BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

29
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1484928 Articles One-Way Contracts: Consumer Protection without Law OMRI BEN -SHAHAR * Abstract: What if consumer contracts were legally enforceable only against the consumers, but not against the business? This paper, part of my project on the ‘myths of consumer protection,’ describes a regime of ‘one-way contracts’–contracts between consumers and business to which only consumers are bound, the business is not. A breaching business would face no contractual liability. The paper argues that many consumer contracts are already disguised one-way contracts. It then demonstrates the variety of alternative consumer protections devices that would emerge in the total absence of legal protection. In a one-way contracts world, trans- actions will be redesigned to limit consumers’ exposure to breach; insurance and bond services would develop to protect aggrieved consumers; reputation services and rating intermediaries would have a greater role; and public enforcement could potentially fill some of the remaining deterrence gaps. Thus, despite weakening the legal protection, the one-way contracts regime has the potential to improve consumers’ well being. The paper concludes that the focus within the consumer protection movement on enhancing access to, and the scope of, contract remedies may be misguided. Résumé: Quid si les contrats de consommation n’étaient exécutoires que contre les consom- mateurs mais pas contre les commerçants? Cet article, qui fait partie de mon projet sur les mythes de la protection des consommateurs, décrit un régime de contrats “à sens unique”, c’est-à-dire des contrats entre des consommateurs et des commerçants ne liant que les premiers et pas les seconds. Un commerçant n’exécutant pas ses obligations n’aurait pas à assumer de responsabilité contractuelle. Cet article soutient que de nombreux contrats de consommation sont en réalité des contrats à sens unique déguisés. Il montre ensuite la variété des instruments alternatifs de protection des consommateurs qui émergeraient en l’absence de protection légale. Dans un monde de contrats à sens unique, les transactions seraient redessinées pour limiter l’exposition des consommateurs à l’inexécution contractuelle ; l’assurance et les services de garantie se développeraient pour protéger les consommateurs mécontents ; les services afférents à la réputation et les agences d’évaluation auraient un rôle plus grand ; et les mesures coercitives publiques pourraient remplir quelques uns des vides qui demeureraient dans les mécanismes de dissuasion. Ainsi, bien qu’il affaiblisse la protection légale, le régime des contrats à sens unique pourrait potentiellement accroître le bien-être des consommateurs. L’article conclut ainsi que l’accent mis, au sein du mouvement de protection des consomma- teurs, sur l’accroissement de l’accès aux remèdes contractuels ainsi que de la portée de ces derniers pourrait être inopportun. Kurzfassung: Was wäre, wenn Verbraucherverträge nur gegenüber Verbraucher durch- gesetzt werden könnten, nicht von diesen? Der vorliegende Beitrag, der sich einordnet in * Frank and Bernice Greenberg Service Professor of Law, University of Chicago Law School. I am grateful to Oren Bar-Gill, Saul Levmore, Ariel Porat, and workshop participants at Chicago for helpful suggestions.

Transcript of BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

Page 1: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1484928

A r t i c l e s

One-Way Contracts: Consumer Protection without Law

OM R I BE N-SH A H A R*

Abstract: What if consumer contracts were legally enforceable only against the consumers, butnot against the business? This paper, part of my project on the ‘myths of consumer protection,’describes a regime of ‘one-way contracts’–contracts between consumers and business to whichonly consumers are bound, the business is not. A breaching business would face no contractualliability. The paper argues that many consumer contracts are already disguised one-waycontracts. It then demonstrates the variety of alternative consumer protections devices thatwould emerge in the total absence of legal protection. In a one-way contracts world, trans-actions will be redesigned to limit consumers’ exposure to breach; insurance and bond serviceswould develop to protect aggrieved consumers; reputation services and rating intermediarieswould have a greater role; and public enforcement could potentially fill some of the remainingdeterrence gaps. Thus, despite weakening the legal protection, the one-way contracts regimehas the potential to improve consumers’ well being. The paper concludes that the focus withinthe consumer protection movement on enhancing access to, and the scope of, contract remediesmay be misguided.

Résumé: Quid si les contrats de consommation n’étaient exécutoires que contre les consom-mateurs mais pas contre les commerçants? Cet article, qui fait partie de mon projet sur lesmythes de la protection des consommateurs, décrit un régime de contrats “à sens unique”,c’est-à-dire des contrats entre des consommateurs et des commerçants ne liant que les premierset pas les seconds. Un commerçant n’exécutant pas ses obligations n’aurait pas à assumer deresponsabilité contractuelle. Cet article soutient que de nombreux contrats de consommationsont en réalité des contrats à sens unique déguisés. Il montre ensuite la variété des instrumentsalternatifs de protection des consommateurs qui émergeraient en l’absence de protectionlégale. Dans un monde de contrats à sens unique, les transactions seraient redessinées pourlimiter l’exposition des consommateurs à l’inexécution contractuelle ; l’assurance et les servicesde garantie se développeraient pour protéger les consommateurs mécontents ; les servicesafférents à la réputation et les agences d’évaluation auraient un rôle plus grand ; et les mesurescoercitives publiques pourraient remplir quelques uns des vides qui demeureraient dans lesmécanismes de dissuasion. Ainsi, bien qu’il affaiblisse la protection légale, le régime descontrats à sens unique pourrait potentiellement accroître le bien-être des consommateurs.L’article conclut ainsi que l’accent mis, au sein du mouvement de protection des consomma-teurs, sur l’accroissement de l’accès aux remèdes contractuels ainsi que de la portée de cesderniers pourrait être inopportun.

Kurzfassung: Was wäre, wenn Verbraucherverträge nur gegenüber Verbraucher durch-gesetzt werden könnten, nicht von diesen? Der vorliegende Beitrag, der sich einordnet in

* Frank and Bernice Greenberg Service Professor of Law, University of Chicago Law School. I amgrateful to Oren Bar-Gill, Saul Levmore, Ariel Porat, and workshop participants at Chicago forhelpful suggestions.

Page 2: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1484928

eine größere Arbeit zum “Mythos des Verbrauchervertragsrechts”, beschreibt die genanntenEinbahnstraßenverträge, die allein gegenüber Verbrauchern durchgesetzt werden könnten,nicht von diesen. Ein vertragsbrüchiges Unternehmen wäre keiner Haftung ausgesetzt. Eswird argumentiert, dass in der Tat viele Verbraucherverträge bereits heute – versteckt –solche Einbahnstraßenverträge bilden. Dann wird auf die Vielzahl alternativer Verbrau-cherschutzmechanismen eingegangen, die sich mangels rechtlicher (Haftungs-)Mechanismenentwickeln würden. In einer Welt von Einbahnstraßenverträgen würden Verträge andersgestaltet, um die Verbraucher vor Vertragsbruch zu schützen, Versicherungslösungen zuihrem Schutz entstünden, Reputations- und Ratingdienste würden wichtiger werden, undeine öffentlichrechtliche Rechtsdurchsetzung könnte die verbleibenden Schutzlücken schlie-ßen. Solchermaßen könnte ein Regime von Einbahnstraßenverträgen, obwohl es die (pri-vat-)rechtlichen Schutzstandards zurückschraubt, im Ergebnis zu höherer Verbraucherwohl-fahrt beitragen. Aus all dem wird der Schluss gezogen, dass die starke Fokussierung desVerbraucherschutzes und seiner Protagonisten auf das Thema “besserer Zugang” zumRechtsschutz in die falsche Richtung führt.

Introduction

Suppose standard form contracts between businesses and consumers were‘one-way contracts’–enforceable only against one party, not the other. Youprobably think: enforceable only against the business, not the consumers–anextreme version of the consumer-protection approach that has been percola-ting broadly. But I actually have in mind the opposite one-way contract–en-forceable only against the consumers, not against the business. The consumersare bound, unable to escape any of their obligations under the substantiveterms or the fine print: they have to pay the contract price, the hidden fees,abide by any restrictive provisions (as long as they are legal), commit to the fullterm of the service, and so on. The business on the other hand, is not legallybound to anything it promised, and aggrieved consumers are unable to legallyenforce any of their rights that appear in what we normally think as the‘contract:’ not timely delivery, not the return policy, not the warranty, noteven the conforming delivery itself. No court-imposed remedy whatsoever.

How in the world can this make sense (even as a thought experiment)? Thereality of the market is already such that businesses have greater power andsophistication. Surely, consumers, not the business, are on the side that needsprotection. They are less informed, less well funded, plagued by collectiveaction problems, and overall less able to secure compliance with their sideof the bargain. If anything, contract law should remedy this asymmetry, notreflect it. Why, then, go astray and imagine a regime of one-way contracts inwhich only consumers are stripped of the power to sue for breach of promise,thus are further disarmed vis-à-vis their mighty business opponents?

I argue that the concept of one-way contracts is a useful concept that deliverstwo essential insights. The first insight is a positive-descriptive metaphor–a

ERCL 3/2010222 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 3: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1484928

way to capture much of the reality of business-to-consumer relations and toinvestigate its effects. The second insight is normative, suggesting that furthergravitation towards a one-way contracts module could actually benefit con-sumers. Rather than augmenting the legal remedies that consumers have undercontract law (the stated goal of the consumer protection movement), the socialcontrols of the business-to-consumer deal ought to be restricted to techniquesthat, unlike contract law, actually work.

The thesis begins with the quite obvious observation that in the existing legallandscape, the power of consumers to legally enforce the terms of the contractprovides a very shabby safety cushion. For the great majority of consumers,the presence of a ‘contract’ accompanying the goods or services, and of con-tract law at the background, is irrelevant. Recognizing this weakness of thelaw, solutions can go in one of two ways. One way is to strengthen contractrights and contract law’s involvement. In this spirit, consumer protectionoriented reforms that are often advocated include better disclosures, moreeffective rituals of assent, stronger remedies for breach of contract, and man-datory substantive terms to assure minimum standards. Elsewhere, I expresseddoubts concerning the effectiveness of some of these efforts1.

A second way to address the weakness of contract law in the consumer area isto abandon contract law as the locus of consumer protection, and to seekprotection from alternative sources, which do not rely on private enforcementof the contract by aggrieved consumers. A significant component of my thesisin this paper is to describe the value of alternative, non-legal protections ofconsumer rights. What are these non-legal protections?

First, if consumer transactions are impossible to legally enforce, they might bedesigned differently, to address consumers’ anxiety about their non-rights. Forexample, instead of paying and then relying on promises and assurances–thelegal guaranty–consumers will prefer the transaction to be carved up intopieces with corresponding ‘progress commitments’. One can imagine thatinstead of buying a computer for $2000 and putting such big payment at risk,consumers will lease computers for $250 per year, with the option to terminateeach year. Innovations in transactions costs technology can make the divisi-bility of commitment efficient.

Second, private bonds and assurances can develop to secure the consumersagainst non-performance. In the same way that eBay Motors provides dis-appointed buyers a fund from which they can recover the lost payment whenthe seller takes the money and runs, market makers and intermediaries might

1 O. Ben-Shahar, ‘The Myth of Opportunity to Read in Contract Law’ 5 European Reviewof Contract Law (2009); O. Ben-Shahar and C. Schneider, The Failure of MandatedDisclosure (Mimeo: University of Chicago Law School, 2009).

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 2 3

Page 4: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

offer bonds and guarantee programs, and set up recovery funds to inducebuyers to enter the market.

Third, consumers may have a greater need to insure against bad performanceby the business (assuming, again, that insurance transactions–another speciesof consumer-to-business contract–are effectively enforceable). A buyer of a$2000 computer might be offered, say, a $100 insurance policy with coveragefor some common problems. Insurers can also monitor the businesses whoseopportunism creates the insured ‘peril’. Like in many insurance markets, in-surers can aggregate and share actuarial data on the non-performance risk thatbusinesses pose, thereby improving the dissemination of information andaccurate pricing.

Fourth, importantly, without effective legal protections consumers have torely even more on the performance reputation of businesses. Thus, the abilityof a business to attract new customers and to charge higher prices woulddepend on the reliability of feedback scores, ratings, consumer surveys, re-ports by watchdog groups–that is, on the aggregate measures of the scatteredexperiences of past customers. These methods exist even in areas in whichcontracts are enforceable two-way, but they are particularly valuable and morewidely available in areas in which consumers fear that the legal rights areworthless. For example, consumers who buy on eBay (where it would be closeto impossible to get a court remedy for breach), rely heavily on the sellers’feedback scores. Further elimination of legal protections would necessarilybreed more of these reputation devices.

Fifth, businesses might have a stronger incentive to go beyond their (legallybinding) rights, to ‘forgive’ consumers who request special accommodations,to refrain from enforcing to the letter fine print and the hidden fees–in short, toact cooperatively in the shadow of their enforceable legal rights. Such conductwould be intended to infuse consumer confidence especially among the ot-herwise reluctant consumers who, themselves without enforceable contractualrights, would be rationally anxious. Thus, ironically, the absence of enforce-able contractual rights could boost the bottom line average value that consu-mers get, all else equal.

Recognizing these (and several other) consumer protections mechanisms, thepaper turns to offer its main normative claim. I argue that consumers canpotentially benefit if their legal rights, which are almost impossible to enforcein court anyway, would be stripped altogether. Taking away legal rights bytransforming consumer contracts into one-way contracts could improve mat-ters for consumers. The absence of legal rights could alert consumers andbolster the emergence of the more effective non-legal consumer protectionsthat might otherwise be slow to develop.

Finally, the ambition of this article is not merely to outline a novel regime,

ERCL 3/2010224 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 5: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

but to argue that many existing markets can be characterized as de factoone-way contracts. I am not referring merely to the phenomenon that mostcontractual rights that consumers get are ineffective and have no threat valuein a lawsuit. Rather, I am referring to consumer transactions that are largelydone without a ‘contract’, at least not one that protects the consumer. Thinkabout supermarket purchases. There is, of course, a legal contract between theconsumer and Giant Foods. A staple of first-year contracts courses is deci-phering the offer, acceptance, and contract formation moment in such generictransactions. But this is merely a ‘pedagogical’ contract. Unlike many otherconsumer transactions, in the supermarket there is no boilerplate involved, noclick ‘I Agree’, no shrinkwrap, no additional term-of-service record attachedto deal–no explicit moment of assent. Pay-the-labeled-price-and-it’s-yours,this is the contract. In fact, there are no contract-based lawsuits filed againstsupermarkets! Supermarket transactions are, for all stated purpose, one-waycontracts, working in a highly satisfactory way. And the same is true withrespect to other common consumer transactions, such as taxicab services andrestaurants.

While the paper takes a highly skeptical view of the role of contract law inconsumer protection, it is by no means an ‘anti-consumer’ manifesto. On thecontrary: the argument in favor of one-way contracts is not based on theinterests of businesses. If my argument is correct, businesses don’t care muchwhether contracts are one- or two-way, since they do not pose a significantthreat of liability either way. The one-way contract thesis is friendly to con-sumer interests because it suggests that meaningful protection can and shouldbe achieved by the design of more potent substitutes. Within contract law, theplight of consumers is often regarded as a basis for enhancing contract enfor-cement and of bolstering the access of consumers to breach of contract reme-dies. The one-way contract idea suggests that this is a misguided priority,barking up the wrong tree. Consumer protection ought to be accomplishedby abandoning contract claims.

Part I of this Essay begins with a brief account of the asymmetric enforcementproblem posed by consumers-to-business contracts, and why this problem isnot solved by standard mechanisms like class actions. Part II of this Essayintroduces the conceptual structure of one-way contracts. Which contractswould this regime apply to? Which terms and which violations will be un-enforceable? Part III explores some real life examples for the one-way con-tracts regime. Part IV is the core of the Essay: it discusses the alternativeprotections that would emerge in the absence of legal enforcement, to safegu-ard the interests of consumers. Part V explains why the one-way contractstructure is necessary to fire up these alternative protections. Finally Part VIconcludes, commenting on the value of the one-way contracts template as aconceptual framework.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 2 5

Page 6: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

I The Problem with Consumers-to-Business Contracts

The phenomenon of standard form contracting between consumers and busi-ness (“B2C”) is as troubling for contract law as it is viable for the economy.Much ink has been spilled to explain why standard form contracting is desi-rable, analogizing it to standard form production of goods. Plenty of attentionhas also been drawn to the dangers involved in standard-form, fine-printcontracting–what many scholars and judges identify as ‘contract of adhesion’.Bad things can be buried in the boilerplate, and when the time comes for thebusiness to fulfill its part of the obligation consumers might be surprised tolearn that what they thought they bargained for was meticulously draftedaway in fine print.

Sometimes the problem with B2C contracts is the bad terms. These are thepro-business terms of the contract: the disclaimers, the limitation of rights, theself-serving definitions, and the like. Other times, the problem with B2Ccontracts is the opposite: there are good terms in the contract–the pro-consu-mer terms–securing consumer rights (eg, the right to get the product as des-cribed, the express warranty, property rights, withdrawal rights), but it turnsout that they are not easily enforceable. Few if any consumers can overcomethe runarounds that a reluctant business, if it decides not to fulfill its obliga-tions, puts them through. Enforcement is costly and largely impractical. In theabsence of a credible threat to sue, businesses are undeterred and consumers’contractual rights are in jeopardy.

There are some obvious problems with techniques aimed at bolstering theenforcement of the consumer side of the deal. Most contractual claims aresmall. Damages, even if measured by the expectation measure, are too insig-nificant to justify a costly suit (whereas large consequential damages are rou-tinely limited in a conspicuous way in the contract). Theoretically, it is possi-ble to aggregate claims into class actions, but the impediments in thecontractual setting are significant. For one, it only applies to systematic vio-lations. When the individual claims are small, members of the class are hard toidentify and only a small compensatory effect is achieved. And given that asubstantial component of the outcome consists of attorneys’ fees, there is anon-trivial problem of separating the meritorious suits from the frivolousones.

Further, businesses can draft around various limitations set by law. For exam-ple, if the law tries to offer additional protection to consumers by increasingremedies, businesses can conspicuously limit the remedies. If the law installsprocedures securing access to justice, businesses can draft their way out ofcourt through choice of law and mandatory arbitration clauses. If the law findssuch arbitration clauses unconscionable and vacates them, businesses againresort to redrafting to introduce incremental changes to these clauses so as

ERCL 3/2010226 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 7: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

to make them legally tolerable. The target for consumer protection is elusive,the business parties are sophisticated and well-counseled, and as long as thelaw is unwilling to fully regulate the contract through mandatory terms, thereis no clear solution.

Legislators have sought to redress these problems by providing a host ofstatutory non-disclaimable remedies and procedures, through the enactmentof consumer protections laws. In the U.S, these are largely public law pro-cedures, initiated by agencies and without direct compensation to consumers.The FTC developed definitions for unfair and deceptive practices and exerci-sed its powers to enjoin and sanction offending businesses2. Subsequently, allstates followed and enacted Consumer Protection Acts (CPAs), taking a sig-nificant step further3. These ‘little FTC acts’ as they are known–often expandthe remunerated list of practices that are presumptively unfair or deceptive,but more importantly they allow aggrieved consumers to bring ‘private attor-ney general’ actions against alleged offenders and make it much easier thantraditional contract law to recover damages, including punitive damage andattorney fees. They also render the class action strategy easier to apply.

These remedies are effective. In fact, some commentators worry that they areoverly effective, leading to excessive and frivolous suits4. In California, forexample, these worries led to a successful referendum to limit ‘shakedown’suits against businesses5. Indeed, one of my arguments below is that streng-thening consumers’ power to bring contractual suits is unnecessary becauseCPA suits accomplish more than contract breach suits can ever hope to. Butwhile CPAs provide legal redress in many contexts, they are not equivalent tocontract breach remedies. For one, they apply only to a subset of what isnormally regarded as breach of contractual duties. That is, they apply tosystematic conduct, mostly precontractual, that is intended to mislead consu-mers by false promises and deceptive descriptions. CPA causes of action areaimed at blameworthy behavior by business, often intentional and systematicdeception; they thus add an element of fault that is usually not necessary for ashowing of breach of contract.

Further, by allowing punitive or statutory damages and authorizing private

2 V.E. Schwartz and C. Silverman, ‘Common-Sense Construction of Consumer ProtectionActs’, 54 U Kan L Rev 1, 7 (2005).

3 See, eg, the Texas Deceptive Trade Practices Act, 17 Tex Bus & Com Code §§ 17.41–17.63.4 Schwartz and Silverman, supra n 2; H.N. Butler and J.S. Johnston, Consumer Harm Acts?

An Economic Analysis of Private Actions under State Consumer Protection Acts (mimeo:2008).

5 See California Secretary of State, Statement of Vote and Supplement to the Statement ofVote, 2004 Presidential General Election, Nov 2, 2004, at 45 (2004), www.ss.ca.gov/electi-ons/sov/2004_general/ssov/formatted_ballot_measures_detail.pdf (Proposition 64 pas-sed with the support of 59% of the votes).

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 2 7

Page 8: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

attorneys general to represent the aggrieved parties, CPAs conform moreclosely to the deterrence model of criminal law than to the compensationmodel of private law. Their purpose is to protect the integrity of the publicsphere–the consumer market–not the individual victim. Also, even though theincidence of CPA suits increased dramatically in recent years, it is still a far cryfrom systematically addressing contract breach. The vast majority of consu-mers who suffer breach of contract by the business are not aware of their CPArights, do not file or join CPA suits, and will not benefit by the remote chancethat there was a filing of a CPA suit by others.

The broad recognition that traditional notions of contract law fail to adequa-tely protect consumers is further demonstrated by the shift towards regulationof the terms of the consumer contract. It is increasingly believed that even incompetitive markets consumers agree to contract terms that are undesirable6.To correct for these market failures, many aspects of consumer contracts areregulated and the terms are mandated by the government. For example, theEuropean Community has promulgated rules that forbid particular termsfrom appearing in consumer contracts7. Similarly, the Obama administrationhas put forward a set of proposals to regulate consumer financial contracts bymandating not only disclosure, but also the substance of important terms8.Whether these minimum standard regulations can help consumers vindicatetheir contractual rights is questionable. A business that breaches a mandatedcontractual right of the consumer still needs to be sued. A contractual rightthat is effectively unenforceable is not any more secure by virtue of beinggovernment mandated.

II One-Way Contracts: the Template

This section describes the legal concept of one-way contracts. The basic fea-ture is simple: the terms of the transaction are enforceable only by one party,the business. They are not enforceable by the other party, the consumer. Thus,if the consumer breaches the terms of the contract, say, by failing to maketimely payment, the business can resort to legal remedies. The business can suethe consumer, employ collection agencies, and engage in any self-help measurethat is legally available. But if it is the business that breaches the terms of the

6 For a recent economic analysis of anticompetitive use of contract language, see D. Giloand A. Porat, ‘The Unconventional Uses of Transactions Costs’, in O. Ben-Shahar (ed)Boilerplate: Foundations of Market Contracts 66 (2006).

7 See, eg DCFR Intr 27–28; DCFR II.-9:411 (‘Terms which are presumed to be unfair incontracts between a business and a consumer’); Council Directive 93/13/EEC of 5 April1993 on unfair terms in consumer contracts.

8 See, eg, Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure Act of 2009 [cite]; Seealso Financial Regulatory Reform 15 (Dept of Treasury 2009).

ERCL 3/2010228 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 9: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

contract, say, by failing to make timely delivery or by tendering non-confor-ming goods or services, the consumer cannot resort to legal remedies forbreach of contract. Other legal claims, if available, may apply (tort, adminis-trative, criminal), but not consumer-oriented contract remedies.

1 Transforming Consumer Contracts into One-Way Contracts

Consider the standard fine print contract between a business and a consumer,say Apple iTunes ‘Terms of Service’9. The agreement contains numerous termsthat are aimed to secure the rights and interests of the business, such as con-venient choice of law or forum, disclaimer of warranties, ownership of intel-lectual property, and, of course, the right to charge consumers for purchaseditem. The agreement also contains terms that confer rights to consumers.Primarily, the consumer acquires downloadable content for a modest price,free of defects, to be delivered in a convenient and immediate manner, to makecopies of downloads, and protection of privacy.

Under the one-way contracts regime, this contract will be enforceable whe-never iTunes has a complaint, eg, when the consumer fails to make the properpayment or makes unauthorized copies. In these situations, iTunes will be ableto apply both its legal remedies to collect damages and self-help measuresthrough digital controls. The contract will not be enforceable, however, if itis the consumer who has a complaint. If, for example, it turns out that the filewas defective or not as described and iTunes refuses to issue a replacement or arefund, the consumer would have no legal recourse. Worse, if the businessviolates its data privacy commitments and collects unauthorized personalinformation in order to sell it to marketers, again the consumer would haveno contract remedy and would not be able to sue and recover damages10.

Similarly, consider air travel transactions. Airlines would have the right tocollect the full payment for the travel from passengers, but any promise totake the passenger to the destination in the designated itinerary would not beenforceable. If an airline promises that flight 001 would land in a specificdestination, they can breach the promise and land in a different destination.None of the consequential harm to the passengers would be legally recover-able within a contract breach action.

Or, phone companies will have the right to collect timely payment for the

9 This is the ‘clickwrap’ contract users accept when they sign up to have an iTunes accountand download the software to play music or movies. It is modified from time to time. Theupdated version can be viewed at http://www.apple.com/legal/itunes/us/service.html.

10 Although the privacy violations may give rise to claims under statutory law, eg, ChildrenOnline Privacy Protection Act, 16 CFR 312.5(a)(1) (inernet privacy); and Privacy ofConsumer Financial Information, 16 CFR 313.8.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 2 9

Page 10: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

services and any termination penalty that is valid under general rules of con-tract law, but their own obligations to provide adequate uninterrupted serviceor to refrain from violation privacy concerns will be unenforceable. Banks andlenders, including credit card issuers, will have the right to collect all the feesand interest rates that they secure in the agreement, but their customers willnot have a legal right to enforce the symmetric promises to, say, pay interest ondeposits. Sellers of consumer goods (TVs, appliances, computers, etc) will havethe right to collect payment but buyers will not have a legal right to enforce theexpress and implied warranties, the return policy, low price guarantees, andthe like.

From the consumers’ perspective, in all these examples they receive an ‘exe-cutory’ promise–one that is to be performed later, after the contract is signedand some of the money is paid. Rarely would these consumers have self-helpmeasures that would completely shield them from loss. Thus, in all theseexamples, legal enforcement is the standard mechanism to safeguard the ot-herwise insecure promise consumers received for their money. One-way con-tracts eliminate this safeguard.

2 Drawing the line between business’ and consumers’ rights

But what happens if the business goes beyond its legal right and takes morethan it is entitled to? What happens if, say, the business charges more than theauthorized amounts from the consumer’s credit card–outright fraud!–and,based on the agreement, the consumer is seeking redress? Can the consumerrecover the excess charge? The right to be paid no less than $0.99 per track isiTunes’ right and it is fully enforceable, but the right not be charged more than$0.99 per track is the right of the consumer. The consumer probably shoppedaround for the preferred deal and chose this particular transaction based lar-gely on the price. Does the one-way contract bar recovery by the consumereven in a case of theft by the business?

The absence of enforceable rights for consumers does not mean lawlessness.Even in a one-sided boilerplate, the limits of the business’ rights are clearlymarked. If the business acts fraudulently and collects $99 instead of $0.99, theconsumer has a right to recover the funds in excess of its contractual obliga-tion. Restitution of $98.01 is not a contractual remedy–it is the same remedythat protects one’s property rights when they are illegally expropriated. Whet-her it is a stranger or a contractual partner that embezzled the consumer’smoney, recovery would be available.

This idea, that some consumer rights are ‘property’ rights and not merelycontractual seems reasonable, but it creates a line drawing problem: whichrights can consumers enforce by law (‘the right not to be charged more than

ERCL 3/2010230 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 11: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

$0.99 per track’) and which rights are not enforceable by law (‘receive theselected track without defects’)?

Conceptually, oneway contracts deprive consumers of any contractual reme-dy, but they leave in tact any other legal remedy that is not founded in thecontract. First, some of the anti-consumer practices employed by the businessare likely to violate consumer protection legislation, anti-fraud laws, and cri-minal laws11. Second, businesses that embezzle their clients’ assets, make un-authorized charges to their clients’ accounts, or destroy the value acquired bythe consumers are committing torts. Here, the consumers’ right to recover themoney or the property taken illegally is not contractual. Rather, it is a resti-tutionary remedy, attached to their property in rem. The consumers are notclaiming their property based on the contract. They are claiming their pro-perty based on the absence of any contractual obligation in which they agreedto part with this property.

I am drawing a distinction here between contract claims on the one hand,which would be eliminated, and all other legal claims–tort, restitution, publiclaw–which would remain in tact. This distinction is an approximation anddoes not rest on exact principles. Roughly, the idea is that non-contractualclaims can potentially be large in magnitude and thus valuable and practical tothe consumer. Even a $5 contract can give rise to large tort and property claimsagainst a misbehaving business.

3 What is a Business-to-Consumer Contract?

The Business-to-Consumer contract (“B2C”) is a transaction between a so-phisticated party on one side and an individual acting as a consumer on theother. The sophisticated party’s interest in the legal consequences of the deal gobeyond this particular transaction, since it enters a multitude of similar trans-actions with many other one-time consumers. The sophisticated party also hasthe resources to engage in legal enforcement measures. The individual on theother side does not have the same repeat game angle. It also does not have thesophistication to know for sure what its legal rights are, whether they werebreached, and to what extent would the alleged breach entitle him to legalremedies. And, above all, the individual consumer does not have the resourcesto pursue any kind of litigation enforcement strategy.

But not all transactions between consumers and business are subject to theenforcement barrier. For one, individuals sometimes enter contracts with busi-ness entities not in their capacity as consumers. An individual hiring a con-struction company to build a custom-designed house is often dealing at armslength with the business: choosing among custom bids, negotiating idiosyn-

11 See, eg, Michigan Consumer Protection Act § 3(1), MCL 445.903(1) (1976).

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 3 1

Page 12: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

cratic terms, dictating contract language, exerting bargaining power, and soforth. The stakes are high and a lawsuit is a viable strategy in cases of breach bythe business.

Thus, the B2C contract can be defined not according to the type of parties–‘Business’, ‘Consumer’–but according to the asymmetric enforcement power.It could be defined as any contract in which on one side stands a sophisticatedparty capable of pursuing legal remedies and on the other side stands anunsophisticated party unable to engage in legal enforcement. Still, in the re-mainder of this essay I will consider only asymmetric enforcement environ-ments in which a consumer interfaces with a business. It is in these environ-ments, I will argue, that consumers have protection strategies that outperformthe meek legal remedies regime.

4 Insurance Contracts

One-way contracts do not include insurance tranactions. True, insurancetransactions are some of the most extreme cases of asymmetric enforcementpower, in which giant insurance conglomerates face off against unsophistica-ted individuals. Still, there are several reasons to let these contracts remainlegally enforceable.

First, individuals are often capable of pursuing litigation against insurancecompanies because the loss to the insured is substantial, worth the cost ofsuing, and high enough to lure an attorney to take the case on a contingencyfee basis. That is, breach by the insurance occurs only when covered perilactually materializes, at which time the obligation to provide coverage hassubstantial value. Further, insurance law offers consumers enhanced recovery,including attorney fees and punitive damages, when the insurer denies claimsopportunistically. Thus, in the insurance area, consumers are more likely torecover their rights than in other generic consumer transactions.

Second, in insurance transactions the ‘product’ is the legal terms. In return forthe money it pays the insured does not get any product enjoy or any other kindof ‘performance’. It gets nothing other than a promise to make contingentpayments if some conditions occur–an elaborate ‘warranty’ term. If the insu-rance policy is legally unenforceable, the insured will be receiving nothing forits purchase. Thus, insurance contracts can remain legally enforceable becausethey do not contain the same systematic failures that other B2C contractshave12.

12 Indeed, it is instructive to note that in some consumer protections acts, the term ‘con-sumer transaction’ is defined to exclude contracts of insurance. Thus, despite the fact thatthese contracts are generally for purposes that are primarily personal or household

ERCL 3/2010232 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 13: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

5 Mutuality

Is a one-way contracts regime reconcilable with legal doctrine? The mainproblem is the conflict with the doctrine of mutuality. Under this doctrine,which is an offshoot of the requirement of consideration in Anglo-Americancontract law, parties cannot enter a contract in which one side is bound and theother side is not13. Such a scheme fails to satisfy mutuality, the contract is notenforceable, and the bound party is free from her obligation. One-way con-tracts are an extreme example of non-mutuality: the consumer is bound, thebusiness is not. Accordingly, contract law would refuse to count these con-tracts as legally enforceable.

There might be ways to overcome the problem of non-mutuality. Generally,all that is required is that the business have some obligation to the client–that itwould not have unfettered discretion to walk away from it obligations. Theobligation may be to provide notice of its decision to terminate its performan-ce14, or to be bound to perform during some minimal initial duration, or,generally, to provide some measure of value to the consumer. That said, Iam not sure how relevant is the problem of mutuality, or its technical solution,for the present study. It might be that the problem of mutuality is insurmoun-table, guaranteeing that the one-way contract regime would never be imple-mented; or it might be solved through some tinkering with the contract design.These are implementation problems. My inquiry here into the one-way con-tract module is not proposed as a blueprint for reform. Rather, this module isoffered here as a challenge to mainstream consumer protection views, whichaim to strengthen the legal remedies available to aggrieved consumers. Thebasic point is that consumer protection can be more successful if legal remediesare instead weakened. In this spirit, one-way contracts can be regarded as anideal type, which may not be legally implementable but may neverthelessexpose desirable directions for development and reform in the law.

III Real One-Way Contracts

One-way contracts are described here as a hypothetical regime, a speciesaltogether different from the existing model of two-way contracts. But in animportant sense already discussed, they are more than hypothetical. Whenconsumers’ rights to sue for legal remedies are impractical and ineffective,never invoked, one-way contracts describe an existing reality.

related, insurance is excluded. See, eg, Indiana Deceptive Consumer Sales Act § 2(a)(1);Ohio Consumer Sales Practices Act § 1345.01(A).

13 E.A. Farnsworth, Contracts (4th ed, 2004) § 3.2.14 Laclede Gas Co v Amoco Oil Co, 522 F2d 33, 37–38 (8th Cir 1975).

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 3 3

Page 14: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

An example of a sector in which consumers have no de-facto contract rights isthe supermarket transaction. There is, of course, a de-jure contract betweenthe consumer and the supermarket. So much so that contracts students werenow routinely asked to practice their command of offer-and-acceptance doct-rines by identifying the legal status of supermarket ads, store window and shelfdisplays–all as an exercise of identifying the time of contract formation. Nodoubt, a strict contract formation moment can be backed out even in a genericsupermarket purchase. But this is merely a ‘pedagogical’ contract, which hasalmost no practical traction in the real world.

Unlike many other consumer transactions, in the supermarket there is noboilerplate involved, no click ‘I Agree’, no additional term-of-service recordattached to deal, you can’t even find any contract on the store’s website15.There are almost no contract disputes on record that required court procee-dings16, no expectation damages, no express warranties, no risk-of-loss pro-blems, in short none of the staple legal issues that accompany contracts for thesale of goods. Instead, there is a deal: Pay the price and the good is yours. Somestores provide accommodations, such as an opportunity to return the goodsafter a reasonable chance to inspect it, either for money restitution of forsubstitute goods. There might be, in the background, another set of contractissues between the consumers and the remote manufacturers. Suits againstmanufacturers are not uncommon. But it is unheard of that a supermarketwould refer an aggrieved consumer to the remote manufacturer. Instead, su-permarkets offer replacement or refunds, and then deal directly with the ma-nufacturers. Are they operating as intermediaries that assure the quality of theproduct in the relationship between the consumer and the business/manu-facturer?

Some stores post signs with return policy and low price guarantees, whichwould count as a contractual obligation. But this is more common in depart-ment stores or in businesses that deal with large ticket or durable items. It isquite uncommon in supermarkets. Supermarkets probably accommodate con-sumers who make reasonable requests to return goods that are visibly non-conforming, but not because they can otherwise be sued.

To be sure, supermarkets can have substantial legal liability to consumers. Tortlaw is one source of liability, when consumers were exposed to unreasonablerisks during the shopping experience. Anti-fraud regulations create additional

15 See, eg, www.wholefoodsmarket.com, which does not contain any link to the contractthat governs the retail grocery transactions. Contrast that with the websites for otherretailers, such www.bestbuy.com or www.dell.com, each of which contains links to theretail contract.

16 I did a Lexis check of New York and Federal cases showing ‘supermarket’ or ‘grocer’ and‘breach/1 contract’ or ‘warranty’ or ‘Restatement/3 Contracts’ or ‘UCC’.

ERCL 3/2010234 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 15: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

liability, when the store engages in deceptive practices such as false advertizingor price labeling17. Antitrust law can create liability when the store’s practice isanti competitive. Food law places requirements of conformity with sanitationand safety standards that, too, can lead to administrative action. And there areprobably many additional licensing and administrative regulations that giverise to liability for violations. But one form of enforcement is missing in thisgeneric, everyday transaction: action for breach of contract. What distinguis-hes these various forms of enforcement from contract suits is the magnitude ofthe remedy and the incentive to pursue it. In tort or antitrust the harm can besubstantial. And in other areas, the absence of private incentive to sue isresolved by public enforcement.

In the end, with all these legal controls, consumers may be more or lesssatisfied with their supermarket experience, but this depends on factors likeservice, cleanliness, selection, ease of product return, and the price/qualityratio18. The quality of the ‘contract’–problems with warranties, breach, non-performance, fine print, and the like–does not feature in the measures ofsatisfaction19.

Supermarkets are not unique in operating in a de-facto one-way contractregime. Taxicabs are another example. It is telling that when a passenger hopsinto a New York or Chicago medallion cab, she immediately views the ‘Pas-senger Bill of Rights’–a list of substantial obligations that the taxi companyand its operator have to comply with to make the service better20. Whenposting the Bill of Rights, the cab company is probably conveying the follo-wing message: ‘we know you have no effective legal recourse against us, butwe nevertheless promise to make our service comply with your reasonableexpectations’. For a variety of reasons, the passenger would find it exceedinglyimpractical to recover from the cab company if any of the billed rights isbreached – if say, the cabin is dirty, the driver plays loud music, or takes along route to the destination. Indeed, in a search I conducted through theentire case law of New York, I found no breach of contract cases that weresuccessfully brought by consumers against taxi companies21.

17 FTC Regulations – Retail Food Stores Advertising and Marketing Practices, 16 CFR424.1 (defining deceptive and unfair marketing acts by food stores).

18 See, eg, D. Dusharme, ‘2007 Retailer Customer Satisfaction Survey’, available online atwww.qualitydigest.com/pdfs/2007retailsurvey.pdf.

19 Measures of the customer satisfaction in the supermarket industry include factors suchperceived quality, perceived value, customer complaints, and customer retention. See, eg,www.theacsi.org/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=147&Ite-mid=155&i=Supermarkets.

20 See New York City Taxi and Limousine Commission, Passenger Information: Taxi CabRider Bill of Rights, at www.nyc.gov/html/tlc/html/passenger/taxicab_rights.shtml.

21 I did a Lexis search for New York and federal cases with text including ‘taxi’ or ‘cab’ and‘breach/1 contract’ or ‘warranty’ or ‘Restatement/3 Contracts’ or ‘UCC’. I found seven

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 3 5

Page 16: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

What about restaurants–do consumers have a de facto contractual right againstthe restaurant, which can give rise to remedies for breach? What if the food isnot as described, in terms of ingredients or preparation? There are, to be sure,situations in which patrons are injured as a result of inadequately preparedfood and seek recovery. It is likely, though, that a combination of tort recoveryfor personal injury and administrative action by licensing bureaus can achieveall of the compensation and deterrence goals that a contract recovery would. Aconsumer right to sue on the ‘contract’ here is either inexistent or redundant–two sides of the one-way contract coin. Here too, a search though case lawrevealed a reality in which no contracts suits are ever brought22.

IV Consumer Protection Substitutes

Stripping consumers of the right to pursue legal remedies in the event ofbreach weakens their contractual entitlement and reduces its value. It can bedebated how significant this weakening would be, given that legal remedies arehard to get, but let’s assume for now that this new regime would be perceivedas bad for consumers. It would generate insecurity, which would translate intoreduced willingness to buy: lower prices to reflect the lesser value consumersget and, at the extreme, exit of consumers from markets. These are marketeffects, and it is therefore natural to ask what other market responses mightemerge to mitigate these effects? How will markets adjust to provide consu-

cases that seemed relevant, but only one that included a pure contractual claim (asopposed to veil piercing or tort)–a claim of implied warranty. The claim against thecab company was rejected. See Ruse v Inta-Boro Two-Way Radio Taxi Associates, Inc,166 AD2d 641(NY App 1990).

22 I did a Lexis search of New York and Federal cases with text including ((‘restaurant’ or‘bistro’ or ‘pizzeria’) not w/5 ‘v.’) and ((breach/1 contract) or warranty or (Restate-ment/3 Contracts) or UCC) and not CORE-TERMS(employ*) and not CORE-TERMS(labor) and not CORE-TERMS(lease) and not CORE-TERMS(insurance)and not CORE-TERMS(tenant) and not CORE-TERMS(landlord). I found many casesin which a contract warranty claim against the food provider was brought along with aclaim for recovery in tort, relating to injury from defective products. Beyond that, I onlyfound a few suits. In one, a plaintiff unsuccessfully made a breach of contract claimagainst a restaurant that had video surveillance in the restroom. Damages for emotionaldistress were awarded in tort. See Dana v Oak Park Marina, 230 AD 2d 204, 212 (1997).In another, a plaintiff sued a restaurant owner on a contract claim for failing to break up afight in which he was injured, but the suit was denied because statute of limitationapplied to the same act with respect to liability in tort. See Smith v Whit Tower Manage-ment, 129 NYS 545, 549 (NY 1954). In another suit, a plaintiff injured by consumingtoxic whiskey during the national Prohibition was denied in its tort claim because of the(then) narrow definition of sellers’ liability. A split court allowed the contractual claimfor breach of warranty despite the illegality of the contract. See Bolivar v Monnat, 232AD 33 (NY 1931).

ERCL 3/2010236 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 17: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

mers with the protections that they perceive to have lost under a one-waycontracts regime?

1 Redesigned Transaction

Consumers are likely to be concerned about putting much money on the linewhen all they get is a promise that not legally enforceable. As a result trans-actions might be designed differently, to address consumers’ anxiety abouttheir non-rights. Recognizing that they have no legal recourse, consumersmight require (and businesses might accord them) a different sequence ofpayments and commitments to reduce the magnitude of the consumers’ lossesin the event that they are cheated. One simple way to achieve this is to deferpayment till some measure of consumer satisfaction is achieved. Consumerswould be accorded a more substantial set of rights to inspect the value of thegoods or services, to reject them if they are non-conforming, all before makingany substantial payment.

To enhance consumers’ rights to inspect goods, transactions would be carvedup into small pieces, with the right for the consumers to exit in several speci-fied loci. For example, a long-term cell phone contract would be broken downto pay-as-you-go structure without any commitment, giving consumers in-creased opportunity to switch. Expensive products may be offered in ‘pie-ces’–leased rather than sold. Big-ticket items like computers and home appli-ances would be offered for rental or through a rent-to-own arrangement, withoption to terminate after specified intervals. The overall cost to consumerswould not need to rise because in equilibrium consumers will choose not toterminate–the option they would have to walk away would assure that thevalue they get is satisfactory.

The basic element of redesign is the increased domain for ‘self-help’–measuresthat consumers can take when they perceive the promise made by the businessto have been breached. The most effective self-help measure is to stop pay-ment. To make this measure safe, consumers would have the right to terminateprospectively at will but only for future performance, not for past inadequateperformance. For example, many telecommunications companies now offerservice without a fixed-term commitment. Trying to lure consumers who areweary of contractual commitments that are replete with unpleasant surprises,companies like Comcast and AT&T provide telephone and cable service thatcan be cancelled any time without penalty. It is quite telling that the marketterm for these types of agreements ‘No Contract Required’. Consumers re-ceive the desired protection with less contract, rather than more.

Not all transactions can yield to simple piece-by-piece break up or at willtermination by consumers. Cars, for example, are already offered for lease, butthe commitment required from the consumer is long, at least several years. A

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 3 7

Page 18: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

smaller commitment–car rental–is disproportionately expensive not only be-cause of the transactions costs, but largely due to asymmetric information andincentive problems. But markets can experiment with small commitments thatare not disproportionately costly. For example, many consumers rent carsfrom zipcars.com, shielded from any long term commitment, without incur-ring a disproportionate cost and with surprisingly low transaction cost.

It is quite possible that any kind of market protections that might develop tosubstitute for legal enforcement would involve some transactions costs thatwould otherwise, under a perfect legal enforcement regime, be saved. But wecan also expect that market experiments would develop with designs thatreduce the added transactions costs. In the present context, contract designsthat carve up long-term contract into pieces may introduce new switching andset up costs, but like the case of zipcars or prepaid cell phones these trans-actions costs can be cleverly minimized.

2 Private Bonds and Assurances

If a transaction is perceived to involve some risk of non-performance or for-feiture, consumers can turn to private bonds and assurances to secure theirpayment. In some limited way, retailers already provide this service. If youbuy a product at Macy’s and find it lacking in any way, you can return it to thestore with little hassle and receive a refund. Most retailers bundle the saletransaction with some form of assurance and charge an appropriate premium,depending on the generosity of the plan. Discount outlets often unbundle thetwo.

But what if the retailer itself is the irresponsive business? What guarantees cana consumer turn to? In the internet, intermediaries specializing in consumerprotection services are already budding. SquareTrade, for example, warrantsinternet purchases of electronics in a way that is relatively cheap and hasslefree23. It supplements the warranty term provided by the retailier or the ma-nufactuer (probably the most important legal right that the consumer has)with its own repair and replace warranty. Its service is easy to price and topurchase and claims are relatively easy to administer.

Other intermediaries that provide some protection immediately after the pur-chase are credit cards. These payment intermediaries provide purchasers withprotection, which goes beyond the risk of contract breach by the seller. Itcovers losses from theft or accident as well. But this coverage is also narrowerin several ways. It does not apply to items lost in the course of delivery; and itis capped by the purchase amount charged to the credit card.

23 See www.squaretrade.com/pages/learn-more-warranty-buyer.

ERCL 3/2010238 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 19: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

Credit card issuers provide purchase protection to buyer in order to inducebuyers to make purchases that they might otherwise not make, and to usethe credit card as the form of payment. Other payment intermediaries do thesame. For example, PayPal offers a Buyer Protection Plan that reimbursesbuyers for the full price and shipping costs in the event that they complaintagainst the seller is found to be meritorious24. In similar fashion, companiesthat operate market platforms can provide customers who enter their marketwith protections. As mentioned in the introduction, eBay Motors providesdisappointed buyers a fund from which they can recover the lost paymentwhen the seller defrauded them, up to $50,00025. This coverage is providedfree for most of the vehicles purchased. It can be extended also to cover thecar’s condition–the express warranty–but only if the seller opts in (and pre-sumably pays eBay to supply this added coverage). As an intermediarybetween many buyers and sellers, eBay can monitor the conduct of sellers‘on behalf’ of the buyers. It can (and does) charge sellers for the cost of thebuyer protection program, but it can differentiate the price according toseller’s record and it can expel sellers who breach their obligations, preven-ting future abuse.

It is plausible that in a one-way contracts regime, where promises would nolonger be legally enforceable, the function of such intermediaries would beexpanded. eBay, for example, could offer a buyer protection program for allpurchases, not just automobiles. Credit card issuers could offer broader gua-rantees, covering not only an extended warranty term or outright fraud, butalso various other types of non-performance.

In these situations, the intermediaries provide not only an insurance function,but also a monitoring and deterrence function. These systems work becausethe intermediaries care to protect the integrity of the market in which they areoperating, to attract as many buyers. eBay would surely kick out a seller whosepattern of performance gives rise to higher incidence of claims. Strong inter-mediaries like eBay or Visa harness their market power to warrant consumers’satisfaction. The intermediaries effectively operate as sophisticated enforce-ment agents for dispersed, unsophisticated buyers.

To be sure, the expansion of the guarantees provided by intermediaries islimited by the intermediaries’ own verification problems. Visa cannot, forexample, confirm whether the hotel room was clean enough, and eBay cannotconfirm whether the iPod was refurbished with a sub-par sound. Their ad-vantage, though, is that monitoring can be done though aggregation. As longas the intermediaries can perform some limited monitoring of individual

24 See https://www.paypal.com/us/cgi-bin/webscr?cmd=xpt/UserAgreement/ua/USUA-outside#pbp-policy.

25 See www.pages.ebay.com/help/buy/ebaymotors-protection.html#vehicles.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 3 9

Page 20: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

claims and weed out the most frivolous ones, they can credibly compare theperformance of businesses. A business that receives a higher ratio of com-plaints is underperforming relative to market averages, suggesting that buyers’expectations are collectively not met. This business will find it more difficultto compete once the coverage premium charged by the intermediaries, whoguarantee its sales, increases.

Of course, the intermediaries themselves are businesses whose obligations tothe buyers are contractual. The problem then becomes circular: without en-forceable legal rights against businesses, consumers do not acquire any legalright against the intermediaries. I will have to argue that the contractual pro-mises made by intermediaries are safe for reasons other the one discussed here.That is, the bond promises are safe not because of some other bonds that securethem or some other intermediary services. If they are safe, it must be due toother market related mechanisms, such as reputation and ratings. In this sense,the bond mechanism has only a limited role. It alone cannot provide theultimate security for contractual promises. But the presence of assurance in-termediaries does facilitate the work of other informal enforcement mecha-nisms. The bond intermediaries specialize in aggregating information aboutthe performance of the business and manage the claims of the consumers in anefficient way, providing a more solid informational basis for the application ofother enforcement mechanisms.

3 Insurance

Like any measurable risk, breach of contract is a risk that might create oppor-tunities for insurance. If the removal of legal remedies imposes greater risk onconsumers, there would be increased demand for coverage against this type ofhazard–an insurance arrangement against bad performance by the business.And if the patterns of this risk can be measured and predicted in a systematicway, insurance companies would supply this coverage.

The insurance arrangement can apply to more hazards than merely warranty-related defects or fraud. It can potentially apply to consequential losses and topersonal injuries and thus go beyond the more limited refund/repair/replaceremedy. It could also provide recovery in contingencies that technically do notconstitute breach, but are nevertheless costly to the consumer. Moreover,insurance coverage can apply even when the consumer had some contributoryfault–dropped the iPod or arrived late for the flight–losses that are usuallyexcluded under warranty plans.

Insurance can be sold per-consumer, rather than per-transaction–applying tothe entire defined class of B2C transactions that the insured would enter duringthe term of the policy. It can attach, for example, to the consumer’s homeowners’ insurance policy, as yet another covered risk–the ‘contract breach

ERCL 3/2010240 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 21: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

peril’26. Further, it is possible that insurance markets would develop new practi-ces to make coverage for the contract breach peril work. They might developsimplified procedures for filing claims and investigating their validity. Consu-mers could choose to have arrangements with their insurers to cover onlycertain types of B2C transactions (eg, all transactions over $1000), where thecosts of administering claims would not overrun the utility of the insurance.

In this environment, insurers would have a role that goes beyond passivecoverage. One obvious role is to manage the claims of the consumers andseparate the valid from the frivolous. In many areas, this verification role isprecisely the craft that insurers perform best. Medical insurance plans, forexample, are often nothing more than claim administrators (the risks are borneby employers). Insurance investigators have the best access to evidence regar-ding the merits of any individual claim ex post, better than courts and surelybetter than the consumer service department of the business who sold thecomplained-over product. And since the insurer has a significant sanctionagainst frivolous claims–increased future premia, forfeiture of other coverage–it can deter such claims better than other potential claim administrators.

Another obvious role of contract breach insurers is to efficiently underwritethe risk. Insurers have more information about the likelihood of a potentialclaim–the insured’s ‘propensity’ to file claims–because they can keep recordsof the rate of past claims by the insured, or infer this from other correlatedbehaviors. Whereas the SquareTrade warranty can, at most, aggregate infor-mation about a particular seller or product, an insurer can cross the sameinformation with each insured’s record. Moreover, insurers have an infra-structure for aggregating data across the industry, something that other assu-rance intermediaries don’t have.

Insurance can also have a deterrent effect against misbehavior by business, butthe deterrent mechanism here is a bit more subtle than either in other insurancecontexts or in the intermediary bonds case. In other insurance contexts, theinsurer is subrogated to the insured’s right against the liable party. The medicalplan or the first party auto insurance can recover their coverage outlays fromthe tort injurer. Contract breach insurers would not be able to sue bad-beha-ving businesses because the aggrieved consumers would not have any legalright to subrogate. Moreover, insurance cannot price coverage according to thebusiness-specific risk, because it is not sold per transaction. Still, insurers candeter bad behavior by business through other practices. For example, they canthreaten to blacklist any business which exhibits a record of high incidence ofclaims, refusing to insure its transactions in the future, and thus alerting con-

26 Many homeowners policies cover personal property including property not located atthe residence, and losses arising from unauthorized use of credit cards. See, eg, InsuranceServices Office HO-3 Policy, Section I Coverage C and D.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 4 1

Page 22: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

sumers and rendering the non-performance risk more salient. Insurers canwrite exclusions such as ‘this policy does not cover purchases from Gateway.’Because insurers can aggregate and share actuarial data on the non-performan-ce risk that businesses pose, these blacklists can be reliable. Or, if blacklists aredistasteful, a different practice can be to offer a menu of premia: the insurancepremium can be $400 if it applies to all purchases, and only $100 if severalexclusions apply. Insurers, for example, can provide a list of businesses withwhom the contracts are fully insured, and apply a significant deductible or capto contract breaches with any business not on the list.

It is not my intention here to go through all possible contours of the contractbreach insurance arrangement. The point is more general. Insurance is notonly a mechanism for spreading risk. Importantly, it is often an efficient in-stitution for handling and verifying claims, administering them, pricing them,and creating accurate deterrence. Currently, insurance companies have no rolein administering consumer claims for contract breach. Rather than relying onthe legal system to clumsily micro-manage such claims, private insurancemarkets can provide an alternative platform.

4 Ratings

When deciding whether to enter a transaction with a business, individualswould care more about their legal ‘exposure’–how likely they are to be af-fected by the absence of remedies for breach. They would have a greater needto predict the degree of overall satisfaction that they will obtain, in light of theprice charged, and relative to other transactions offered by other businesses.Knowing that there are no legal remedies, consumers would have a greatermotivation to know how likely is breach to occur, or when it does, the extentto which the business will redress their dissatisfaction. They would thereforeturn to find out how satisfactory was the experience of previous consumerswho dealt with this business in this type of transaction. Indeed, basing theprediction on the experience of strangers is more reliable than basing it onpainstaking research or reading legal documents27.

Ratings of the features of the transaction is a deep-rooted market practice thatallows consumers to conduct price/satisfactions predictions. For example,when reserving a hotel online, Expedia.Com and other reservations servicesrate each hotel on the basis of average customer reviews along several attri-butes (cleanliness, service, comfort). When deciding how to vote for a senator,voters can check how the candidate is rated by the Environmental DefenseFund or the NRA. When choosing a restaurant, Zagat and other review net-works provide a score and a simple breakdown of features that reflect the

27 See, generally, D. Gilbert, Stumbling on Happiness (2007).

ERCL 3/2010242 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 23: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

quality of the establishment relative to its cohort. When buying a new car,Consumer Reports provides a variety of ratings of performance, safety, dura-bility, as well as overall recommendations. And various intermediaries provideratings that help shoppers predict the quality of the goods sold and theirreliability. For example, eBay uses a well-known feedback rating of each seller,showing the number of prior sales, the percentage of satisfied customers, andits score over several dimensions of satisfaction. In fact, it is hard to think ofmarket transactions that are not subject to consumer or expert ratings: movies,restaurants, music, new books, used books sellers, blenders, pizzas, coffee,dentists, even the teaching ratings of professors.

In a one-way contracts regime, consumers will have to rely even more on theperformance reputation of businesses and less on their promises. Thus, theability of a business to attract new customers and to charge higher priceswould depend all the more on the reliability of feedback scores, ratings, con-sumer surveys, reports by watchdog groups–that is, on the aggregate measuresof the scattered experiences of past customers and experts.

These rating scores aggregate some, but not all aspects of the transaction withthe business. Averages might not capture the subtleties. Still, individuals whoare not interested in spending the time to study the details can rely on theratings to chaperone them through the comparison shopping process. Theiradvantage is that they put weight on those aspects that average consumers andusers actually care about most, the factors that predict the ex-post degree ofsatisfaction. Moreover, techniques that provide relevant and reliable aggrega-tions are likely flourish. It is imaginable that a finer breakdown of aspects canbe offered, including for example a rating of the ‘contract’ or of the ‘legal’experience–the quality of the boilerplate terms once they are brought to bearon the transaction. How good is the warranty and repair service? How diffi-cult it is to return the goods for replacement, repair, or refund? How effecti-vely did the vendor respond to problems with the service? Were there hiddenfees and surprising burdens originating from the fine print? Were there res-trictions–legal or digital–on the types of permitted uses? To the extent thatconsumers want to know these issues in advance, ratings can provide such ofinformation28.

Ratings and similar reputation scores have become all the more important inelectronic commerce, and the inner works of rating schemes have been per-fected by successful web services like eBay, Amazon, and Expedia. Internetcommerce relies so heavily on ratings precisely because standard remedies forbreach are significantly weaker in internet transactions. Businesses are remote,unfamiliar, small, under-capitalized, sometimes deal in used or refurbishedgoods, and offer significant discounts–all are factors that normally increase

28 For discussion of some issues related to ratings of contracts, see Ben-Shahar, supra n 1, 1.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 4 3

Page 24: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

consumers’ apprehension and require extra assurances. Remedies for breach ofcontract in these settings are extremely weak. There is nothing much the lawcan do to help a consumer defrauded by a fly-by-night business. Contractshere are perceived to be one-way not by legal design but by practical con-straints. It is quite telling, therefore, that the pragmatic decline of traditionallegal remedies went hand-in-hand with the phenomenal rise of ratings andreputation scores.

Indeed, the power of each consumer to post a negative feedback providespowerful deterrence. Consumers can provide accounts of their experience,highlighting horror stories, to alert future users. While this provides little orno redress (once the negative feedback is posted, it is often difficult to undoand thus businesses have no incentive to remedy the particular complaint), itprovides significant deterrence. For one, the effect on future business fromconsumers who are exposed to the negative rating could be more painful than alegal remedy for breach. More importantly, these ratings are very easy to postand thus the threat to inflict then on a misbehaving business is far morecredible than the threat of an aggrieved consumer to file suit.

5 Voluntary Accommodations

The mechanisms discussed thus far suggest that businesses’ obligations, whilelegally unenforceable, could nevertheless be largely complied with even in aregime of one-way contracts. But it is possible that legal non-enforceabilitywill nurture compliance beyond the letter of the promise. Businesses may beready to accord their customers more accommodations, to go beyond thecontractual language, to forgive immaterial burdens and fees, in short, to pro-vide consumers with value that exceeds what was literally promised29. Suchconduct would be intended to infuse consumer confidence especially amongthe otherwise reluctant consumers who, themselves without enforceable con-tractual rights, are rationally anxious. Thus, ironically, the absence of enforce-able contractual rights could boost the bottom line average satisfaction thatconsumers get, all else equal.

Their obligations being unenforceable, businesses don’t have to grant anyvalue to consumers, and certainly don’t have to grant any voluntary accom-modation. But they can do so selectively. Consumers who are regarded by thebusiness as honest or as source for continued profit, or who are regarded aslikely to leave a positive feedback that would affect the business’ rating if

29 For an analysis of how and why businesses already go beyond the contract language andaccord consumers accommodations, see L.A. Bebchuk and R.A. Posner, ‘One-SidedContracts in Competitive Consumer Markets’, in Ben-Shahar (ed), supra n 6, 3–11;J.S. Johnston, ‘Cooperative Negotiations in the Shadow of Boilerplate’, in Ben-Shahar(ed), supra n 6, 12–28.

ERCL 3/2010244 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 25: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

treated well and negative feedback otherwise, would be treated to more ac-commodations than consumers who are suspected of cheating or chiseling, orwhose further business is no longer sought. Thus, in a one-way contractregime, given that businesses can easily ‘stick it’ to some consumers, a greaterwedge can be created between the values received by desired versus undesiredconsumers.

Of course, this ability to selectively abuse some consumers is troublesome,and hopefully the mechanisms discussed above diminish such potential. Butthe upside–the ability to accommodate ‘good’ consumers–can be an importantsource value.

V Why Are One-Way Contracts Necessary

The substitute protection devices described above may very well arise in theabsence of contract enforcement, but would they not also arise in the presenceof contract enforcement? Aren’t these devices–fragmented transactions, insu-rance services and purchase protection plans, ratings, consumer protectionacts–already available, alongside contract enforcement? Is it necessary totransform contracts into a one-way module to attain the benefit of the variousalternative protection devices? If one-way contracts benefit both business andconsumers, why do parties not opt into such a regime voluntarily, writingcontracts with minimal legal protections for consumers?

To be sure, some of the alternative protection devices are emerging side-by-side with the (de jure) availability of contract remedies. And yet we don’t see,for example, an insurance product for the contract breach peril. Consumersare not willing to pay for an assurance that is perceived to merely replicate theassurance they receive from the business (say, double up a new product war-ranty). That is, despite the fact that contract promises made by businesses arealmost impossible to legally enforce, many individuals maintain a potentiallyfalse sense of security in the knowledge that they are contractually protected,and are unwilling to buy additional insurance (other than warranty extensionprograms). Most consumers have not tried to sue businesses or to pursue legalremedies for breach and thus have not experienced the futility of this strategy.For them, having an enforceable contract creates a perception of security thatmakes other protections seem less necessary.

While this false perception of security can be irrational, it may also have arational foundation, which explains why it persists and why the alternativeprotection devices are slow to emerge. Even in the absence of a credible threatto sue, breach of contract is an infrequent event. The great majority of con-sumer transactions are adequately performed by business. The great majorityof products and services consumers purchase live up to the expectation. Even if

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 4 5

Page 26: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

consumers interpret episodes of non-performance as indication of the wea-kness of contract, these may be offset by the inverse interpretation of morenumerous episodes of adequate, or above-expectation performance. In short,it is difficult to generate an accurate assessment of low probability events.

There are additional, more subtle reasons why the alternative protections areslower to develop in a two-way contract world. One reason is asymmetricinformation. If a business were to direct consumers to alternative protectionssuch as insurance, warranty services, and ratings, this could be taken as a signalby consumers that there are greater-than-otherwise-perceived grounds forinsecurity. Why else would the business promote, or refer to, other protecti-ons? That is, all else equal, the protections are more necessary the weaker thecontractual commitment, or the greater the propensity to breach. Since thebusiness has private information about this propensity, the endorsement ofsuch protections would lead to a negative inference by consumers about thisinformation. In this setting, efficient protective devices will not be promotedby the business. It is still possible that they will be developed by third parties,but without the bundling of these assurance services with the purchase itself,such devices would impose added transactions costs and will be slower todevelop.

Indeed, on eBay, where the value of legal remedies for breach of contract isknown to be low, vendors openly refer buyers to their rating scores, to assu-rance program like SquareTrade, to non-legal dispute resolution services, andother protections. Here, there is no asymmetric information: consumers knowthat the value of legal remedies for breach is negligible. Businesses who ack-nowledge this fact by highlighting the presence of other protections do notsuffer a penalty in the form of reduced willingness to pay. In contrast, whenselling insurance policies, car leases, or cellphone calling plans, the vendorsemphasize the policy and the legal terms, and do not refer the customers toconsumer satisfaction ratings or other assurances.

This is an unraveling problem. Another way to think about it is the following.Suppose the market developed a new insurance instrument–the contract bre-ach hazard policy, and would price it in accordance with the actuarial risk thatdifferent businesses pose. The business would then have an incentive to inducethe consumer not to purchase this insurance, by providing it in-house, bundledwith the primary consumer transaction (in the same way that stores offerextended warranty programs). Even if the business knows that there is a sub-stantial likelihood of breach, it would offer the consumer discounted or ‘free’insurance, in attempt to signal quality and boost product price. The businesswould have an incentive to underprice this component, because it increases thewillingness of the consumer to enter and to pay for the primary transaction.Thus, in a world of two-way contracts, the threat by the business to appro-priate the insurance component of the service undermines the emergence of

ERCL 3/2010246 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 27: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

such independent insurance products. This problem would not arise in a one-way contract regime because consumers–having no legal remedies to fall backon–would not be willing to rely solely on the business’ unenforceable con-tractual promise.

One-way contracts could strengthen the alternative consumer protections foranother reason, by refocusing social controls and reforms. Currently, much ofthe consumer advocacy effort is directed at improving the legal terms associa-ted with contract, the opportunity of consumers to read the fine print incontracts, the access of consumers to courts, and the legal remedies availableagainst a breaching business. For example, the two main proposals made in theALI’s Principles of Software Contracts, which represent the latest effort toprotect the rights of consumer-users against software vendors, are (1) to pro-vide users with a ‘robust’ opportunity to read the terms upfront30, and (2) tostrengthen or make mandatory some warranties31. Or, to take another pro-minent example, it is often argued–and held by courts–that mandatory arbi-tration terms ought not be enforced because they deprive consumers thepower to file private suits, vindicate their contractual rights and breach reme-dies in court32. Similar agenda is pursued by the European Community, focu-sing on sharpening the legal remedies available to consumers in private law33.

If one thinks that these reforms would help many consumers, then the one-way contracts regime ought to be rejected. One-way contracts do not streng-then private suits but eliminate them. My own view is that these legal rightswould do far too little to help. Improving the consumers’ opportunity to readwould help very few potential readers (estimated at far less than 1% of thepopulation of consumers)34. Providing mandatory quality and striking arbi-tration terms would help very few potential litigants, the sophisticated oneswho can secure legal representation in adjudication.

The one-way contracts regime suggests, instead, that efforts should be redi-rected towards improving the availability of effective ratings, reducing trans-actions costs for redesigned deals which give consumers more choice and more

30 American Law Institute, Principles of the Law of Software Contracts § 2.01 and com-ment c (Discussion Draft, March 30, 2007).

31 American Law Institute, Principles of the Law of Software Contracts § 3.02 (DiscussionDraft, March 30, 2007).

32 Armendariz v Foundation Health Psychcare, 6 P3d 669, 689-90 (Cal 2000).33 Counsel Directive 99/44, OJEC 1999 L171/12 (remedies); Directive 2001/95 (trans-

parency). See, generally, S. Weatherill, EU Consumer Law and Policy (2005).34 F. Marotta-Wurgler, ‘Are “Pay Now, Terms Later” Contracts Worse for Buyers? Evi-

dence from Software License Agreements’, 38 J Legal Stud (2009); Y. Bakos,F. Marotta-Wurgler, and D.R. Trossen, Does Anyone Read the Fine Print? Testing aLaw and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts (Mimeo: 2009). See, generally,Ben-Shahar, supra n 1.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 4 7

Page 28: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

ways out, creating easy-to-use insurance products, improving platforms forreputation to develop, and the like. Rather than provide an opportunity to readfor consumers who would never utilize this opportunity, or provide a theo-retical opportunity to sue for consumers who are exceedingly unlikely topursue this strategy (or gain any meaningful compensation through it), con-sumer protection would follow a different path. Thus, the value of one-waycontracts regime would be to shift reform effort to areas where it wouldactually help.

VI Conclusion

It is well recognized that consumers’ well being depends on factors other thanthe protection afforded to them by private law. I am surely not the first toargue that other safeguards are important. My purpose here was to go beyondsome of the age-old truths, eg, that competition among businesses or thateducation of consumers and disclosure of information can help bolster theintegrity of consumer transactions and improve consumer satisfaction. I high-lighted some additional devices, independent of competition and disclosure,which can substitute for legal protection of consumers.

The claim in the paper, though, is more ambitious than merely identifyingseveral substitutes for contract enforcement. After all, the fact that substitutesexist is not a reason to eliminate of one of the devices, however ineffective itmight be. Instead, I argue that consumers can benefit from the elimination ofthe contract enforcement device. It is in the interest of consumers, I argued, totransact within a legal regime that strips them of the power to seek contractremedies for breach, while at the same time reserving the business side’s powerto enforce contracts. The removal of one protection device would strengthenthe other devices and would render consumer protection more robust overall.

There is a sense in which the one-way contracts idea is merely a thoughtexperiment. For one, I conceded up front that as a pure doctrinal move it islikely to be a non-starter, conflicting with very basic notions of contract law.One-way contracts are not contracts: in law, either both parties are bound, ornone are bound–this is a fundamental corollary of the consideration doctrine.Further, the arguments developed here are exploratory in nature. I have notmeasured, neither analytically nor empirically, how much protection would belost and how much would be gained by the removal of contract enforcement. Ihave also not proved, in any rigorous manner, that the alternative protectiondevices would indeed develop faster in the absence of contract enforcement.Some anecdotes might suggest that much, but they are subject to variouspossible interpretations, not all consistent with the logic of one-way contracts.Indeed, I left some of the boundaries as to what are B2C contracts vague,precisely because the value of the contract enforcement device can vary.

ERCL 3/2010248 O m r i B e n - S h a h a r

Page 29: BEN-SAHAR, O. One-way Contracts.pdf

There is a payoff to such thought experiment even if it does not lend itself toimmediate law reform, because it sheds light on which factors matter when wetalk about consumer protection. As I remarked in the Introduction, the paperis meant to be friendly to the interests of consumers. But it’s a different versionof friendliness. Rather than paying lip service to consumers’ ‘vindication ofrights’, ‘access to justice’ or proposing make-believe solutions like mandatorydisclosure, the paper takes the reality of non-enforcement as given and con-siders ways to overcome it. It is the cultivation of more potent substitutes thatcan help consumers.

So, in the end, it might be that the law will not relinquish consumers’ right tolegally enforce their contracts. The message, though, remains. The way to helpconsumers is not to secure their rights to go to courts and get ‘meaningful’legal remedies. The one-way contract idea suggests that this is a misguidedpriority. Consumer protection ought to be accomplished by focusing on al-ternative protection devices.

ERCL 3/2010 O n e - Wa y C o n t r a c t s : C o n s u m e r P ro t e c t i o n w i t h o u t L a w 2 4 9