to Cooperators would

    be willing to have more children. If we were to assume that a mans type is inherited

    or modeled by his male children (see Chodorow, 1978 or Cunningham, 2001), then

    the proportion ofCooperators should be steadily increasing over generations as all

    female types would marry and have more children with such men, assuming no other

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    13/39

    12

    differences in fertility among the different pairings. Recent evidence from several

    countries suggests that mens greater participation in domestic tasks increases the

    likelihood of higher parity births (Cooke, 2004; Olh, 2003). In contrast, as women

    gain more economic autonomy and more non-traditional gender ideology, marital

    probabilities are lower in pairings with the first two types of men:Hardliners would

    marry only Traditionalwomen, who, as Hakim (2000) reports, are only a small

    proportion of women in modern industrialized societies, andAdjusters would marry

    only TraditionalandAutonomous women.

    These outcomes can only occur, however, if there is complete information

    about each partners type during courtship. The assumption of complete information

    also rules out any possibility of divorce (shown by the absence of any equilibria in

    which the womans second move is Quit in response to a mans move of Defect)

    because women and men would know which pairings led to divorce and so avoid

    them. Consequently, it is more plausible to proceed under the supposition that

    information about the other is incomplete at the time of marriage. Thus, the

    equilibrium outcomes of the game with incomplete information will depend on the

    players mutual beliefs about the others type and the actions they take in the light of

    these.

    One might argue that couples can discern their partners true type during

    courtship, but evidence suggests that considerations of social desirability lead people

    to claim a more non-traditional gender ideology that does not translate into more

    non-traditional behaviour once married (Press and Townsley, 1998).2 In addition,

    Hochschild (1989) noted that the crisis in the family division of labour occurs after

    the birth of the first child, regardless of what each partner believed about the extent

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    14/39

    13

    of the others egalitarian gender ideology beforehand. Cohabitation also does not

    appear to provide reliable information as to true types: evidence suggests that the

    division of domestic tasks is different among cohabitors than among married couples

    (Brines and Joyner, 1999), and that persons who cohabit prior to marriage are more

    likely to divorce (Berrington and Diamond, 1999; Lillard et al., 1995; Santow and

    Bracher, 1994). Consequently, the model we develop assumes that neither men nor

    women know the true type of the person they are playing against at the time of the

    decision to marry. 3

    The distribution of male types,Hardliner, Adjusterand Cooperator, in the

    population is indexed by 1, 2, 3 and female types (Traditional, Transitionaland

    Autonomous) by 1, 2, 3. These distributions, and, are known to individuals

    because they reflect the normative gender role behaviours within the culture,

    reinforced through media representations and the shared experiences of others.

    Consequently, when a woman meets a man, she assigns an initial probability of

    1that he is aHardliner, 2 that he is anAdjusterand 3 (=112) that he is a

    Cooperator. The man similarly assigns initial probabilities 1, 2, 3 as to which type

    of woman he is facing.

    To find the games equilibria we make two assumptions: the first is that the

    probability of a Transitionalwoman marrying is never greater than the probability

    for anAutonomous woman. A Transitionalwoman will prefer to marry (play Yes

    rather than No) given thatAdjustermen Cooperate rather than Defect, and that the

    expected payoff from Yes exceeds the payoff from No: that is,

    SCR >++ )( 321 . (1a)

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    15/39

    14

    Likewise, anAutonomous woman will prefer Yes to No given thatAdjustermen

    Cooperate rather than Defect and that

    SCD >++ )( 321 . (1b)

    So our first assumption could be interpreted as saying that the payoff to an

    Autonomous woman from divorce is as big or bigger than the payoff to a

    Transitionalwoman from remaining in an uncooperative marriage, given that all

    other payoffs do not differ between them.

    The second assumption is that, as reported by Hochschild (1989), the

    proportion ofCooperatormen is sufficiently small so that neitherTransitionalnor

    Autonomous women will marry if noAdjustermen will cooperate. The assumption is

    that the equivalent conditions to 1a and 1b that arise when allAdjusters defect are

    never met. For example, forAutonomous women this means that the expected payoff

    to Yes when anAdjusterdefects is less than the payoff to No:

    SCD .

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    16/39

    15

    The actions ofTransitionalandAutonomous women will depend upon the

    actions of the maleAdjusters and their share in the male population, while the actions

    ofAdjusters depend on the proportion ofAutonomous women and on the actions of

    Autonomous and Transitionalwomen. AnAdjusterwill prefer to cooperate when

    faced with anAutonomous woman but defect when faced by any other female type,

    but his beliefs about the distribution of possible types he is facing will depend on the

    initial belief distribution, , and on the actions taken by women, in the light of which

    he updates his beliefs using Bayess rule. These updated beliefs concern the

    probability distribution of female types who have played Yes in other words, the

    distribution of possible types a man has married (we denote this distribution Y).

    AnAdjusterwill cooperate ifY3 is sufficiently large and defect otherwise.

    But given that, in equilibrium, men know the actions taken by all types of woman, Y

    is wholly determined by the initial distribution, . In particular, Y

    3 > 3 when

    Autonomous women marry but Transitionals do not; Y3 = 3 when both marry; and

    Y3 =0 when neither marry. Thus when onlyAutonomous (and Traditional) women

    marry, anAdjusterwill prefer to cooperate if ~

    3 . If all women marry he will

    prefer to cooperate if 3 . If only Traditionalwomen marry thenAdjustermen

    will always defect. The two threshold beliefs forAdjusters are thus~

    , the minimum

    proportion ofAutonomous women in the population sufficient to makeAdjustermen

    cooperate when onlyAutonomous (and Traditional) women marry; and , the

    minimum proportion ofAutonomous women in the population sufficient to make

    Adjustermen cooperate whenAutonomous and Transitional(and Traditional)

    women marry. It follows that ~ > .

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    17/39

    16

    The resulting equilibria of the marriage game are shown in Figure 2. Which

    equilibria can be reached depends on the initial distributions ofAdjustermen and

    Autonomous women.

    (1) For all combinations of and there is an equilibrium in which only

    Traditionalwomen will marry andAdjustermen will defect (this is the N,N;d

    equilibrium shown in Figure 2).

    (2) Given a share ofAdjustermen,TA

    222

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    18/39

    17

    ofAutonomous women for which anAdjusteris indifferent between cooperating and

    defecting, and, given an initial belief ~

    3

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    19/39

    18

    An increasing proportion of Autonomous women will be associated withgreater male participation in domestic tasks only given a sufficiently large

    proportion of Adjuster men. This implies a significant interaction effectbetween the proportion of Autonomous women and the proportion of Adjuster

    men in a society.

    This hypothesis will be tested using data from the 1994 International Social

    Survey Programme (ISSP).4

    Data and Measures

    We use data from the module on Family and Changing Gender Roles that

    was fielded in the 1994 ISSP.5 Because our hypothesis concerns observed country

    differences in the division of domestic tasks, the individual data reported by married

    or cohabiting6

    women and men in each of 22 countries are used to construct national

    aggregated measures. A scale of who in the household is responsible for domestic

    tasks is regressed on the distribution of gender types within the country using

    ordinary least squares regression.

    Dependent Variable: A Scale of Domestic Responsibility

    The scale measuring couples relative responsibility for domestic tasks is

    derived from questions on who is normally responsible for: 1) caring for the sick, 2)

    doing laundry, 3) doing the grocery shopping, 4) deciding what to have for dinner,

    and 5) doing small repairs (reverse coded). In a traditional division of domestic

    labour, the women would always do the first four tasks and the man would always do

    small repairs.7

    Factor analysis (results available from authors) reveals high loadings

    on a single factor for all but the fifth item. Consequently, the domestic responsibility

    scale is created by summing responses across the four dominantly female tasks and

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    20/39

    19

    dividing by four, resulting in a scale ranging from 1, a traditional division of unpaid

    labour where the woman is always responsible for the tasks, to 5, a non-traditional

    division where the man is always responsible. Cronbachs (1951) alpha is between

    0.50 and 0.59 in Bulgaria, East Germany, Hungary, Israel, Russia and Slovenia;

    between 0.60 and 0.69 in Austria, the Czech Republic, Italy, Japan, Norway, Poland,

    Sweden and West Germany; and 0.70 and above in Australia, Canada, Great Britain,

    Ireland and Northern Ireland, the Netherlands, New Zealand and the United States.

    Womens rather than mens, reports of the division of domestic responsibility are

    used because they have been found to be more accurate given that women tend to

    perform most of the tasks (Berk and Shih, 1980; Press and Townsley, 1998).

    Independent Variables

    The ISSP survey contains numerous questions on gender and family attitudes

    with which to construct female and male types based on ideology (see Table 2). We

    first attempted to construct a factor score for gender types, but the same questions did

    not always load on the same factors across the countries. Further, as argued in detail

    by Braun et al. (1994), the interpretation of individual questions pertaining to

    children also varies across cultural contexts. One question, however, assesses the

    extent to which respondents support a normative notion of a gendered division of

    labour: A mans job is to earn money; a womans job is to look after the home and

    family. Possible responses are on a five-point Likert scale, ranging from 1, strongly

    agree, reflecting the most traditional gender ideology, to 5, strongly disagree.

    [Table 2 about here]

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    21/39

    20

    We categorize individuals based on their responses to this question.

    Hardlinermen and Traditionalwomen either agree or strongly agree with the

    statement;Adjustermen and Transitionalwomen are either neutral or somewhat

    disagree; andAutonomous women and Cooperatormen strongly disagree with the

    statement. The grouping of disagreement with traditional norms together with neutral

    responses reflects that reported attitudes might shift ahead of behaviour (Press and

    Townsley, 1998). An interaction term is computed by multiplying the percentage of

    Autonomous women in a country by the percentage ofAdjustermen. This

    interaction is expected to predict the greatest shift in the division of domestic

    responsibility.

    The marriage game dynamics are predicted to hold across capitalist countries,

    but there is ambiguity as to whether they hold within transitional economies. In

    formerly state socialist economies all adults were expected to be part of the labour

    force, yet the wage structure was such that it is doubtful whether either gender could

    be economically autonomous. This could affect marital bargaining and so we include

    a control variable for formerly state socialist countries.

    Results

    The distribution of gender types by country is presented in Table 3. On

    average, in each country a third of men areHardliners, less than a third of women

    are Traditional; roughly half areAdjustermen orTransitionalwomen; and the mean

    percentage ofCooperatormen is just 17 percent, similar to Hochschilds (1989)

    estimate based on her qualitative data. The mean proportion ofAutonomous women

    is one-quarter.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    22/39

    21

    [Table 3 about here]

    Regression results are presented in Table 4. The top panel presents results of

    the tests of our hypothesis; the bottom panel presents the same analyses but replacing

    Adjusters with Cooperatormen. According to our model, the size of this group

    should be unrelated to the distribution of the division of domestic responsibility. The

    first model predicts womens reports of the division of domestic labour as a function

    of the control variable for former state socialist economies and the percentage of

    Autonomous women. It explains very little variance in the reported division of

    domestic tasks and the coefficient for the percentage ofAutonomous women, while

    statistically significant, is substantively quite small, with a single percentage point

    change predicting just a 0.01 shift along the five-point scale of domestic

    responsibility.

    The second model in the top panel includes the percentage ofAdjustermen

    and explains substantially more variation in mens domestic responsibility. As

    expected, increases in both the percentage ofAutonomous women and ofAdjuster

    men are associated with a more equal division of domestic work, though the

    coefficient for the former is now even smaller and does not reach statistical

    significance.

    [Table 4 about here]

    The interaction term ofAdjuster*Autonomous in the third model in the top

    half of the table predicts a significant shift in the division of domestic responsibility,

    providing clear support for our hypothesis. Furthermore, once the interaction term is

    included, the main effect of the percentage ofAutonomous women becomes

    significantly negative. The results imply that if the share ofAdjustermen is greater

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    23/39

    22

    than about 47 percent (slightly below the mean for our sample), an increase in the

    percentage ofAutonomous women will lead to a more egalitarian domestic division

    of labour, but below this threshold an increase in the percentage ofAutonomous

    women results in a reporting of a more traditional division of domestic labour. By

    contrast, the models reported in the lower part of Table 4, in which the share of

    Cooperatormen is used in place of the share ofAdjusters, fare very poorly, with

    none of the explanatory variables reaching statistical significance.

    Conclusion

    We have proposed a game theoretic model of marriage to explain the slow

    observed reduction in the gendered division of domestic labour despite womens

    rising labour force participation. As argued by Oppenheimer (1988, 1997), gender

    specialization is no longer an optimal family strategy in an era of flexible labour

    markets. As a result, employment, not domesticity, is an increasingly desired female

    attribute in the marriage market (Sweeney, 2002). But the shift away from a rigid

    gendered division of labour adds additional uncertainty into the marriage market

    because women and men no longer possess common knowledge about expected roles

    in marriage. We capture this new uncertainty in the marriage game by mens and

    womens lack of knowledge about the type of partner they are facing during

    courtship.

    Under the resulting model, the proportion of marriages in which men

    contribute to domestic work may increase as the proportion ofAutonomous women

    increases, but this effect is contingent on the share of maleAdjusters in the

    population. Thus, to realize an aggregate change in the division of domestic labour,

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    24/39

    23

    both a greater proportion of women within a society must beAutonomous so that

    they can credibly threaten divorce in the face of a non-cooperating man, and a greater

    proportion of men must have a sufficiently non-traditional gender ideology to prefer

    domestic participation over divorce.

    We have not investigated the mechanisms by which the distributions of types

    of men and women in a country change, or whether individuals change their type

    during their lifetime, although these are both areas worthy of future investigation. It

    is reasonable to assume that an increase inAutonomous women is driven by

    exogenous processes that will be reflected in their gender ideology. This is evident

    here in that women in all countries, on average, report more non-traditional gender

    attitudes than men. But possible mechanisms for change among men is less obvious,

    particularly since the opportunities and constraints on mens labour force

    participation have changed much less than those on womens. Bianchi and her

    colleagues (2000) found that womens declining time contribution to domestic tasks

    since the 1960s was in large part due to compositional changes brought on by

    employment outside the home, delayed marriage and reduced fertility. In contrast,

    only a small proportion of mens modest increase in domestic time contribution can

    be attributed to similar factors.

    Future research might also explore under what circumstances Lundberg and

    Pollaks (1993) assertion holds regarding reduced fertility as the initial threat point in

    family bargaining. It is possible that policy shapes whether divorce or fertility is the

    viable threat point for women. When faced with a non-cooperating partner, women

    in countries with strong policy support for the male breadwinner model can only

    reduce fertility within marriage, compared with women in countries with better

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    25/39

    24

    access to market or state resources that enable greater economic autonomy and give

    credibility to a threat of divorce. Analyzing these dynamics requires having panel

    data for a wide range of countries representing a range of policy contexts.

    Appendix

    Here we discuss other equilibria that arise when some degree of separation of

    signals of type is possible. We assume that men and women try to signal their type

    (truthfully or not) to their potential partner before the marriage game begins and we

    model their attempts to do so by simultaneous signaling, after which they update

    their beliefs and the woman then makes the decision of whether to marry or not.

    Which types have an incentive to signal falsely? Among men, Cooperators

    have no such incentive. They have a dominant strategy of always cooperating in the

    marriage game and so women of all three types would play Yes when faced with a

    Cooperator.Adjusters always have an incentive to try to appear to be Cooperators

    because this will induce Transitionalwomen (who would not knowingly marry an

    Adjuster) to marry them.Hardliners will have an incentive to pose as Cooperators

    (though not asAdjusters) under certain conditions. They always defect, and this will

    yield them their most-preferred outcome ifTraditionalorTransitionalwomen play

    Yes, but, when faced with anAutonomous woman, they would do better if she played

    No. TransitionalandAutonomous women will not marry aHardlinerbut will marry

    a Cooperator, and so aHardlinershould signal that he is a Cooperatorif

    BM

    PB

    >

    )(32

    In words, he should signal that he is a Cooperatorprovided that the share of

    Transitionalwomen is large enough to induce him to take the risk of sending the

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    26/39

    25

    wrong signal to anAutonomous woman. Among women, Transitionals have an

    incentive to appear to beAutonomous, since this would yield them cooperative

    marriages withAdjustermen (which they otherwise would not have). Traditional

    women also have an incentive to signal that they areAutonomous for the same

    reason, provided that we take their payoffs as C>R>S>D. However if, as noted in an

    earlier footnote, their payoffs were R>C>S>D then they would have no such

    incentive.

    Fortunately, whether or not Traditionalwomen andHardlinermen signal

    that they are, respectively,Autonomous and Cooperators, makes no difference to the

    qualitative features of the equilibria of the marriage game. If men can discern

    Traditionalwomen and women can spotHardlinermen, this simply shifts downward

    the threshold initial beliefs shown in Figure 2 which determine the actions of the

    other four types. Since beliefs are updated after signaling using Bayess rule, a signal

    that distinguishes Traditionalwomen (but not the other types) will lead a man to the

    belief that the non-Traditionalwoman he is facing isAutonomous with probability

    3/(2+3), compared with 3 in the absence of signaling. Likewise, a womans belief

    about the probability that she is facing anAdjusterwill be higher than her initial

    belief if, after signaling, she knows for certain that she is not facing aHardliner.8

    The upshot of this is that the thresholds shown in Figure 2 can be reached with lower

    initial beliefs, 2 and 3.

    In the text we showed the equilibria of the game under two assumptions

    about signaling: mutual separation (MS) in which everyone knows the type of the

    person they face (the results of which are shown in Table 1) and mutual pooling

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    27/39

    26

    (MP) in which there are no reliable signals of type. Now we turn to equilibria of the

    game under two other assumptions about signaling.

    (i) Male Pooling Female Separating (MPFS). Here the man knows the womans type

    but not vice versa (with the possible exception thatHardlinermen can be identified).

    In this case, a Transitionalwoman will always play No and anAutonomous woman

    will play Yes ifA

    22 . So in this case there are two equilibria: in one (which

    holds for any values ofand) only Traditionalwomen marry,Hardliners and

    Adjusters defect and Cooperators cooperate; in the other equilibrium, (which can

    occur when A22 ) TraditionalandAutonomous women marry,Hardliners

    always defect, Cooperators always cooperate andAdjusters defect or cooperate

    depending on whether they marry a Traditionalor anAutonomous woman.

    (ii) Female Pooling Male Separating (FPMS). Here the woman knows the mans type

    but not vice versa (with the possible exception that Traditionalwomen can be

    identified). The equilibria here are those shown on the top row of Figure 2. They

    depend on mens beliefs about the proportion ofAutonomous women because this

    determines the actions ofAdjustermen.

    These different signaling scenarios carry consequences for the proportion of

    cooperative marriages and the trend in the domestic division of labor that differ from

    those arising from our preferred scenario, MP. Under MPFS the proportion of

    cooperative marriages is increasing in the share ofAdjustermen, while under FPMS

    it is increasing in the share ofAutonomous women. But in our analyses we saw that

    there is a significant interaction effect between these two which is not predicted by

    either MPFS or FPMS but which does follow from MP.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    28/39

    27

    Notes

    1. A Traditionalwomans preferences might be ordered R ~C>S>D or even

    R>C>S>D inasmuch as she actively prefers to have greater responsibility for

    domestic duties as shown by Greensteins (1996) evidence that women with the most

    traditional gender ideology perform more domestic tasks regardless of their

    husbands gender ideology, and Allen and Hawkinss (1999) evidence that a

    proportion of women act as gatekeepers to their husbands involvement in domestic

    tasks.

    2. One might also argue that it is easier for men to assess a womans type since

    policies and her education and employment are known early in courtship, whereas a

    woman can only infer a mans ideology. Yet as Hakim (2000) has argued, highly

    educated women with the potential for high earnings may in fact prefer to remain at

    home. In this circumstance, the man may incorrectly conclude that a highly-

    educated woman isAutonomous when she is in fact Traditionalin her preferences.

    3. But in the appendix we investigate the equilibria of the game under the

    assumptions that one sex knows the type of members of the other.

    4. Given the multiple equilibria in some of the cells of Figure 2 it is possible that, in

    a given country, we would observe no change in the proportion of marriages in

    which men co-operate, even if the shares ofAdjusters andAutonomous women

    increased: but provided that this does not hold true of all countries, then a cross-

    sectional comparison of the type we perform here should demonstrate the

    relationships described in the hypothesis.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    29/39

    28

    5. More information on the ISSP, including codebooks, is available at

    http://www.issp.org. A module on this same topic was also fielded in the 1988 ISSP

    but it did not include questions about responsibility for domestic tasks.

    6. The ISSP does not distinguish between whether people are legally married or

    living as married.

    7. One response category was tasks done by third person, although it was unclear

    if this was hired assistance or other family members. Further, only 1 percent of

    respondents answered in this way, so this category was recoded as missing.

    8. By Bayess rule we have that the probability that the man is anAdjuster(adj for

    short) given that he does not signal that he is aHardliner(ns for short) is equal to:

    2

    32

    2

    )(~)|~()()|(

    )()|(

    >

    +=

    +

    adjpradjnspradjpradjnspr

    adjpradjnspr

    Acknowledgements

    Thanks to Hans-Peter Blossfeld, Diego Gambetta, Shelly Lundberg, Valerie Kincaid

    Oppenheimer, Daniel Verdier, participants at a seminar at the Centro de Estudios

    Avanzados en Ciencias Sociales, Instituto Juan March, Madrid on October 30, 2002,

    and, particularly, Margaret Meyer for comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    30/39

    29

    References

    Aberg, Y. (2003). Social Interactions: Studies of Contextual Effects and

    Endogenous Processes. PhD dissertation, Department of Sociology, University

    of Stockholm, Sweden.

    Allen, S. M. and Hawkins, A. J. (1999). Maternal gatekeeping: mothers beliefs and

    behaviors that inhibit greater father involvement in family work. Journal ofMarriage and the Family, 61: 199-212.

    Becker, G. S. (1985). Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor.Journal of Labor Economics, 3, Part 2: S33-S58.

    Becker, G. S. (1981). A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard

    University Press.

    Becker, G. S., Landes, E. M. and Michael, R. T. (1977). An economic analysis of

    marital instability. The Journal of Political Economy, 85, 6: 1141-1188.

    Berk, S. F. (1985). The Gender Factory: The Apportionment of Work in AmericanHouseholds. New York: Plenum Pres.

    Berk, S. F. and Shih, A. (1980). Contributions to household labor: comparing

    wives and husbands reports. In Berk, S.F. (Ed.), Women and Household Labor.Beverly Hills, California: Sage.

    Berrington, A. and Diamond, I. (1999). Marital dissolution among the 1958 British

    birth cohort: the role of cohabitation. Population Studies, 53:19-38.

    Bianchi, S. M., Milkie, M. A., Sayer, L. C. and Robinson, J. P. (2000). Is anyone

    doing the housework? trends in the gender division of household labor. SocialForces, 79, 1: 191-228.

    Bittman, M., England, P., Sayer, L. C., Folbre, N. and Matheson, G. (2003). When

    does gender trump money? bargaining and time in household work. AmericanJournal of Sociology, 109(1): 186-214.

    Blau, P. (1960). Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley andSons.

    Blau, F. D., Ferber, M. A. and Winkler, A. (2002). The Economics of Women, Men,

    and Work, Fourth Edition. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Blau, F. D. and Kahn, L. M. (1996). Wage structure and gender earningsdifferentials: an international comparison. Economica, 63, Supplement: S29-

    S62.

    Blood, R. O. and Wolfe, D. M. (1960).Husbands and Wives. New York: Free Press.

    Blossfeld, H.-P. and Hakim, C. (1997). Between Equalization and Marginalization:

    Women Working Part-Time in Europe and the United States of America. Oxford:Oxford University Press.

    Blossfeld, H.-P. and Drobnic, S. (2001).A Cross-National Comparative Approach to

    Couples Careers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Braun, M., Scott, J. and Alwin, D. F. (1994). Economic necessity or self-

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    31/39

    30

    actualization? attitudes toward womens labour-force participation in East andWest Germany. European Sociological Review, 10(1): 29-47.

    Brines, J. (1994). Economic dependency, gender and the division of labor at home.American Journal of Sociology, 100: 652-688.

    Brines, J. and Joyner, K. (1999). The ties that bind: principles of cohesion incohabitation and marriage. American Sociological Review, 64: 333-55.

    Bumpass, L. L., Martin, T. C. and Sweet, J. A. (1991). The impact of family

    background and early marital factors on marital disruption. Journal of FamilyIssues, 12: 22-42.

    Chen, Z. and Woolley, F. (2001). A Cournot-Nash model of family decisionmaking. The Economics Journal, 111: 722-748.

    Chodorow, N. (1978). The Reproduction of Mothering: Psychoanalysis and the

    Sociology of Gender. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Cooke, L. P. (2004). The gendered division of labor and family outcomes inGermany. Journal of Marriage and Family, 66: 1246-1259.

    Cronbach, L. (1951). Coefficient alpha and the internal structure of tests.Psychometrica, 16: 297-334.

    Cunningham, M. (2001). Parental influences on the gendered division of housework.

    American Sociological Review, 66: 184-203.

    England, P. (1993). The separative self: androcentric bias in neoclassical

    assumptions. In Ferber, M. A. and Nelson, J. A. (Eds),Beyond Economic Man:

    Feminist Theory and Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    England, P. and Farkas, G. (1986). Households, Employment, and Gender: A Social,

    Economic and Demographic View. New York: Aldine deGruyter.

    England, P. and Kilbourne, B. S. (1990). Markets, marriages, and other mates: the

    problem of power. In Friedland, R. and Robertson, A. F. (Eds), Beyond the

    Marketplace: Rethinking Economy and Society. New York: Aldine Publishing.

    Gershuny, J. (2000). Changing Times: Work and Leisure in Postindustrial Society.

    Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Gibbons, R. (1997). An introduction to applicable game theory. The Journal ofEconomic Perspectives , 11, 1: 127-149.

    Goldin, C. (1990). Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of

    American Women. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Gray, J. S. (1998). Divorce law changes, household bargaining, and married

    womens labor supply. The American Economic Review, 88: 628-642.

    Greenstein, T. N. (1996). Husbands participation in domestic labor: interactive

    effects on wives and husbands gender ideologies. Journal of Marriage and the

    Family, 58: 585-595.

    Hakim, C. (2000). Work-Lifestyle Choices in the 21st

    Century: Preference Theory.

    Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    32/39

    31

    Hochschild, A. (1989). The Second Shift: Working Parents and the Revolution at

    Home. London: Piatkus Ltd.

    Hoffman, S. D. and Duncan, G. J. (1995). The effect of incomes, wages, and AFDCbenefits on marital disruptions. Journal of Human Resources, 30: 19-41.

    Huber, J. and Spitze, G. (1980). Considering divorce: an expansion of Beckerstheory of marital instability. American Journal of Sociology, 86(1): 75-89.

    Lehrer, E. and Nerlove, M. (1986). Female labor force behavior and fertility in the

    United States. Annual Review of Sociology, 12: 181-204.

    Lennon, M. C. and Rosenfeld, S. (1994). Relative fairness and the division of

    housework: the importance of options. American Journal of Sociology, 100:506-531.

    Lillard, L. A., Brien, M. J. and Waite, L. J. (1995). Premarital cohabitation and

    subsequent marital dissolution: a matter of self-selection? Demography, 32:

    437-457.

    Lundberg, S. and Pollak, R. A. (1993). Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage

    market. Journal of Political Economy, 101: 988-1010.

    Lundberg, S. and Pollak, R. A. (1994). Noncooperative bargaining models of

    marriage. American Economic Review, 84: 132-137.

    Lundberg, S., Pollak, R. A. and Wales, T. J. (1997). Do husbands and wives pooltheir resources? Journal of Human Resources, 32: 463-480.

    Manser, M. and Brown, M. (1980). Marriage and household decision-making: abargaining analysis. International Economic Review, 21: 31-44.

    McElroy, M. B. and Horney, M. J. (1981). Nash-bargained household decisions:

    toward a generalization of the theory of demand. International EconomicReview, 22: 333-349.

    Moffitt, R. A. (2000). Female wages, male wages, and the economic model ofmarriage. In Waite, L. J. (Ed.), The Ties That Bind: Perspectives on Marriage

    andCohabitation. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

    Nixon, L. (1997). The effect of child support enforcement on marital dissolution.The Journal of Human Resources, 32, 1: 159-181.

    Olh, L. (2003). Gendering fertility: second births in Sweden and Hungary.

    Population Research and Policy Review, 22: 171-200.

    Oppenheimer, V. K. (1988). A theory of marriage timing. American Journal of

    Sociology, 94: 563-591.

    Oppenheimer, V. K. (1997). Womens employment and the gain to marriage: thespecialization and trading model. Annual Review of Sociology, 23: 431-453.

    Orloff, A. S. (1993). Gender and the social rights of citizenship: the comparativeanalysis of gender relations and welfare states. American Sociological Review,

    58: 303-328.

    Parsons, T. (1953). A revised analytical approach to the theory of social

    stratification. In Bendix, R. and Lipset, S. M. (Eds.), Class, Status and Power.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    33/39

    32

    New York: Free Press.

    Phipps, S. A. and Burton, P. S. (1995). Social/institutional variables and behavior

    within households: an empirical test using the Luxembourg Income Study.Feminist Economics, 1: 151-174.

    Press, J. E. and Townsley, E. (1998). Wives and husbands housework reporting:gender, class and social desirability. Gender and Society, 12, 2: 188-218.

    Ruggles, S. (1997). The rise of divorce and separation in the United States, 1880-

    1990. Demography, 34, 4: 455-466.

    Santow, G. and Bracher, M. (1994). Change and continuity in the formation of first

    marital unions in Australia. Population Studies, 48: 475-496.

    Schoen, R., Astone, N. M., Rothert, K., Standish, N. J. and Kim, Y. J. (2002).Womens employment, marital happiness, and divorce. Social Forces, 81, 2:

    643-662.

    South, S. J. (2001). Time dependent effects of wives employment on maritaldissolution. American Sociological Review, 66: 226-245.

    South, S. J. and Lloyd, K. M. (1995). Spousal alternatives and marital dissolution.American Sociological Review, 60: 21-35.

    South, S. J. and Spitze, G. (1994). Housework in marital and nonmarital households.

    American Sociological Review, 59: 327-347.

    Sweeney, M. M. (2002). Two decades of family change: the shifting economic

    foundations of marriage. American Sociological Review, 67: 132-147.

    Weber, M. (1958). From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology. New York: OxfordUniversity Press.

    West, C. and Zimmerman, D. H. (1987). Doing gender. Gender and Society, 1, 2:

    125-151.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    34/39

    33

    Figure 1

    The Marriage Game

    marry?W

    (S,B)

    H

    (C,C)

    W

    (D,P)

    (R,M)W= wife's moveH= husband's move

    Cooperate

    Defect Divorce

    No

    Yes

    Remain

    Male Types:

    1:Hardliner: M > B > P > C -- always defects

    2:Adjuster: M > C > B > P

    3: Cooperator: C > M > B > P -- always cooperates

    Female Types:

    1: Traditional: C > R > S >D -- always plays Yes; remains in marriage

    2: Transitional: C > S > R >D -- always remains in marriage

    3:Autonomous: C > S > D >R -- always plays Yes

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    35/39

    34

    Table 1

    Subgame Perfect Equilibrium, with Complete Information

    Player Movesa

    (Wifes First/Wifes Second; Husbands)

    Male types and probabilitiesFemale types and

    probabilities Hardliner1 Adjuster2 Cooperator3

    Traditional1 YS;d YS;d YS;c

    Transitional2 NS;d NS;d YS;c

    Autonomous 3 NQ;d YQ;c YQ;c

    Notation:

    Womens Possible Moves:Move 1 Move 2Y= Marry S=Stay in the marriage N= Not Marry Q=Quit the marriage

    Mens Possible Moves:d= Defect (no help)

    c=Cooperate (help)

    a. The notation includes both the expected moves and moves off the equilibrium path. For example,

    anAutonomous

    woman is not expected to marry aHardliner

    man (N). Were she to go off theequilibrium path, however, and do so, he would defect (d) and she would subsequently quit (Q)

    the marriage.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    36/39

    35

    A2 = minimum proportion ofAdjustermen in the population sufficient to make

    Autonomous women prefer to marry, when allAdjusters cooperate

    T2 = minimum proportion ofAdjustermen in the population sufficient to makeTransitionalwomen prefer to marry, when allAdjusters cooperate

    ~

    = The minimum proportion ofAutonomous women in the population sufficient

    tomakeAdjusters cooperate when just TraditionalandAutonomous women

    marry.^

    = The minimum proportion ofAutonomous women in the population sufficient

    tomakeAdjusters cooperate when all three female types marry.

    Figure 2

    Equilibria of the Marriage Game

    For Transitional and Autonomous Women and Adjuster Men

    N,N;d

    N,N,:d

    p,Y;r

    N,q:r

    N,N,d

    Y,Y;c

    N,q;r

    N,N;dN,N;d

    N,Y;c

    N,q:r

    N,N;d

    N,Y;c

    N,q;r

    N,N;d N,N;d N,N;d

    ~

    ^

    Womans

    initial belief

    about

    proportion

    of

    Adjuster

    men

    Mans initial belief

    about proportion of

    Autonomous women

    Note: The equilibria are Transitionalwomans First Move,Autonomous WomansFirst Move;AdjusterMans Move.

    The moves ofTraditionalWomen and ofHardlinerand Cooperatormen arenot reported (these are always Y, d, c, respectively).

    In the mixed strategy equilibrium, p is the probability than a Transitionalwoman plays Y, q is the probability that anAutonomous woman plays Y, and

    r is the probability than anAdjusterplays c.

    2

    2

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    37/39

    36

    Table 2

    1994 ISSP Attitude Questions Pertaining to the Gendered Division of Labour

    1. A working mother can establish just as warm and secure a relationship withher children as a mother who does not work. (R)2. A pre-school child is likely to suffer if his or her mother works.3. All in all, family life suffers when the woman has a full-time job.4. A job is all right, but what most women really want is a home and children.5. Being a housewife is just as fulfilling as working for pay.6. Most women have to work these days to support their families. (R)7. Both the man and woman should contribute to the household income. (R)8. A mans job is to earn money; a womans job is to look after the home and

    family.

    9. It is not good if the man stays at home and cares for and the woman goes outto work.

    10.Women should stay at home full-time when there is a child under school age(3-point scale: home full-time, work part-time, work full-time).

    11.Work is best for womens independence. (R)Note: (R) indicates reverse coding so that a higher score reflects more non-traditional

    attitudes.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    38/39

    37

    Table3

    PercentageDistrib

    utionofGenderTypesAcrossCountries

    MarriedorC

    ohabitingIndividuals,Age1

    8-65

    WOMENSTYPES

    MENSTYPES

    Traditional

    Transitional

    Autonomous

    Hardliner

    Adjuster

    Cooperator

    Australia

    17%

    51%

    31%

    25%

    57%

    18%

    Austria

    35

    37

    27

    39

    45

    16

    Bulgaria

    62

    26

    11

    62

    27

    11

    Canada

    7

    48

    45

    9

    55

    36

    CzechRepublic

    48

    42

    9

    54

    40

    6

    EastGermany

    8

    52

    40

    9

    63

    28

    GreatBritain

    17

    59

    23

    22

    61

    17

    Hungary

    47

    44

    9

    55

    38

    7

    Ireland

    23

    52

    25

    31

    51

    17

    Israel

    19

    54

    27

    27

    54

    20

    Italy

    25

    50

    25

    34

    50

    16

    Japan

    29

    36

    35

    40

    35

    26

    Netherlands

    12

    62

    26

    17

    63

    20

    NewZealand

    16

    55

    28

    20

    60

    20

    NorthernIreland

    20

    57

    23

    16

    67

    16

    Norway

    10

    49

    41

    13

    61

    26

    Poland

    55

    42

    3

    69

    28

    2

    Russia

    64

    34

    2

    68

    30

    1

    Slovenia

    33

    53

    14

    39

    54

    8

    Sweden

    8

    46

    46

    10

    59

    30

    USA

    12

    58

    29

    23

    58

    17

    WestGermany

    25

    48

    26

    36

    50

    14

    Note:Percentagesmay

    nottotalto100duetorounding.

  • 8/4/2019 Breen Cooke

    39/39

    38

    Table4

    OLSUnsta

    ndardizedCoefficientsPredicting(WomensReportsof)M

    ensParticipationinDomes

    ticTasks

    (1,womanalway

    sresponsible,to5,manalwaysresponsible)

    22Countries1994

    MODEL1

    MODE

    L2

    MODE

    L3

    b

    SE

    b

    SE

    b

    SE

    Constant

    1.673***0.147

    1.267***

    0.216

    2.302***

    0.318

    Formersocialistcountry

    0.185

    0.119

    0.253*

    0.111

    0.061

    0.098

    PercentAutonom

    ouswomen

    0.010*

    0.005

    0.005

    0.005

    -0.044**

    0.013

    PercentAdjustermen

    0.010*

    0.004

    -0.011

    0.006

    Autonomous*Ad

    juster

    0.094***

    0.025

    Fchange

    2.3

    1

    5.6

    0*

    14.3

    4***

    AdjustedR2

    0.1

    1

    0.2

    8

    0.5

    9

    MODE

    L2

    MODE

    L3

    b

    SE

    b

    SE

    Constant

    1.662***

    0.153

    1.818***

    0.257

    Formersocialistcountry

    0.194

    0.124

    0.130

    0.152

    PercentAutonom

    ouswomen

    0.015

    0.015

    0.011

    0.017

    PercentCooperatormen

    -0.007

    0.020

    -0.019

    0.026

    Autonomous*Cooperator

    0.032

    0.043

    Fchange

    1.5

    1

    1.2

    5

    AdjustedR2

    0.0

    7

    0.0

    5

    *p