Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

download Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

of 41

Transcript of Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    1/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 1Running Head: BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND HAPPINESS

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness: Can the former impact the latter?

    Scott Thor

    George Fox University

    Edited Using APA 5th Edition

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    2/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 2Abstract

    The field of economics has progressed significantly over the last several centuries,

    beginning with its establishment as a separate discipline by Smith in the 1700s, and

    evolving more recently into numerous sub disciplines such as behavioral and happiness

    economics. The field of psychology was yet to be established during the birth of

    economics, but an argument can be made that early economic scholars did not exclude

    psychological factors into their thoughts on the subject. A gradual transition to a purely

    quantitative approach emerged as the discipline progressed, and psychological factors

    were considered irrelevant in the economic models that assume individuals always act

    rationally. Recently, a transition has begun to take place suggesting irrational behavior

    cannot be ignored, which has led to the field of behavioral economics discussed in this

    paper. Behavioral economists argue that a greater understanding of irrational behavior

    may lead to advancements in the field of economics. This paper also argues that by

    increasing the understanding of irrational behavior we may also uncover opportunities to

    increase happiness. Happiness economics has emerged as a sub discipline of

    economics over the last several decades and seeks to understand what makes us

    happy. This paper also provides a historical overview in the study of happiness, and

    offers suggestions on how behavioral economic theory may help increase levels of

    happiness. The paper also explores the historical influences in both fields of study. A

    final discussion point includes criticisms of behavioral and happiness economics by

    many researchers and scholars who suggest the experimental and subjective nature of

    both adds little value to economic thinking.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    3/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 3Introduction

    Little argument is needed to suggest that increasing happiness is a worthy

    endeavor. We all strive to live a life in which we seek happiness through a variety of

    means. Even the founding fathers of the U.S., who included the pursuit of happiness in

    the Declaration of Independence, believed happiness was, and one could argue still is,

    a critical element to the foundation of the country. The challenge then becomes

    understanding what makes us happy, and how we position ourselves to maximize

    opportunities to create happiness.The field of economics provides one potential source in understanding both how

    to improve happiness, and the potential discovery of factors contributing to increasing

    levels of happiness. The evolution of economics has progressed significantly since

    Smith helped to establish the discipline in the 1700s. Over the past several centuries

    the field of economics has evolved, transitioning from a study in which psychological

    factors were once considered, to a primarily quantitative approach, placing a heavy

    emphasis on rational behavior represented by statistical models (Camerer &

    Loewenstein, 2004).

    The pursuit of perfection in the quantitative models used by economists make the

    assumption that individuals always act in a rational manner, and have all available

    information needed to make a correct decision when faced with several choices. Two

    psychologists, Tversky and Kahneman (1974), argue that individuals do not always act

    rationally, and often rely on a number of heuristics that sometimes lead to systematic

    errors when faced with making a decision. If the arguments made by Tversky and

    Kahneman are valid, as many modern economists believe (Ariely, 2008, 2009; Camerer

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    4/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 4& Loewenstein, 2004; Tideman, 2005), the foundation of rational thinking represented in

    economic models may not be as accurate as once thought. The early work done by

    Tversky and Kahneman gave rise to what has become the economic sub discipline of

    behavioral economics.

    Camerer and Loewenstein (2004) describe behavioral economics as a way to

    increase the explanatory power of economics by providing it with more realistic

    psychological foundations (p. 3). The authors argue that behavioral economics

    provides a means for generating additional economic insights, which result in better

    predictions of field phenomena, ultimately leading to better policies. Camerer and

    Loewenstein suggest that behavioral economics is not meant to replace the

    neoclassical approach, but does provide a basis on which to add to the foundations of

    economic thought rooted in the neoclassical perspective.During the same time in which behavioral economics was emerging as a sub

    discipline of economics so to was the study of individual happiness. This research

    would eventually lead to the development of another sub discipline of economics

    described as happiness economics. Graham (2009) defines happiness economics as

    an approach to assessing welfare which combines the techniques typically used by

    economists with those more commonly used by psychologists (p. 6). Stated in more

    general terms, happiness economics can be described as a combination of psychology

    and economic techniques for better understanding a societys level of happiness

    through quantitative analysis, typically assessed by individual surveys.Easterlin (1974) conducted what has become seminal work in the field of

    happiness economics that led to the development of the Easterlin Paradox (Graham,

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    5/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 52009, p. 12), which argues that within a society the rich are happier than the poor, rich

    societies tend to not be happier than poor societies once basic needs are met, and as

    countries become wealthier they do not get happier. Since Easterlins early work, the

    field has emerged into an exciting body of research that has uncovered several

    elements that have been argued to have a relationship with levels of happiness. The primary focus of this paper is to explore behavioral and happiness

    economics. The paper provides a historical overview and detailed discussion describing

    the evolution of behavioral and happiness economics. Both fields of study are not

    without critics, and discussions on the criticisms of both economic perspectives are also

    reviewed. A final aspect to the paper is a discussion into whether or not the possibility

    behavioral economic thinking may have a positive impact on increasing happiness.

    Behavioral EconomicsCamerer (2006) describes economics as a collection of ideas and conventions

    which economists accept and use to reason with. Namely, its a culture (p. 2).

    Behavioral economics, as Camerer states, represents a change in that culture (p. 2).

    One could argue the field of economics has been in a constant state of change since it

    emerged as a separate discipline in the 1700s, but the rise of behavioral economics

    over the past few decades may represent one of the most radical changes in economic

    theory since classical economic thinking emerged.

    Defining Behavioral EconomicsNo standard definition of behavioral economics exists, but several researchers,

    scholars, and authors have offered their perspectives on defining the developing body

    of knowledge. Mullainathan and Thaler (2000) describe behavioral economics as a

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    6/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 6combination of psychology and economics that seeks to understand what happens

    when individuals within a market display human limitations and complications. Diamond

    and Vartiainen (2007) suggest behavioral economics is an umbrella of approaches (p.

    1) that seeks to build on the conventional economic framework to account for human

    behavior not modeled into traditional economic designs. Angner and Loewenstein

    (2007) reinforce the aforementioned descriptions, adding the emphasis that behavioral

    economics provides a means for improving the explanatory and predictive power within

    economic thinking. Thus, behavioral economics can be summarized as a melding of

    psychology, sociology, and economics that provides an approach to better

    understanding why individuals make decisions, that in the view of traditional economic

    thinking, are irrational.

    The Need for and Benefits of Behavioral EconomicsWhy is behavioral economics a worthy endeavor? What benefits can be derived

    from a better understanding into why individuals make decisions that are not based on

    rational thought? Behavioral economists offer several answers and arguments to these

    questions, most of which suggest that behavioral economics fills a critical gap left void

    by conventional economic thinking.

    Mullainathan and Thaler (2000) argue that conventional, or neoclassical,

    economic thinking views the world as being populated by unemotional, calculating

    maximizers known as Homo Economicus (p. 3). The Homo Economicus, what Thaler

    and Sunstein (2009) describe as economic man (p. 6), suggests we all think and make

    choices without mistakes. This view of economics argues for an anti-behavioral

    (Mullainathan &Thaler, p. 3) perspective long considered a cornerstone in neoclassical

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    7/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 7economics. Mullainathan and Thaler suggest that neoclassical economists who argue

    that markets will wipe out irrational behavior are optimistic. They argue that based on

    recent empirical and experimental research, behavioral economists suggest the power

    of irrational behavior cannot be eliminated based on what neoclassical economists

    believe is a self-correcting invisible hand (Mankiw, 2008, p. 10) described by Smith as

    the forces of supply and demand, self-interest, and competition.Behavioral economics, argue Camerer and Loewenstein (2004), also offers an

    opportunity to create better policy. An argument can be made that if individuals

    frequently make irrational acts, by better understanding this behavior economists have

    the potential to improve not only markets, but also society as a whole. Mullainathan and

    Thaler (2000) provide a summation to the need and benefits of behavioral economic

    research, which they describe in two key elements. First, the field of research identifies

    ways in which actual behavior differs from the standard models, and second, behavioral

    economics illustrates how this behavior matters to the economic environment. Evolution of Behavioral Economic Thinking

    An argument can be made that behavioral economics was born out of research

    grounded in the field of cognitive psychology. Tversky and Kahneman (1974), both

    psychologists, are widely recognized as providing the impetus for which a number of

    behavioral economic concepts and theories are based upon (Angner & Loewenstein,

    2007; Camerer & Lowenstein, 2004; Diamond & Vartiainen, 2007). The psychologists

    suggest individuals are biased in their judgments and often rely on a series of heuristics,

    often described as rules of thumb (Mullainathan & Thaler, p. 5), which can lead to

    systematic errors in judgment. Kahneman and Tversky (1979) have also challenged

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    8/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 8expected utility theory, which argues that decision makers choose between uncertain or

    risky prospects by comparing their expected utility values (Davis, Hands, & Maki, 1998),

    with a theory of their own which they define as prospect theory. Prospect theory can be

    described as a theory that tries to model decisions an individual makes in real life

    situations, unlike expected utility theory which models the optimal decision (Kahneman

    & Tversky, 1979).

    In their early work Tversky and Kahneman (1974) describe three heuristics that

    include representativeness, availability, and adjustment and anchoring. The researchers

    argue that individuals rely on heuristics as a means to reduce complicated tasks of

    predicting values and assessing probabilities into simple judgment activities. Tversky

    and Kahneman believe heuristics can be useful in making decisions, but can also lead

    to choices conventional economists, and perhaps people in general, would judge to be

    irrational.The representativeness heuristic is a means to which individuals make a decision

    or prediction based on the probability of comparable known events and/or objects. For

    example, if Scott is described as a quiet intellectual who is a superlative academic

    writer that is well read in the subject of economics, when asked for the probability of his

    occupation as that of a consultant or an economist, one is likely to believe the

    description is more representative of the latter than the former, even though it is quite

    possible he could be a consultant. Similarity, or representativeness, Tversky and

    Kahneman (1974) argue, leads to errors because neither is influenced by the factors

    that should be used to assess probabilities for making judgments.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    9/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 9Representativeness, Tversky and Kahneman (1974) posit, leads to a number of

    systematic mistakes that include insensitivity to prior probability of outcomes, sample

    size, and predictability. In experiments conducted by the researchers in which they

    asked participants to determine the probability about an individuals occupation based

    on a description of the person, such as the previous one about Scott, in addition to the

    statistical composition of the sample group from which the person was drawn (i.e. 30

    economists and 70 consultants), participants ignored the statistics, which suggest a .3

    chance Scott is an economist and a .7 chance he is a consultant, and instead based

    their decision on the description of Scott. Participants did, however, make correct

    probabilities when given only statistical data related to the composition of the group.

    This, argue Tversky and Kahneman, demonstrates that when given irrelevant

    information prior probabilities are ignored, but when given no specific evidence such as

    a description, prior probabilities are correctly utilized.

    The researchers found similar conclusions related to sample size in which the

    judgments of participants failed to appreciate the need to evaluate sample size when

    making decisions. Tversky and Kahneman also uncovered insensitivities to predictability

    related to predictions such as the future value of a stock. Through their experimentation

    the researchers found that participants based the value of a stock differently for two

    companies when only descriptive data was given for each, which should have led to

    equal values for each company since descriptive data has no relation to stock price or

    profitability.The availability heuristic, argue Tversky and Kahneman (1974), is based on the

    theory that the frequency of a phenomenon or the probability of an event that a person

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    10/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 10has foremost in their mind will lead to mistakes in judgment. For example, the risk of

    becoming diabetic by men over the age of forty may be assessed by recalling the

    number of acquaintances one has to such individuals. The researchers also argue the

    availability heuristic can lead to biases due to the retrievability of instances, such as the

    belief that the likelihood of a car accident is higher after driving by an accident. Even

    though the chances for an accident have not changed, after witnessing an accident

    individuals are more likely to believe the odds of being involved in one are higher.

    Tversky and Kahneman suggest that individuals place a higher probability of an event

    happening when it is foremost in their memory, which can lead to errors in judgment.

    The final heuristic offered by Tversky and Kahneman (1974) is the belief that

    when given a starting point individuals tend to make judgments based on that point

    even though it may have no relationship with making a rational decision. The

    researchers define this heuristic as adjusting and anchoring. Ariely (2008) recently

    conducted a series of experiments based upon the anchoring heuristic in which

    participants were asked to bid on a number of items. Before bidding on the items, which

    included an assortment of electronics, books, food, and wine, participants were asked to

    write the last two digits of their Social Security number in the upper corner of their bid

    sheet. The participants then wrote this same number next to each item listed on their

    bid sheet, and then answered with a yes or no whether they would pay that amount for

    the item. For example, if the last two digits of a participants Social Security number

    were 62 would they pay 62 dollars for a bottle of 1996 Hermitage wine, or would they

    pay 62 dollars for a cordless keyboard? Ariely, as would Tversky and Kahneman,

    argues that a rational person should not be influenced by the Social Security number

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    11/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 11and should bid on the items based on their actual value. The results of the experiment

    reveal a drastically different result. Ariely discovered that participants with higher Social

    Security numbers outbid those with lower numbers. The researcher also demonstrated

    a statistically significant correlation between a participants Social Security number and

    the bid price for each item, suggesting arbitrary information has the potential to distort

    the decision making process.Emanating from their work with heuristics, Kahneman and Tversky (1979) sought

    to develop a theory to better predict decision making under risk. In contrast to expected

    utility theory that had previously dominated analysis of decision making under risk,

    Kahneman and Tversky propose an alternative theory, which they label prospect theory.

    Prior to their work, expected utility theory was generally accepted as the normative

    model of rational choice (Keeney & Raiffa, 1976), and was widely applied as the

    descriptive model of economic behavior (Arrow, 1971; Friedman & Savage, 1948). This

    led to the belief that individuals usually act in a rational manner, modeled in the

    expected utility theory.In prospect theory Kahneman and Tversky (1979) challenge expected utility

    theory, suggesting people tend to outweigh probable outcomes in comparison to

    outcomes that are most certain. The researchers describe this as the certainty effect,

    which contributes to avoiding risks in decisions that lead to sure gains, and taking

    unnecessary risks in decisions that lead to sure losses. Kahneman and Tversky also

    believe that individuals eliminate elements that are common to all prospects, which they

    argue leads to inconsistent preferences when the same options are presented in

    different forms. They describe this as the isolation effect. In their theory Kahneman and

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    12/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 12Tversky assign values to gains and losses instead of the asset, and probabilities are

    replaced by decision weights. The result is what the researchers call the value function

    illustrated in Figure 1. In the value function the curve is typically concave for gains and

    convex for losses, and has a steeper slope for losses than for gains, suggesting a

    decrease in sensitivity for gains and losses the larger they are, and the further they lie

    from the reference point.

    Figure 1. The value function suggests individuals assign greater value to losses than

    they do to gains. From Wikipedia (n.d.). Prospect theory. Retrieved November 29, 2010

    from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Valuefun.jpgThe value function can be described by the concept of loss aversion, which

    argues that individuals would rather avoid losses to increasing gains (Kahneman,

    Knetsch, & Thaler, 1991). Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler conducted experiments with

    Cornell University students that illustrate the loss aversion concept in which some

    students were given coffee mugs and others were not. The students were then given

    the opportunity to either sell or buy mugs from each other. What the researchers

    discovered was that many of those with mugs were reluctant to sell them, suggesting a

    greater loss of utility outweighs the increase in utility from either selling or purchasing a

    mug, respectively.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    13/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 13Several other concepts have evolved from the foundational work conducted by

    Kahneman and Tversky that include fairness, self-serving bias, and present bias.

    McDonald (2008) describes fairness as a false assumption by conventional economists

    who believe individuals are only interested in the volume of goods and services they get

    to consume, which behavioral economists believe to be inconsistent with human

    behavior. A number of experiments have challenged the notion of fairness, most notably

    the ultimatum experiment. In this experiment one person plays the role of proposer and

    the other of responder. The proposer is given an amount of money to divide between

    the two, which is done if the responder agrees to the proposed share. If the responder

    does not agree neither participant receives any money. In most experiments proposers

    offer on average 40 percent of the money, which is usually accepted, and in cases

    where the offer is less than 20 percent the offer is typically rejected (McDonald). This,

    argued by behavioral economists, is in contrast to what conventional economics would

    suggest.The self serving bias is demonstrated through surveys in which 90 percent of

    people place themselves in the top 50 percent of managerial skills, driving ability,

    health, productivity, and ethics (McDonald, 2008). Clearly many of them are wrong

    since only 50 percent can be in the top 50 percent. Present bias contradicts

    conventional economic thinking that assumes individuals discount the future using the

    rate of time preference, but experimental research suggests people tend to place more

    emphasis on the present, which may lead to bad decisions (McDonald). Some

    examples include saving too little for retirement and eating an unhealthy diet.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    14/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 14The early work conducted by Tversky, Kahneman, and several others helped to

    establish a consistent methodology that has continued to be the basis for much of the

    contemporary work in behavioral economics. Camerer and Loewenstein (2004)

    describe this pattern of research consisting of four steps that include evaluating

    normative assumptions used by economists, identifying anomalies in the assumptions,

    creating alternative theories that address the anomalies, concluding with the

    development of new theories and models that can be tested. While the majority or early

    behavioral economic research focused on laboratory experiments, recent work has

    evolved into field research, computer simulation, and a new emerging field of

    neuroeconomics that may offer new insights into decision making through the use of

    brain scans.

    Historical InfluencesDespite the recent popularity in the field of behavioral economics, an argument

    could be made that many of the thoughts in which the subject is based can be found in

    work conducted throughout the classical and neoclassical periods. Psychological

    themes are abundant in the work of many early economists, but the drive to develop the

    perfect economic model, and the advancement of statistical analysis capabilities, drove

    the field of study away from a mixture of qualitative and quantitative analysis to a purely

    mathematical approach (Camerer & Loewenstein, 2004). Several prominent economists

    even suggested psychology had no part in the study of economics, pushing the subjects

    even further apart. Perhaps the most vocal was Robbins (1932) who stated:

    Why the human animal attaches particular value in this behaviouristic

    sense to particular things is a question, which we do not discuss. That

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    15/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 15may be quite properly a question for psychologists or perhaps even

    physiologists. All that we need to assume is the obvious fact that different

    possibilities offer different stimuli to behavior, and that these stimuli can be

    arranged in order of their intensity. (p. 86)

    With a clear link between psychology and economics developing with the

    behavioral economic movement, contemporary economic researchers have begun

    looking back to early influences that include the work of Smith and Keynes (Angner &

    Loewenstein, 2007; Ashraf, Camerer, & Loewenstein, 2005; Camerer & Loewenstein,

    2004; Pech & Milan, 2009).

    Ashraf, Camerer, and Loewenstein (2005) explore passions and the impartial

    spectator (p. 131) Smith wrote about in his early work. The researchers describe

    passions as hunger, sex, emotion, fear, and pain, and the impartial spectator as a moral

    third person looking over an individuals shoulder. Ashraf et al. argue that Smith

    believed the impartial spectator could be led astray by emotions. The researchers quote

    Smith (1759/2007) who states:There are some situations which bear so hard upon human nature that the

    greatest degree of self-governmentis not able to stifle, altogether, the

    voice of human weakness, or reduce the violence of the passions to that

    pitch of moderation, which the impartial spectator can entirely enter into

    them. (p. 132)Camerer and Loewenstein (2004) also quote Smith who stated, we suffer

    morewhen we fall from a better to worse situation, than we ever enjoy when we rise

    from a worse to better (p. 4). The authors argue this is a clear demonstration of the

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    16/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 16concept of loss aversion discussed previously. One can hardly argue against Smith

    believing psychological factors influenced economic behavior.Keynes has also been the focus of many behavioral economists suggesting, like

    Smith, he also considered behavioral factors important to economic thought. Pech and

    Milan (2009) explore Keynes work for links to behavioral economics arguing his

    research is filled with references to psychological underpinnings. One of the key

    findings the researchers argue is that Keynes made numerous references to the

    concept of heuristics common to behavioral economic theory. Pech and Milan cite

    Keynes (1964) who states:

    It would be foolish, in forming our expectations, to attach great weight to

    matters which are very uncertain. It is reasonable, therefore, to be guided

    to a considerable degree by the facts about which we feel somewhat

    confident, even though they may be less decisively relevant to the issue

    than other factors about which our knowledge is vague and scant. (p. 148)Pech and Milan (2009) argue this passage is a clear link to the availability

    heuristic. The authors go on to argue Keynes work has ties to behavioral economics

    citing numerous passages from Keynes writing using the word psychological and/or

    psychology. Pech and Milan also argue Keynes thoughts had ties to other heuristics

    such as representativeness and anchoring.

    Criticisms of Behavioral EconomicsDespite the research suggesting behavioral economic thinking provides a new

    means of contributing to the body of knowledge within the field of economics, criticisms

    still exist, making behavioral economics a somewhat controversial field of study. The

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    17/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 17critics argue a number of points such as, experimentally observed behavior does not

    accurately mimic the true market (Myagkov & Plott, 1997), and that markets will cancel

    out individual psychology (Stewart, 2005).

    Over the past several decades behavioral experiments have been replicated

    numerous times with similar results, providing an argument the conclusions reached

    through early experimentation have validity (Camerer, Loewenstein, & Rabin, 2004;

    Rabin, 1998). Conventional economists continue to believe individual behavior is not

    significant enough to shift markets, and behavioral economists agree (Stewart, 2005)

    more work is needed to push their side of the argument further, suggesting the

    controversial nature of this research is likely to continue into the future. What is

    abundantly clear is that both sides of the argument want to continue to develop the field

    of economics in pursuit of greater understanding, which is likely to result if existing

    theories continue to be challenged.

    Happiness EconomicsAristotle was believed to have stated, happiness is the meaning and purpose of

    life, the whole aim and end of human existence (Schwerin, n.d., p. 4). Little argument is

    needed that living a happy life is desirable, but what can be argued is what leads to

    happiness, and whether greater understanding of happiness is of value in the field of

    economics. Research on happiness amongst economists was nearly non-existent three

    decades ago, but has since risen in popularity, reaching over one thousand economic

    journal articles having happiness in the title as of 2007 (Clark, Frijters, & Shields,

    2008).

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    18/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 18Graham (2009) describes happiness economics as an approach to assessing

    welfare which combines the techniques typically used by economists with those more

    commonly used by psychologists (p. 6). Similar to behavioral economics in relation to

    psychological factors, happiness was a focus of early philosophers and economists

    such as Aristotle, Bentham, Mill and Smith, but as a transition to a more quantitative

    approach in economics progressed less emphasis was put into understanding the

    subjective concept of happiness (Graham). Believing all humans act in a rational

    manner, neoclassical economists have been challenged in their assumptions related to

    maximizing utility, which leads one to argue that choices such as those related to

    selecting a job are based purely on quantitative measures such as salary. Happiness

    economists have challenged this assumption suggesting that despite the opportunity to

    earn a higher salary many individuals often choose a job with lower compensation that

    provides a greater level of happiness. If, as happiness economists argue, individuals

    seek not to maximize utility, but to balance utility with happiness, then the challenge

    becomes measuring and understanding what leads to happiness.

    Measuring HappinessAs the study of happiness has emerged several methods for measuring the

    construct have been utilized. The primary method of measurement is through survey

    data represented by a number of questions asked to participants related to their current

    level of happiness. The process of surveying individuals has ranged from highly

    complex systems to simple multiple-choice questions.In early happiness research conducted by Cantril (1965) participants from 14

    countries were surveyed using what the researcher describes as a self anchoring

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    19/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 19striving scale. Representing the more complex method of measuring happiness,

    Cantrils approach began by asking individuals to describe a life that they would be

    happy living in the future. The researcher asked probing questions to help participants

    describe their hopes and dreams related to creating a happy future. On the opposite

    end of the spectrum participants were asked to describe what would make them

    unhappy. Using the two extremes as anchoring points, individuals were then asked to

    rate their current level of happiness on a scale of zero (the worst life) to 10 (the best

    life).Using a more simplistic approach, organizations such as Gallup and the National

    Opinion Research Center (NORC) have utilized multiple-choice questions to gauge the

    level of happiness in respondents from around the world. Early research by Gallup

    asked whether an individual was very happy, fairly happy, or not very happy (Easterlin,

    1974). NORC has used a similar question since 1972 in the General Social Survey

    (GSS) that asks participants whether they are not too happy, pretty happy, or very

    happy (Brooks, 2008). Whether a more complex evaluation such as Cantrils is used, or

    a more simplistic version such as that of Gallup, the concept of happiness both measure

    is the same (Easterlin, 1974). In either case the individual is believed to be the best

    judge of their own feelings.

    The measurement of happiness is far from a perfect science. Issues can arise

    based on where happiness questions are placed within a survey, but overall agreement

    of the aforementioned methods have been widely accepted in the happiness economics

    literature (Brooks, 2008; Graham, 2009; Hagerty & Veenhoven, 2003; Stevenson &

    Wolfers, 2008).

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    20/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 20Evolution of Happiness Economics

    The study of happiness economics has greatly evolved over the last half century,

    and greater understanding into what leads to happiness has grown exponentially as

    data from countries around the world has been collected an analyzed. Cantril (1965)

    offers some of the earliest insights into happiness research. Studying the happiness of

    Americans in the 1960s, Cantril uncovered common themes among participants as they

    described their hopes and dreams during the process of establishing the

    aforementioned anchoring scale. Table 1 includes the most frequently mentioned items

    leading to happiness. To summarize the results Cantril grouped the items into

    categories shown in Table 2.Item Percent Response

    Own health 40%Decent standard of living 33%

    Children 29%Housing 24%

    Happy family 18%Family health 16%Leisure time 11%

    Table 1. Items most frequently mentioned by Americans when discussing their hopes

    and dreams. From Cantril, H. (1965). The pattern of human concerns. New Jersey, NJ:

    Rutgers University Press.

    Category Percent ResponseEconomic 65%

    Health 48%Family 47%

    Personal values 20%

    Status quo 11%Job or work situation 10%

    Table 2. Categories of items most frequently mentioned by Americans when discussing

    their hopes and dreams. From Cantril, H. (1965). The pattern of human concerns. New

    Jersey, NJ: Rutgers University Press.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    21/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 21Cantrils (1965) research provided some of the impetus for Easterlins (1974)

    seminal work in happiness economics. Easterlin is largely credited as establishing the

    field of happiness economics (Brooks, 2008; Graham, 2009; Hagerty & Veenhoven,

    2003; Wolfers & Stevenson, 2008). In his early work the researcher sought to

    understand whether or not a positive relationship exists between economic growth and

    happiness. Easterlin analyzed data from a variety of surveys that included Gallup,

    NORC, and the American Institute of Public Opinion (AIPO). In the analysis Easterlin

    first reviewed data from within countries before moving on to a comparison between

    countries.

    Easterlins (1974) findings suggest a positive correlation between income and

    happiness exists within countries. In each of the surveys the higher earning

    respondents were happier on average than the lower earners. Easterlins analysis also

    uncovered a positive correlation between happiness and years of education. The data

    also suggests married people are happier than unmarried, younger individuals are

    happier than older ones, and whites are happier than other races. Even though

    correlation does not mean causation, Easterlin argues, I am inclined to interpret the

    data as primarily showing a causal connection running from income to happiness (p.

    104). The researcher bases his conclusion on the responses of participants who

    overwhelmingly state personal economic concerns are directly tied to their levels of

    happiness.

    In the comparison of countries Easterlin (1974) states, if there is a positive

    association among countries between income and happiness it is not very clear (p.

    108). This conclusion is in conflict with Cantrils (1965) research studying 14 countries a

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    22/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 22decade earlier in which a positive correlation was uncovered. Easterlins final

    conclusion, working with time series data from the U.S. from 1946-1970, creates the last

    element in what has become known as the Easterlin Paradox (Graham, 2009, p. 12).

    Analyzing the time series data, Easterlin concludes that even though income levels

    were higher in 1970 than they were in 1946 the percentage of very happy people did not

    change significantly. In explaining this phenomenon Easterlin cites Duesenberrys

    (1952) relative income explanation, which suggests that unless an individuals income

    rises at a greater rate than those in which comparisons are made, a feeling of greater

    wealth will not be realized. In a sense, argues Easterlin, individuals are constantly

    comparing their wealth with that of others and when it is rising at the same rate as

    others a greater sense of wealth is not achieved. From Easterlins work three elements

    have come to establish the Easterlin Paradox. They include:

    1. Within a society richer are happier than poorer.

    2. Rich societies tend not to be happier than poorer (once basic needs are met).

    3. As countries get richer they do not get happier. (Wolfers, 2008)

    Since Easterlins groundbreaking work, the field of happiness economics has

    been filled with controversy related to the Easterlin Paradox. Some researchers have

    found small effects between happiness and national income (Hagerty, 2000; Oswald,

    1997) while others have found none (Diener & Oishi, 2000; Easterlin, 1995). Recent

    research by Hagerty and Veenhoven (2003) and Wolfers and Stevenson (2008) appear

    to be helping establish an argument suggesting increased levels of happiness are

    related to rising national income levels.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    23/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 23Using the World Database of Happiness (Veenhoven, 1999) that includes data

    from 21 countries, 9 of which are developing nations, Hagerty and Veenhoven (2003)

    argue that increasing national income is positively correlated to increasing happiness.

    Based on their analysis the researchers reject Easterlins claim that an individuals

    happiness is not dependant on absolute income, but on their income relative to others.

    In a rebuttal to the Hagerty and Veenhoven paper, Easterlin (2004) argues against their

    conclusions using the U.S. GSS data illustrated in Figure 2. As the data clearly

    illustrates, argues Easterlin, despite a rise in GDP per capita the percentage of

    individuals stating they are very happy has not changed.

    Figure 2. Trends in per capita GDP and percentage of individuals stating they are very

    happy. From Davis, J. A., Smith, T. W., & Marsden, P. V. (2008). General Social Survey

    1972-2006. Chicago: National Opinion Research Center.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    24/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 24The reason Easterlin (2004) argues Hagerty and Veenhoven (2003) arrived at a

    different conclusion is due to the use of survey data not included in the GSS from 1972-

    1974. Hagerty and Veenhoven acknowledge the inclusion of the additional survey data

    in their paper stating that sampling design and administration may have differed, which

    Easterlin does not agree with. Easterlin suggests that the difference in results are due to

    seasonal and context effects (the GSS is conducted in spring when happiness is

    higher).

    The most recent challenge to the Easterlin Paradox has come from Wolfers and

    Stevenson (2008). Their research that used recent data collected from the Gallup World

    Poll argues against the paradox suggesting richer people are happier, richer countries

    are happier than poorer countries, and as countries increase their wealth happiness

    also increases. Figure 3 illustrates the relationship between average life satisfaction and

    per capita GDP. Although the Gallup data measures life satisfaction, an overall measure

    of well-being, and not happiness, Wolfers and Stevenson argue that correlations

    between life satisfaction and happiness show the two are quite similar measures. With

    more data continuing to be collected, the argument between happiness and wealth is

    likely to continue into the future. Perhaps, as the data set continues to grow, happiness

    economist will begin to consolidate their views, and the argument for or against the

    Easterlin Paradox will be settled. Until then energy may well be better spent focusing on

    non-income related factors to happiness.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    25/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 25

    Figure 3. Relationship between average life satisfaction and per capita GDP. Size of

    circle is relative to population of country. From Deaton, A. (2008). Income, health, and

    well-being around the world: Evidence from the Gallup world poll. Journal of Economic

    Perspectives, 22(2), 53-72.Application of Happiness Economics

    While significant debate continues related to income and happiness, most

    happiness researchers agree that certain factors such as education, religion, marital

    status, age, health, and employment are positively related to happiness (Graham,

    2009). Certain activities such as volunteering, charitable giving, and participating in

    religious events have also been shown to increase happiness (Brooks, 2008).

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    26/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 26If happiness economists are mostly in agreement with the aforementioned

    factors, perhaps the next question facing researchers should be what to do with this

    knowledge. How can society use happiness data to increase overall well-being?

    Graham (2009) argues that happiness research should be used for better

    understanding inequality and poverty, and setting policy related to individual welfare and

    controlling addictive substances. Studying happiness may also provide exciting

    opportunities to improve worker productivity. Research suggests that happier workers

    tend to perform better and have increased future earning potential (Diener, Sandvik,

    Seidlitz, & Diener, 1993; Graham, Eggers, & Sukhtankar, 2004). With time, more

    research into happiness is bound to uncover new opportunities to better understand

    what leads to increased levels of happiness, and how capitalizing on this knowledge

    can help create a better society.

    Criticisms of Happiness EconomicsThe study of happiness is not without criticisms. The subjective measurement of

    happiness is perhaps the most significant criticism facing the field of happiness

    economics. Nearly all happiness data is based on individual survey responses, and

    based on the time of year (Easterlin, 2004) or even the time of day (Layard, 2004),

    levels of happiness tend to fluctuate.

    Despite these fluctuations and the subjectivity of happiness measures, an

    argument can be made that the conclusions dating back to research conducted by

    Cantril (1965) in the 1960s proceeding on through to the most recent research suggest

    a very consistent theme in what makes individuals happy. In spite of its subjectivity,

    happiness research has been consistent in elements such as wealth within a country,

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    27/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 27education, health, age, and marital status. New developments in neuroscience have

    also provided further evidence that the subjective nature of happiness can be measured

    through brain activity (Layard, 2004). Happy feelings tend to stimulate the left pre-frontal

    cortex, while negative feelings stimulate the right. Moving forward, neuroscience may

    offer a more quantitative method of measuring happiness, giving the field of study

    greater credibility.

    The bright spot in the happiness economics research suggests that many of the

    elements leading to increased happiness are within an individuals control. An argument

    can be made that an individuals behavior and the decisions they make play a

    significant role in determining their current and future potential happiness. Bad

    decisions related to happiness factors such as financial savings, education, physical

    and mental health, and employment may lead to lower levels of happiness. Tideman

    (2005) argues that conventional economics does not help society in the pursuit of

    happiness, having left out the psychological elements that arguably play a key role in

    happiness. Perhaps one solution lies in using the concepts found in behavioral

    economics to help individuals make better decisions that lead to a higher probability of

    creating happiness.

    Increasing Happiness Through Behavioral EconomicsCan behavioral economic thinking help make the world a happier place? While a

    paper such as this cannot fully explore the answer to this question, an attempt will be

    made to provide an argument for areas in which behavioral economic thinking has the

    opportunity to positively influence individual happiness. These areas include education,

    financial planning, and health care. The focus is not so much on providing detailed

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    28/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 28solutions, although some suggestions are offered, but more so on arguments related to

    the areas in which behavioral economists (or those acting as behavioral economists)

    could have the potential to make a positive impact on happiness. A final point of

    discussion is related to what is perhaps the most significant barrier to sustained

    happiness-materialism.Choice Architecture, Libertarian Paternalism, and Nudges

    One could argue a great deal of unhappiness is related to bad choices

    individuals make throughout their lives. Deciding not to finish high school or go to

    college, taking out a mortgage that is beyond ones means, not saving for retirement,

    eating an unhealthy diet, living a sedentary life that leads to obesity and eventually

    health issues, and abusing drugs and alcohol are all examples of poor choices. While

    many of these decisions may lead to short-term happiness they are highly unlikely to

    garner happiness over the course of ones lifetime.Many of the bad decisions individuals make are due to heuristics, or rules of

    thumb, discussed previously. The research conducted by Tversky and Kahneman

    (1974) clearly indicates individuals often times take shortcuts in making decisions that

    lead to undesirable results. To combat the probability of making bad decisions,

    behavioral economists have the ability to become what Thaler and Sunstein (2009)

    describe as choice architects (p. 3). The authors describe a choice architect as having

    the responsibility for organizing the context in which people make decisions (p. 3).

    A simple example in choice architecture can be described using the analogy of

    creating elementary school lunch selections (Thaler & Sunstein, 2009). Designing a

    school lunch menu can be based on several factors such as choosing food randomly to

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    29/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 29increase choice options, focusing on profit maximization by choosing low cost/high

    margin foods, or arranging food to help students make healthy selections. From a

    conventional economic perspective one would choose to maximize profit, although

    unhealthy eating in elementary school may lead to an adult life of unhealthy eating,

    ultimately resulting in long-term health issues such as obesity. Thaler and Sunstein

    argue that a choice architect will select the healthy choice for students, which is in the

    best interest of the student, but does not necessarily prohibit them from making an

    alternative selection such as bringing their own lunch or eating somewhere else. Choice

    architecture is based in the concept the authors describe as libertarian paternalism (p.

    4). Libertarian suggests the freedom of individuals to make their own decisions, while

    paternalism centers on the idea of paternalistic oversight that helps in making good

    decisions that lead to living healthier happy lives.

    At first the concept may seem like someone else is making decisions for

    individuals without their input, but as Thaler and Sunstein (2009) suggest, libertarian

    paternalists want to make it easy for people to go their own way; they do not want to

    burden those who want to exercise their freedom (p. 5). The authors describe this

    process of helping individuals make decisions as a nudge (p. 6). A nudge can be

    defined as any aspect of the choice architecture that alters peoples behavior in a

    predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic

    incentives (p. 6). Choice architecture, libertarian paternalism, and nudging may be one

    way in which behavioral economists can help increase happiness.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    30/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 30Nudging Toward Happiness

    One can easily argue the U.S. could use a nudge when it comes to education,

    personal financial management, and health care. The previously discussed happiness

    research suggests that each of these areas has an impact on individual happiness,

    providing three potential areas in which behavioral economic thinking could help

    improve individual happiness.

    As the old adage suggests, higher learning leads to higher earning, and what is

    consistent throughout the happiness data is the relationship between happiness and

    income and higher education. Higher earners and those with more education tend to be

    happier than less educated lower earners (Graham, 2009). Despite the improvement in

    high school dropout rates in the U.S., which have declined from 14 percent in 1980 to

    eight percent in 2008 (U.S. Department of Education, 2010), there are still over one

    million students who dropout of high school each year (Alliance for Excellent Education,

    2009). Clearly, a nudge that could help entice students to stay in school, and even

    better still go on to college, would help increase the chances for happiness. One

    potential nudge could come in the form of tempting students who have graduated high

    school and are in college to become mentors to those still in high school. Research

    suggests that while parents play a key role in helping their children succeed in school a

    greater influence to success is played by those they interact with the most (peers,

    teachers, etc.) (Levitt & Dubner, 2005). Providing a financial incentive to potential

    mentors, such as tuition reimbursement, may also help nudge them to become mentors

    for high school students. An added side benefit may be that the mentors also go on to

    graduate from college, which is highly likely to impact their future level of happiness.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    31/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 31Personal savings is another area in which behavioral economic thinking may help

    to increase happiness. Surprisingly, even though the mainstream media continues to

    bombard the public with the challenges of funding Social Security and the need to

    establish individual retirement savings accounts, 27 percent of individuals report they

    have less than $1,000 in savings and 54 percent have less than $25,000 in investments

    (Employee Benefit Research Institute, 2010). Thaler and Sunstein (2009) offer two

    suggestions that may help provide the nudge needed to increase personal savings. One

    suggestion is to make the default option for employer funded 401(k) retirement savings

    programs to automatically enroll employees at a level that takes advantage of company

    matched investment. Employees still have the option to pull out of the plan, but by

    making enrollment the default Thaler and Sunstein argue more are likely to stay in than

    opt out. Another suggestion by the authors is what they call the save more tomorrow

    (p. 105) plan. This technique allows an employee to automatically invest future

    increases in earnings into a savings plan. Since the employee never receives the

    increase on their paycheck by selecting this option they never miss the added income.

    Health care is another area in which behavioral economic thinking may provide

    an opportunity to improve happiness. There is no question Americans have an obesity

    problem as the number of individuals considered obese has risen dramatically since

    1990 when no state had an obesity level greater than 15 percent to what in 2009 has

    increased to only two states having less than 20 percent, and 33 states greater than or

    equal to 25 percent (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, 2010). As the U.S.

    population grows larger, figuratively and literally, health care costs are likely to continue

    increasing. One could argue the irrational behavior of consumers has had a dramatic

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    32/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 32affect on their health, and behavioral economic thinking may provide some answers into

    helping individuals make healthier choices. Some suggestions might be to give healthy

    individuals the opportunity to pay lower health care premiums by completing routine

    annual exams proving they are living a healthy lifestyle, and forcing those who do not

    have the exams to pay higher premiums. This suggestion is no different than the

    process used to price auto insurance policies for those who pose a greater risk. Better

    caloric labeling of foods has helped to inform consumers as to what they are buying, but

    the temptation is still high when healthy choices are intermixed with unhealthy options.

    Another suggestion could be to mandate a segregation of unhealthy food from healthy

    food in grocery stores to make it easier for consumers to avoid high calorie foods. An

    even more radical proposition may be to enact an obesity tax for airline travelers who

    are overweight. Stepping on a scale before getting on a plane and having to pay an

    additional fee is bound to change some individuals behavior.

    There are certainly a multitude of others ways in which behavioral economic

    thinking presents an opportunity to increase happiness solely on the choices individuals

    are faced with. Many of the decisions individuals make are based on the default options

    given, which creates a number of arguments as to who chooses the default options, and

    who determines which are the best for society. There is no simple solution, but as

    Thaler and Sunstein (2009) argue, the goal of choice architecture is not to force

    individuals into a decision, but to help them increase the probability of choosing wisely.

    Even if individuals make better decisions as a result of behavioral economic thinking,

    another ever-increasing hurdle to happiness continues to threaten society-materialism.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    33/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 33Materialism and Happiness

    Bogle (2009) describes an interesting conversation between Kurt Vonnegut and

    Joseph Heller, both famous authors, at a party on Shelter Island that is hosted by a

    billionaire hedge fund manager. Vonnegut tells Heller that their host has made more

    money in one day than he has made over the entire history of his popular novel Catch-

    22, to which Heller responds, yes, but I have something he will never haveenough

    (p. 1). The concept of enough Heller describes is similar to what has become a common

    argument by happiness economists as to the reason happiness has not significantly

    increased despite the twofold rise in GDP per capita in the past 34 years (see Figure 2).

    Economists describe the phenomenon as a hedonic treadmill (Graham, 2009, p. 15),

    which suggests that once basic needs are met human aspirations continue to rise, and

    changes in income are measured in relative rather than absolute terms. A more

    common phrase used by many to describe this situation is keeping up with the

    Joneses. In effect, a point of reaching enough is never achieved, thus, individuals

    continue to pursue more, always chasing the elusive situation of having enough. This

    analogy leads to the question; if an individual can never achieve or have enough will

    they ever be able to reach a maximum state of happiness?

    It is unlikely that behavioral economics will be a panacea to all problems related

    to happiness such as materialism, but the field of study offers some promising hope that

    by simply helping individuals make better choices they can live a much happier life.

    Tideman (2005) argues the bigger challenge for economists lies in changing the warped

    sense of progress that is tied primarily to growing levels of GDP and corporate

    profitability, much like societys measure of individual prosperity that is heavily rooted in

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    34/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 34material wealth. Behavioral economics may not be the solution Tideman is searching

    for, but it is likely to help emphasize those non-materialistic elements that lead to

    happiness, which could someday help society focus less on material wealth as the

    primary source of happiness and measure of success.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    35/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 35References

    Alliance for Excellent Education (2009). High school dropouts in America. Retrieved

    November 29, 2010 from

    http://www.all4ed.org/files/GraduationRates_FactSheet.pdf

    Angner, E., & Loewenstein, G. (2007). Behavioral economics. Manuscript in

    preparation. Retrieved November 29, 2010 from

    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=957148

    Ariely, D. (2008). Predictably Irrational: The hidden forces that shape our decisions.

    New York: HarperCollins Publishers.

    Ariely, D. (2009). The end of rational economics. Harvard Business Review, 7(8), 78-84.

    Arrow, K. J. (1971). Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Chicago: Markham.

    Ashraf, N., Camerer, C. F., & Loewenstein, G. (2005). Adam Smith, behavioral

    economist. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 131-145.

    Bogle, J. (2009). Enough. True Measures of Money, Business, and Life. Hoboken, NJ:

    John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

    Brooks, A. C. (2008). Gross national happiness: Why happiness matters for America

    and how we can get more of it. New York: Basic Books.

    Camerer, C. F. (2006). Discussion of behavioral economics. Retrieved November 29,

    2010 from http://arielrubinstein.tau.ac.il/papers/behavioral-economics.pdf

    Camerer, C. F., & Loewenstein, G. (2004). Behavioral economics: Past, present, future.

    In C. Camerer, G. Loewenstein, & M. Rabin (eds.)Advances in behavioral

    economics (pp. 3-51). New York and Princeton: Russell Sage Foundation Press

    and Princeton University Press.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    36/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 36Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (2004).Advances in behavioral

    economics. New York and Princeton: Russell Sage Foundation Press and

    Princeton University Press.

    Canterbery, E. R. (2001).A brief history of economics: Artful approaches to the dismal

    science. River Edge, NJ: World Scientific Publishing Company.

    Cantril, H. (1965). The pattern of human concerns. New Jersey, NJ: Rutgers University

    Press.

    Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (2010). Overweight and obesity. Retrieved

    November 29, 2010 from http://www.cdc.gov/obesity/data/trends.html

    Davis, J. B., Hands, D. W., & Maki, U. (1998). The handbook of economic methodology.

    Northampton, MA : Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Diamond, P., & Vartiainen, H. (2007). Behavioral economics and its application.

    Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Diener, E., & Oishi, S. (2000). Money and happiness: Income and subjective well-being

    across nations. In E. Diener & E. M. Suh (eds.) Subjective well-being across

    cultures (pp. 185-218). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Diener, E., Sandvik, E., Seidlitz, L., & Diener, M. (1993). The relationship between

    income and subjective well-being: Relative or absolute? Social Indicators

    Research, 28, 195-223.

    Deaton, A. (2008). Income, health, and well-being around the world: Evidence from the

    Gallup world poll. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(2), 53-72.

    Duesenberry, J. S. (1952). Income, saving and the theory of consumer behavior.

    Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    37/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 37Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical

    evidence. Retrieved October 4, 2010 from

    http://graphics8.nytimes.com/images/2008/04/16/business/Easterlin1974.pdf

    Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Will raising the income of all increase the happiness of all?

    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 35-47.

    Easterlin, R. A. (2004). Feeding the illusion of growth and happiness: A reply to Hagerty

    and Veenhoven. Retrieved November 29, 2010 from http://www-

    bcf.usc.edu/~easterl/papers/HVcomment.pdf

    Employee Benefit Research Institute (2010). The 2010 retirement confidence survey:

    Confidence stabilizing, but preparations continue to erode. Retrieved November

    29, 2010 from http://www.ebri.org/pdf/briefspdf/EBRI_IB_03-

    2010_No340_RCS.pdf

    Friedman, M., & Savage, L. J. (1948). The utility analysis of choices involving risks.

    Journal of Political Economy, 56(4), 279-304.

    Graham, C. (2009). Happiness around the world: The paradox of happy peasants and

    miserable millionaires. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Graham, C., Eggers, A., & Sukhtankar, S. (2004). Does happiness pay? An initial

    exploration based on panel data from Russia. Journal of Economic Behavior and

    Organization, 55, 319-342.

    Hagerty, M. R. (2000). Social comparisons of income in ones community: Evidence

    from national surveys of income and happiness. Journal of Personality and

    Social Psychology, 78(4), 746-771.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    38/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 38Hagerty, M. R., & Veenhoven, R. (2003). Wealth and happiness revisited: Growing

    wealth of nations does go with greater happiness. Social Indicators Research,

    64, 1-27.

    Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment

    effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspective, 5(1),

    193-206.

    Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under

    risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263-292.

    Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and

    value tradeoffs. New York: Wiley.

    Keynes, J. M. (1964). The general theory of employment, interest and money. New

    York: Harvest/Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Publishers.

    Layard, R. (2004). Happiness and public policy. Retrieved on November 29, 2010 from

    http://www.hpm.org/Downloads/partner_publications/Happiness_and_Public_Poli

    cy_LSE_DP14_2005.pdf

    Levitt, S. D., & Dubner, S. J. (2005). Freakonomics: A rogue economist explores the

    hidden side of everything. New York: HarperCollins Publishers.

    Mankiw, N. G. (2008). Principles of economics. Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage

    Learning.

    McDonald, I. M. (2008). For the student: Behavioral economics. The Australian

    Economic Review, 41(2), 222-228.

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    39/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 39Mullainathan, S., & Thaler, R. (2000). Behavioral economics. Working paper 7948.

    Retrieved November 29, 2010 from http://www.cours.ecn.ulaval.ca/cours/ECN-

    60214/Behavioraleconomics.pdf

    Myagkov, M., & Plott, C. R. (1997). Exchange economies and loss exposure:

    Experiments exploring prospect theory and competitive equilibria in market

    environments.American Economic Review, 87(5), 801-828.

    Oswald, A. J. (1997). Happiness and economic performance. The Economic Journal,

    107(445), 1815-1831.

    Pech, W., & Milan, M. (2009). Behavioral economics and the economics of Keynes.

    Journal of Socio-Economics, 38(6), 891-902.

    Rabin, M. (1998). Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1),

    11-46.

    Robbins, L. (1932).An essay on the nature and significance of economic science.

    London: Macmillan & Co., Limited.

    Schwerin, D. A. (n.d.). The economics of happiness. Retrieved November 29, 2010 from

    http://www.consciousthinking.com/economicsofhappiness.pdf

    Smith, A. (2007). The theory of moral sentiments. New York: Cosimo, Inc. (Original

    work published 1759)

    Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being:

    Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox. Retrieved November 23, 2010 from

    http://bpp.wharton.upenn.edu/jwolfers/Papers/EasterlinParadox.pdf

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    40/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 40Stewart, S. A. (2005). Can behavioral economics save us from ourselves? Retrieved

    November 23, 2010 from

    http://magazine.uchicago.edu/0502/features/economics.shtml

    Tideman, S. G. (2005). Mind over matter: Towards a new paradigm for business and

    economics. Retrieved November 21, 2010 from

    http://www.gpiatlantic.org/conference/papers/tideman.pdf

    Thaler, R. H. (1997). Irving Fisher: Modern behavioral economist. The American

    Economic Review, 87(2), 439-441.

    Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2009). Nudge: Improving decisions about health,

    wealth, and happiness. New York: Penguin Books.

    Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and

    biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124-1131.

    U.S. Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics. (2010). The

    Condition of Education 2010 (NCES 2010-028), Indicator 20. Retrieved

    November 29, 2010 from

    http://nces.ed.gov/programs/coe/2010/section3/indicator19.asp

    Veenhoven, R. (1999). World database of happiness. Retrieved November 29, 2010

    from http://www.eur.nl/fsw/research/happiness

    Veenhoven, R., & Hagerty, M. (2003). Wealth and happiness revisited. Retrieved

    October 12, 2010 from

    http://www2.eur.nl/fsw/research/veenhoven/Pub2000s/2003e-full.pdf

  • 8/8/2019 Behavioral and Happiness Economics-Scott Thor

    41/41

    Behavioral Economics and Happiness 41Wolfers, J. (2008, April 16). The economics of happiness, part 1: Reassessing the

    Easterlin Paradox. The New York Times. Retrieved November 29, 2010 from

    http://freakonomics.blogs.nytimes.com/2008/04/16/the-economics-of-happiness-

    part-1-reassessing-the-easterlin-paradox/

    Wolfers, J., & Stevenson, B. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being:

    Reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Retrieved October 22, 2010 from

    http://bpp.wharton.upenn.edu/betseys/papers/Happiness.pdf