Bog Gio 2016

download Bog Gio 2016

of 23

Transcript of Bog Gio 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    1/23

    Cambridge Journal of Economics2016,1 of 23doi:10.1093/cje/bev067

    The Author 2016. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society.

    All rights reserved.

    International competitiveness in post-Keynesian growth theory: controversiesand empirical evidence

    Luciano Boggio and Laura Barbieri*

    A fundamental starting point for post-Keynesian theory concerning growth inopen economies is succinctly expressed in the following statement by Kaldor:[T]he main autonomous factor governing both the level and the rate of growthof effective demand of an industrial countryis the external demand for its exports:and the main factor governing the latter is international competitiveness, which in

    turn depends on the level of its industrial cost relatively to other industrial exporters(Kaldor, 1971, p. 7; italics added). Moreover, thanks to increasing returns inmanufacturing, export expansion and international competitiveness would inter-act so as to create vicious or virtuous circles of cumulative causation. A few yearslater Kaldor, having found a positive correlation between the time changes ofthe main industrial countries relative manufacturing export shares and that oftheir relative unit costsa correlation that became known as the Kaldor para-doxdismissed his original cumulative causation theory and adopted a versionclose to Harrods foreign trade multiplier. The purpose of this paper is to reaf-firm the Kaldorian cumulative causation theory in its original version, by provid-ing a firmer analytical basis and showing that, contrary to the Kaldor paradox,time changes in export performance must be explained by levels rather than bychangesin unit costs.

    Keywords: International competitiveness, Post-Keynesian growth theory, Kaldorparadox, replicator equation

    JEL classifications:F43, O10

    Manuscript received 8 August 2013; final version received 13 January 2015.Address for correspondence:Laura Barbieri, Universit Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Dipartimento di Scienze

    Economiche e Sociali, Via Emilia Parmense, 84 29122 Piacenza, Italy.

    *Universit Cattolica del Sacro Cuore. Financial help by 2007 PRIN Heterogeneous Sectors, Growthand Technical Change is gratefully acknowledged. The authors would like to thank the Final Conference

    participants of that project, held in Naples (2729 April 2011), as well as Antonella Palumbo and otherparticipants of the S.I.E., Annual Scientific Meeting, held in Rome (1415 October 2011) for the stimulat-ing discussions and, last but not least, they would like to thank Bruno Soro for his insightful comments onKaldors and Harrods views. This paper is based on the research that was being carried out by ProfessorBoggio, who died unexpectedly as the work was coming to its conclusion. Laura Barbieri is deeply consciousof the debt she owes him finishing the work in his absence and feels honoured to have collaborated with himon the project. She would like to extend her gratitude to all those who assisted her in finishing it, in particularEnrico Bellino, Antonella Palumbo and Mariacristina Piva.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    2/23

    Page2 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    1. Introduction

    According to the mainstream theory of growth, based on the assumption of full

    employment of factors of production, economic growth is simply the combined effect

    of increases in the supply of factors and in their productivity. No room is left for an

    autonomous role of effective demand, its pressure on productive capacity and factor

    employment, nor its role in determining the rate of investment.According to another view, proposed in particular by the post-Keynesian theory

    of growth and shared by the present writers, the assumption of full employmentof

    labour in particularwhen the time period considered is not a secular one is not the

    most useful starting point for explaining differences in growth performances.

    An extreme version of this view was given by Nicholas Kaldor in the following

    terms: economic growth isalways demand-inducedand not resource-constrained.

    Resources, such as capital and labour do not determine growth, partly because they

    are mobile between regions, and partly because they are never optimally allocated

    (there are always economic sectors where labour is in surplus in the sense that its mar-

    ginal productivity is zero or even negative, as e.g. in agriculture); and partly because

    capital (in the sense of industrial capacity) is automatically generated as part of, and

    in consequence of, the growth of demand (Kaldor, 1981, p. 603; italics in original).

    As long as post-Keynesian theory deals with open economies, the following state-

    ment by Kaldor (1971, p. 7; italics added) offersin the writers opiniona funda-

    mental starting point: [T]he main autonomous factor governing both the level and

    the rate of growth of effective demand of an industrial country with a large share of

    exports in its total production and of imports in its consumption is the external demandfor its exports: and the main factor governing the latter is international competitiveness,

    which in turn depends on the level of its industrial cost relatively to other industrial

    exporters. Moreover, thanks to increasing returns in manufacturingVerdoorns

    lawexport expansion and international competitiveness would interact so as to cre-

    ate vicious or virtuous circles of cumulative causation (Myrdal, 1957; Kaldor, 1970).1

    This position was partly modified a few years later in a paper where Kaldor (1978)

    compared the time changesover periods longer than ten yearsof the main indus-

    trial countries relative manufacturing export shares with that of their relative unit

    costs2and found apositivecorrelation between the two variables.This paradox has various explanations. The simplest is that [h]igher prices could

    equally well reflect higher quality, which, in turn, might justify higher wages. From this

    perspective higher growth in relative unit labour cost (RULC) could just as well be seen

    as an indicator of growing quality relative to other countries or increasingrather than

    deterioratingcompetitiveness (Fagerberg, 2002, p. 1). A second (ambitious) inter-

    pretation, which has a clear Kaleckian flavour, is that lower unit labour costs (ULCS)

    should not necessarily be interpreted as implying that an economy is more competi-

    tive, i.e., that it will grow faster, and vice versa. In wage-led growth economies, an

    increase in the wage share leads to an increase in the equilibrium capacity utilizationrate, which leads to an increase in the growth rate of the capital stock. Hence it is pos-

    sible to find that the countries with fast-growing ULCSare the ones registering faster

    1 Boyer and Petit (1981), while discussing Un modle dinspiration kaldorienne, summarized the essenceof their arguments in the diagram they presented on p. 1128, which offers an immediate comprehension.

    2 A useful way of visualising this relationship can be obtained from the first two columns ofTable 1fromFagerberg (1996), p. 41.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    3/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page3of23

    growth in exports or in GDP, [so that] Kaldors paradox ceases to be an anomalous

    result (Felipe, 2005).3

    A further explanation is that a third factor, like GDP growth, is positively linked to

    growth in both exports and wages, hence in unit labour costs (GDP growth in turn

    being strongly influencedaccording to the prevailing viewby technology4), thus

    creating a positive link between the two time series.Or, as Kaldor himself put it, several years after the previous sentence quoted: There

    is only one important matter on which the events of the 1970s caused me to change my

    mind. This concerns the relative importance of price (or cost?) competition, as against

    other non price factors, such as superiority of design or quality, length and reliability

    of delivery dates, after-sales service, etc. Exchange rate adjustments operate mainly on

    cost and prices, and despite vast changes in relative exchange ratesin real, and not

    just in nominal termsthere was little effect on the pattern of trade in manufacturing

    (Kaldor, 1986, p. 25).

    The perverse (positive) relationship between export growth and price/unit labourcosts growth became known as the Kaldor paradox. This paradox was a damaging

    blow for Kaldors thinking and led him to dismiss his own theory and endorse Harrods

    foreign trade multiplier5 and Thirlwalls model of balance-of-payments-constrained

    growth (Kaldor, 1981).

    In that paper, cumulative causation was reduced to the fact that, because of increas-

    ing returns (in the production of goods and technical progress), success breeds further

    success (ibid., p. 596), whilst when increasing competitiveness and the widening of

    international market shares were an essential feature of the cumulative causation pro-

    cessas in the earlier Kaldorian formulationit appeared a much more importantand powerful phenomenon.

    We believe that the theory, put forward in the 1960s and 1970s by Kaldor (and

    Beckerman before him) to explain the contrast between the fast growth of Japan and

    some countries of continental EuropeWestern Germany and Italy in particular

    and the slow growth of the United Kingdom and the United States, is still very useful

    nowadays for understanding contemporary experiences, like those of the Asian NICs,

    of fast growth with strong international competitiveness.6

    The purpose of this paper is to reaffirm the Kaldorian cumulative causation theory

    in its original version, by providing a firmer analytical base and showing, on the basis

    of empirical evidence, that the Kaldor paradox is a weaker empirical regularity than

    others fully favourable to that theory.

    3This Kaleckian explanation of Kaldors paradox essentially implies that growth is not really export led,but rather domestically led. Actually, many post-Keynesians have expressed scepticism about the whole ideathat growth is always or typically export led, and favour an investment-driven approach instead (especiallyfor larger countries, and maybe for all countries). We thank one of the anonymous referees for drawing ourattention to that point.

    4This explanation of the paradox appears consistent with the sectoral investigations of the determinants

    of export performance which began to appear in those years, and which gave an essential role to technologi-cal variables, in contrast to the poor or perverse (that is, positive) sign, in such investigations, of (the growthof) unit labour cost or wages. See Table 3of Fagerberg (1996), summarizing five research projects of thiskind, Dosi and Soete (1983), and Dosi et al.(1990), ch. 6.

    5 In his 1981 paper, Kaldor asserts that the Harrod multiplier (Thirlwalls model) is dynamically stable(we thank Bruno Soro for attracting our attention to this point). This assertion seems rather unwarranted,but some kind of crude proof had been in Kaldor (1970), p. 342. On this point, see also Palumbo (2009),pp. 35152. Both Palumbo (2009)and Soro (2011)show that Harrod himself did not share this assertion.

    6 Data and analysis supporting this proposition can be found in Boggio (1995) for Italy and Boggio(2003)for the Asian NICS.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    4/23

    Page4 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    Later studies seem to confirm the paradox. For instance, Fagerberg (1996)shows

    that, considering the period 197894, unit labour costs growth, a typical variable

    expressing technological factors affecting competitiveness, has poorer explicative

    power for exportgrowththan changes in GDP and in R&D as a share of GDP.

    In effect, the consequence of the Kaldor paradox can be expressed by letting the

    traditional multiplicative form of export demand be

    x p p yx x x x

    = + + > ( ) , , 0 (1)

    where x,p,p*andy*are the growth rates of, respectively, exports, home and foreign

    price indexes measured in common monetary unit, and rest of the world income; and

    x

    and x

    are the price and income elasticities of export demand. Hence, (p+p*) is

    the relative price of foreign goods.

    Because of the paradox, there is a change of sign in the relative price effect and the

    addition of other variables of technological factors expressed by T:

    x p p y T x x

    = + + ( ) . (2)

    In the light of these premises, the aim of this paper is twofold. First, we theoretically

    and empirically reassert the importance of cost competitiveness as a channel through

    which cumulative growth dynamics can be sustained in open-economy growth mod-

    els. Second, we show that in macrodynamics, the growth rates of some variables may

    depend on the levels (rather than the growth rates) of other variables when replicatordynamics governs out-of-equilibrium behaviour.

    In Sections 2 and 3, we briefly examine the two main theoretical strands of Kaldorian

    derivation, namely the Kaldorian models of balance-of-payments-constrained growth

    (BPCG) and the Kaldorian models of export-led growth (ELG), in order to assess

    their relationship with the Kaldorian cumulative causation theory. In Section 3, we

    propose an alternative approach to that theory, based on the replicator equation and

    Beckerman model. After a brief examination of the literature on the replicator equa-

    tion, an empirical comparison between the ability of the Kaldor paradox and the repli-

    cator-like approach in explaining the growth of export is presented in Section 4.

    2. Kaldorian models of balance-of-payments-constrained growth (BPCG)

    A problem with the original Kaldorian approach is that the possibility of balance-of-

    payments problems is not considered.Thirlwall (1979)suggests a simple model for

    avoiding the possibility based on traditional demand equations for both exports and

    imports and their equality. It can be summarized using the standard multiplicative

    form of export demand, equation (1), expounded above, and similarly also for import

    demand:

    m p p ym m m m

    = + > ( ) , , 0 (3)

    where m,p,p*andyare the growth rates of imports, home and foreign price indexes,

    and domestic income, respectively, while m

    and m

    are the price and income elastici-

    ties of import demand.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    5/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page5of23

    But if, as Thirlwall maintains, either relative prices did not vary in the long run,

    p p = 0, (4)

    or, alternatively, x m

    + 1 0 , then we get

    x m x m

    y y y y = =/ / , (5)

    which explains growth rate differentials in terms of income elasticity differentials.

    Thirlwall showed that the growth rate of income of the main industrial countries dur-

    ing the period 196073 was approximated very well by the formula

    y yx m

    = / . (6)

    According to him (Thirlwall, 1979, pp. 5253), and supported by Kaldors opinion

    (Kaldor, 1981, p. 603), the income elasticities of this model reflect the innovative abil-

    ity and adaptive capacity of the producers in different countries.

    Many empirical estimates have been produced in subsequent years about the two

    crucial assumptions of the BPCG model, each eliminating the role of relative prices:

    a) no long-run changes in relative prices; and b) the sum of price elasticities of export

    and import demand approaching one. They tend to support the view that in the very

    long period (50 years or more)but notfor shorter periods, ranging from one to a few

    decadessuch assumptions are likely to be confirmed.7What matters more from ourviewpoint is that here the Kaldorian cumulative causation processes are not considered and no

    theoretical foundation is offered to them.

    3. Kaldorian models of export-led growth (ELG)

    The Kaldorian theory of cumulative causation circles in open economies during the

    past decades has not ceased to attract the attention of economists.

    The algebraic translation of a Kaldorian ELG model goes back to Dixon and

    Thirlwall (1975), who established a tradition, with which we disagree on a fundamen-

    tal point, namely the export equation. In this exposition, we shall use the more recent

    versionsvery similar to the first oneby Setterfield and Cornwall (2002)(p. 72) and

    Blecker (2013). The ELG model can be written using the symbols already introduced:

    x p p yx x x x

    = + + > ( ) , . 0 (7)

    It is interesting to see that the Kaldor paradox is completely neglected/forgotten.

    By the small country assumption, foreign price p* is taken as exogenously given.Setting wand qas changes in wages and labour productivity, changes in domestic price

    are determined by changes in unit labour costs (w q) and the gross profit markup, :

    p w q= + . (8)

    7For an accurate discussion of the literature on this point, see Blecker (2013)and Garcimartn et al.(2010).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    6/23

    Page6 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    By Verdoorns law:

    q q y= + < 0

    sufficient conditions foryE> 0 are

    > 0 (is satisfied if the sum of the direct and indirect effects ofy*on xis positive),

    1 / >x x

    (is satisfied if the Verdoorn effectis small relative to the price effect

    viaexports ony, or f fPR DR x x

    = > =1 / ).

    There is a further problem with the above equation system: the behaviour of the econ-

    omy outside the constant rate of growth cannot be established.

    But if we introduce a lag in the system, as Dixon and Thirlwall (1975)did, we can

    deal with the problem. We may, for instance, assume a slow Verdoorn effect, so that

    q f y y qt PR t t+

    = +1

    1

    0( ) (19)

    y f qt DR t = ( ) (20)

    y f q f f yt DR t DR PR t + +

    = =

    1 1

    1( ) [ ( )]. (21)

    The stability will prevail if and only if

    f fPR DR x x

    / ,=

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    8/23

    Page8 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    4. Beckerman model and the replicator equation

    4.1. Replicator equation

    To capture Darwins notion of the survival of the fittest, Fisher (1930)introduced what

    are now calledafter Richard Dawkins (Dawkins, 1976, pp. 1321)replicator equa-

    tions9

    , of which we give below a very simplified version.Let us consider a population composed of ndistinct competingvarieties of a

    given natural species and denote by x i n xi i i

    , , ,..., , ,= =1 2 1 the relative frequen-

    cies of the ith variety in the population. To each variety, let us associate its fitness

    level expressed by function f xi i( ) . In continuous time, their evolution might be

    described by the following equations (as usual, dot over the variable denotes a time

    derivative):

    x x f x f x f f x x f xi i i i i i i i i

    = > [ ( ) ( )], , ( ) ( ). 0 (23)

    This equation embodies the principle of natural selection: varieties with above-average

    fitness will expand, those with below-average fitness will contract and the average fit-

    ness f x( ) will increase. If the fitness functions f xi i( ) are simple constants, the average

    fitness will increase monotonically towards a state where only the varieties (or group of

    varieties) with maximum fitness survive(s).

    Notice that the last equation can be put in the form

    x x f x f xi i i i / ( ) ( ),= (24)

    which can be read as the proportional change in the share of the ith variety is an

    increasing function of its fitness advantage.

    But for the purpose of empirical analysis, a discrete version is necessary. It can be

    obtained by adaptingVerspagen (1993), p. 191.

    Let xitbe the level of export in country iat time t, t = 1 2 3, , , ..., i n=1 2, ,... andyit

    the country is share of world export at time t:

    yx

    xy y y y

    it

    it

    n

    i it

    it it it it

    , ( ) / .+1

    (25)

    Then the rate of change ofyit, namely yit , is given by

    ( / ), , ,..., ,,

    y E E E y E j mit j

    m

    j jit jt jt i

    n

    it jit = = 1 1 2 (26)

    where Ejit

    is the competitiveness variable jof country iat time t, and j

    the corre-

    sponding (fixed) parameter to be estimated.

    Equation (26) represents a typical R-like equation.

    9 For a more detailed analysis, see Hofbauer and Sigmund (1997); for economic applications, seeSilverberg (1997)and Silverberg and Verspagen (1995).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    9/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page9of23

    4.1.1. The replicator-like equations in the literature.Empirical tests of R-like equations

    found in the existing literature are very few, since the bulk of the literature on the effect

    of international competitiveness on export growth is based on growth rather than

    levelsof competitiveness variables. On the whole, they show that unit cost/wage levels

    are significant (with the expected sign) in the explanation of export shares, sometimes

    more significant than technology variables.In Verspagen (1993), regressions are performed for the whole sample of pooled

    observations (196487) for each of the 18 industrial sectors. The equation employed

    is a modified version of (26), and the whole exercise is explicitly under the heading of

    the replicator equation.

    In the various specifications tried, wage and labour productivity variables give good

    results, much better than those for the specifications of the patent variables (p. 215).

    The paper of Amendola et al.(1993)deals with manufacturing export market shares of

    16 OECD countries from 1967 to 1987. It is the only one that refers to the total manufac-

    turing export of each country. Starting from an equation almost identical to equation (26),a general autoregressive-distributed lag (ADL) is derived, giving rise also to long-run mul-

    tiplier estimates. The independent variables are unit labour cost, investment in machinery

    and total patents. However, in the reformulated ADL equations with long-run multipliers,

    the independent variables are again time changes. The Kaldor paradoxthey assert

    [a]s a long-term phenomenonseems the outcome of a spurious correlation (p. 465).

    Amable and Verspagen (1995)present an estimation of an empirical model of mar-

    ket share dynamics for five industrialized countries and 18 industries. In their paper, a

    long-run export market shareX*is built as follows:

    X k a PC b IN c PTij ij ij ij ij ij ij ij

    = + + + . (27)

    PCis a measure of unit labour cost, IN is (derived from) the ratio of investment to

    production and PT is based on total patents for each sector. For each independent

    variable, the following bell-shaped lag structure is adopted:

    Z Z Z Z Z PC IN PT= =( ( )) ( ( )) ( ( )) , , , .1 2 303 04 03 (28)

    The error-correction mechanism is built on the long-run value of the market share

    (27), giving

    X X Xij i ij ij

    = + ( )[ ( )], 1 (29)

    where iis a country dummy.

    The unit labour cost variable on average performs very well, better than the other

    two. Verspagen and Wakelin (1997)do not specify their model in the form of an exactreplicator, but base their functional specification upon earlier empirical models, such

    as Amendola et al.(1993)and Amable and Verspagen (1995). Market shares of each

    market are estimated for 10 countries and 15 manufacturing sectors. The average rate

    of growth of a market share is regressed on the average of competitiveness variables for

    the period 198085. These are patents and R&D, share of investment in output and

    wages in dollars (significant in 16 or 22 cases out 45), share of investment in output

    (significant in 29 cases) and wages (significant in 20 cases).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    10/23

    Page10 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    4.2. Beckerman model

    In this subsection, we shall consider the model published by W. Beckerman in 1962,

    a few years beforeKaldors papers mentioned above that anticipated some of the main

    ideas, in particular the cumulative growth model in open economies.10But, differently

    from all later Kaldorian models, Beckerman implicitly adopts an R-equation (shorthand for

    replicator equation) form for his export equation, therefore also anticipating the application ofthat idea to economic problems.11

    In this model, export changes are a decreasing function of the price of given country

    relative to competitor countries (Beckerman, 1962, p. 914). More precisely, the rate

    of growth of the share of world exports held by a given country, hence the differences

    in the growth of exports, depends not on time changesof relative priceas in the tra-

    ditional approach to export determination, exemplified by the exports equation of the

    BPCG and ELG modelsbut on cross-country price differences.

    The first reason we adopt the latter approach is that, accordingly with the Kaldors

    non-equilibrium thinking, we believe market shares are often far from their long-run

    equilibrium value and that their rates of change over time can be approximated by a

    replicator-type equation. This statement becomes clearer if we express the main reason

    we stress cross-country differences in levelsof unit costs or prices: normally, they also

    imply cross-country differences in profit margins, hence in the ability of the single firm

    to invest, expand its productive capacity, pursue technical progress and spend in non-

    price competition. In this waycontrary to an export growthbased approach on the

    demand side only, as in the model described in the previous sectionswe implicitly

    introduce also the supply sideof the firms.12

    We shall now describe the Beckerman model (Beckerman, 1962, pp. 91819), intro-

    ducing slight modifications that will make further formal developments easier.

    The symbols used are the same as those to be used in later years by the models

    expounded above, but for the productivity growth rate, for which we shall maintain q

    as above.

    The most interesting equations are the first ones, embodying the replicator equation

    principle:

    x a b= + ( ),1 (30)

    where is the price level of a given country relative to competitor countries and acan

    represent the rate of increase in world trade (ibid., p. 919). The meaning of is made

    more clear by explicitly introducing the levelof prices in the two countries: letpibe

    the level of prices (in common units) in country i, i = 1 2, , where 1 is the home country

    and 2 a competitor country. Then p p1 2

    / and x a b1

    1= + ( ) .

    Then we have

    10 Dixon and Thirlwall (1975)noticed that Beckermans model bears many similarities to Kaldors andpredates it (p. 202, fn. l), but (mis)interpreted Beckermans export equation as a wrong specification of anexport demand (p. 211). Cf. alsoThirlwall and Dixon (1979)and Cornwall (1977).

    11 In the writers opinion, Beckermans model could be seen as embodying the replicator equation prin-ciple even if the author does not consciously refer to it.

    12 Models spelling out a plausible description of the causal link between across firms differences in unitcost levels on one side and differences in profits, investments and productive capacity growth on the othercan be found in Boggio (1974, 1996, 2003).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    11/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page11of23

    productivity (output per head) equation13

    q c dx1 1

    = + , (31)

    wage equation

    w z vq n1 1

    1= +

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    12/23

    Page12 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    x a b = ( ),1 (38)

    the left-hand side is the rate of growth of the share of the countrys exports on the

    world total, which is made dependent on the competitiveness factor .

    Let us further develop this model (see also Boggio and Seravalli, 2003).

    If we maintain the assumption that the parameters in the basic equations are thesame in all countries (Beckerman, 1962), then

    ( / ), ( ) = = = >d

    dtp p v bd

    log

    1 2 1 1 0 (39)

    = d

    dt

    ( ),2 1 (40)

    so that the model gives rise to a differential equation and assumes the following graphic

    representation seen in Figure 1.

    Within the open interval ( , )0 , only one equilibrium, = 1, exists. Outside this equilib-

    rium, moves away from it, entering either a virtuous circle of cumulative causation or a

    vicious one. In the former case, competitiveness, the growth of exports, output, productiv-

    ity and wages all increase and, for a while, at an increasing speed. In the latter, competitive-

    ness, the growth of exports, output, productivity and wages decrease at an increasing speed.

    Fig. 1. Beckerman models representation in (, ).

    14 Beckerman, on the basis of his observation of European countries, rejected the suggestionthat dif-ferential rates of growth of the labour force may be an important explanation for differential growth ratessimply does not stand up to empirical verification (ibid., 921, fn. 2). See also his Reply (Beckerman, 1963)to Balassa (1963).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    13/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page13of23

    Obviously, only proximity to the equilibrium should be considered as economically

    meaningful, because, as long as a less extreme version than Kaldors of the premises

    of the post-Keynesian theory of growth is adopted, it should be stressed that many

    supply-side factors concur in dampening the divergence brought out by the model.14

    Similarly, one should remember that in the real world, technical progress not amenable

    to Verdoorns law may turn out to be most important.As with all models, ours is an abstraction, a glimpse of reality, that, if accepted,

    catches a true aspect of reality.

    Ours is one of the divergent circles of cumulative causation based on national com-

    petitiveness as in the original Kaldorian theory.

    5. Empirical evidence

    As mentioned before, empirical tests of R-like equations found in the existing literature

    show that unit cost/wage levels are significant (with the expected sign) in the explanation ofexport shares, sometimes more significant than technology variables.

    Therefore, we decided to try some preliminary tests, in order to begin to assess the

    relevance of Kaldors paradox relative to that of R-like equations.15

    5.1. Our first tests

    Very simple regression equations were performed, starting from OECD data for 33

    countriesincluding India, China and Brazilon aggregate good exports in US dol-

    lars (EXP) and manufacturing unit labour costs (ULC) for the 15-year period 19932007. The regressions are based on equation (26) (replicator equation): the dependent

    variable yit

    is the average growth rate of export share (EXPGR)16of country iover the

    15 years, while Ejitis the value of thejth competitiveness indicator for country i; the

    independent variables are the average unit labour costs (ULCAV) and their average

    growth rate (ULCGR) over the 15 years (see Appendix Afor more details).

    According to the Kaldor paradox, EXPGRshould mainly be determined by ULCGR

    (with positive coefficient) and according to replicator-like equations by ULCAV(with

    negative coefficient). The results of the cross-section analysis are inTable 1.

    The ULCAVvariable is always significant, also when coupled with ULCGR. The latternever reaches a standard level of statistical significance. Hence, the replicator-like speci-

    fication turns out very relevant, whilst the Kaldor paradox specification is not significant.

    In order to take advantage of the time-series dimension of the disposable data, which

    can be relevant for the phenomenon under consideration, we also implemented a panel

    data analysis, which fully confirms the previous results about the relationship between

    EXPGR, ULCAVand ULCGR.

    First, the three regressions presented in Table 1have been re-estimated in pooled

    data (see Appendix Bfor details on the variables construction and some descriptive

    15 Alonso and Garcimartn (1998)and Len-Ledesma (2002), starting from a BPCG and an ELG model,respectively, developed additional refinements based of the theory here illustrated and empirically tested itwith econometric estimates. Nevertheless, their models differ from our design, which focuses on the use ofreplicator equations and avoids lag complexity referring to a different and less monetary instable historicalperiod (19932007 in our case).

    16 Following the original specification proposed by Kaldor (cf. Kaldor, 1978, fn. 2, p. 102), our design isbased on export shareinstead of on the quantity of exportas in Len-Ledesma (2002).

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    14/23

    Page14 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    statistics). The results are reported in the first three columns ofTable 2; it is easy to

    note that they confirm the conclusion of the cross-section analysis.Specifically, as regards the first regression, the ULCvariable seems to have a significantly

    negative impact on the dependent variable, while the second regression shows that the

    ULCGRvariable is not significant. Finally, when we insert both independent variables in

    the regression, the significance of the ULCvariable is confirmed with a negative coefficient.

    Moreover, in order to control for potential endogeneity of the unit labour cost

    growth rate regressor (i.e. not only slower growth of relative unit costs promotes more

    rapid export growth, but also successful export growth leads to more rapid increases

    in relative unit costs), the significance of the lagged regressors has been verified. The

    results, reported in column (4) ofTable 2, prove the absence of reverse causality.We reach the same results considering the random-effects model,17 for which we

    obtain the results inTable 3.

    5.2. Introducing technology variables

    As amply discussed in the first part of this paper, several authors, while highlighting

    the Kaldor paradox, stressed the role of technical progress as an alternative explana-

    tion of trade flows. Therefore, we would like to introduce in our equations a variable

    expressing such a role.To this end, after having considered the measures of technological capabilities pro-

    posed byArchibugi and Coco (2005)(see Appendix Cfor more details), we choose the

    average gross domestic expenditure in R&D of the 19952000 period (GERDAV) and,

    17We chose a random-effects model after considering alternatives from fixed-effects and random-effectsmodels and implementing the Hausman test, which did not reject the null hypothesis, suggesting we userandom-effects model.

    Table 1. OLS estimation of the replicator equation. Cross-section analysis

    Dependent variable: export share growth - EXPGR

    Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)

    ULCAV -0.137*** -0.137**(0.042) (0.057)

    ULCGR -0.001 1.60E-05(0.001) (0.001)

    const 0.094*** 0.010 0.095**(0.028) (0.007) (0.036)

    Number of obs. 33 33 33R-squared 0.202 0.047 0.202

    JB(2) 2.114 3.449 2.119

    Reset(2) 1.196 0.043 1.191

    White(2) 6.037** 2.216 7.551

    1.Data refer to 33 OECD countries.2.Standard errors are in parenthesis. In the first equation, they are corrected for the presence of heteroske-

    dasticity, given the results of the White test.3.*Statistically significant at the 10% level; **significant at the 5% level; ***significant at the 1% level.4.JB stays for the Jarque-Bera statistic for normality; Reset is the Ramsey test for specification errors;

    White is the homoskedasticitys test.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    15/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page15of23

    alternatively, the average gross domestic product of the same period (GDPAV) as the

    main variables that should capture the innovation capability of a country.

    By inserting the GERDAVvariable into our third equation, we obtain the results

    reported in Table 4.

    The GERDAVvariable is not significant, and its effect on the equation results is neg-

    ligible. The ULCAVvariable is significant at the 5% level, while ULCGRis not. This

    seems to confirm the validity of the replicator approach against the Kaldor paradox

    and technological capabilities.

    However, things are not so simple: if we take the GDPAV variable as expressing

    the technological capabilities and introduce it into our equations, in spite of the high

    Spearman correlation between GDPAVand GERDAV, the results turn out very differ-

    ently. If we replace the latter by the former variable in the last three equations, the only

    significant variable turns out to be GDPAVitself (see model (2),Table 4).

    Various specificationsintroducing dummies for the UE or the Eurozone, as well as

    weights based on GDP, distinguishing countries according to an income threshold

    did not significantly change the results.18

    However, GDPAVnot only expresses the technological level of the country, but it

    approximates the manufacturing productivity, which in turn is the denominator of

    the ULCAV. This suggests, followingVerspagen (1993)and Verspagen and Wakelin

    (1997), that the latter could be conveniently replaced by the wage rate. To this aim,

    we introduced the WAGESAV independent variable, computed for each country as

    Table 2. OLS estimation of the replicator equation. Pooled regressions

    Dependent variable: export share growth - EXPGR

    Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)

    ULC -0.111*** -0.111***(0.025) (0.028)

    ULCGR 0.0003 0.0002(0.0003) (0.0003)

    ULC(t1) -0.112***(0.029)

    ULCGR(t1) 0.0002(0.0003)

    const 0.079*** 0.014*** 0.079*** 0.079***(0.016) (0.004) (0.017) (0.017)

    Number of obs. 448 440 440 411R-squared 0.036 0.002 0.038 0.038

    JB(2) 0.456 0.476 0.439 0.210

    Reset(2) 0.034 0.346 0.028 1.196

    White(2) 5.121* 0.151 5.228 5.022

    1.Data refer to the 33 OECD countries over the period 19932007.2.Standard errors are in parenthesis. In the first equation, they are corrected for the presence of

    heteroskedasticity.3.*Statistically significant at the 10% level; **significant at the 5% level; ***significant at the 1% level.

    4.JB stays for the Jarque-Bera statistic for normality; Reset is the Ramsey test for specification errors;White is the homoskedasticitys test.

    18 Results are available upon request.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    16/23

    Page16 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    Table 3. Random effects GLS regression for panel data

    Dependent variable: export share growth - EXPGR

    Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)

    ULCAV -0.088** -0.084**(0.038) (0.039)

    ULCGR 0.0003 0.0002(0.0003) (0.0003)

    const 0.065*** 0.014** 0.064***(0.023) (0.006) (0.024)

    Number of obs. 440 440 440R-squared within 0.001 0.002 0.001 between 0.175 0.013 0.191

    overall 0.036 0.002 0.038Wald(2) 5.320** 0.750 5.510*

    1.Data refer to the 33 OECD countries over the period 19932007.2.Standard errors are in parenthesis. In the first equation, they are corrected for the presence of

    heteroskedasticity.3.*Statistically significant at the 10% level; **significant at the 5% level; ***significant at the 1% level.

    Table 4. OLS estimation of the replicator equation with technological variables. Cross-sectionanalysis

    Dependent variable: export share growth - EXPGR

    Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)

    ULCAV -0.136** -0.090

    (0.058) (0.064)WAGESAV -3.08E-06***

    (1.07E-06)

    ULCGR 3.46E-05 0.001 -4.84E-04(0.001) (0.005) (0.001)

    GERDAV -6.37E-06(1.94E-05)

    GDPAV -1.49E-06** 1.21E-06(5.92E-07) (1.02E-06)

    const 0.097*** 0.104** 0.071***(0.037) (0.038) (0.019)

    Number of obs. 31 31 27R-squared 0.205 0.274 0.484

    JB(2

    ) 2.270 0.941 2.450Reset(2) 1.581 10.078 1.259

    White(2) 10.128 7.519 7.203

    1.Data refer to 33 OECD countries.2.Standard errors are in parenthesis. In the first equation, they are corrected for the presence of heteroske-

    dasticity, given the results of the White test.3.*Statistically significant at the 10% level; **significant at the 5% level; ***significant at the 1% level.4.JB stays for the Jarque-Bera statistic for normality; Reset is the Ramsey test for specification errors;

    White is the homoskedasticitys test.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    17/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page17of23

    the average wage of the 15 disposable annual data (see Appendix Afor more details),

    obtaining the results shown in the last column ofTable 4.

    The main result is that the level of the wage rate, expressed by WAGESAV, when

    per capita GDP (GDPAV) is included in the regression, is very significant, whilst the

    growth of unit costs (ULCGR) has a coefficient smaller than the standard error. Similar

    results are obtained when using GERDAVinstead of GDPAV, or when the logarithm ofGDP or the above described DUMMIES are introduced.

    6. Concluding remarks

    Since we consider the original Kaldorian cumulative causation theory as the most

    important tool of analysis to understand the historical experiences of fast-growing

    open economies, the main purpose of this paperas stated at the beginningis to

    reaffirm such a theory, by providing a firmer analytical basis and showing that Kaldors

    paradox cannot impair that basis.We believe that our discussion of the replicator equation and the developments we

    presented of Beckermans model may provide these firmer theoretical bases. Also, the

    results of the quantitative work done along the lines of the replicator equation by vari-

    ous authors and by ourselves may support the view that export growth depends on lev-

    els of competitiveness factorslabour cost in particularrather than on their growth.

    Hence, the Kaldor paradox, though statistically significant in some papers discussed in

    the introduction, in recent years is a weaker hypothesis than the replicator-type equa-

    tions, and thus cannot diminish the importance of the original Kaldorian cumulative

    causation theory as interpreted in light of Beckermans model.The results we obtained when per capita GERD and GDP are introduced could

    suggest that, even with variable expressing technological capabilities, the fundamental

    results of this paper are confirmed: namely, the validity of the replicator approach vis-

    -vis the Kaldor paradox.

    This shows that replicator dynamics are a potential boon to Kaldorian growth the-

    ory (with its emphasis on growth as an out-of-equilibrium or non-equilibrium pro-

    cess), and may assist in both the further development and advancement of this theory

    and reconciliation of Kaldorian growth theory with empirical evidence.

    Conflict of interest statement. None declared.

    Bibliography

    Alonso, J. and Garcimartn, C. (1998). A new approach to balance-of-payments constraint:some empirical evidence,Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 25982

    Amable, B. and Verspagen, B. (1995). The role of technology in market shares dynamics,AppliedEconomics, vol. 27, no. 2, 197204

    Amendola, G., Dosi, G. and Papagni, E. (1993). The dynamics of international competitiveness,

    Review of World Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv), vol. 129, no. 3, 45171Archibugi, D. and Coco, D. (2005). Measuring technological capabilities at the country level: a

    survey and a menu for choice, Research Policy, vol. 34, 17594Balassa, B. (1963). Some observations on Mr. Beckermans `export-propelled growth model,

    Economic Journal, vol. 73, 76384Beckerman, W. (1962). Projecting Europes growth, Economic Journal, vol. 72, 91225Beckerman, W. (1963). Some observations on Mr. Beckermans `export-propelled growth

    model: a reply, Economic Journal, vol. 73, 78587

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    18/23

    Page18 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    Beckerman, W. (1965). Demand, exports and growth, pp. 4472 in Beckerman, W. and Associates(eds.), The British Economy in 1975, National Institute of Economic and Social Research.Reprinted in Feinstein, C. (ed.) (1997), The Economic Development of the United Kingdom Since1870: Volume II(pp. 379411), Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar Publishing

    Blecker, R. (2013). Long-run growth in open economies: export-led cumulative causation ora balance-of-payments constraint? pp. 390414 in Harcourt, G. and Krielser, P. (eds.), The

    Oxford Handbook of Post-Keynesian Economics, vol. 1, Oxford, Oxford University PressBoggio, L. (1974). Crescita e specializzazione produttiva in uneconomia aperta, Milano, Vita ePensiero

    Boggio, L. (1995). Italy: from semi-industrialized economy to the sixth industrial power, RivistaInternazionale di Scienze Sociali (also at Universidad Catolica Argentina, Facultad de CienciasSociales y Economicas), vol. 53, no. 2, 22352

    Boggio, L. (1996). Growth and international competitiveness in a Kaldorian perspective,Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, vol. 7, 299320

    Boggio, L. (2003). A model of take-off and fast growth in open economies, Metroeconomica, vol.54, no. 23, 30125

    Boggio, L. and Seravalli, G. (2003). Lo Sviluppo Economico: fatti, teorie, politiche, Bologna, Italy,

    Il MulinoBoyer, R. and Petit, P. (1981). Progres technique, croissance et emploi: un modle dinspiration

    kaldorienne pour six industries europennes, Revue conomique, vol. 32, no. 6, 11131153Boyer, R. and Petit, P. (1988). The cumulative growth model revisited, political economy,Studies

    in the Surplus Approach, vol. 4, no. 1, 2344Castellacci, F. (2001). A technology-gap approach to cumulative growth toward an integrated

    model: empirical evidence for Spain, 19601997, DRUID Working Paper, 01-04Cornwall, J. (1977).Modern capitalism: its growth and transformation, New York, St Martins PressDawkins, R. (1976). The Selfish Gene, Oxford, Oxford University PressDixon, R. and Thirlwall, A. (1975). A model of regional growth-rate differences on Kaldorian

    lines, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 27, 20114Dosi, G., Pavitt, K. and Soete, L. (1990). The Economics of Technical Change and InternationalTrade, Brighton, Wheatsheaf and New York, New York University Press

    Dosi, G. and Soete, L. (1983). Technology gaps and cost-based adjustment: some explorationson the determinants of international competitiveness,Metroeconomica, vol. 35, no. 3, 197322

    Fagerberg, J. (1996). Technology and competitiveness, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 12,no. 3

    Fagerberg, J. (2002). Technology, Growth and Competitiveness: Selected Essays, Cheltenham, UK,Edward Elgar

    Felipe, J. (2005).A note on competitiveness, unit labor costs and growth: is Kaldors paradox a figmentof interpretation?Australian National University, CAMA Working Paper 6/2005

    Fisher, R. (1930). The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection, Oxford, Clarendon PressGarcimartn, C., Rivas, L. and Martnez, P. (2010). On the role of relative prices and capital

    flows in balance-of-payments-constrained growth: the experiences of Portugal and Spain inthe Euro area,Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, vol. 33, no. 2, 281306

    Hofbauer, J. and Sigmund, K. (1997). The Theory of Evolution and Dynamical Systems, Cambridge,Cambridge University Press

    Kaldor, N. (1970). The case for regional policies, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 18,33747

    Kaldor, N. (1971). Conflicts in national economic objectives, Economic Journal, vol. 81, 116Kaldor, N. (1972). The irrelevance of equilibrium economics, Economic Journal, vol. 82,

    December, 12371255Kaldor, N. (1978). The effect of devaluations on trade in manufactures, pp. 99118 inFurtherEssays on Applied Economics, London, Duckworth

    Kaldor, N. (1981). The role of increasing returns, technical progress and cumulative causationin the theory of international trade and economic growth, Economie Applique, vol. 34, no. 4,593617

    Kaldor, N. (1986). Recollections of an economist, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review,vol. 39, no. 154, 326

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    19/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page19of23

    Len-Ledesma, M. (2002). Accumulation, innovation and catching up: an extended cumulativegrowth model, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 26, no. 2, 20116

    Myrdal, G. (1957). Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, London, University Paperbacks,Methuen

    Palumbo, A. (2009). Adjusting theory to reality: the role of aggregate demand in Kaldors latecontributions on economic growth, Review of Political Economy, vol. 21, no. 3, 34168

    Setterfield, M. (2002). A model of Kaldorian traverse: cumulative causation, structural changeand evolutionary hysteresis, in Setterfield, M. (ed.), The Economics of Demand-Led Growth:Challenging the Supply-Side Vision of the Long Run, Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar

    Setterfield, M. and Cornwall, J. (2002). A neo-Kaldorian perspective on the rise and decline ofthe golden age, in Setterfield, M. (ed.), The Economics of Demand-Led Growth: Challenging theSupply-Side Vision of the Long Run, Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar

    Silverberg, G. (1997). Evolutionary Modeling in Economics: Recent History and Immediate Prospects,University of Maastricht, MERIT

    Silverberg, G. and Verspagen, B. (1995). Evolutionary theorizing on economic growth, in Dopfer,K. (ed.), The Evolutionary Principles of Economics, Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers

    Soro, B. (2011). Harrod, Kaldor, and the idea of the foreign trade multiplier, Economia inter-

    nazionale, vol. 65, no. 1, 17387Thirlwall, A. (1979). The balance of payments constraint as an explanation of international

    growth rate differences, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, vol. 32, no. 1,4553

    Thirlwall, A. and Dixon, R. (1979). A model of export-led growth with a balance of paymentsconstraint, in Bowers, J. (ed.), Inflation Development and Integration, Leeds, Leeds UniversityPress

    Verspagen, B. (1993). Uneven Growth between Interdependent Economies: An Evolutionary View onTechnology Gaps, Trade and Growth, Aldershot Brookfield USA, Avebury

    Verspagen, B. and Wakelin, K. (1997). Technology, employment and trade: perspectives on

    European integration, pp. 5674 in Fagerberg, J., Hansson, P., Lundberg, L. and Melchior, A.(eds.), Technology and International Trade, Aldershot, Edward Elgar

    A. Data used and main variables

    The source of the data used is OECD. Data used:

    export data of the International Trade (MEI) data set measured in billions of US

    dollars (EXPORT);

    unit labour costs, which measure the average cost of labour per unit of output (ULC);

    gross domestic product (expenditure approach) per head, US dollars, constantprices, constant PPPs, OECD base year (GDP);

    gross domestic expenditure on R&D per capita population (current PPP $) from the

    OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators (GERD);

    average annual wages in 2009 USD PPPs and the 2009 constant pricesaverage

    annual wages per full-time, full-year equivalent, dependent employee(WAGES).

    As regards the cross-section analysis, the dependent variable EXPGR is the average

    growth rate of the export shares (EXPshare) over the 19932007 period for 33 OECD

    countries.19The export shares are computed as the ratio of the exports of country i

    in year tand the sum of the exports of all the countries under consideration in year t;

    that is,

    19The sample includes Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, China, Czech Republic, Denmark,Estonia, Luxembourg, Mexico, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, India, Ireland, Israel, Italy,Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia,Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom, and the United States.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    20/23

    Page20 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    EXPshareEXPORT

    EXPORTit

    it

    i it

    =

    (41)

    with i = 1 33,..., and t = 1993 2007,..., , and so

    EXPGR

    EXPshare EXPshare

    i

    i i=

    log log ( ) ( ), ,2007 1993

    14 (42)

    with 14 being the number of annual periods divided into the 19932007 interval.

    The independent variables are the average unit labour costs (ULCAV) and their

    average growth rate (ULCGR) over the 15 years computed as replicator equations

    ULCAVULC

    i

    t it=

    15

    (43)

    ULCGRULC

    ULC EXPsharei

    i

    i i avi

    =

    1, (44)

    where ULCiis the average growth of the ULCof country iover the period consid-

    ered, i.e.

    ULC

    ULC ULC i

    i i=

    log log ( ) ( ),

    , ,2007 1993

    14 (45)

    and

    EXPshare

    EXPORT

    EXPORTav

    t

    it

    i

    t

    iti

    =

    15

    15

    33

    .

    (46)

    An additional independent variable computed on the wages and introduced in Section

    5.2 is

    WAGESAVWAGES

    i

    t it=

    15, (47)

    i.e. the average country wage computed on the disposable time period.

    B. Panel data analysis

    In the panel data analysis, the variables are computed also considering their time-series

    dimension: thus, the dependent variable EXPGR is the annual growth rate defined

    modifying equation (42) as follows:

    EXPGR EXPshare EXPshareit i t i t

    =

    log( ) log( ),, , 1

    (48)

    with i= 1,,33 and t= 1993,,2007.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    21/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page21of23

    The independent variables are the unit labour costs (ULCit) and their annual growth

    rate (ULCGR) computed as replicator equations:

    ULCGRULC

    ULC EXPshareit

    it

    i it t it

    =

    [ ( )],1 (49)

    where ULCitis the annual growth of the ULCof country ifrom time t 1 to t, i.e.

    ULC ULC ULC it it i t

    =

    log( ) log( ), 1

    (50)

    We considered the descriptive statistics of the variables concerned; seeTable 5.

    As far as the export variable is concerned, we can note that the within variabil-

    ity overcomes the between variability, meaning that the variability over time in each

    country in the period under consideration prevails over the variability of exportsbetween countries.

    On the contrary, as far as the ULCvariable is concerned, the between variability

    overcomes the within variability, pointing at wider differences among countries than

    the individual dynamics.

    As regards the ULCGR, the results seem to highlight a predominance of the indi-

    vidual dynamic variability over the variability across countries.

    C. Technology variable selectionIn order to introduce into our equations a variable expressing the technical progress, we

    shall consider the variables studied in the work of Archibugi and Coco (2005)to cap-

    ture the technological capabilities of a country. In their paper, alternative measures are

    considered of national technological capabilities that generate country rankingsthese

    are precisely the measures proposed by the World Economic Forum (WEF Technology

    index), the UN Development Program (UNDP Technology Achievement index),

    the UN Industrial Development Organization (Industrial Development Scoreboard

    UNIDO), the RAND Corporation (Science and Technology Capacity Index STCI)

    and a measure proposed by the authors (Technological Capabilities Index ArCo).20

    The variables considered in Archibugi and Cocos paper, from our viewpoint, suffer

    an important shortcoming: they cover only a small part of our equations time interval.

    To obviate it, we shall consider the use of two variables that do not suffer that short-

    coming, namely per capita GDP and per capita GERD (gross expenditure on R&D),21

    and test their ability to fulfill the role of indicators of national technological capabilities

    by comparing them with Archibugi and Coco variables.

    20 Similarities and differences between the various methodological results at the aggregate level are ana-lyzed without considering the nature of technological capabilities available in each country. Specifically, theauthors show that the results frequently diverge because of the different social indicators taken into account.Nevertheless, a strong similarity in the rank correlations is interpreted as evidence of the reliability of eachindicator. This supports the idea that it is impossible to generate a unique measure of technological capa-bilities, but methodological variety helps create a better understanding of social phenomena. Moreover, allingredients of technological capability are as relevant as the final measure, and in order to assess the impactof technological capabilities on economic and social indicators, individual indicators and sub-indexes shouldbe taken into account.

    21 SeeAppendix Afor more details.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    22/23

    Page22 of23 L. Boggio and L. Barbieri

    For the sake of homogeneity with the latter indexes (almost all of which are com-

    puted over the 19972000 or 19952000 period), averages of per capita GDP and per

    capita GERD of the 19952000 period are calculated (namely GDPAVand GERDAV,

    respectively). The sample of countries selected is common to the Archibugi and Coco

    set, i.e. 28 countries.

    The rankings of our indicators, reported inTable 6, are very similar to those of theindicators considered by Archibugi and Coco (2005, p. 186,Table 2), as confirmed by

    Table 7, which shows for the 28 countries the co-graduation matrix among rankings

    by means of Spearman correlations.

    There is a high correlation between our indicators and the other indexes confirming

    our hypothesis that the two variables could be valid indicators of national technologi-

    cal capabilities.

    The highest correlation coefficients, however, are found for GERDAV. GDPAVshows

    significant correlation, in one case equal to GERDAV, but lower in the other cases.

    In view of these results, we choose GERDAVas the main variable that should cap-ture the innovation capability of a country.

    Table 5. Descriptive statistics of the panel data variables

    Variable Mean Std.Dev. Observations

    EXPGR overall 0.014 0.077 N=440between 0.037 n=33within 0.69

    ULC overall 0.590 0.132 N=440between 0.119 n=33within 0.057

    ULCGR overall -0.490 11.267 N=440between 3.338 n=33within 10.758

    1.Data refer to 33 OECD countries over the period 19932007.

  • 7/25/2019 Bog Gio 2016

    23/23

    International competitiveness: controversies and empirical evidence Page23of23

    Table 6.Technology indicators

    GERDAV GDPAV

    Australia 14 4Austria 9 6Belgium 10 8Canada 12 5China 28 28Czech Republic 21 23Finland 5 15France 7 12Germany 6 7Greece 24 20Hungary 25 24Ireland 16 10

    Israel 4 17Italy 17 14Japan 3 9Korea 15 22Mexico 27 26Netherlands 8 3New Zealand 19 18Norway 11 1Poland 26 27Portugal 22 19Slovak Republic 23 25

    Slovenia 18 21Spain 20 16Sweden 1 13United Kingdom 13 11United States 2 2

    Table 7. Spearman correlations

    GERDAV GDPAV WEF UNDP ARCO RAND

    GERDAV 1()

    GDPAV 0.75 1(5.74) ()

    WEF 0.67 0.67 1(4.59) (4.61) ()

    UNDP 0.83 0.72 0.85 1(7.73) (5.28) (8.06) ()

    ARCO 0.90 0.74 0.78 0.88 1(10.55) (5.69) (6.73) (9.43) ()

    RAND 0.93 0.78 0.79 0.89 0.96 1(12.62) (6.39) (6.60) (9.75) (16.89) ()

    1.t-statistics are in parenthesis, showing that all correlations are significant at the 1% level.